Abstract
This article considers the optimal control of the SIR model with both transmission and treatment uncertainty. It follows the model presented in Gatto and Schellhorn (2021). We make four significant improvements on the latter paper. First, we prove the existence of a solution to the model. Second, our interpretation of the control is more realistic: while in Gatto and Schellhorn (2021) the control is the proportion of the population that takes a basic dose of treatment, so that occurs only if some patients take more than a basic dose, in our paper, is constrained between zero and one, and represents thus the proportion of the population undergoing treatment. Third, we provide a complete solution for the moderate infection regime (with constant treatment). Finally, we give a thorough interpretation of the control in the moderate infection regime, while Gatto and Schellhorn (2021) focused on the interpretation of the low infection regime. Finally, we compare the efficiency of our control to curb the COVID-19 epidemic to other types of control.
Keywords: SIR model, Population control, COVID-19, Stochastic optimal control, Epidemiology
1. Introduction
This article extends the analysis of the model presented in [1]. In that article the authors gave analytical expressions for the optimal proportion of infected to undergo treatment in a pandemic. Analytical approaches allow to better understand the form of the solution compared to numerical approaches, which are currently more prevalent in this domain. It was possible for the authors to find formulae because of the type of objective function they chose. Rather than minimize an expected value of the number of infected or the cumulated number of infected (under a constraint on the dispersion of the results), we chose to minimize the expected value of a convex increasing function of the number of infected at the horizon. The quadratic utility function is a special case of the latter, and we indeed show results for a whole family of functions, called isoelastic functions. Each function in this family is characterized by a single parameter, called the risk-aversion parameter, and varying this parameter as we shall see enables us to better understand how the optimal control depends smoothly on the level of aversion to risk, where risk is understood as the probabilistic uncertainty of the result. In contradistinction, the optimal control of deterministic epidemiological models is often of the bang–bang type (see for instance [2], [3]). Several authors, such as [3], [4], [5], [6] use Pontryagin’s maximum principle. Some authors (e.g., [7]) use dynamic programming. Laarabi et al. [8] use the same framework, but add delay. The literature on the control of stochastic epidemiologic models tends to be more sparse and more recent. A variety of models and numerical methods has been proposed: Markov chain [9], backward SDE solved by the 4-step scheme [10], simulated annealing [11], stochastic programming [12], genetic algorithms [13]. Wang et al. [14] consider time-varying parameters.
The contributions of this article are fourfold. First, we prove existence of a solution. Second, whereas in [1] the optimal control has the interpretation of the proportion of the population that takes a basic dose of treatment, so that occurs only if a proportion of the population takes more than a basic dose of treatment. In the low infection regime part of our paper, is constrained to be between zero and one, and represents thus the proportion of the population undergoing treatment. The latter interpretation is much more realistic, as it is uncommon to ration treatment. Third, we provide a complete solution for the moderate infection regime (with constant treatment). The final improvement is a thorough numerical analysis and sensitivity analysis of the moderate infection regime, while [1] focused exclusively on the interpretation of the control in the low infection regime. This enables us to discover some errors in the second-order term of the solution in [1], which we correct here. Finally, we compare the efficiency of our control to curb the COVID-19 pandemic to other types of control. Our optimal control is, as expected, superior to a full control (or no control), in terms of expected utility. It is clearly superior in the case of low infection, but the benefit is less pronounced in the case of moderate infection. There are two possible reasons for that. First, we included only few terms in the analytic series of the optimal control. Adding more terms would have yielded slightly better results. More importantly, the quality of the treatment available to COVID-19 patients in the US in 2020 was probably not sufficient to make a difference if the number of infected had climbed to more than 1%.
The structure of the article is as follows. In Section 2 we briefly introduce the model in [1], and provide a proof of existence of the solution. In Section 3, we show our results for the low infection regime. In Section 4, we extend and analyze the solution in the moderate infection regime. Section 5 shows our experimental results when applying our methodology to the COVID-19 in the US in 2020. We draw the conclusion in Section 6.
2. A stochastic SIR model with treatment uncertainty
Let , , be the proportions of susceptible, infected, and out of infection (recovered, and dead), respectively. Let be the transmission rate and be the death rate.
In the SIR model, the rate of decrease of the proportion of susceptible is equal to the constant transmission rate time . As in [1], we add a term , where is white noise, in order to model the error in the transmission rate:
Infected patients are either treated or not treated against the disease. In both cases they either recover or die. We denote by () the constant death rate without (with) treatment and by the recovery rate of the treatment. The optimal policy is a progressively measurable process that represents the proportion of the infected population that receives treatment, thus . This constraint is an important addition to the model in [1]. Depending whether the individual is treated or not, there are then four different ways for an infected individual to exit the pool of infected:
-
•
not treated and recover
-
•
not treated and die
-
•
treated and recover
-
•
treated and died.
Thus, the “out of infection rate” will be:
(1) |
For simplicity, we assume that the Brownian motion driving transmission uncertainty () is independent from the Brownian motion driving treatment uncertainty (). Usually (people die faster without treatment than with treatment), but not necessarily. Most of the time (treatment is better than no treatment), but not necessarily. We relax this requirement somewhat by requiring:
(2) |
In order to keep the treatment rate within bounds, we model it as an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process:
with the mean-reversion rate and the long run value of the treatment rate . It is well-known that is Gaussian, with variance equal to:
Thus, if mean-reversion is large compared to volatility , constraint (2) is satisfied. We simplify (1) by:
Putting everything together, the dynamics of the infected is:
We try to minimize a measure of the infected over our horizon . This article focuses on the solution of the Mayer problem, i.e., the objective is expressed as a measure of . Another possible control would have been the time-integral of the number of infected over the horizon (the Lagrange problem). Both figures have their merit,1 and we leave for future research the control of (a measure) of the Lagrange and Bolza problems. Rather than trying to minimize the expected value of the infected, namely , we include in our objective the risk caused by the uncertainty of the model and its observations. Decision-makers are notoriously risk-averse. For this reason, Morgenstern and Von Neumann [15] introduced a class of utility functions that bears their names. A decision-maker in epidemiology that is averse to risk will thus minimize the expected utility of the infected, namely where is increasing and convex. Alternately, one can maximize the negative thereof, i.e., maximize the expected value of a concave and decreasing function of . The policy obtained in maximizing the expected value of a concave utility function can be showed, under certain conditions, to maximize the expected value of the outcome (here ) under a constraint on the dispersion of the outcome. Out of the universe of concave decreasing utility functions, we choose the power utility function:
The coefficient is often called the risk-aversion parameter . When the decision-maker is risk-neutral, meaning that the uncertainty does not have an influence on her decisions. It is straightforward to check that this power utility function is concave in when , which we will assume. The more negative the more risk-averse is the decision-maker. Taking for instance , we see that the objective is to
which returns the same policy as:
The importance of analytic formulations is that other figures of interest in this model, like the expected number of deaths from treatment can be analytically calculated, and depend on . Thus, a decision-maker can calibrate its risk-aversion parameter on other goals. Expected number of deaths is only one type of goal and economic factors that can be easily added. We define
Our controlled SIR model is thus:
(3) |
(4) |
(5) |
The relative sign of our volatilities and is important. We will assume without loss of generality that . The sign of is the sign of covariance between the measured value of today’s treatment rate and the change in value of the treatment rate between today and a future date. An example may help illustrate the difference. Suppose that over a week one performs daily measurements of the treatment recovery rate as well as daily forecasts of the evolution of the treatment recovery rate over the next day. The two quantities measured each day are proportional to the same white noise 1 day. One then calculates weekly estimates of and of over these 7 daily observations. Since we arbitrarily choose , a negative shows a correlation of +1 between the measurement (of today’s treatment rate) and the forecast. Fig. 1 is a depiction of our model.
Fig. 1.
A stochastic SIR model.
Let be the time when the infection stops, i.e., the first time when either or or both are equal to zero. We naturally require the control to go down to zero at that time, for definiteness reasons. The next result considers an open-loop control.
Theorem 1
For a given progressively measurable control , with and given initial values there exists a unique solution of (3) (4) (5) up to time .
The proof of Theorem 1, included in Appendix A, follows the proof of a theorem of Yamada and Watanabe (1971), as exposed in the book by Karatzas and Shreve [16, Prop. 2.13, Sec. 5.2]. We showed in a companion document that the probability that either or is equal to zero over a finite interval is zero, following the method of proof in [17], [18]. It is thus unlikely that a simple discretization of our model results in negative values.2 For notational simplicity we define the impact of treatment risk :
as well as the long run impact of the treatment risk :
We define and . For simplicity we write .
In the absence of bounds on , Gatto and Schellhorn [1] show that, when a smooth optimal closed-loop control exists, there exists a probability measure 3 under which is a martingale and is the optimal state. Moreover, has the explicit form:
(6) |
(7) |
and is twice continuously differentiable. In the sequel we will shorten this statement by saying that “ solves the martingale problem (6)”.
3. Results in the low infection regime
We assume close to one and . Thus the term:
is assumed constant. With this simplification, we give an analytical solution to the constrained problem, i.e., the case where , a significant improvement over [1], who considered the unconstrained case.
We consider first the case where the treatment rate is constant, and then the case where it follows an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process.
3.1. Constant treatment rate
Let . The problem is:
(8) |
Theorem 2
The following constant control is optimal:
The proof is in Appendix B, and follows closely [19].
3.2. Treatment rate as Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process
The problem is
(9) |
In the low infection regime our solution will depend on a kernel with , while in the moderate infection regime it will also depend on two other kernels and that are closely related. In order to unify notation we define the kernels. Define
(10) |
and, for
(11) |
where
(12) |
(13) |
(14) |
We provide an explicit formula for in Appendix C.
Gatto and Schellhorn [1, Prop. 1] provide an explicit solution to the PDE that in (6) satisfies, but with some typos in the expression of , which we correct here.
Theorem 3 Proposition 1 in [1] —
If then solves the martingale problem (6) , where
where
The corresponding control is given by:
(15)
This control has some very clear properties. It is decomposed into a myopic policy and a hedging policy, namely the second term of (15). Recall that is most often negative. Both myopic control and hedging policies are thus inversely proportional to the degree of risk aversion and to the volatility which corresponds to the contemporaneous transmission measurement error. The hedging policy gives protection against the risk of making decisions too soon. As expected, its magnitude decreases as time approaches the horizon . This is a typical feature of the Mayer problem, which is usually attenuated in the Bolza problem.
4. Results in the moderate infection regime
We first handle the Ornstein–Uhlenbeck treatment rate case, which was presented in [1, Prop. 2].
4.1. Treatment rate as Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process
The problem is defined in Section 2. We rewrite here for convenience,
(16) |
We further define
(17) |
(18) |
From this, we can calculate:
Theorem 4
Let . If then solves the martingale problem (6) , where:
where satisfies:
The corresponding control where:
The proof is in Appendix D. We refer to [1] for a discussion of . In the moderate infection regime, the control (which is the control in the low infection regime) dominates the corrections due to transmission of the disease. Our asymptotic expansion thus indicates how the optimal control should change as the pandemic progresses. The sign of is determined by the signs of and
(19) |
More specifically, is positive if and (19) are both positive or negative. is negative if one of them is positive and the other one is negative.
It is obvious that the magnitude of both and decrease with time and are equal to zero when . Therefore, the importance of decreases as time increases.
To further discuss the sign of (19), we rewrite it by
Thus, suppose , , and are all positive, (19) is positive, and vice versa. In the following cases, we provide two simple cases that we can easily discuss the sign of :
-
•
if , , then is positive.
-
•
if , , then is negative.
In the following, we discuss the full expansion of the solution in Theorem 4. Consider equation (57) in [1]:
This time we use full asymptotic expansion:
and obtain:
The terms of our asymptotic expansion are thus determined by:
(20) |
(21) |
We use the Ansatz:
We have showed that and in the proof of Theorem 4. By the same process, we can also calculate the expressions for , in the sequel.
4.2. Constant treatment rate
The problem is:
(22) |
The HJB equation of this problem is obtained by simplifying (6), i.e., making the value function independent from . Let , the solution kernels for are given by:
(23) |
where
(24) |
(25) |
Theorem 5
Let , then solves the martingale problem (6) , where:
where , , can be obtained by (47) , and satisfies:
The corresponding control is equal to , where and are equal to
The proof is in Appendix E, where we also provide a formula for . Observe that
is always positive because the signs of and are the same. The signs of and are determined by the sign of .
5. Application to COVID-19
We use the same weekly US COVID-19 data from June 7, 2020 to November 1, 2020 as in ([1] Sec. 5.1) and the parameters in Table 1 are estimated using the COVID-19 data set. In the following, we show both simulation plots and one scenario real data plots under low infection regime with constant treatment, low infection regime with OU treatment, moderate infection regime with constant treatment, moderate infection regime with OU treatment, respectively. We compare three types of treatment:
-
•
no control, i.e., .
-
•
full control, i.e., .
-
•
optimal control, i.e. the control from Theorems 2, 3, 4, 5.
The Github repository for implementing the models and generating the plots can be found at https://github.com/yujiading/optimal-control-sir-model.
Table 1.
Parameters.
Treatment parameter | Symbol | Value |
---|---|---|
Death rate/no treatment | 0.0575 | |
Death rate | 0.0575 | |
Recovery rate/no treatment | 0.2559 | |
Recovery rate at time 0 | 0.2559 | |
Long run value of recovery rate | 0.4612 | |
Volatility of the measurement of today’s recovery rate | 0.4418 | |
Volatility of changes in the recovery rate | −1.1647 | |
Speed of mean-reversion of the recovery rate | 0.7692 | |
Transmission rate | 0.025 | |
Proportion of infected at time 0 | 0.01 | |
Time step | 0.001 | |
Volatility of the measurement of today’s susceptible rate | 2.17 |
5.1. Simulations
In Figs. 2, 3, 4, and 5 we use the Euler scheme to simulate scenarios using the parameters in Table 1 and calculate the expected values of and utility of for each regime. The risk-aversion parameters that are considered are between and . In all the regimes, the expected utility of our control is higher than full control and no control, as expected. This effect is more pronounced in the low infection than in the moderate infection regime. When becomes more negative, the expected utility of no control is higher than that of full control. This is because when becomes more negative, the decision-maker becomes more risk averse and trades off expected value of against dispersion of . In the low infection regime, the expected number of infected is lower with full control than with no control, as expected, and, with the optimal control, it depends on the level of risk-aversion, as expected. When treatment is risky the more risk-averse a decision maker, the less he or she is likely to invest in treatment.
Fig. 2.
Expected infection and expected utility of optimal control, full control, and no control of low infection regime with constant treatment. Using simulation scenarios.
Fig. 3.
Expected infection and expected utility of optimal control, full control, and no control of low infection regime with OU treatment. Using simulation scenarios.
Fig. 4.
Expected infection and expected utility of optimal control, full control, and no control of moderate infection regime with constant treatment. Using simulation scenarios.
Fig. 5.
Expected infection and expected utility of optimal control, full control, and no control of moderate infection regime with OU treatment. Using simulation scenarios.
5.2. One scenario real data
In Fig. 6, we use the one scenario COVID-19 data as introduced above to plot the infections with optimal control, full control, and no control for each of the regimes. We can see that as gamma varies, some plots show contrafactual results. In fact, it is possible for a particular scenario to result in a better or worse outcome. This does not contradict our theoretical results, as in stochastic control the goal is not to optimize a single scenario.
Fig. 6.
Infection of optimal control, full control, and no control of low infection regime with constant treatment, low infection regime with OU treatment, moderate infection regime with constant treatment, and moderate infection regime with OU treatment. Using real COVID-19 data.
6. Conclusion
We showed that a stochastic optimal control approach enables to more efficiently use treatment in an pandemic such as COVID-19. On a theoretical level, we show that, in a first approximation, the control does not depend on the transmission of the pandemic, i.e., the control in the moderate infection regime resembles the control in the low infection regime. The influence of key parameters of the problems, namely risk-aversion and volatility, are clearly demonstrated in our formulas. On a practical level, we show that an optimal control would have been better than a full control, had it been available in the low infection regime which we experienced in summer 2020 in the US for COVID-19. However the relative poor efficiency of the treatment that we experienced then would have translated into a poor performance of any type of control, had the pandemic moved into a moderate infection regime. In that regime, the influence of the type of control would have turned out not to be significant.
In the Mayer problem, which we study here, the control depends significantly on the horizon. The study of the full Bolza problem remains to be done. Many other interesting problems remain to be solved. For instance, we showed optimality of the constrained control only in the constant, low infection regime case. Verification theorems need to be worked out in the multiple treatment case or the Ornstein–Uhlenbeck case. Optimal vaccination is another area where we believe a similar asymptotic approach can be used. Finally, Bertozzi et al. [20] use Hawkes processes to model COVID-19. The control of Hawkes processes remains a largely open problem that deserves attention, in particular for its application to epidemiology.
Declaration of Competing Interest
The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.
Footnotes
We thank an anonymous referee for this comment.
We note that we never encountered a negative value of in our simulations.
Equivalent to the original measure , which is the measure under which and are Brownian motions.
Supplementary material related to this article can be found online at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.mbs.2021.108758.
Appendix A. Proof of Theorem 1
We follow the proof in [16, Prop. 2.13, Sec. 5.2]. They consider the one-dimensional case. Let be a strictly increasing function with and
(26) |
In our case, we take . Because of (26), there exists a strictly decreasing sequence with and such that . For every there exists continuous function on with support on so that
and . Then the function
is even and twice continuously differentiable, with and . Suppose there are two strong solutions and ,
so that
Thus, since ,
where
Observe that:
Since and is positive,
Taking results in
Since ,
But,
Since , and thus
and local uniqueness follows by Gronwall’s inequality.
Appendix B. Proof of Theorem 2
We refer to the problem treated by Gatto and Schellhorn [1] as the unconstrained problem. Indeed, in that problem was not constrained. We refer to our problem as the constrained problem. We follow the method of proof in [19], referred to hereafter as CK. They introduce auxiliary problems, which are unconstrained. They show that there exists an auxiliary problem which solution can be used to construct the solution of the original constrained problem. We follow the numbering of the sections in CK in order to ease understanding.
CK Section 2. The model.
To ease the correspondence with the CK paper, we define , , and
Observe that .
CK Section 3. Portfolio and consumption processes.
Define:
Denote by the infected process subject to and control . It is admissible if
The set of admissible is denoted . Note that (See (3.5) in CK)
CK Section 4. Convex sets and their support functions.
The difference between CK and this paper is that our objective is to minimize. This means that the key relation between our auxiliary infected and infected is reversed compared to the first equation in CK. Indeed if solves the auxiliary problem and the original problem, we must have:
Define
(27) |
It is subadditive:
(28) |
CK Section 5. Utility functions.
The main difference between our utility functions and the utility functions in financial economics is that our utility functions are decreasing for positive arguments. Recall indeed that our utility function is, for :
Since
We have and , again for . This is unlike CK and [21] who consider the case with utility of wealth . In their case, and .
We define to be the inverse of , with on . By straightforward calculations:
We also define the Legendre–Fenchel dual
This function satisfies:
CK Section 6. The constrained and unconstrained optimization problems.
We define:
The supremum of the unconstrained problem is denoted by , while the supremum of the constrained problem is denoted by , namely:
CK Section 7. Solution of the unconstrained problem.
We note that the expectation
is finite for every . We define its inverse :
The solution of the unconstrained problem is well-known, and equal to:
CK Section 8. Auxiliary unconstrained optimization problems.
Recall in (27). It is easily seen that:
We introduce a new process by:
Likewise we introduce
We denote by the class of for which
Since the solution of our dual problem will have , clearly . We define:
We define a class of progressively measurable processes in by:
Proposition 8.3. in CK shows that, if for some the corresponding control is optimal for the auxiliary optimization problem and if
then and is optimal for the constrained problem.
The solution of the unconstrained problem is:
(29) |
CK Section 9. Contingent claims attainable by constrained portfolios.
We sketch the proof of Theorem 9.1 in CK, as the signs are different, and the structure of the control is slightly different.
CK 9.1 Theorem
Let be a positive -measurable random variable and suppose there is a process such that, for all
(30) Then there exists a control such that .
Sketch of Proof
See CK p.782 for a definition of the stopping time . By (30) and subadditivity of (28):
where
By Ito’s lemma.
which implies
Therefore,
It is easy to see that, for any , take :
(31) and, taking , we obtain:
which together with (31) for yields:
CK Section 10. Equivalent optimality conditions.
The most important implication to prove is (D) (B) (A) in CK. It shows that the solution of the dual problem solves the auxiliary problem, and that, moreover, it is feasible and optimal for the original constrained problem. We make it more explicit here.
(Part of) CK 10.1 Theorem
Suppose that for every ,
(32) then there exists a control that is optimal for the constrained problem and such that
Proof
Since ,
By Theorem 9.1 there exists a control such that:
Clearly is optimal for the constrained problem, and
Thus by proposition 8.3, is optimal for the constrained problem. □
CK Section 12. A dual problem.
Define:
In our case,
Thus
Let . Then:
Typically, , so that:
The main problem in condition (32) is to find the optimal process (across all ) but it depends on which depends on . Thus the dual must be fixed for a fixed but arbitrary real number . The objective has the form
The right hand-side of the equation (see [22, p.134]) is the maximum of the function for all non-negative measurable with . Thus a minimization over all positive numbers of would yield the optimal utility of the unconstrained problem. We could thus first minimize in , and then minimize over . However, the main idea is to first minimize over , and then minimize over , hoping that the two can be interchanged.
CK 12.1 Proposition
Suppose that for any there exists such that . Then there exist an with which is optimal for the primal problem, and we have:
Proof
Write for . Then
and we conclude by CK Theorem 10.1. □
CK Section 15. Deterministic coefficients and feedback formulae.
Define:
Recall
The HJB equation is:
Again, with . We choose
Thus
Dividing by , the problem becomes:
(33) |
Recall that if is positive, then thus we solve (33) and obtain
since and is negative. If is negative, then , thus .
From (29), the solution is
Suppose and treatment is better than no treatment . Thus is positive. Thus
Appendix C. Explicit formula of in (14)
Appendix D. Proof of Theorem 4
We follow the proof of Proposition 2 in [1]. Recall the equations (58) (59) in [1] and following same notations:
(34) |
(35) |
where are equations (53) (54) in [1].
Solution of (34).
We postulate that:
Substitution in (34) shows that solves:
(36) |
where the operator is defined by:
Using the Ansatz (11), we can rewrite the LHS of (36) into:
Clearly all terms must be identically zero. Thus:
Solution of (35).
The second equation can be rewritten
(37) |
We try the Ansatz:
(38) |
Thus
We use Lemma 6 to obtain the in (18).
The optimal policy is:
where
Lemma 6
Let . The solution to
(39)
is in (18) .
Sketch of Proof
Define and to be such that:
Let be the solution of:
(40) Defining:
(41) we see that:
(42) Thus (40) can be rewritten:
Using the integrating factor , we have:
Under the boundary condition the only possible solution is:
Define . Clearly:
where:
By Ito’s lemma, and for the exact same reason as (42):
The stochastic equivalent of (39) is:
The solution is:
where:
Clearly, for some volatility
We are now ready to define a change of numeraire. Let
By Theorem 9.2.2 in [23], is a -martingale, i.e.,
where
From (11),
Let us now take:
Thus:
(43) Thus when (43) holds can be calculated exactly the same way as when (41) holds. The structure is also affine, and there will be a solution of the form:
To summarize, since
(44) Let as in (17) and
Clearly:
Thus we can calculate:
We can further develop:
Appendix E. Proof of Theorem 5
When is a constant, equations (53) and (54) in [1] become
Use the Ansatz and insert in (20) shows that solves:
(45) |
where the operator is defined by:
Using the Ansatz (23), we can rewrite (45) into:
Clearly all terms must be identically zero. Thus
which admit the solutions (24), (25) at .
Now use . We can rewrite (21) by
(46) |
Let and
Then
and the stochastic equivalent of (46) is:
which admits
(47) |
We have showed that . Here we also provide the and in the following:
Suppose we use the first two expansions, the optimal policy is given by:
where
Appendix F. Supplementary data
The following is the Supplementary material related to this article.
Online supplement for Optimal Control of the SIR model with constrained policy, with an application to COVID-19.
References
- 1.Gatto Nicole M., Schellhorn Henry. Optimal control of the SIR model in the presence of transmission and treatment uncertainty. Math. Biosci. 2021;333 doi: 10.1016/j.mbs.2021.108539. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 2.Ledzewicz Urszula, Schättler Heinz. Conference Publications. American Institute of Mathematical Sciences; 2011. On optimal singular control for a general SIR model with vaccination and treatment; pp. 981–990. (Special). [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Bolzoni Luca, Bonacini Elena, Soresina Cinzia, Groppi Maria. Time-optimal control strategies in SIR epidemic models. Math. Biosci. 2017;292:86–96. doi: 10.1016/j.mbs.2017.07.011. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 4.Grigorieva E.V., Khailov E.N. Optimal vaccination, treatment, and preventive campaigns in regard to the SIR epidemic model. Math. Model. Nat. Phenom. 2014;9(4):105–121. doi: 10.1051/mmnp/20149407. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Gaff Holly, Schaefer Elsa. Optimal control applied to vaccination and treatment strategies for various epidemiological models. Math. Biosci. Eng. 2009;6(3):469–492. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2009.6.469. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Tchuenche J.M., Khamis S.A., Agusto F.B., Mpeshe S.C. Optimal control and sensitivity analysis of an influenza model with treatment and vaccination. Acta Biotheor. 2011;59(1):1–28. doi: 10.1007/s10441-010-9095-8. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Hethcote Herbert W., Waltman Paul. Optimal vaccination schedules in a deterministic epidemic model. Math. Biosci. 1973;18(3–4):365–381. doi: 10.1016/0025-5564(73)90011-4. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Laarabi Hassan, Abta Abdelhadi, Hattaf Khalid. Optimal control of a delayed SIRS epidemic model with vaccination and treatment. Acta Biotheoretica. 2015;63:87–97. doi: 10.1007/s10441-015-9244-1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 9.Ball Frank G., Lyne Owen D. Optimal vaccination policies for stochastic epidemics among a population of households. Math. Biosci. 2002;177–178:333–354. doi: 10.1016/S0025-5564(01)00095-5. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Ishikawa Masaaki. Proceeding of the ISCIE International Symposium on Stochastic Systems Theory and its Applications, Vol. 2012. 2012. Stochastic optimal control strategies of a SIR epidemic model with vaccination; pp. 57–62. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Pennisi Marzio, Catanuto Roberto, Pappalardo Francesco, Motta Santo. Optimal vaccination schedules using simulated annealing. Bioinformatics. 2008;24(15):1740–1742. doi: 10.1093/bioinformatics/btn260. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Tanner Matthew W., Sattenspiel Lisa, Ntaimo Lewis. Finding optimal vaccination strategies under parameter uncertainty using stochastic programming. Math. Biosci. 2008;215(2):144–151. doi: 10.1016/j.mbs.2008.07.006. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Patel Rajan, Longini Jr. Ira M., Halloran M. Elizabeth. Finding optimal vaccination strategies for pandemic influenza using genetic algorithms. J. Theoret. Biol. 2005;234(2):201–212. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2004.11.032. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 14.Wang Xinwei, Peng Haijun, Shi Boyang, Jiang Dianheng, Zhang Sheng, Chen Biaosong. Optimal vaccination strategy of a constrained time-varying SEIR epidemic model. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul. 2019;67:37–48. doi: 10.1016/j.cnsns.2018.07.003. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Morgenstern Oskar, Von Neumann John. Princeton University Press; 1953. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. [Google Scholar]
- 16.Karatzas Ioannis, Shreve Steven. Springer; 2014. Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Agarwal Ravi P., Badshah Qaisar, ur Rahman Ghaus, Islam Saeed. Optimal control & dynamical aspects of a stochastic pine wilt disease model. J. Franklin Inst. B. 2019;356(7):3991–4025. doi: 10.1016/j.jfranklin.2019.03.007. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 18.Gray Alison, Greenhalgh David, Hu Liangjian, Mao Xuerong, Pan Jiafeng. A stochastic differential equation SIS epidemic model. SIAM J. Appl. Math. 2011;71(3):876–902. doi: 10.1137/10081856X. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 19.Cvitanić Jakša, Karatzas Ioannis. Convex duality in constrained portfolio optimization. Ann. Appl. Probab. 1992;2:767–818. doi: 10.1214/aoap/1177005576. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 20.Bertozzi Andrea L, Franco Elisa, Mohler George, Short Martin B, Sledge Daniel. The challenges of modeling and forecasting the spread of COVID-19. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 2020;117(29):16732–16738. doi: 10.1073/pnas.2006520117. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 21.Wachter Jessica A. Portfolio and consumption decisions under mean-reverting returns: An exact solution for complete markets. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2002;37:63–91. doi: 10.2307/3594995. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Korn Ralf. World Scientific; 1997. Optimal Portfolios: Stochastic Models for Optimal Investment and Risk Management in Continuous Time. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Shreve Steven E. Springer-Verlag New York; 2004. Stochastic Calculus for Finance II: Continuous-Time Models. [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Supplementary Materials
Online supplement for Optimal Control of the SIR model with constrained policy, with an application to COVID-19.