Skip to main content
. 2023 Feb 21;20(5):3857. doi: 10.3390/ijerph20053857

Table 2.

Current Dutch payment models based on the typology of Quinn (2015) [35] and the HCP-LAN (2017) [36] and their (financial) incentives.

Payment Model Providers Incentivises Literature
Combination of contract capitation payment and fee for service General practitioner Positive
Fewer referrals
Adequate provision of care (no under- or overtreatment)
Preventive care
Negative
Collaboration not explicitly addressed
[20,47,48,49]
Fee for service (FFS) Physiotherapist, exercise therapist, speech therapist, dietician, and district nursing Positive
High productivity
Transparency of the delivered care
Negative
Overprovision
Unnecessary readmissions and diagnostics
Quality of care not explicitly addressed
Fragmentation of care
Preventive care not stimulated
[50,51,52,53]
Per time period Salary paid health care providers Positive
Cost-conscious behaviour
Negative
Undertreatment
Selection of patients
Low productivity which could result in longer waiting lists
Quality of care not explicitly addressed
Unnecessary referrals
[54,55,56]
Per episode (chronic care) The SDMPs for chronic diseases in primary care Positive
Integrated care (coordination and continuity)
Cost-conscious behaviour
High quality of care
Efficient care
Negative
Risk selection
‘Over-bundling’ *
Double billing
Unnecessary referrals
Undertreatment within the bundle
[14,50,57,58,59,60]
Per episode (1. DTCs in specialist care, 2. Per patient profile and time, and 3. Per treatment activity and time)
  1. Medical specialists

  2. General basic psychologists

  3. Specialist psychologists

Positive
Less fragmentation of care
Efficiency
Negative
Strategic declaration behaviour
Overprovision
Upcoding
[61,62,63]
Contract capitation in combination with a patient co-payment (€19 per month) Social care Positive
Wide access because of the low co-payment
Flexibility to tailor help to personal circumstances
Negative
Underuse because of accumulating co-payments
[64,65]
Pay for performance Alternative payment model Positive
Quality of care explicitly addressed
Transparency of care
Positive spill-over effects **
Negative
Negative spill-over effects **
Risk selection
Gaming behaviour
No incentive if threshold is met
Providers held accountable for outcomes they may not be able to influence
[37,40,41,66,67,68,69,70]
Shared savings model Alternative payment model Positive
Cost-conscious behaviour
Integrated care (coordination and continuity)
Preventive care
Quality of care (implicitly and explicitly)
Negative
Undertreatment
To drive the expenditures of the benchmark
[13,14,15,42,43,71,72,73,74]
(Sub)population—based bundled payment Alternative payment model Positive
Integrated care (coordination and continuity)
Quality of care
Cost-conscious behaviour
Preventive care
Negative
High risk for the contracting entity
Reduction of necessary care in the bundle
Less freedom of choice
Risk selection
[16,17,18,45]

Note: DMPs = disease management programmes, DTCs = disease-treatment combinations. * Over-bundling refers to the incentive to broaden the diagnoses, as to increase the target population for which a provider receives a bundled payment (e.g., including pre-diabetes patients at risk of developing diabetes in the bundled payment of diabetes patients). ** Positive spill-over effects occur when non-measured outcomes improve as well, as a consequence of the extra attention for the measured outcomes. Negative spill-over effects occur when a focus on measured outcomes leads to non-measured outcomes being neglected and deteriorating.