1. INTRODUCTION
Complaints about the U.S. pharmaceutical industry and its pricing are well known. Even after accounting for discounts and rebates, prices of leading brand‐name drugs in the United States are two to four times higher than they are in Canada, Japan, and many European countries. 1 Most new cancer drugs cost hundreds of thousands of dollars per patient annually, even though many seem to offer modest gains in life expectancy or lack such evidence at all. 2 , 3 Even some older, generic products like insulin have experienced dramatic price increases. Rising drug spending stretches already stretched public budgets. 4 , 5 Out‐of‐pocket spending for deductibles and coinsurance creates financial difficulties for individuals and their families, particularly among the sickest patients. 6 , 7 , 8 , 9
Critically, high prices for brand‐name drugs—rather than reflecting a policy flaw or “bug” in the system—is an expected and even intentional outcome. Monopolistic pricing is a system feature, designed to incentivize companies to invest in expensive and risky drug discovery that can take years by providing the prospect of a big payoff if the investment succeeds. The government grants firms that develop new drugs exclusive, though temporary, rights (through legally protected patents and market exclusivity) to sell their products and thus recoup their investments and earn profits. Congress has enhanced these exclusivity provisions to encourage certain policy goals (e.g., the Orphan Drug Act of 1983). Companies with new drugs can charge what the market will bear without worrying that a generic manufacturer will undercut their pricing. 10
When patents expire, generic drugs enter the marketplace and prices of brand‐name products fall, often precipitously, benefiting future generations of patients. Generics now comprise 90% of all prescriptions in the United States (though high and increasing prices of some generic drugs have also come under scrutiny, further highlighting the complexity of drug markets and the need for reforms). 11
But how much protection should patents and market exclusivity offer? How much is enough to incentivize drug development? At what point do high drug prices become an unnecessary and excessive industry windfall?
2. PROPOSED SOLUTIONS FOR RISING DRUG PRICES
Taking action on prescription drug prices has attracted bipartisan support. 12 , 13 , 14 , 15 , 16 Some of the proposals are as follows: rein in the “middlemen”; increase competition; align U.S. drug prices with the lower prices available in other wealthy countries; and leverage the government's bargaining power. Each has challenges.
2.1. Cutting out the middleman
Pharmaceutical benefits managers (PBMs)—entities that negotiate with drug manufacturers on behalf of insurers and manage high‐cost specialty medications—use volume‐buying leverage to negotiate discounts from manufacturers. 17 They seek the return of revenue in the form of “rebates.” Because patient co‐payments can depend on a drug's list price (not the net price after rebates), those co‐payments often remain elevated if the PBM negotiates a substantial rebate (returned to the insurance company) rather than a reduced list price. 18 Proposed measures aim to funnel gains to customers but they do not always have the intended effect because in “converting” PBM rebates to consumer discounts, drug manufacturers would reduce the rebates, and that would, in turn, raise premiums. 19
2.2. Lower prices through competition
Competition from generics has reduced prices for many drugs, 20 but their introduction can be hampered by regulatory delays. 21 , 22 Moreover, some off‐patent drugs enjoy temporary de facto monopoly status because they are produced by a single manufacturer, or serve small markets or benefit from a closed distribution system. 23
Policymakers have proposed various measures, such as increasing food and drug administration (FDA) funding for generic drug application reviews. 24 , 25 Keeping prices low for generics, however, would have little effect on drug prices in the aggregate because the drugs most likely to lack real generic competition tend to serve small markets and hence add little to overall drug spending. 26 Other proposals target tactics brand‐name drug companies use to delay the introduction of generics, though the resulting savings would likely be modest because the courts and Federal Trade Commission challenges have already addressed the most egregious cases. 27 , 28 For biosimilars—near copies of complex pharmaceuticals that are grown, rather than manufactured—some have proposed simply mandating lower prices once the 12‐year exclusivity period for the originator biologic expires. 29
2.3. Importation
Allowing Americans to import prescription drugs from Canada is a popular concept 8 but would trigger other effects. One study found that Canadian drug supplies would be exhausted in under 8 months if the United States imported even 10% of its prescription drugs from its northern neighbor. 30
2.4. International reference pricing
“Reference pricing” means that drug companies can charge no more for their products in the United States than a benchmark reflecting what they charge elsewhere (e.g., in selected European countries). 31 , 32 In theory, savings could be substantial, 1 but by adopting other countries' prices, the United States would implicitly embrace the preferences for trade‐offs from those countries and hence their notions of value.
2.5. Direct negotiations
Medicare negotiates Part D drug prices indirectly through the many private plans that administer the program, though those entities have limited leverage because each covers only a fraction of the Medicare population. 33 Proposed legislation would eliminate Medicare's “noninterference” clause and require the Secretary of Health and Human Services to negotiate to reduce drug prices. 34 In March, Senate Democrats introduced the Medicare Drug Price Negotiation Act, which would enhance Medicare's purchasing power by (a) allowing the program to use benefit design and formulary tools employed by commercial insurers to extract greater discounts and rebates; and (b) establishing “fallback” prices based on an index of prices paid by other federal agencies and key countries. 35
In addition to the concerns raised above on reference pricing, the proposed legislation has its own trade‐offs. Any credible negotiator must be willing to walkaway from the table—that is, deny access to a drug if its price is not acceptable. 36 Various proposals, for example, imposing binding arbitration, 37 ostensibly avoid such outright denials, but they risk reduced future innovation and patient health.
2.6. Eliminating patent protection
A more radical strategy would remove patent protection and have the government directly fund drug development. Of course, there are issues. Most federally funded research (over 90%) 38 cannot substitute for drug company product‐specific development because it instead focuses on basic research questions that facilitate the development of multiple therapies. 38 ,pp. 91–96, Importantly, someone must still assess the downstream value of products because research must be prioritized.
In sum, the proposed solutions have their own challenges, and many are incremental in nature. Moreover, while policy prescriptions focus unsurprisingly on reducing drug prices, they sidestep the question of what prices are “reasonable” or “fair.” Value‐based pricing answers that question by aligning prices with the value of a drug's benefits.
3. MEASURING THE VALUE OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
Although drug companies retain exclusive marketing rights for drugs prior to their going generic, their pricing power faces limits. Beyond government rules that influence and constrain prices, drug companies must also contend with competition from other brand‐name products, physician and patient demand for a product, 39 ,p.47 limits on what the market can afford, and concerns about the “court of public opinion”—the idea that overly aggressive pricing will attract unwanted government intervention.
Drug companies price their products by forecasting product demand. Because some of the factors influencing these forecasts have little to do with perceived (patient) value, this kind of modeling does not necessarily result in value‐based pricing. A major factor is the role played by prescribing clinicians, whose incentives are often not perfectly aligned with their patients' interests. Another factor is the price of existing products, whether they are aligned with value. While drug prices often align with clinical benefit and the number of competitors, 40 there are exceptions—for example drugs introduced for more severe conditions command high prices regardless of the competition, 41 and prices for all drugs in a therapeutic class sometimes rise to meet a new entrant. 42 , 43 For certain drugs, pharmaceutical companies enjoy substantial leverage that persists for many years. 44
Although economists have used different approaches to value health programs, 45 , 46 , 47 , 48 , 49 the favored method in recent years has been cost‐effectiveness analysis (CEA). CEA expresses health gains using a standard metric—for example, quality‐adjusted life years (QALYs) gained—thus avoiding the need to monetize health benefits. It describes value as the ratio of an intervention's incremental costs to its incremental benefits. Smaller ratios, like lower prices, are more favorable because they indicate that an intervention produces health at a lower cost.
There are many controversies about appropriate practices. One pertains to perspective, which dictates the elements included in a study. A “health care sector” perspective includes the patient's health and costs incurred by the health care system, but it can omit important outcomes, such as effects on a patient's family. In contrast, a societal perspective accounts for everything that matters to somebody, including, for example, an intervention's impact on worker productivity or on a student's school performance.
In 2016, the Second Panel on Cost‐Effectiveness in Health and Medicine recommended that the health care sector and societal perspectives share top billing. 50 Still, most international health technology assessment guidelines and published cost‐effectiveness analyses prioritize a health care sector (or payer) perspective. 51 In many cases, the choice of perspective has a modest impact on results, 51 but in some cases, it can matter a lot (e.g., vaccines in a pandemic for which societal costs and benefits are immense). 52
The use of QALYs has also been controversial. QALYs account for both longevity and quality of life, but some argue they are not patient‐focused, that health insurers use them as rationing tools, and that quantifying the value of life with different health conditions is dehumanizing. 53 , 54 , 55 Critics complain that QALYs do not capture certain aspects of people's preferences (e.g., particular goals individuals have in treatment decisions). 56 People may prioritize treatments for severe diseases, even if it is inconsistent with QALY‐maximization. 57 , 58 A key objection is that QALYs discriminate against older and disabled individuals. 59 , 60
Determining the value of a QALY—that is, how much we ought to pay for each additional QALY—is a longstanding matter. For many years, most cost‐effectiveness analyses in the United States referenced a benchmark of $50 000 per QALY, despite its lack of a clear conceptual or empirical basis. 61 Research based on surveys and on trade‐offs people make when making real‐world purchasing decisions have yielded values from $1000 to $5.4 million per QALY. 62 , 63 , 64 , 65 Studies of how people might balance purchases of health care against purchases of other goods and services indicate people would be willing to pay about twice their annual incomes (or about $110,000 in the United States) for a QALY—and that as incomes increase, so does a QALY's value. 66 , 67 Other approaches that have examined how much it costs to improve health have estimated a QALYs value to generally be less than each country's GDP per capita. 68 , 69 , 70 , 71 , 72
A reasonable question is whether value assessments need QALYs at all. For example, Germany's assessment agency does not use QALYs. If a new drug provides no more clinical benefit than drugs already available, Germany does not pay any more for the new drug than for the available alternatives. If a new drug does confer added benefit, the national association of insurers negotiates a price with the manufacturer. France's approach is similar.
Although Germany and France boast drug prices substantially below U.S. prices, their approaches have limitations. 73 Although the relative prices for drugs treating the same condition may seem sensible (e.g., drugs with no added benefits have the same price as existing drugs), the lack of a common metric, like the QALY, means that these systems cannot readily compare spending across diseases. Moreover, the trade‐offs and values behind their negotiations are opaque. Finally, in some cases, Germany and France rely on reference pricing—that is, drug prices set by other countries—thus importing the decision making criteria from countries, including in some cases use of the QALY.
4. TOWARD VALUE‐BASED PRICING FOR DRUGS
Several issues must be addressed for value‐based pricing to advance in the United States. First, payers must insist on value as a criterion for reimbursement. For public payers, new legislation would be helpful. For example, Congress could grant Medicare authority to directly negotiate drug prices based on value. By itself, that move would put much of the nation's medication purchases within a value‐based regime.
Because private payers often follow Medicare's example, such legislation could also promote value‐based pricing in the commercial insurance market. That impact would be important, as few private insurers openly promote the use of formal value assessments to align drug prices with value.
There are some exceptions—for example, Premera Blue Cross, a regional plan in the Pacific Northwest, implemented a value‐based formulary benefit for its employees that assigned drugs to co‐payment tiers based on cost‐effectiveness. 74 CVS Caremark announced in 2018 that it would allow its client health plans to exclude coverage of high‐cost, “me‐too” drugs with cost‐effectiveness ratios exceeding $100,000 per QALY, as projected by the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review (ICER). 75 But while such initiatives have attracted attention, few other plans have adopted the models. Most commercial plans have been reluctant to use economic evaluations too openly. 76 ,pp. 23–25, 77
Congress could broaden the FDA's mandate to make drug approval contingent on a “fair” or “value‐based” price, though such a change would be ill‐advised. Determining whether a drug is safe and effective already taxes the FDA. Diverting the FDA's attention away from clinical matters toward economic concerns risks eroding its considerable public support. Judgments about value and reimbursement are better left to public and private payers who are better positioned to consider their budgets and their enrollees' characteristics.
Second, the question of who should conduct value assessments in the United States must be addressed. Although formal drug value assessment efforts worldwide tend to be carried out by government reimbursement authorities, 78 , 79 , 80 , 81 , 82 , 83 , 84 , 85 that approach has met with resistance in the United States. The Congressional Office of Technology Assessment was abolished in 1995. The Oregon Health plan, which famously attempted to develop a prioritized list of paired medical conditions and treatments based in part on cost‐effectiveness, proved controversial and was never attempted elsewhere. 76 The Medicare program for years attempted to incorporate cost‐effectiveness analysis into its decision making processes for new drugs and other technologies, but has been thwarted by legal and political hurdles. 86 The government‐funded technology assessment functions that have endured (e.g., U.S. Preventive Services Task Force) have focused on clinical (not economic) evidence, and on preventive services, rather than treatments. 87
Against this backdrop, the emergence of ICER is notable. Though it is a private, nonprofit organization with no regulatory authority or reimbursement responsibilities, ICER's clinical and economic assessments have garnered headlines and stirred debate about drug prices and affordability. 88 , 89 External parties (mostly drug companies) submit scores of comments during ICER's public input period. 90 When surveyed, health plan officials concur that ICER influences their price negotiations and conditions of reimbursement. 88 , 91 , 92 Some drug companies have even reduced their prices to earn a more favorable designation by ICER. 93 Certain state Medicaid programs and the Veterans Administration have attempted to use ICER's findings to obtain lower prices for drugs. 94 Though other organizations (e.g., the Americal Society of Clinical Oncology and the National Comprehensive Cancer Network) have issued their own value frameworks, they have played a more limited role and have proven hard to apply in practice.
ICER has wrestled with a host of methodological issues and controversies. For example, in response to criticisms that budget considerations (i.e., a drug's total cost across the whole population) should not be part of value determinations, ICER excluded a drug's budget impact from its calculation of a value price. 95 To allay concerns that the QALY discriminates, ICER has added a value calculation based on Equal Value of Life Years Gained (evLYG), which equally values any gains in length of life, regardless of a treatment's impact on quality of life. 96 ICER has also adopted elements of a societal perspective and now presents a modified societal perspective as a co‐base case for certain topics (when including societal impacts substantially influenced estimates). 97 p. 25
Some additional changes to ICER's approach would help to legitimize its role as a public resource—for example, elevating the societal perspective; accounting for price changes over a drug's life cycle (properly discounted); making the source code for its computer simulation models public (to make its science as transparent as possible) 98 ; and providing value‐based price estimates corresponding to a wide range of cost‐per‐QALY benchmarks. ICER points to the feasibility and sustainability of a private sector solution, but as a private organization lacking public accountability, the question of the legitimacy of ICER's role remains. Creating a new public health technology assessment institute, based on the ICER model, would be valuable, though the political hurdles to such an institute remain formidable. 99
Finally, a major source of resistance to value‐based pricing is the concern that it will not make drugs affordable and hence accessible. That concern reflects the reality that ensuring prices are in line with conventional cost‐effectiveness benchmarks of $100 000 per QALY—would still leave many therapies out of reach of most Americans. The solution, however, is not the abandonment of value‐based pricing. Rather, insurance should protect against such expenses. Instead, many insurers now impose high cost‐sharing requirements on patients or restrict access in other ways (e.g., step‐therapy protocols). 77 There is little evidence that co‐payment or restrictions reflect a therapy's value. 100 , 101 , 102 A better approach would encourage high‐value care and discourage low‐value care though value‐based insurance designs and restrictions that align with value. 102 Just as the government makes the COVID vaccines free to individuals to encourage their use, insurance should remove cost as a barrier to the use of other medicines that confer favorable value.
5. CONCLUSIONS
Pharmaceutical industry critics presume that much drug company revenue is superfluous, fueling excessive profits, inflated executive compensation, and wasteful spending on marketing and advertising. The implication is that drug company revenues could be reduced without affecting vital innovation. But attempting to discern how much revenue the drug industry “needs” for important innovation is an endless conundrum. Instead, revenue should be seen as a potent if imperfect signal to stimulate worthy technological advances. Prices and innovation are inextricably linked: higher prices and profits attract more investment, which in turn gives rise to more rapid innovation and more therapies.
The critical question is not how we can keep drug prices down. Constraining drug prices is easy, as the government could readily impose price controls and other measures. The important question is: what is a reasonable price for each drug? Paying too high a price diverts resources from better uses elsewhere. Paying too little fails to send industry suitable signals to incentivize the development of new drugs. The right price corresponds to value, measured appropriately.
Value‐based pricing may mean higher insurance premiums, possibly raising questions of health insurance affordability; if so, the value conferred by other types of health care and by nonhealth spending should be assessed. We are living in a time of remarkable scientific breakthroughs, but these advances come at a cost. In the end, paying value‐based prices, even as we strive to promote access to health care, makes sense because it helps ensure that drug companies produce more of what people want—products that improve people's health—while considering society's other pressing priorities.
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
This commentary is adapted from Neumann PJ, Cohen JT, Ollendorf DA, The Right Price: A Value‐Based Prescription for Drug Costs (Oxford University Press, 2021). The authors are grateful to Meghan Podolsky for excellent research assistance.
Neumann PJ, Ollendorf DA, Cohen JT. Value‐based drug pricing in the Biden era: Opportunities and prospects. Health Serv Res. 2021;56(6):1093–1099. 10.1111/1475-6773.13686
[Correction added on 17 June 2021, after first online publication: The acronym ICER was corrected to stand for the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review.]
REFERENCES
- 1. Kang S‐Y, DiStefano MJ, Socal MP, Anderson GF. Using external reference pricing in medicare part D to reduce drug price differentials with other countries. Health Affairs. 2019;38(5):804‐811. 10.1377/hlthaff.2018.05207. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 2. Rimer BK. The Imperative of Addressing Cancer Drug Costs and Value. Bethesda, Maryland: National Cancer Institute; 2018. https://www.cancer.gov/news-events/cancer-currents-blog/2018/presidents-cancer-panel-drug-prices, Accessed June 12, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- 3. Langreth R. Drug Prices. New York, NY: Bloomberg; 2020. https://www.bloomberg.com/quicktake/drug-prices, Accessed June 12, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- 4. National Health Expenditure Data: Historical. Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services. https://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/NationalHealthExpendData/NationalHealthAccountsHistorical, Accessed June 22, 2020
- 5. Anderson‐Cook A, Maeda J, Ding R, Patel YM, Nelson L. Prices for and spending on specialty drugs in Medicare part D and Medicaid; 2019. https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2019-03/54964-Specialty_Drugs.pdf, Accessed June 22, 2020
- 6. Claxton G, Levitt L, Rae M, Sawyer B. Increases in cost‐sharing payments continue to outpace wage growth. San Francisco, CA: Peterson‐Kaiser Family Foundation; 2018. https://www.healthsystemtracker.org/brief/increases-in-cost-sharing-payments-have-far-outpaced-wage-growth/#item-start, Accessed June 25, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- 7. Dusetzina SB, Huskamp HA, Keating NL. Specialty drug pricing and out‐of‐pocket spending on orally administered anticancer drugs in Medicare part D, 2010 to 2019. Jama. 2019;321(20):2025‐2028. 10.1001/jama.2019.4492. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 8. Kirzinger A, Lopes L, Wu B, Brodie M. KFF Health Tracking Poll: February 2019: Prescription Drugs. San Francisco, CA: Kaiser Family Foundation; 2019. https://www.kff.org/health-costs/poll-finding/kff-health-tracking-poll-february-2019-prescription-drugs/, Accessed June 25, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- 9. Cohen RA, Villaroel MA. Strategies Used by Adults to Reduce their Prescription Drug Costs: United States, 2013. Hyattsville, MD: National Center for Health Statistics; 2015. https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/databriefs/db184.pdf, Accessed June 25, 2020 [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 10. Lupkin S. Government‐protected 'monopolies' drive drug prices higher, study says. Kaiser Health News . https://khn.org/news/government-protected-monopolies-drive-drug-prices-higher-study-says/, Accessed July 1, 2020
- 11. Bai G, Sen AP, Anderson GF. Pharmacy benefit managers, brand‐name drug prices, and patient cost sharing. Ann Internal Med. 2018;168(6):436‐437. 10.7326/M17-2506. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 12. Grassley C. Grassley Op‐ed: Top priority is reducing health care costs. https://www.grassley.senate.gov/news/news-releases/grassley-op-ed-top-priority-reducing-health-care-costs, Accessed July 6, 2020
- 13. Grassley C. Grassley, Wyden invite 7 major pharmaceutical companies to drug pricing hearing. https://www.grassley.senate.gov/news/news-releases/grassley-wyden-invite-7-major-pharmaceutical-companies-drug-pricing-hearing, Accessed July 6, 2020
- 14. Whyte D. Top 10 pharmaceutical hubs in the USA; Proclinical. https://www.proclinical.com/blogs/2016-3/top-10-pharmaceutical-hubs-in-the-usa, Accessed August 3, 2020
- 15. Bebinger M. Baker outlines steps to lower medicaid drug prices. CommonHealth https://www.wbur.org/commonhealth/2019/01/24/baker-steps-lower-medicaid-drug-prices, Accessed July 6, 2020
- 16. Young S. Newson: California leads on prescription drugs. Kaiser Health News https://khn.org/news/newsom-california-leads-on-prescription-drugs/, Accessed July 6, 2020
- 17. Werble C. Pharmacy benefit managers. Health Affairs. 2017;12:1–4. 10.1377/hpb20171409.000178. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 18. Pharmacy benefit managers and their role in drug spending. Commonwealth Fund . https://www.commonwealthfund.org/publications/explainer/2019/apr/pharmacy‐benefit‐managers‐and‐their‐role‐drug‐spending, Accessed July 6, 2020
- 19. Incorporating the effects of the proposed rule on safe harbors for pharmaceutical rebates in CBO's budget projections – supplemental material for Updates Budget Projections: 2019 to 2029; 2019.
- 20. Generic competition and drug prices. U.S. Food & Drug Administration. https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/center-drug-evaluation-and-research-cder/generic-competition-and-drug-prices, Accessed July 6, 2020
- 21. Gupta R, Kesselheim AS, Downing N, Greene J, Ross JS. Generic drug approvals since the 1984 Hatch‐Waxman Act. JAMA Intern Med. 2016;176(9):1391‐1393. 10.1001/jamainternmed.2016.3411. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 22. Greene JA, Anderson G, Sharfstein JM. Role of the FDA in affordability of off‐patent pharmaceuticals. Jama. 2016;315(5):461‐462. 10.1001/jama.2015.18720. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23. Collins SM, McCaskill C. Sudden price spikes in off‐patent prescription drugs: the monopoly business model that harms patients, taxpayers, and the U.S. health care system; 2016.
- 24. Wouters OJ, Kanavos PG, Mc KM. Comparing generic drug markets in Europe and the United States: prices, volumes, and spending. Milbank Q. 2017;95(3):554‐601. 10.1111/1468-0009.12279. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 25. Engelberg AB, Avorn J, Kesselheim AS. Addressing generic drug unaffordability and shortages by globalizing the market for old drugs. Health Affairs. 2016. 10.1377/hblog20160223.053266. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 26. ASPE issue brief: Understanding recent trends in generic drug prices; 2016.
- 27. Barlas S. FTC gives generics victory on "pay for delay": reverse payments crimped, patent thickets untouched. P T. 2019;44(5):234‐266. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 28. Silverman E. Supreme Court lets pay‐to‐delay ruling against pharma stand. Stat https://www.statnews.com/pharmalot/2016/11/07/supreme-court-pay-delay-glaxo-teva/, Accessed July 7, 2020
- 29. Bach PB, Trusheim M. Time to throw in the towel on biosimilars. Wall Street Journal https://www.wsj.com/articles/time-to-throw-in-the-towel-on-biosimilars-11566428299, Accessed July 7, 2020
- 30. Martell A. Exclusive: Canada warns U.S. against drug import plans, citing shortage concerns. Reuters . https://www.reuters.com/article/us-canada-pharmaceuticals-exports-exclus/exclusive-canada-warns-us-against-drug-import-plans-citing-shortage-concerns-idUSKCN1UD2LN, Accessed July 7, 2020
- 31. Roy A. Trump's dramatic new proposal to lower Medicare drug prices by linking to an international index. Forbes https://www.forbes.com/sites/theapothecary/2018/10/26/trumps-dramatic-new-proposal-to-lower-medicare-drug-prices-by-linking-to-an-international-index/#71494474c3a1, Accessed July 7, 2020
- 32. ANPRM international pricing index model for Medicare part B drugs; 2018. https://www.cms.gov/newsroom/fact-sheets/anprm-international-pricing-index-model-medicare-part-b-drugs
- 33. McCaughan M. Health policy brief, prescription drug pricing #6: medicare part d. Health Affairs. 2017;6:1–4. 10.1377/hpb20171008.000172. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 34. Cubanski J, Neuman T, True S, Freed M. What's the latest on Medicare drug price negotiations. Kaiser Family Foundation https://www.kff.org/medicare/issue-brief/whats-the-latest-on-medicare-drug-price-negotiations/, Accessed July 7, 2020
- 35. The Medicare Drug Price Negotiation Act of 2021; 2021. https://www.sanders.senate.gov/wp-content/uploads/Summary-The-Medicare-Drug-Price-Negotiation-Act.pdf
- 36. A detailed description of CBO's cost estimate for the Medicare prescription drug benefit (Congressional Budget Office); 2004.
- 37. Frank RG, Nichols LM. Medicare drug‐price negotiation—why now… and how. N Engl J Med. 2019;381(15):1404‐1406. 10.1056/NEJMp1909798. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 38. Gruber J, Johnson S. Jump‐Starting America: how Breakthrough Science Can Revive Economic Growth and the American Dream. Hachette Book Group: Public Affairs; 2019. [Google Scholar]
- 39. National Academies of Sciences Engineering Medicine . Making Medicines Affordable: A National Imperative. Washington, D.C: The National Academies Press; 2018:234. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 40. Ekelund M, Persson B. Pharmaceutical pricing in a regulated market. Rev Econ Stat. 2003;85(2):298‐306. 10.1162/003465303765299828. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 41. Tironi P. Pharmaceutical pricing: a review of proposals to improve access and affordability of prescription drugs. Annals of Health Law. 2010;19(2):65–311. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 42. Hartung DM, Bourdette DN, Ahmed SM, Whitham RH. The cost of multiple sclerosis drugs in the US and the pharmaceutical industry: too big to fail? Neurology. 2015;84(21):2185‐2192. 10.1212/WNL.0000000000001608. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 43. Rosenthal E. Why competition won't bring down drug prices. New York Times; 2018;
- 44. Kesselheim AS, Avorn J, Sarpatwari A. The high cost of prescription drugs in the United States: origins and prospects for reform. Jama. 2016;316(8):858‐871. 10.1001/jama.2016.11237. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 45. Kiker BF. The historical roots of the concept of human capital. J Political Econ. 1966;74(5):481‐499. [Google Scholar]
- 46. Warner KE, Luce BR. Cost‐Benefit and Cost‐Effectiveness Analysis in Health Care: Principles, Practice, and Potential. Chicago, IL: Health Administration Press; 1982. [Google Scholar]
- 47. Jennings WP, Jennings PR. Risk, the willingness‐to‐pay, and the value of a human life. J Insurance Issues. 2000;23(2):180‐184. [Google Scholar]
- 48. Johannesson M. The revealed preference approach. Theory and Methods of Economic Evaluation of Health Care. Midtown Manhatta, NY: Springer‐Verlag US; 1996:65‐74. [Google Scholar]
- 49. Johannesson M. The expressed preference approach. Zweifel P, HE Frech III, Theory and Methods of Economic Evaluation of Health Care. New York, NY: Springer; 1996:75‐100. [Google Scholar]
- 50. Neumann PJ, Sanders GD, Russell LB, Siegel JE, Ganiats TG. Cost‐Effectiveness in Health and Medicine. 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2017. [Google Scholar]
- 51. Kim DD, Silver MC, Kunst N, Cohen JT, Ollendorf DA, Neumann PJ. Perspective and costing in cost‐effectiveness analysis, 1974–2018. PharmacoEconomics. 2020;38:1135–1145. 10.1007/s40273-020-00942-2. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 52. Neumann PJ, Cohen JT, Kim DD, Ollendorf DA. Consideration of value‐based pricing for treatments and vaccines is important, even in the COVID‐19 pandemic. Health Aff. 2021;40(1):53‐61. 10.1377/hlthaff.2020.01548. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 53. Neumann PJ, Cohen JT. QALYs in 2018—advantages and concerns. Jama. 2018;319(24):2473‐2474. 10.1001/jama.2018.6072. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 54. Perfetto EM. ISPOR's initiative on US value assessment frameworks: a missed opportunity for ISPOR and patients. Value Health. 2018;21(2):169‐170. 10.1016/j.jval.2017.12.002. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 55. Coelho T. Congress must protect health care access from being denied based on flawed analysis. The Hill https://thehill.com/opinion/healthcare/379351-congress-must-protect-patients-from-being-denied-access-to-care-based-on, Accessed May 15, 2018
- 56. Doshi JA, Sonet EM, Puckett JT, Glick H. The need for a new patient‐centered decision tool for value‐based treatment choices in oncology. Health Affairs Blog. 2018. [Google Scholar]
- 57. Nord E, Richardson J, Street A, Kuhse H, Singer P. Maximizing health benefits vs egalitarianism: an Australian survey of health issues. Soc Sci Med. 1995;41(10):1429‐1437. 10.1016/0277-9536(95)00121-M. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 58. Linley WG, Hughes DA. Societal views on NICE, cancer drugs fund and value‐based pricing criteria for prioritising medicines: a cross‐sectional survey of 4118 adults in Great Britain. Health Econ. 2013;22(8):948‐964. 10.1002/hec.2872. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 59. Cookson R, Mirelman AJ, Griffin S, et al. Using cost‐effectiveness analysis to address health equity concerns. Value Health. 2017;20(2):206‐212. 10.1016/j.jval.2016.11.027. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 60. Brock DW, Daniels N, Neumann PJ, Siegel JE. Ethical and distributive considerations. In: Neumann PJ, Sanders GD, Russell LB, Siegel JE, Ganiats TG, eds. Cost‐Effectiveness in Health and Medicine. 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2017. [Google Scholar]
- 61. Neumann PJ, Cohen JT, Weinstein MC. Updating cost‐effectiveness—the curious resilience of the $50,000‐per‐QALY threshold. N Engl J Med. 2014;371(9):796‐797. 10.1056/NEJMp1405158. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 62. Hirth RA, Chernew MA, Miller E, Fendrick AM, Weissert WG. Willingness to pay for a quality‐adjusted life year: in search of a standard. Med Decis Making. 2000;20(3):332‐342. 10.1177/0272989X0002000310. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 63. Ryen L, Svensson M. The willingness to pay for a quality adjusted life year: a review of the empirical literature. Health Econ. 2015;24(10):1289‐1301. 10.1002/hec.3085. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 64. Braithwaite RS, Meltzer DO, King JT, Leslie D, Roberts MS. What does the value of modern medicine say about the $50,000 per quality‐adjusted life‐year decision rule? Med Care. 2008;46(4):349‐356. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 65. Chambers JD, Neumann PJ, Buxton MN. Does medicare have an implicit cost‐effectiveness threshold? Med Decis Making. 2010;30(4):E14‐E27. 10.1177/0272989X10371134. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 66. Garber AM, Phelps CE. Economic foundations of cost‐effectiveness analysis. J Health Econ. 1997;16(1):1‐31. 10.1016/S0167-6296(96)00506-1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 67. Phelps CE. A new method to determine the optimal willingness to pay in cost‐effectiveness analysis. Value Health. 2019;22(7):785‐791. 10.1016/j.jval.2019.03.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 68. Vallejo Torres L, Garcia B, Castilla Rodríguez I, et al. On the estimation of the cost‐effectiveness threshold: why, what, how? Value Health. 2016;19:19. 10.1016/j.jval.2016.02.020. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 69. Woods B, Revill P, Sculpher M, Claxton K. Country‐level cost‐effectiveness thresholds: initial estimates and the need for further research. Value Health. 2016;19(8):929‐935. 10.1016/j.jval.2016.02.017. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 70. Edney LC, Haji Ali Afzali H, Cheng TC, Karnon J. Estimating the reference incremental cost‐effectiveness ratio for the australian health system. PharmacoEconomics. 2018;36(2):239‐252. 10.1007/s40273-017-0585-2. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 71. Siverskog J, Henriksson M. Estimating the marginal cost of a life year in Sweden's public healthcare sector. Eur J Health Econ. 2019;20(5):751‐762. 10.1007/s10198-019-01039-0. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 72. van Baal P, Perry‐Duxbury M, Bakx P, Versteegh M, van Doorslaer E, Brouwer W. A cost‐effectiveness threshold based on the marginal returns of cardiovascular hospital spending. Health Econ. 2019;28(1):87‐100. 10.1002/hec.3831. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 73. Sarnak DO, Squires D, Bishop S. Paying for prescription drugs around the world: why is the U.S. an outlier? The Commonwealth Fund; 2017. https://www.commonwealthfund.org/publications/issue-briefs/2017/oct/paying-prescription-drugs-around-world-why-us-outlier, Accessed August 4, 2020 [PubMed]
- 74. Sullivan SD, Yeung K, Vogeler C, et al. Design, implementation, and first‐year outcomes of a value‐based drug formulary. J Managed Care Specialty Pharm. 2015;21(4):269‐275. 10.18553/jmcp.2015.21.4.269. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 75. Gopalan A. CVS announcement of cost‐effective benchmarks puts ICER in the spotlight. Stat. 2018. [Google Scholar]
- 76. Neumann PJ. Using Cost‐Effectiveness Analysis to Improve Health Care: Opportunities and Barriers. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
- 77. Chambers JD, Kim DD, Pope EF, Graff JS, Wilkinson CL, Neumann PJ. Specialty drug coverage varies across commercial health plans in the US. Health Affairs. 2018;37(7):1041‐1047. 10.1377/hlthaff.2017.1553. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 78. INAHTA Members List. International Network of Agencies for Health Technology Assessment https://www.inahta.org/members/members_list/, Accessed January 6, 2020
- 79. Chamova J. Mapping of HTA National Organisations, Programmes and Processes in EU and Norway. Brussels, Belgium: European Union; 2017. https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/971cf96d-0aef-11e8-966a-01aa75ed71a1 [Google Scholar]
- 80. García‐Mochón L, Espín Balbino J, Olry de Labry Lima A, Caro Martinez A, Martin Ruiz E, Pérez Velasco R. HTA and decision‐making processes in central, eastern and South Eastern Europe: results from a survey. Health Policy. 2019;123(2):182‐190. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2017.03.010. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 81. Simoens S. Health technology assessment and economic evaluation across jurisdictions. Value Health. 2010;13(6):857‐859. 10.1111/j.1524-4733.2010.00756.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 82. Rosselli D, Quirland‐Lazo C, Csanádi M, et al. HTA implementation in Latin American countries: comparison of current and preferred status. Value Health Reg Issues. 2017;14:20‐27. 10.1016/j.vhri.2017.02.004. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 83. Castro HE. Advancing HTA in Latin America: the policy process of setting up an HTA agency in Colombia. Global Policy. 2017;8:97‐102. 10.1111/1758-5899.12333. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 84. Policy Brief: Conducive Factors to HTA Development in Asia. HITAP International Unit http://www.globalhitap.net/projects/policy-brief-conducive-factors-to-hta-development-in-asia-2/, Accessed January 7, 2020
- 85. NECA ‐ National Evidence‐Based Healthcare Collaborating Agency. International Network of Agencies for Health Technology Assessment. https://www.inahta.org/members/neca/, Accessed January 7, 2020
- 86. Neumann PJ, Chambers JD. Medicare's enduring struggle to define “reasonable and necessary” care. N Engl J Med. 2012;367(19):1775‐1777. 10.1056/NEJMp1208386. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 87. Saha S, Hoerger TJ, Pignone MP, Teutsch SM, Helfand M, Mandelblatt JS. The art and science of incorporating cost effectiveness into evidence‐based recommendations for clinical preventive services. Am J Prev Med. 2001;20(3):36‐43. 10.1016/S0749-3797(01)00260-4. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 88. White N, Johns A, Latch E. Industry Perceptions and Expectations: the Role of ICER as an Independent HTA Organisation. Leopardstown, Ireland: ICON; 2019. https://iconplc.com/insights/value-based-healthcare/the-role-of-icer-as-an-independent-hta-organisation/ [Google Scholar]
- 89. Berkrot B. Spark's price for Luxturna blindness gene therapy too high: ICER. Reuters; 2018. https://www.reuters.com/article/us-spark-icer/sparks-price-for-luxturna-blindness-gene-therapy-too-high-icer-idUSKBN1F1298, Accessed August 11, 2020
- 90. Cohen JT, Silver MC, Ollendorf DA, Neumann PJ. Does the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review revise its findings in response to industry comments? Value Health. 2019;22(12):1396‐1401. 10.1016/j.jval.2019.08.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 91. Sampsel E, Watkins J, Kenney J. ICER: payer perspectives on the use and usage of ICER reports; 2019
- 92. Lising A, Drummond MF, Barry M, Augustovski F. Payers' Use of Independent Reports in Decision Making—Will there Be an ICER Effect?. Lawrenceville, NJ: International Society for Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes Research: Value & Outcomes Spotlight; 2017. [Google Scholar]
- 93. Lovelace BJ. Regeneron CEO. Puts conditions on lowering his $14,000‐per‐year cholesterol drug. CNBC https://www.cnbc.com/2018/03/12/regeneron-ceo-puts-conditions-on-lowering-his-14000-cholesterol-drug.html, Accessed April 20, 2021
- 94. Thomas K. A drug costs $272,000 a year. Not so fast, says New York State. The New York Times. 2018.
- 95. Overview of the ICER value assessment framework and update for 2017‐2019. 2018. https://icer.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/10/ICER-value-assessment-framework-Updated-050818.
- 96. Cost‐effectiveness, the QALY, and the evLYG. Institute for Clinical and Economic Review. https://icer.org/our-approach/methods-process/cost-effectiveness-the-qaly-and-the-evlyg/#:~:text=To%20complement%20the%20use%20of,improve%20patients'%20quality%20of%20life, Accessed April 20, 2021
- 97. 2020–2023 Value Assessment Framework; 2020. https://icer.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/10/ICER_2020_2023_VAF_102220.pdf.
- 98. Cohen JT, Neumann PJ, Wong JB. A call for open‐source cost‐effectiveness analysis. Ann Internal Med. 2017;167(6):432‐433. 10.7326/M17-1153. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 99. Lakdawalla DN, Neumann PJ, Wilensky GR, et al. Health Technology Assessment in the U.S. – A Vision for the Future. 2021. https://healthpolicy.usc.edu/research/health-technology-assessment-in-the-u-s-a-vision-for-the-future/
- 100. Neumann PJ, Lin P‐J, Greenberg D, et al. Do drug formulary policies reflect evidence of value. American Journal of Managed Care. 2006;12:30–36. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 101. What is value‐based insurance design? University of Michgan: Center for Value‐Based Insurance. https://vbidcenter.org/about-v-bid/
- 102. Chernew ME, Rosen AB, Fendrick AM. Value‐based insurance design. Health Affairs. 2007;26(suppl 2):w195‐w203. 10.1377/hlthaff.26.2.w195. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]