Skip to main content
Wiley Open Access Collection logoLink to Wiley Open Access Collection
. 2022 Dec 8;32(3):574–619. doi: 10.1002/hec.4635

The effect of health financing systems on health system outcomes: A cross‐country panel analysis

Jacopo Gabani 1,2,, Sumit Mazumdar 1, Marc Suhrcke 1,3
PMCID: PMC10107855  PMID: 36480236

Abstract

Several low‐ and middle‐income countries are considering health financing system reforms to accelerate progress toward universal health coverage (UHC). However, empirical evidence of the effect of health financing systems on health system outcomes is scarce, partly because it is difficult to quantitatively capture the ‘health financing system’. We assign country‐year observations to one of three health financing systems (i.e., predominantly out‐of‐pocket, social health insurance (SHI) or government‐financed), using clustering based on out‐of‐pocket, contributory SHI and non‐contributory government expenditure, as a percentage of total health expenditures. We then estimate the effect of these different systems on health system outcomes, using fixed effects regressions. We find that transitions from OOP‐dominant to government‐financed systems improved most outcomes more than did transitions to SHI systems. Transitions to government financing increases life expectancy (+1.3 years, p < 0.05) and reduces under‐5 mortality (−8.7%, p < 0.05) and catastrophic health expenditure incidence (−3.3 percentage points, p < 0.05). Results are robust to several sensitivity tests. It is more likely that increases in non‐contributory government financing rather than SHI financing improve health system outcomes. Notable reasons include SHI's higher implementation costs and more limited coverage. These results may raise a warning for policymakers considering SHI reforms to reach UHC.

Keywords: health expenditure, health financing, health system, social health insurance, universal health coverage

1. INTRODUCTION

Universal health coverage (UHC) captures the ambition that the entire population in a given jurisdiction receive the quality health services they need, without suffering financial hardship, regardless of socio‐economic conditions (World Health Organization, 2020). Several countries are currently considering health financing system (HFS) reforms to accelerate progress toward UHC (Savedoff & Yazbeck, 2020; Yazbeck et al., 2020). These reforms may entail the expansion of non‐contributory government financing arrangements (e.g., Brazil, Bolivia), or the introduction and/or expansion of contributory social health insurance (SHI) arrangements (e.g., Ghana, Ethiopia). In this paper, SHI financing refers to health expenditures channelled via SHI agencies, implying that a contribution is required to access services, irrespective of whether the contribution is subsidized by the government or not. Government financing refers to any other non‐contributory public health expenditure, that is, where access to services is automatic, not linked to contributions, and usually based on citizenship or residency status. In either case, the aim is to increase pooled public health expenditure and to transition away from out‐of‐pocket (OOP) private health expenditure (World Health Organization, 2019) toward UHC. HFS reforms entail substantial long‐term administrative efforts (e.g., setting up new laws and functional agencies), and may impact financial risk protection and population health for years to come.

Despite the importance of HFS as a major factor for achieving UHC, there is scarce empirical cross‐country evidence on the impact of HFSs on health system outcomes. Two important but regionally focused studies (on OECD and Eastern European countries) from more than a decade ago concluded that introducing SHI led to no improvement or even to a deterioration of health outcomes, while having increased costs (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff and Moreno‐Serra, 2009a). A common issue in these studies is that a country's HFS, depending on existing laws, could only be classified as either “tax‐based” or “SHI”. By allowing only these two classifications, countries financed predominantly by OOP expenditures were (mis‐)classified as either tax‐based or SHI. In addition, only the effects of transitioning from tax‐based to SHI HFS were examined, thus ignoring the potential effects of transitioning from predominantly OOP to either tax‐based or SHI HFSs. Another global study found that (proportional) increases in expenditure in contributory SHI and non‐contributory government financing are positively correlated with service coverage indicators, but only non‐contributory government financing is correlated with improvements in financial risk protection (Wagstaff & Neelsen, 2020). This study investigated the association of HFS with financial risk protection and service coverage but not health status, controlled only for GDP per capita, and most importantly did not investigate transitions from OOP to either SHI or government financing predominant HFS, which is arguably the decision commonly faced by policymakers when contemplating potential paths toward UHC. Other, broadly related studies have investigated the impact of public health expenditure on health system outcomes, mostly finding a positive effect (Nakamura et al., 2016), yet without differentiating public health expenditures into government or SHI financing sources. Finally, a recent systematic review of relevant country case‐studies concludes that public health insurance, defined as SHI and community‐based health insurance, appears to reduce financial risk protection (Erlangga et al., 2019). However, it is not clear whether this effect is applicable to the entire populations of SHI‐countries, or to SHI beneficiaries alone.

In this paper, we seek to assess the impact of different HFSs on health system outcomes (i.e., health status, financial risk protection and utilization (Kutzin, 2008)), and on health expenditures, with a view to informing decisions about potential transitions to either contributory SHI or non‐contributory government financing, aimed at accelerating progress toward UHC. We also shed light on potential contextual factors likely to affect the impact of HFSs.

We find that transitions from OOP‐ to SHI‐predominant HFS resulted in increased total health expenditure. However, transitions to government‐predominant HFS resulted in greater immunization coverage, and improved health system outcomes (life expectancy, under‐5 mortality and incidence of catastrophic health expenditure). As potential reasons, we discuss the role of (higher) costs for implementing SHI, its benefits being contribution‐linked, the tendency to favor secondary/tertiary care expenditures, and SHI's limited ability to decrease OOP expenditures. We also detect a role for contextual factors: in particular, increases in informal sector size diminish the effects of HFS on most health system outcomes. Other contextual factors considered (GDP per capita, governance) also act as effect modifiers of HFS, albeit to a lesser extent.

Endogeneity, driven by reverse causality (e.g., as countries with low financial risk protection may be more likely to introduce SHI) and omitted variable bias, is a central challenge in all studies investigating the association between HFS, health expenditure and health system outcomes (Nakamura et al., 2016), and our study is no exception in this regard. We seek to address endogeneity via fixed effects regressions, exploiting the variation in HFS generated by the health financing transition, which allows controlling for the influence of unobservable or unmeasured time‐invariant factors. As our results are robust to most, but not all, different specifications and outcomes, concerns regarding endogeneity driven by reverse causality are not completely resolved. For this reason, we do not claim to provide entirely causal evidence.

This paper contributes to the literature in several ways. First, we refine the classification of HFS by using a machine‐learning, data‐driven approach, which allows us to distinguish contributory SHI‐, non‐contributory government‐, and OOP‐predominant HFSs. Second, we examine the separate effects of transitions from OOP‐predominant to SHI‐ or government‐predominant HFSs. This is an advance on previous studies that commonly considered public health expenditure as a bundled aggregate, irrespectively of its specific financing nature (Filmer & Pritchett, 1999; Moreno‐Serra & Smith, 2015; Nakamura et al., 2016; Rajkumar & Swaroop, 2008), and on studies that did not model transitions from OOP‐ to SHI‐ or government‐predominant HFSs (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a; Wagstaff & Neelsen, 2020). We also use panel data across more country‐years than previous HFS studies, and—in order to reduce omitted variable bias—we take into account the potential role of multiple contextual factors that were used in the public health expenditure literature (Nakamura et al., 2016), but were neglected in previous SHI‐related studies (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a; Wagstaff & Neelsen, 2020). Finally, we provide more depth to the conclusion that “context matters”, by empirically investigating interactions between contextual factors (e.g., informal sector size) and HFS transitions.

While these results should not be taken to imply that non‐contributory government‐predominant HFSs are always ‘better’ than contributory SHI‐predominant systems, they may raise a warning to policymakers favoring the path of SHI to accelerate progress toward UHC, while reassuring those aiming for expansions of non‐contributory government‐financed systems.

2. HEALTH FINANCING SYSTEMS (HFS) AND HYPOTHETICAL EFFECTS ON HEALTH SYSTEM OUTCOMES

Figure 1 illustrates the hypothetical pathways mapping HFS reforms to health system outcomes through intermediate outputs and outcomes. More detailed pathway examples are provided in Appendix 1. A country with ‘predominant‐OOP HFS’ has its total health expenditure (THE) predominantly contributed through OOP, as identified via cluster analysis, and similarly for other classification categories (more on this in Section 3.1).

FIGURE 1.

FIGURE 1

Conceptual framework. Source: authors' elaboration, expanding frameworks presented in (Kutzin, 2008). The conceptual framework follows a logic model representation. Black lines represent potential causal pathways between HFS and health system outcomes; numbers attached to black lines refer to hypotheses listed in the “Hypotheses” section. The two hypotheses and two unintended consequences noted in the figure are not exhaustive. Red lines represent the pathways investigated by this study. Blue lines represent pathways investigated by existing cross‐country regression studies: Wagstaff and Moreno‐Serra, 2009, and Wagstaff and Neelsen, 2020

As shown in the above framework, governments may reform their HFSs to increase (pooled, pre‐paid) public revenues and public health expenditure. These efforts are in line with the recommendation of increasing public health expenditures in order to avoid that OOP expenditures increase impoverishment (Xu et al., 2003) and decrease utilization of health services (Qin et al., 2019). For example, assume a country with very high OOP health expenditures decides to subsidize completely all health services to under‐5 year old children and pregnant women. The pool of (fully) covered patients increases and more public revenues (payroll contributions and/or general taxes) are then raised to pay for those services. OOP expenditures of pregnant women and families with under‐5 year old children will be expected to decrease as services previously paid by OOP are now subsidized by the government via pre‐paid taxes: these families are now more protected against financial risk (related to OOP health expenditures). Government non‐contributory financing emerges as the largest contributor to THE, exemplifying what we call a transition (Fan & Savedoff, 2014a; World Health Organization, 2019) from OOP‐predominant to government‐predominant HFS. As in the health financing transition described in the literature (Fan & Savedoff, 2014a), THE per capita is likely to grow while government financing expenditure becomes predominant and OOP expenditure as percentage of THE decreases. Higher THE, especially via increased government financing and decreased OOP expenditure, would translate into more services offered to the population (Qin et al., 2019). Assuming there is demand for the services, the population will use more services than before, and, if those services are of sufficient quality, population health will improve (Moreno‐Serra & Smith, 2015). Similarly, THE may be spent more efficiently when it is pooled and pre‐paid: families paying for services OOP do not pool together their financial resources and pre‐pay for complex and efficient services, such as vaccination or public health campaigns, and neither can they share the risks of ill health across life‐stages (old‐young) or social strata (rich‐poor). Pre‐paid pooled expenditures in principle allow the government to deliver cost‐effective, preventative health services such as vaccinations, community health, and others, as well as to pool the risks of different individuals together (Moreno‐Serra & Smith, 2015). In both these cases (i.e., when THE increases and/or when THE is spent more efficiently), if pregnant women and families with children under‐5 who utilize public services belong to poorer population groups, health equity may also be positively impacted.

Contextual factors and unintended consequences are included in the conceptual framework. Contextual factors are to a certain extent not directly part of—and to a certain extent may be external to—HFS transitions (e.g., quality of governance, education or income per capita), and may modify the effect of HFSs on health system outcomes (Rajkumar & Swaroop, 2008). One example of an unintended consequence is that the introduction of SHI funded via payroll contributions SHI may drive lower formal employment (Savedoff, 2004; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009b; Yazbeck et al., 2020), which in turn may reduce the amount of revenues generated to fund the system and hence limit SHI coverage.

Figure 1 also shows the effects investigated by previous studies (blue lines), and the effects investigated in this paper (red lines), highlighting our contribution to the literature. An important clarification is required: as shown by the red arrow, we do not investigate the effect of an SHI reform in the way this has been done in (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a), which would classify as “SHI” any country with SHI policies, laws and institutions. The effect we investigate is that of health expenditure transitions, from being OOP‐predominant to being government‐ or SHI‐predominant. Take for example, Ghana, which introduced the National Health Insurance Fund (NHIF, a form of SHI) in 2004. By 2017, OOP still accounted for the largest proportion of Ghana's total health expenditures. Hence, Ghana is classified in this paper as an OOP‐predominant HFS country, rather than a SHI country, despite the existence of SHI laws and institutions. Therefore, our analysis does not estimate the effect of the introduction of the SHI policy in Ghana. Similarly, Brazil's public health system was instituted by law in 1990, but its HFS transitioned from being OOP‐predominant to being government‐predominant only in the 2000–2017 period: our study measures the effect of Brazil's (and other countries') health financing transition out of OOP expenditure, rather than the introduction of laws to expand primary healthcare services. As these examples illustrate, our baseline estimates of the effects for SHI‐ and government financing‐predominant HFS should be interpreted as the effects of SHI or government financing policies that are successful in making a HFS transition from OOP predominance to SHI or government financing predominance. SHI or government financing policies that fail to do so would result in HFS being classified as OOP predominant HFS. The effect of increased SHI or government financing expenditure that does not translate into a change in predominant HFS is explored in models where we use SHI and government finance as % of THE as treatment variables (Appendix 6), instead of using SHI‐ and government financing‐predominant HFS dummies, and in models exploring within‐group changes in financing arrangements percentages (Appendix 4).

3. METHODS

3.1. Health financing system definition

Different health financing arrangements tend to coexist in a country's HFS. The three major health financing arrangements contributing to THE are government financing, social health insurance (SHI) and OOP. These financing arrangements account for 89% of THE on average across all countries, all years (2000–2017); the remainder is largely voluntary health insurance, which includes community‐based health insurance. Details regarding data sources is in Appendix 2, while detail about health financing arrangements are presented in Appendix 3 (Wagstaff, 2009b).

Government financing is universal in that it provides healthcare coverage to the population automatically based on residency or citizenship status, without requiring a direct contribution. Health services are pre‐paid, usually by general taxation, and there is usually a common pool for all residents/citizens. Predominantly government‐financed countries, whose public health systems are often referred to as “national health service”, are for example, UK, Italy, Spain, Australia, Canada, and Cuba. Publicly funded health insurance schemes that are entirely non‐contributory (e.g., Thailand Universal Coverage Scheme (Sumriddetchkajorn et al., 2019), or India Ayushman Bharat Pradhan Mantri Jan Aarogya Yojana) are also considered government financing. Due to data limitations, non‐contributory government financing arrangements that show features typical of health insurance schemes (e.g., provider and payer split, health insurance premiums or budgets paid by the government) cannot be separated from other non‐contributory government financing arrangements. SHI‐financing is also pre‐paid, but it differentiates itself from government financing by being contributory: a contribution has to be paid for a person/household to be able to receive healthcare coverage. Traditionally, the contribution is a deduction from the person's payroll. Individuals or households that do not contribute are not covered. In recent ‘extended’ forms, population groups that are usually identified as unable or ineligible for payroll or premium contributions are covered through government subsidies out of general tax revenues. In either of these cases, there may be different pools in the same country. Examples of SHI‐predominant countries are for example, Germany, France, Austria, Japan, Poland, and Turkey. Both government financing and SHI financing are heterogeneous and implementation differs by country. OOP financing is generally characterized by private citizens buying or paying for health services when needed, without any pre‐payment or risk pooling. Some government financing‐ and SHI‐predominant HFSs may have OOP co‐payments made by citizens/members: these fees are included in OOP expenditures. OOP‐predominant countries are for example, Armenia, Bangladesh, Mali, Ecuador, Liberia and India.

Previous studies have classified into the “SHI” group those countries with SHI laws, SHI institutions and/or earmarked payroll deductions (Wagstaff, 2009b; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a) (i.e., the Bismarck model). All other countries were usually classified as “tax‐based” (i.e., the Beveridge model (van der Zee & Kroneman, 2007)). This approach arguably runs the risk of potentially having misclassified OOP‐predominant countries as tax‐based HFS (Armenia, Azerbaijan, Ukraine, Uzbekistan, Kyrgyz Republic). As shown in Table 1, A1, A2, A4, in all these countries, OOP expenditure is the main contributor to THE. In addition, we provide examples from other countries not included in (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a).

TABLE 1.

Comparison of countries' health financing system (HFS) classification across studies

Country HFS classification in this paper* HFS:SHI or tax‐based (Wagstaff, 2009b; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a)* SHI financing as % of THE Government financing as % of THE OOP expenditures as % of THE
Liberia OOP Tax‐based 0 31.74 45.51
Armenia OOP Tax‐based 0 14.18 84.35
Azerbaijan OOP Tax‐based 0 15.45 83.86
Kyrgyz Republic OOP Tax‐based 6.760 35.47 56.38
Ukraine OOP Tax‐based 0 44.64 52.32
Uzbekistan OOP Tax‐based 0 44.98 53.43
Bolivia Government SHI 30.08 39.92 25.08
Indonesia OOP SHI 22.65 26.46 34.61
Ecuador OOP SHI 24.18 29.37 39.40
El Salvador OOP SHI 24.7 24.65 29.20
Nicaragua OOP SHI 24.12 39.67 32.60
UK Government Tax based 0 78.80 15.96
Italy Government Tax‐based 0 73.71 23.49
France SHI SHI 78.05 5.326 9.384
Germany SHI SHI 78.05 6.308 12.67
Hungary SHI SHI 61.09 8.118 26.89

Note: *possible classifications: OOP‐, government‐ or SHI‐predominant,. As an example, we take 2017 data. Countries in italics were not included in (Wagstaff, 2009b; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a), we classified them based on the rules used in those papers. The sum of OOP, government financing and SHI as % of THE may not equal 100% due to other health financing arrangements (e.g., voluntary private health insurance arrangements, non‐resident arrangements).

Source: Author elaboration.

One option is to use expenditure data to define HFS via arbitrary thresholds. However, arbitrary choices may also misclassify countries with no clearly predominant financing arrangement.

By contrast, a clustering approach provides a classification that has two main benefits: it is largely data‐driven and uses as input health expenditures, rather than more arbitrary classification mechanisms based on information, which would be hard to interpret or collect across all world countries. Using k‐means clustering (MacQueen, 1967), each country‐year combination is assigned to the HFS that has the closest mean values of government‐, SHI‐ and OOP‐expenditure as percentage of THE. More detail regarding the clustering procedure is provided in Appendix 3. In this approach, the arbitrary choices are limited to the input factors and the number of groups. For the input factors, OOP, SHI and government financing expenditure as % of THE are chosen because, together, they make 89% of total health expenditure in our sample. Other schemes (non‐profit institutions serving households (NPISH), voluntary health insurance) are below 5% as a % of THE, and in no country‐year observation are found to be the largest scheme. We choose to have three groups because in this way we can better address the research question (i.e., the effect of transitions from OOP to SHI and government financing HFSs), and because clustering optimization analyses (Makles, 2012) suggest that three groups is an optimal choice (see Appendix 3). The HFS variable generated by the analysis has three possible values: government‐, SHI‐ and OOP‐predominant HFS by country‐year. We use the word “predominant” because in all cases HFS are a mix of different health financing arrangements: while one arrangement is predominant, other arrangements coexist. In fact, another benefit of clustering is that it recognizes the mixed nature of HFS by considering data regarding all three major health financing arrangements when assigning country‐year observations to HFS groups. In this paper, a health financing transition is defined as a country's “switch” that lasts at least 2 years from an OOP‐predominant HFS to a SHI‐ or government‐predominant HFS.

As the definition of the predominant HFS by country‐year may affect our results, we explore the robustness of our main results to different ‘predominant HFS’ definitions. First, we define the predominant HFS using the highest value between government‐, SHI‐ and OOP‐expenditure as percentage of THE. Second, to address concerns that country‐year observations may be classified as OOP‐predominant while having OOP expenditures as % of THE below 40% (see Table 1), we use different thresholds to define OOP‐predominant HFS. In other words, we define a country‐year observation as OOP‐predominant only if OOP expenditures as percentage of THE is larger than a threshold t, for example, 50%, 45%, 40%, etc. Third, we add other health financing arrangements variables to the clustering procedure so that all health financing arrangements making up 100% of THE (i.e., NPISH as % of THE, voluntary health insurance as % of THE, enterprise schemes as % of THE, and rest of the world schemes as % of THE) are considered.

3.2. Empirical strategy: Fixed effects and specification tests

3.2.1. Empirical strategy

The main specification is as follows:

Yit=α+ρ1SHIit+ρ2GOVit+γXit+Tt+Ci+εit (1)

Where Y represents an outcome of interest from Figure 1, in country i at time t. SHI and GOV are HFS dummies that take value 1 if the country‐year observation respectively belongs to the SHI‐predominant or government‐predominant HFS group, and 0 otherwise. OOP is the reference HFS. X is a vector of control variables. T represents time fixed effects (FE), and C country FE, which respectively control for cross‐country shocks and time‐invariant unobservable variables. Coefficients ρ1 and ρ2 can be interpreted as the within‐country effect on outcome Y of transitioning (i.e., switching) from OOP, the reference category, to SHI‐ and government‐predominant HFS, holding controls (detailed later) constant.

To investigate the question “how does context matter”, we augment our model by interacting SHI‐ and government‐predominant HFS dummies with several contextual factors (Equation 2), detailed later.

Yit=α+β1SHIit×CFit+β2GOVit×CFit+CFit+SHIit+GOVit+Xit+Tt+Ci+εit (2)

For the contextual factor analysis, we are interested in the interaction terms coefficients β1 and β2, which will be interpreted as CFit modification on the effect of SHIit and GOVit on outcome Yit by computing SHIit and GOVit at different values of CFit.

The main model in Equation (2) is similar to a generalized difference‐in‐difference (DiD) estimator, with two reversible treatments, one reference group (OOP predominant group), and different treatment timing (i.e., a country can switch from the OOP group to SHI or GOV groups and vice versa at any t). DiD assumes a parallel trend: we therefore subject our results to tests of the DiD parallel trend assumption as done in (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a).

3.2.2. Specification tests

We conduct tests of the parallel trend assumption using random trend and differential trend models. In the random trend model, we relax the parallel trend assumption by adding country‐specific linear trends (cit), as shown in the following equation:

Yit=α+ρ1SHIit+ρ2GOVit+γXit+Tt+Ci+cit+εit (3)

We estimate Equation (3) with and without country‐specific linear trends. We then test whether the SHI and GOV effects are different in FE models with country‐specific trends (FECS) and FE models without them (FE) (Clogg et al., 1995):

Z=ρ1FECSρ1FESEρ1FECS2+SEρ1FE2 (4)

This test allows using SEs clustered at country level. Non‐rejection of the tests in Equation (4) (2 tests per model, one for ρ1 and one for ρ2) would suggest that ρFECS and ρFE are not different, that cit are not correlated with SHI or GOV, and that the parallel trend assumption (PTA) is consistent with our data. This can be seen intuitively: Equation (3) without cit is equal to Equation (1).

The random trend model assumes that each country trend is linear and is not affected by SHI and GOV. These assumptions are likely to not hold in our case, as it is likely that SHI and GOV affect country trends. We therefore relax the parallel trend assumption using a differential trend model (Blundell & Costa Dias, 2009; Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a). The error term is now:

εit=Ci+kSmt+εitifSHI=1Ci+kGmt+εitifGOV=1Ci+kOmt+εitifSHI=GOV=0 (5)

Where mt is an unobserved (differential) trend whose effect on the outcomes is different across SHI‐, government‐ and OOP‐predominant countries. This allows each HFS group trend to be non‐linear and modified by SHI and GOV, as shown in the following equation:

Yit=α+ρ1SHIit+kSkOSHIitmt+ρ2GOVit+kGkOGOVitmt+γXit+kOmt+Ci+εit (6)

Equation (6) can be estimated via fixed effects, with interactions between year dummies (first year dummy is excluded and used as reference) and treatment dummies:

Yit=α+ρ1SHIit+t=2Tρ1tSHIitYEARt+ρ2GOVit+t=2Tρ2tGOVitYEARt+γXit+βtYEARt+Ci+εit (7)

The effect of each transition can be calculated as the average effect of SHI and GOV, respectively:

MeanSHIimpact=ρ1+t=2Tρ1t/T1MeanGOVimpact=ρ2+t=2Tρ2t/T1 (8)

As shown in (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a) the PTA in the differential trend implies that kSkO=kGkO=0, which can be tested via the following nonlinear restriction, for ρ1t and ρ2t:

kSkOtmtkOtmt=t=2Tρ1tt=2Tβt=0kGkOtmtkOtmt=t=2Tρ2tt=2Tβt=0 (9)

Again, non‐rejection of these tests would suggest that the PTA is consistent with our data. This can be seen intuitively: Equation (6) reduces itself to Equation (1) when kSkO=kGkO=0

Reverse causality does remain a concern, as a country will likely increase SHI and government financing when population health is deteriorating (e.g., a health crisis such as Ebola or COVID‐19): we expect that reverse causality will bias the estimated coefficients for SHI and government HFSs downward for life expectancy, and upward for mortality and catastrophic health expenditure incidence. We run a test of reverse causality (in a Granger sense) used in the related literature (Gruber & Hanratty, 1995; Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a), noting that the test does not necessarily imply causality (Angrist a&nd Pischke, 2008a). We add to Equations (1), Equations (3) and (7) lead HFS variables (SHIi,t+1, GOVi,t+1) that indicate whether the following year there will be a transition from OOP to SHI or government financing. A non‐zero coefficient would suggest that endogeneity is not appropriately addressed, while a zero coefficient would indicate the opposite.

Finally, the recent literature on country and time FE regressions has highlighted the problem (“negative weights”) that, in the context of heterogeneous treatment effects, the FE estimator is a weighted average of different effects, including the treatment effect of early versus late treatment adopter, and vice‐versa (Goodman‐Bacon, 2018). We therefore decompose ρ1 and ρ2 (Equation 1) to explore whether this issue is affecting our results, for countries for which the transition was staggered (i.e., they remained exposed to the HFS they transitioned to).

Stata 14 (StataCorp, 2015) has been used. Heteroskedastic‐ and within‐panel serial correlation‐robust SEs, clustered at the country level, are reported. A replication package is provided in the data availability statement.

4. DATA

We use annual data for the 2000–2017 period across a global sample of countries from different sources; due to data limitations, our main models include 124 countries. Sample construction details, variables definition, and source datasets are provided in Appendix 2.

4.1. Health financing data

The data on health expenditures (by financing arrangement) as percentages of THE, which is used for the cluster analysis, are from the WHO Global Health Expenditure Database (GHED), for the 2000–2017 period. WHO collects GHED data from countries using the System of Health Accounts (SHA) 2011 methodology (OECD et al., 2017). We use data under the “Health Care Financing Schemes” section, classification codes HF.1–4. In this paper, we use “arrangement” as a synonym of scheme, to avoid confusion with HFS (health financing system). If tax revenues are used to finance a SHI agency providing contributory SHI coverage, those revenues are “channelled via” SHI and are counted as SHI expenditure. Predominance can be read as “health expenditures channelled predominantly via a” non‐contributory government, contributory SHI, or OOP arrangement, based on clustering results. As noted in the literature (Rannan‐Eliya, 2008), OOP financing estimates suffer from potential data quality concerns. SHI as a health financing scheme comprises both compulsory public health insurance (96% of total SHI, across all countries, 2000–2017) and compulsory private health insurance (4% of total SHI financing, across all countries, 2000–2017).

4.2. Intermediate outcomes and health system outcomes

Intermediate outcomes comprise the immunization coverage index (i.e., the average of measles, DPT and hepatitis immunization rates) from World Bank World Development Indicators (WDI) (World Bank, 2019c), and (logged) THE per capita in current US$ from WHO GHED. Health status health system outcomes are life expectancy (LE), maternal mortality (MM), and under‐5 child mortality (U5M), also from WDI. Mortality outcomes have been logged, as done in the related literature. The World Bank Health Equity and Financial Protection indicators (HEFPI) dataset (World Bank, 2019a) has been used for the financial risk protection health system outcomes. Since there are many different measures of financial risk protection, the most commonly used (Wagstaff et al., 2018) has been chosen: catastrophic health expenditure incidence at the 10% level (CAT 10%). Health equity and the UHC index are not used as an outcome due to data limitations. Data for the UHC index was available only for 2010 within the data period of the analysis 2000–2017 from the Global Burden of Disease UHC dataset (Lozano et al., 2020).

4.3. Contextual factors: Control variables and interaction terms

We select control variables (contextual factors in our conceptual framework, Figure 1) that may confound the relationship between public health expenditure and health outcomes (Nakamura et al., 2016). The WDI dataset was used for (logged) GDP per capita (PPP, constant 2011 US$), education (primary school enrollment gross %), urbanization rate, % population with drinking water access, Gini index, and proportion of population above‐65 and below‐14 (Nakamura et al., 2016). The Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) dataset (World Bank, 2019b) was used to extract the control variables government effectiveness and corruption control. We do not control for THE, hospital beds and health workforce, as these factors would be on the causal pathway between HFS and health system outcomes (i.e., “bad controls” (Angrist & Pischke, 2008b)).

Contextual factors used as interaction terms in Equation (2) are often cited as “conditions required for” HFS to be successful (Yazbeck et al., 2020): (logged) GDP per capita, government effectiveness, corruption control, percentage of health revenues from payroll contributions (i.e., labour‐tax), informal sector size (informal workers as % of non‐agricultural jobs), and general government expenditure (GGE) as % of GDP.

5. RESULTS

This section is organized as follows: first, we show clustering results, then we present FE estimates, and, finally, tests and robustness checks including sub‐sample analysis (e.g., for LMICs specifically) are shown.

5.1. Clustering analysis results

Figure 2 shows the results of the k‐means clustering analysis. In the 2000–2017 period, the proportion of predominantly‐OOP countries decreased (−8%), while SHI‐predominant and government predominant increased (+4% each). The clustering analysis confirms the health financing transition from OOP to public health expenditure (Fan and Savedoff, 2014b), that is, government and SHI HFS (World Health Organization, 2019).

FIGURE 2.

FIGURE 2

Proportion of 124 countries by HFS, year 2000 to year 2017. Source: Author elaboration. The graph represents the percentage of countries assigned to each predominant‐HFS per year

Table 2 provides descriptive statistics for the three HFS groups. In SHI‐predominant country‐year observations, SHI channelled expenditure does not exceed 50% of THE, and there is slightly higher public health expenditure as a proportion of THE (i.e., sum of SHI and government financing as a % of THE) versus predominantly‐government financed systems. Table 2 suggests that selection into a HFS may not be random: SHI‐predominant observations show higher income, better health systems outcomes, higher THE, lower investments in primary health care (PHC) and lower informal sector size, versus other HFS′ groups. The OOP‐predominant HFS group is characterized, on average, by government financing being almost 30% of THE: in other words, OOP‐predominant systems are government financing systems with low public health expenditure.

TABLE 2.

Means of main characteristics for full sample and across HFS clusters

Variable Used as Full sample Predominant government HFS Predominant OOP HFS Predominant SHI HFS
N (max) 2646 848 1282 516
Life expectancy, at birth, years Outcome 68.8 68.8 65.5 77.0
Under‐5 mortality, per 1000 live births Outcome 44.3 39.4 62.1 8.3
Maternal mortality ratio, per 100,000 live births Outcome 218.3 180.9 324.2 16.8
Catastrophic health expenditure, 10% threshold Outcome 8.1 4.5 9.2 9.0
Immunization index Outcome 85.3 89.1 79.7 93.0
Compulsory health insurance (SHI) as % of THE Used to build HFS variable 16.0 2.7 7.3 59.3
Government financing as % of THE Used to build HFS variable 36.1 62.6 28.6 11.0
Out‐of‐pocket (OOP) as % of THE Used to build HFS variable 36.5 21.4 51.6 23.6
GDP per capita, PPP, current, international US$ Control and interaction term 15,394 21,662 7771 24,185
Corruption index Control and interaction term −0.10 0.293 −0.655 0.627
Government effectiveness Control and interaction term −0.05 0.242 −0.561 0.753
School enrollment, primary (% gross) Control 102.0 103.5 100.7 102.6
% population using drinking water services Control 83.0 83.5 76.6 98.0
% Population above 65 years old Control 7.7 7.7 5.2 14.1
% Population below 14 years old Control 29.6 28.8 34.7 18.4
Urbanization (% pop.) Control 56.2 59.1 48.6 70.3
Gini index Control 38.0 36.4 41.8 35.7
Health revenues from payroll contributions (%) Interaction term 12.0 2.1 6.3 42.7
Informal sector size (% of non‐agricultural jobs) Interaction term 57.38 48.40 65.95 32.68
GGE (% GDP) Interaction term 30.31 34.47 23.90 39.38
GGHE (% GGE) Intermediate outcome 9.7 10.4 7.6 13.7
THE (% GDP) Intermediate outcome 6.1 6.0 5.5 7.9
THE per capita, PPP, current international US$ Intermediate outcome 1006 416 2046 1274
Primary health care expenditure, as a % of THE Intermediate outcome 51.6 53.0 57.5 43.6

Source: Author elaboration, data: see Section 4.

Figure 3 focuses on the countries that switched from OOP to SHI or government financing HFS, or vice versa, in 2000–2017 (full list across 18 years in Appendix 3). Given that in FE regressions, within‐country variation is the focus (see 3.2.1), we note that seven countries switched from OOP to SHI, and 30 countries switched from OOP to government financing systems. SHI transitions show a lower decrease in OOP expenditures as % of THE (−6% percentage points), compared to government financing transitions (−13% percentage points). In both cases, the main public health expenditure arrangement increased significantly. In SHI transitions, not only OOP but also government financing did decrease (−8% of THE). For the government financing predominant HFS, the transition from OOP predominant to government financing predominant HFS is driven by growth in GGE as % of GDP (+6%) and growth in domestic health expenditure as % of GGE (+18%), which have finally resulted in a substantial increase in non‐contributory government financing as % of THE (Figure 4).

FIGURE 3.

FIGURE 3

Average of OOP, SHI and government financing as % of THE, during health financing transitions. Source: Author elaboration. The figure shows SHI, OOP and government financing as % of THE for countries that switched from OOP‐ to SHI‐predominant and government financing‐predominant HFS. The sum of OOP, government financing and SHI as % of THE may not equal 100% due to other health financing arrangements (e.g., voluntary private health insurance, non‐resident arrangements)

FIGURE 4.

FIGURE 4

Histogram of parallel trend assumption specification tests p‐values. Source: Author elaboration. Histogram of p‐values resulting from PTA tests of the (Savedoff & Yazbeck, 2020) GOV and SHI dummy variables, across 2 specifications, random trend model PTA test (Equation 4) and differential trend model PTA test (Equation 9), all 6 outcomes (total of 24 tests)

5.2. Regression results

Table 3 shows estimates from Equation (1). HFS coefficients in Table 3 represent the decrease/increase in the dependent variable (“outcome”) as a result of switching to a government‐ or SHI‐predominant HFS, from the reference OOP‐predominant system. HFS coefficients ρ for logged outcomes (THE per capita, U5M and MM) are interpreted as y%=(eρ1).

TABLE 3.

FE estimates for intermediate outcomes, health system outcomes

Intermediate outcomes HEALTH system outcomes
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log THE per capita Imm. Coverage LE Log U5M Log MM CAT 10%
FE FE FE FE FE FE
Government‐predominant 0.043 3.804 1.341** −0.083** −0.040 −3.256***
(0.041) (2.921) (0.579) (0.036) (0.040) (0.931)
SHI‐predominant 0.117*** −1.486 −0.128 0.051 0.034 6.467***
(0.035) (1.606) (0.395) (0.037) (0.067) (1.129)
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R 2 0.869 0.177 0.752 0.879 0.646 0.224
Observations 950 970 970 970 970 407
Number of countries 124 124 124 124 124 111

Note: FE estimates are the result of Equation (1). Robust SEs, clustered at country‐level, in parentheses. Details on HFS switches are detailed in Appendix 3. Full regression results including control variables are presented in Appendix 4. All models control for all variables listed as “control” in Table 2. p‐values for two‐sided t‐tests are reported as: ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Source: Author elaboration.

In terms of intermediate outcomes (as depicted in Figure 1), SHI transitions increase THE (column 1, +12.4%), while no such effect is visible for government financing transitions. FE estimates in column (Savedoff & Yazbeck, 2020) show that transitioning from a predominantly OOP to government‐ or SHI‐predominant HFS have effects that are not statistically different from zero on immunization coverage.

As for health system outcomes, transitioning from OOP‐ to government‐predominant HFS shows–for LE, U5M and CAT10%, respectively–rather strong evidence of an improvement (LE: +1.3 years, U5M: −8.7%, CAT10%: −3.3% points). Government‐predominant HFS transitions improve LE, U5M, and CAT10% (three out of four health system outcomes) significantly (p < 0.05) more so than SHI‐predominant HFS transitions. However, for CAT10%, the SHI lead tests–results not shown, see –suggest that SHI reverse causality may be a concern: since the SHI HFS lead is statistically different from zero, it appears that SHI transitions occur when CAT10% is high, and high CAT10% “anticipates” SHI transitions. No significant SHI transitions effects are found for maternal or under‐5 mortality.

One concern is that health financing mix heterogeneity within HFS groups may affect our results. For example, an increase in SHI‐financing as % of THE within the OOP predominant group may affect outcomes. To scrutinize this, we run FE regressions of government, SHI, and OOP expenditures as a percentage of THE on all outcomes within the government‐, SHI‐ and OOP‐predominant sub‐groups: in only six models out of 36, within‐group changes in financing arrangements show effects on outcomes different from zero (at 10% level) (see Appendix 4). In other words, within‐group heterogeneity in the percentage of expenditure channelled via different health financing arrangements has limited impact on outcomes.

5.3. How does context matter?

Estimates of Equation (2) using all six outcomes and six contextual factors (GDP per capita, informal sector size, proportion of health revenues from labor taxes, government expenditure as percentage of GDP, control of corruption, government effectiveness) are presented in Appendix 5. In seven of the 36 models estimated, at least one interaction term is significant (5% level), confirming empirically a non‐trivial role of contextual factors. We report on those significant estimates only.

The informal sector size is the contextual factor modifying the effect of HFS transitions in most cases: a one percentage point increase in informal sector size together with a transition to SHI‐predominant HFS increases U5M by 0.6%, and decreases immunization coverage by 0.2% points (the latter, when informal sector is beyond 65%). The same increase in informal sector size together with government financing HFS has a very similar effect on immunization coverage, but no effect on U5M. An increase in the log of GDP per capita improves the negative effect of SHI transitions on immunization coverage (+4.8% points), while better corruption control together with SHI‐predominant HFS transition delivered higher general government health expenditure as % of general government expenditure (+0.9% points in general government health expenditure per 1 point increase in the control of corruption index).

A percentage point increase in general government expenditure (as % of GDP) together with government‐predominant HFS transitions decreases general government health expenditure (% of general government expenditure), but the effect is very small (−0.08% points): possibly ministries of finance having large budgets tend to prioritize health sector funding slightly less as a proportion of total budget, when high absolute funding levels are considered sufficient. A one percentage point increase in health revenues coming from labor taxes together with SHI‐predominant transitions also decreases general government health expenditure (% of general government expenditure) (−0.12% points).

5.4. Specification tests and robustness checks

We present first the results of parallel trend assumption specification tests (Equations 4 and 9) which suggest that the parallel trend assumption is consistent with our data in the large majority of cases (∼75%), justifying the use of Equation (1) as our main specification. In the cases interested by potential parallel trend assumption rejections, we present random trend and differential trend model estimates (see Appendix 6, Panel G). These results do not change our conclusion.

Second, we present in Figure 5 the results of the reverse causality tests (p‐values of GOV and SHI 1‐year leads in Equations (1), (3), and (7)): the vast majority of lead HFS (∼85%) are not significantly different from zero, suggesting that reverse causality is a rather limited issue across the vast majority of outcomes. However, the reverse causality (in a Granger sense) tests suggest that SHI transition occur when CAT 10% is particularly high, therefore the SHI coefficient for CAT 10% is likely affected by reverse causality.

FIGURE 5.

FIGURE 5

Histogram of reverse causality test p‐values. Source: Author elaboration. Histogram of p‐values of leads of GOV and SHI dummy variables regressed on 6 outcomes across 3 specifications: main DID specification, random trend model (Equation 3), and differential trend model PTA test (Equation 7) (total of 36 tests)

Beyond specification tests, we subject our estimates to a series of robustness checks (Appendix 6). First, based on potentially very different contextual patterns in LMICs as compared to high‐income countries, we restrict the sample to LMICs. We also run sub‐group analyses restricting the sample to the high‐ and middle‐income countries, and to middle‐income countries only. Second, given concerns about public health data quality (Moreno‐Serra & Smith, 2015; Nakamura et al., 2016), we remove outliers (approx. 1% of the sample) using a non‐arbitrary methodology (Billor et al., 2000). Third, we use 1‐year lagged HFS independent variables as HFS effects on health system outcomes may not be contemporaneous. To explore the robustness of our main results to potentially lagged effects and reverse causality (in a Granger sense), we also implement visual event studies. Fourth, since general government expenditure as a percentage of GDP may limit the impact of HFS, we add it as a control variable. Fifth, we estimate Equation (1) using government and SHI as % of THE instead of HFS dummy variables (removing OOP expenditures as % of THE from the model due to collinearity issues, since the sum of all health financing arrangements is 100%). Sixth, we provide estimates of random trend and differential trend models in cases where the parallel trend assumption is rejected. Seventh, In the related literature, mortality outcomes have been either log‐transformed (Bokhari et al., 2007; Filmer & Pritchett, 1999; Rajkumar & Swaroop, 2008) or un‐transformed (Moreno‐Serra & Smith, 2015; Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a): to accommodate this alternative practice, in Panel H we use the natural units version of previously logged outcomes. Eighth, since the use of one of our control variables (Gini index) results in a loss of approximately half of total observations, we remove it to check for potential selection bias induced by missing observations. In addition, we remove other controls so that all countries in the dataset are included in the regression. Ninth, we add development assistance for health (as % of THE) to the list of control variables. Finally, we apply adjustments to all time‐varying controls that are related to HFS treatment (Zeldow & Hatfield, 2021).

Our baseline results are largely robust to the vast majority of the above‐mentioned specifications changes. Using random trend and differential models that relax the parallel trend assumption, the estimated coefficients on LE and CAT10% lose significance but show the same sign as the baseline coefficients. Adding unit‐specific linear trends (i.e., random trend model) would increase the importance of countries treated at the beginning and end of the panel (Goodman‐Bacon, 2018). For all other outcomes, baseline results are unaffected by relaxing the parallel trend assumption. In one specification (HFS percentages), the government HFS effect on LE loses significance. In the same specification, government financing improves CAT10% and U5M significantly more than SHI (not shown). Our results are particularly sensitive to this robustness check: while our clustering‐based HFS definition captures changes in the predominant HFS, HFS percentages capture changes in THE composition regardless of the predominant HFS. In other words, these results suggest that increasing SHI or government financing as a percentage of THE may not have a sizable impact on health outcomes, if the predominant HFS does not change.

Event studies confirm that government financing improves LE and U5M, in particular after 4–5 years, while SHI does not show improvements for any outcome. Using different definitions of HFS (i.e., using the highest value between government financing, SHI and OOP expenditures as a percentage of THE, and using OOP thresholds, as described in Section 3.1) does not substantially affect the main results either. In the “highest HFS value” specification, the coefficient for SHI effect on THE lose significance and the coefficient for SHI effect on logged MM shows a worsening, significant effect (+12.1% points, p < 0.01), suggesting possible health system outcomes worsening due to SHI transitions. The main results are also confirmed when adding all health financing arrangements variables in WHO GHED (i.e., NPISH as % of THE, enterprise schemes as % of THE, voluntary health insurance as % of THE), and when we add all health financing arrangement variables plus THE per capita as input variables to the clustering procedure: in either case, government financing HFS performs better than SHI HFS for all outcomes. Setting the number of clusters to four also shows that government financing predominant HFS perform better than predominant SHI HFS for U5M and CHE 10%, and never shows government financing being worse than SHI. Using additional health system outcomes (CHE 25%, impoverishment driven by OOP expenditures at the 1.90US$ and 3.20US$ poverty line, male and female adult mortality), and health system outcomes from different data sources (i.e., World Bank WDI “Maternal Mortality Ratio, National Estimates”; infant mortality and U5M from Demographic and Health Surveys), confirms that in most cases government financing predominant HFSs show better outcomes than SHI‐predominant HFSs.

Our baseline results are not affected by comparisons of late and early switchers (“negative weights”): the weight of ρ1 and ρ2 (Equation 1) driven by comparing late and early switchers outcomes is marginal for countries switching from OOP‐predominant to government financing HFS (weight 3%–5%) and to SHI‐predominant HFS (weight 1%–2%).

Across our three main specifications (DiD FE, random trend, and differential trend models), government financing transitions improve (at the 10% level) outcomes more than SHI transitions in most cases (53% of the time, Figure 6). The effects of SHI transitions on health outcomes do not exceed that of government financing transitions for any of the outcomes. Estimates from robustness checks largely confirm these conclusions.

FIGURE 6.

FIGURE 6

p‐values for difference between government financing and SHI coefficients. Source: Author elaboration. The Figure shows the histogram of p‐values for difference between government financing and SHI coefficients (ρ1ρ2=0 in [1], [3], [7]). Whenever the p‐value is below 10%, there is at least suggestive evidence that government financing HFS transitions show better results than SHI HFS transitions. The p‐values are 15, resulting from three models (FE model, random trend model and differential trend model) times five health system outcomes (LE, U5M, MM, CAT 10%, immunization). THE is not considered as an outcome because larger health expenditure is desirable only if larger expenditure translates into more services coverage

6. DISCUSSION

Achieving UHC is a widely shared health policy objective, and several countries are considering health financing systems (HFS) reforms (Yazbeck et al., 2020) to accelerate progress toward UHC. These HFS reforms seek to accelerate the health financing transition (Fan & Savedoff, 2014b; World Health Organization, 2019) from OOP‐predominant to public health expenditure (i.e., SHI‐ or government‐predominant expenditure as % of THE) predominant HFS. As policymakers face alternative health financing paths, it is important to understand what (if any) differences to health system outcomes they make.

Our main research objective has been to investigate the effect of transitions from OOP‐predominant to government‐ or SHI‐predominant HFSs on health system outcomes (i.e., health status, financial risk protection and utilization). Based on a conceptual framework for HFS transitions, we model HFS transitions from OOP‐predominant to SHI‐ and government‐predominant HFSs, assigning each country‐year observation to a predominant HFS using clustering—a machine learning approach. We estimate the effect of HFS transitions on intermediate and health system outcomes via FE regressions, controlling for time‐invariant as well as several contextual factors, while excluding potential “bad controls” (Angrist & Pischke, 2008b) on the causal pathway.

Transitions from OOP‐ to both government‐predominant and SHI‐predominant HFSs are both expected to deliver health system outcomes improvements via increased public health expenditure (see Section 2). However, we find that the effects of government‐predominant HFS transitions was more favourable than SHI‐predominant HFS transitions, for most outcomes. For the few outcomes where this was not the case, SHI and government‐predominant HFSs showed similar results. Hence, there is no outcome for which SHI transitions showed significantly better outcomes than government financing. These results are robust to most checks and tests.

Why do transitions to government financing appear to be superior to those to SHI? While we do not conduct a formal mediation analysis, we discuss several hypotheses on channels of influence, commenting on how the data may or may not support each possible channel.

The main difference between government and SHI financing is that SHI requires contributions made by or on behalf of the person accessing healthcare services. Despite recent cases of general taxation funding SHI expenditure (World Health Organization, 2019), SHI remains mostly financed by regular, typically wage‐related contributions (i.e., labor taxes, see Table 2): for many LMIC countries, this means that while formal workers are covered via compulsory contributions, for large parts of the population (i.e., informal workers) insurance coverage is voluntary (Barasa et al., 2021). SHI arrangements to cover the uninsured vary considerably across countries, and may generate pool fragmentation and pro‐rich bias (Barasa et al., 2021) (e.g., a pool with comprehensive benefit package for well‐off formal workers, and another one with a limited benefit package for the poor, the elderly, or an otherwise defined population group). Even when the non‐contributing poor or vulnerable are covered by subsidies, the informal non‐poor may be left out of affordable and quality options (Wagstaff, 2010). In our findings, informal sector size turns out indeed as the contextual factor with the biggest negative impact on the effects of HFS transitions.

SHI expansions may also come at higher costs and take longer time, compared to expansions of existing government financing mechanisms (see column (World Health Organization, 2020), Appendix 6). SHI requires institutional, technical and managerial capacity, and substantial investment to collect revenues and manage the provider‐payment system (Wagstaff, 2010). Limited regulatory capacity of purchasing institutions has been noted as a key issue (Wagstaff, 2010), and the time to develop capacity is not negligible: several countries in Western Europe took more than 70 years to reach UHC via SHI (Carrin & James, 2005). Expanding existing government financing arrangements would likely require less costs and time. The non‐healthcare‐related costs of SHI introductions or expansions may increase public health expenditure versus an OOP‐predominant‐system, with little improvements to healthcare coverage and finally health outcomes. SHI HFS have also traditionally focused on secondary/tertiary healthcare (Wagstaff, 2010) (suggested by Table 2, PHC expenditure descriptive statistics), which may be less efficient than PHC (Anderson et al., 2018). A full assessment of the relative performance of different types of HFS reforms would of course require a comparison of both the incremental costs and benefits of either HFS‐type–a challenge that is beyond the scope of this paper, and one that has hitherto not been met in the existing research (Kreif et al., 2021).

SHI transitions appear to not have succeeded in decreasing OOP expenditures as % of THE by as much as government financing transitions. SHI transitions decreased the reliance of THE on OOP expenditures, but they did so partially at the expense of non‐contributory government financing (see Figure 3). By contrast, government financing transitions did not result in a significant decrease in SHI financing (as % of THE), as illustrated by the experience of Moldova and Russia (see Appendix 7): increases in SHI expenditure (as % of THE) were accompanied by substantial decreases in government financing (as % of THE), less so in OOP (as % of THE), and a flattening of the U5M curve. At the same time, THE in both countries continued to grow.

Estimates using SHI and government financing as a % of THE (rather than predominant financing dummy variables) do not support the idea of SHI as a complementary arrangement either (Appendix 6, Panel F). Increases in SHI expenditure (% of THE) increased THE, but did not improve outcomes. This is compatible with the hypothesis that SHI for formal workers may result in pool fragmentation and pro‐rich health expenditure (Wagstaff, 2010), and that implementation costs are a reason for SHI's limited effects. Both these issues arise regardless of SHI being a complementary or a predominant HFS. Rather than introducing SHI as a complementary arrangement, favourable SHI features (e.g., provider‐purchaser split, explicit benefit packages entitlement, beneficiaries included in governance bodies, covering vulnerable groups via ad‐hoc interventions (Wagstaff, 2009a; Wagstaff, 2010; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009a)) could be included in existing government financing systems, and vice‐versa (e.g., via removing SHI link between contributions and services' access, making it de‐facto government financing).

Government‐financed systems may have undesirable features, too. While automatic universal coverage is a positive feature, benefit packages are often too ambitious, so that the “depth” of this coverage and the actual package of services delivered is often limited in LMICs (Wagstaff, 2013). Often, the purchaser‐provider split is missing, and when it is present, there is no joint decision‐making body, which includes purchaser(s), covered populations and providers. These arrangements can be implemented in government‐predominant HFS, but they are more typical of SHI‐predominant HFS. SHI‐predominant HFS could see a positive healthcare coverage effect from efficient purchaser‐provider systems: however, for such effect to materialize, a well‐functioning provider network is required. Assuming that a higher GDP per capita may mean better provider networks, the fact that SHI transitions have a more beneficial effect on immunization coverage when GDP per capita is higher (see Appendix 5 and Section 5.3) seem to support this idea. Similarly, a realistic and explicit benefit package, and the idea of entitlement provided by SHI, are seen as the main advantages of SHI (Yazbeck et al., 2020), and could be considered for inclusion in government financing systems.

Other contextual factors play a role, too. Perhaps counter‐intuitively, higher labour‐tax financing resulted in decreases in government health expenditure (in % of general government expenditure), for SHI‐predominant HFS transitions (see Appendix 5, column 36). Ministries of Finance may respond to higher SHI labour‐tax revenues by decreasing transfers from general tax revenues to health. While we find no evidence that a (proportional) increase in labour‐tax revenues modifies HFS effects on health, labour‐tax increases may increase informal sector size (Wagstaff, 2010; Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009b), which we find worsen SHI effects on health (Appendix 5, columns 1–6). Since we do not investigate the HFS impact on labor outcomes, and research in LMICs on this topic is limited (Le et al., 2019), this is an area for further research.

Many countries are contemplating SHI reforms for different reasons (Savedoff & Yazbeck, 2020; Yazbeck et al., 2020): increasing financial autonomy and increased budgets for health via earmarked‐to‐health labor taxes, the political attraction of providing entitlements (usually to formal sector workers, which include civil servants), and considering SHI enrollment as the UHC coverage measure. With government financing, all citizens/residents are covered, and the issue is the depth of such coverage, which is difficult to measure, while with SHI there is the SHI coverage measure to report on as “progress toward UHC”. Further research could focus on other reasons driving a resurgence in SHI reforms.

Since concerns about reverse causality and the parallel trends assumption could not be entirely resolved, and our results were robust to most–but not all–different specifications and outcomes, we do not claim to have presented fully causal impact estimates. The limitations that are to be borne in mind when interpreting the findings include: first, we do not take into consideration more extensive HFS and health system heterogeneity due to data limitations. Other health system features (e.g., gatekeeping, different provider‐payment systems, pooling fragmentation, private‐public providers, provider networks, governance structures, etc.) may also affect health system outcomes, but data on a global scale does not exist to capture those. Second, we note that the sample comprises only seven largely middle‐income countries that transitioned from OOP to SHI predominant systems (as mentioned in Section 5.1). However, interactions of the HFS treatment variable with log GDP per capita show limited heterogeneity in the effect of HFSs due to changes in log GDP per capita (Appendix 5), suggesting that this might not be a major issue. Finally, we have not addressed formally “how” (e.g., via mediation analysis) or “for whom” different HFSs work (e.g., health equity), due to data limitations.

While bearing these caveats in mind, the policy implication of these findings is that policymakers considering SHI transitions to accelerate progress toward UHC should take these results as a call for caution. For LMIC policymakers facing the challenge of large informal sectors, re higher poverty rates, and often not‐well‐functioning provider networks, the odds of accelerating progress toward UHC via introduction or expansion of contributory SHI appear more contained, as noted in the recent literature (Barasa et al., 2021). Pursuing the road toward non‐contributory financing expansions to accelerate progress toward UHC would appear as the more promising avenue, based on our findings. But then again, one cannot exclude the possibility that SHI can be made to work well for health system outcomes, and we cannot present non‐contributory government financing as being unambiguously superior to contributory SHI in every situation (Savedoff, 2004; Wagstaff, 2010; Yazbeck et al., 2020). For both expansions, our contextual factors analysis findings suggest that SHI performs better when informal sector is smaller, GDP per capita is higher, and, to a lesser extent, when control of corruption is higher and labor tax financing is lower. Other contextual factors that may improve the effects of SHI transitions comprise higher wages, functioning provider networks, higher government technical, regulatory and financial capacity, and lower average household size (Hsiao et al., 2007). Information regarding these contextual factors, and their expected trend, can further strengthen decision‐making confidence regarding HFSs reforms. These policy implications and findings are also relevant for governmental and non‐governmental development partners supporting governments in moving toward UHC via technical and financial assistance.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

None of the authors has any conflict of interest to declare.

ETHICS STATEMENT

We did not have to obtain ethical approval. All data used is secondary country‐level data from publicly available sources.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We would like to thank Dr. Rodrigo Moreno‐Serra for thoughtful comments, participants and especially discussants at the Health Economics Study Group meeting 2020, the IHEA conference 2021, the World Bank Health Financing Global Solutions Group seminar in October 2021, and the Centre for Health Economics seminar in February 2021. Jacopo Gabani receives funding via the Alan Maynard PhD scholarship from the University of York, Centre for Health Economics. The funder had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

APPENDIX 1. Differentiation across reforms of different health financing functions

The below figure helps clarify the idea that health financing reforms may impact health system outcomes through different pathways depending on the health financing function that is being reformed, as shown below.

graphic file with name HEC-32-574-g011.jpg

APPENDIX 2. Detail of variables and data construction

Sample construction:

Item Number of countries from item Number of countries (cumulative)
Total number of countries after merging all datasets and deleting countries not present in all datasets 183 183
Countries taken out because not all years present in a dataset 8 (Zimbabwe, Afghanistan, Yemen, Syria, Lybia, Iraq, South Sudan, Timor‐Leste) 175
Country missing outcome (life expectancy or maternal mortality) for at least 1 year 6 (Andorra, Dominica, Marshall Islands, Palau, San Marino, St. Kitts and Nevis) 169
Countries missing GHED data for at least 1 year 3 (Greece, Saudi Arabia, Albania) 166
Countries taken out because population <500.000 people in at least one period 18 (Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Cabo Verde, Grenada, Iceland, Kiribati, Luxembourg, Maldives, Malta, Micronesia, Samoa, Sao Tome and Principe, Seychelles, Solomon Islands, St. Lucia, Suriname, Tonga, Vanuatu) 147
Countries missing control variables 23 (United Arab Emirates, Bahrain, Bosnia Herzegovina, Cuba, Djibouti, Eritrea, Gabon, Equatorial Guinea, Guyana, Haiti, Japan, Cambodia, Kuwait, Lebanon, Myanmar, Namibia, New Zealand, Oman, Papua New Guinea, Qatar, Singapore, Turkmenistan, Trinidad and Tobago) 124
Total countries in study 124

Note: The table describes the sample construction.

Source: Author elaboration.

We have taken out 18 small and island countries, given that governance, health systems and health financing for those countries present peculiarities when compared to other countries. In small and island countries, changes in predominant HFS are more frequent than other countries (0.72 changes per country for small and island countries, vs. 0.43 in other countries, in the 2000–2017 period), and there are transitions from SHI to government financing system (and vice‐versa) that are not seen in other countries, raising concerns about data quality and relevance in the context of a cross‐country analysis.

Baseline results change when these countries are included, and when the HFS is defined via clustering. However, the main conclusion that the effect of government financing on health system outcomes is more or as favourable as that of SHI transitions is maintained. We also include all countries and define the predominant HFS using the highest value among government financing, SHI and OOP expenditures as % of THE, showing that estimates are similar to our baseline results and that, again, the conclusion that government financing effect on health system outcomes is better or as good as SHI is confirmed. These checks are presented with other robustness checks in Appendix 6, Table A3, panels E and F.

Variable definitions and source:

Variable Definition Source
Government financing as % of THE “Participation is automatic: For all citizens/residents; or a specific group of the population (e.g., the poor) defined by law/government regulation.” WHO GHED (WHO, 2019), based on OECD SHA. Definition is quoted from OECD SHA (World Bank, 2019a).
SHI as % of THE “Participation is mandatory: For all citizens/residents; or a specific group of the population defined by law/government regulation. In some cases, however, the enrollment requires actions to be taken by the eligible persons.”
OOP expenditures as % of THE “Participation is voluntary: Willingness to pay of the household.”
Immunization coverage Average of immunization coverage for measles, DPT and hepatitis World Bank WDI
Life expectancy Life expectancy at birth World Bank WDI
Maternal mortality Maternal mortality ratio, modeled estimate, per 100,000 live births World Bank WDI
Under‐5 mortality Under‐five mortality rate (death per 1000 live births) World Bank WDI
Catastrophic health expenditure Catastrophic health expenditure incidence (% population), at the 10% threshold World Bank HEFPI
GDP per capita GDP per capita, current, international US$, PPP World Bank WDI
Primary school enrollment (gross, %) Primary school enrollment (gross, % of population) World Bank WDI
Urbanization rate % Population in urban areas World Bank WDI
Drinking water access % Population with drinking water access World Bank WDI
Demographics: population below 14 % population below 14 World Bank WDI
Demographics: population above 65 % population above 65 World Bank WDI
Government effectiveness “Government effectiveness captures perceptions of the quality of public services, the quality of the civil service and the degree of its independence from political pressures, the quality of policy formulation and implementation, and the credibility of the government's commitment to such policies” World Bank WGI, definition quoted from https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/Home/downLoadFile?fileName=ge.pdf
Corruption control “Control of corruption captures perceptions of the extent to which public power is exercised for private gain, including both petty and grand forms of corruption, as well as "capture” of the state by elites and private interests.” World Bank WGI, definition quoted from: https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/Home/downLoadFile?fileName=cc.pdf

APPENDIX 3. Health financing arrangement details, and k‐means clustering

The health financing arrangement classifications (government financing, SHI and OOP) are not decided by the authors: they are defined by the System of Health Accounts (SHA), Health Financing Scheme (Chapter 7) standards, which form the basis for the WHO GHED. The reader is referred to the SHA manual for a detailed description of the health financing schemes mentioned and used in the paper.

Figure A1 clarifies the meaning of government‐financed, SHI‐financed and OOP‐financed. Government financing refers to “Government schemes”. SHI‐financing refers to Compulsory contributory health insurance schemes, which includes both SHI‐proper and private compulsory health insurance. We call it SHI‐financing to avoid confusion, since this is the usual name in the literature. Community based health insurance (not shown in the figure) is included under voluntary payment schemes. We also emphasize that in WHO GHED, what matters is the health financing scheme through which the monies are spent: if tax revenues are used to finance the country SHI agency providing contributory SHI, then such monies will be recorded under SHI (see p. 170 of the SHA 2011 manual (StataCorp, 2015)). However, if government pays premiums or finance the budget of an agency providing non‐contributory health insurance or services, those monies count as government financing. To avoid confusion, THE in this paper refers to “current health expenditure” in the GHED dataset. Finally, we note that external financing (i.e., development assistance for health) will be considered part of any given country's public financing scheme (i.e., SHI or government financing) if on‐budget. When off‐budget, external financing will largely be considered as financing via not‐for‐profit institutions serving households.

FIGURE A1.

FIGURE A1

Health financing schemes definitions. Source: Author elaboration based on OECD, Eurostat, WHO, 2017, Chapter 7

K‐means clustering (MacQueen, 1967) is an unsupervized machine learning technique described in many books. The k‐means cluster algorithm assigns each country‐year combination (i.e., each observation) to the cluster with the least squared Euclidean distance (other distances can be used), which is the cluster with the closest mean.

In this study, we choose to have three clusters as we expect to have country‐year combinations that belong to one of the following three groups: predominantly government‐financed, SHI‐financed or OOP financed. We choose that the variables used for clustering are government‐, SHI‐, and OOP‐financing as a % of THE. The algorithm starts by assigning random cluster “centroids” (a vector of three values, government schemes, SHI, and OOP, as a % of THE) and assigning each country‐year combination to the nearest cluster (i.e., the cluster with the least Euclidean distance). At this point, a new cluster centroid is calculated: it is a vector of the mean of the country‐year combinations assigned to the cluster. The process is repeated until the cluster centroids position does not change. Via this process, k‐means minimizes intra‐cluster variance: in other words, the sum of squared distances between each country‐year combination and the centroid of the assigned cluster is minimized.

K‐means clustering therefore considers, for each country‐year combination, the vector of government schemes, SHI, and OOP, each as a % of THE, and that k‐means is non‐arbitrary, except in the choice of the number of clusters, which we do based on theoretical reasoning about having 3 groups (government schemes, SHI, and OOP) and the variables used for clustering (government schemes, SHI, and OOP, each as a % of THE). One problem with this approach is that countries may move repeatedly and in short period of times in‐and‐out a certain group, therefore switches lasting only 1 year have been removed. We note that inclusion in a group is reversible: countries can go from SHI to OOP or OOP to government financing, and vice versa.

It might occur that a country‐year observation is classified, for example, in the government financing HFS group, even if OOP as % of THE is higher than government financing as % of THE. This is because each country‐year observation is a vector of three values: government financing as % of THE, OOP as % of THE, and SHI as % of THE. Each cluster can also be thought of as a vector of government financing, OOP, and SHI, as % of THE (called centroids), which are measured as the means of all the country‐year observations within that same cluster.

The k‐means clustering algorithm does not formally consider which one of the three values forming the country‐year observation vector (government financing as % of THE, OOP as % of THE, and SHI as % of THE) is the highest. Country‐year observations are classified into each group (government financing, OOP, SHI) based on the country‐year observation vector Euclidean squared distance to the cluster centroids vector. Therefore, a country‐year observation with a very high OOP as % of THE might be classified as “government‐financing” when its distance to the government financing cluster is shorter than the distance to the OOP cluster. However, the OOP, government‐financing, and SHI cluster will show, respectively, OOP, government financing, and SHI as % of THE as the highest value of the three. This is because the k‐means clustering algorithm minimizes distance within clusters' observations and maximizes distance across clusters.

The centroids of the final clusters are the average OOP as % of THE, SHI as % of THE, and government financing as % of THE for each cluster, which are shown in Table 2, Section 5.1.

These clustering concerns are substantially less relevant when we run the following robustness checks:

  • (1)

    We classify country‐year into HFS groups/clusters using the largest value between OOP, SHI and government financing as % of THE. In 229 country‐year observations (8% of total observations) the predominant HFS defined via clustering is different from the predominant HFS defined by the “largest % of THE” method. An example of this is shown below, for all countries, Year 2017.

  • (2)

    We use a minimum threshold of OOP as % of THE to classify country‐year observations in the OOP‐predominant group that is, a country‐year can only be classified as OOP‐predominant if the cluster procedure identifies it as OOP predominant and its OOP as % of THE is higher than a certain threshold (50%, 45%, 40%, etc.)

We note that data is usually standardized when variables used for clustering are on different scales (e.g., age and income). In our case, all clustering variables are percentage of THE, therefore no standardization is required.

Number of switches resulting from cluster analysis, with countries in brackets:

Switch Full sample (in italic, countries with missing controls data)
OOP ↔ SHI
  • 8 switches, 7 countries (Argentina 2, Bulgaria 1, China 1, Moldova 1, Russia 1, Uruguay 1, USA 1)

  • 7 switches from OOP to SHI, 1 switch from SHI to OOP

OOP ↔ GOV
  • 46 switches, 30 countries (Angola 2, Burundi 3, Bulgaria, 1 Bolivia 1, Brazil 1, DRC 2, Rep of Congo 2, Djibouti 1, Ethiopia 3, Gambia 1, Gabon 3, Guinea‐Bissau 1, Guyana 2, Jordan 2, Kazakhstan 1, Kenya 1, Sri Lanka 1, Latvia 1, Madagascar 1, Mongolia 1, Mauritius 1, Malaysia 1, Panama 1, Rwanda 1, Tanzania 3, Trinidad & Tobago 1, Ukraine 2, Venezuela 2, Zambia 2)

  • 28 switches from OOP to GOV

  • 18 switches from GOV to OOP

SHI ↔ GOV 0

Note: The table lists all the switches from OOP predominant HFS to SHI or GOV (government financing) predominant HFS.

Source: Authors' elaboration.

There are 26 cases (1% of all country‐year observations), for which the clustering analysis resulted in a 1‐year long HFS switch. In such cases, the previous year predominant HFS was used: Bolivia, 2001; Central African Republic, 2015; Republic of Congo, 2009; Djibouti, 2003; Ethiopia, 2004; Gambia, 2002; Guinea‐Bissau, 2002; Guyana, 2010; Jamaica, 2001; Kazakhstan, 2002; Kyrgyzstan, 2009; Laos, 2009; Lebanon, 2012; Madagascar, 2002; Madagascar, 2009; Madagascar, 2013; Moldova, 2005; Moldova, 2009; Mauritius, 2003; Mongolia, 2005; Panama, 2016; Trinidad and Tobago, 2014; Tunisia, 2013; Ukraine, 2011; Uzbekistan, 2014; Vietnam, 2001.

Regarding the choice of the number of clusters, we measure the within‐sum‐of‐squares (WSS), the ln (WSS), η2 defined as η2=1WSS(k)WSS(1) and the proportional reduction of error coefficient (PRE), defined as PRE(k)=WSS(k1)WSS(k)WSS(k1). While for WSS, ln (WSS), and η2 the optimal cluster number is seen where there is a kink in the curve, or when the decrease becomes smaller versus previous decreases, in the PRE methodology the optimal cluster number is identified when the PRE(k) value is large (vs. other PRE(k) values). The graphs suggest that the optimal number of clusters is three, in line with the number of clustering input variables (OOP, SHI and government financing as % of THE, making 89% of THE on average). This is also in line with the literature on HFS, which often suggested using SHI and government financing predominant HFS systems (Wagstaff & Moreno‐Serra, 2009), to which we have added OOP predominant HFSs. We also run a robustness check using four clusters instead of three, and find that the overall conclusion is not changed.

graphic file with name HEC-32-574-g007.jpg

Source: Authors elaboration. The above figures are the results of the calculations described in the previous paragraph for WSS, ln(WSS), eta squared, PRE

Country Code 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Algeria DZA GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP
Angola AGO GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Argentina ARG SHI SHI SHI SHI OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Armenia ARM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Australia AUS GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Austria AUT SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Azerbaijan AZE OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Bahrain BHR GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Bangladesh BGD OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Belarus BLR GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Belgium BEL SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Benin BEN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Bhutan BTN GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Bolivia BOL OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV
Bosnia and Herzegovina BIH SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Botswana BWA GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Brazil BRA OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Bulgaria BGR GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Burkina Faso BFA GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Burundi BDI OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP GOV GOV
Cambodia KHM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Cameroon CMR OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Canada CAN GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Central African Republic CAF OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Chad TCD OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Chile CHL SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
China CHN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Colombia COL SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Comoros COM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Congo, Dem. Rep. COD OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Congo, Rep. COG OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP
Costa Rica CRI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Cote d'Ivoire CIV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Croatia HRV SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Cuba CUB GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Cyprus CYP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Czech Republic CZE SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Denmark DNK GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Djibouti DJI OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Dominican Republic DOM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Ecuador ECU OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Egypt, Arab Rep. EGY OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
El Salvador SLV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Equatorial Guinea GNQ OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Eritrea ERI OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Estonia EST SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Eswatini SWZ GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Ethiopia ETH OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV
Fiji FJI GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Finland FIN GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
France FRA SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Gabon GAB OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP GOV GOV
Gambia, the GMB OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Georgia GEO OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Germany DEU SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Ghana GHA OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Guatemala GTM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Guinea GIN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Guinea‐Bissau GNB GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Guyana GUY GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Haiti HTI OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Honduras HND OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Hungary HUN SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
India IND OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Indonesia IDN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Iran, Islamic Rep. IRN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Ireland IRL GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Israel ISR SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Italy ITA GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Jamaica JAM GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Japan JPN SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Jordan JOR OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP
Kazakhstan KAZ OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Kenya KEN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV
Korea, Rep. KOR SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Kuwait KWT GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Kyrgyz Republic KGZ OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Lao PDR LAO OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Latvia LVA OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Lebanon LBN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Lesotho LSO GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Liberia LBR OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Lithuania LTU SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Madagascar MDG OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Malawi MWI GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Malaysia MYS OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Mali MLI OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Mauritania MRT OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Mauritius MUS GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Mexico MEX OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Moldova MDA OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Mongolia MNG GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Morocco MAR OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Mozambique MOZ GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Myanmar MMR OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Namibia NAM GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Nepal NPL OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Netherlands NLD SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
New Zealand NZL GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Nicaragua NIC OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Niger NER OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Nigeria NGA OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
North Macedonia MKD SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Norway NOR GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Oman OMN GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Pakistan PAK OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Panama PAN GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Papua New Guinea PNG GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Paraguay PRY OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Peru PER OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Philippines PHL OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Poland POL SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Portugal PRT GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Qatar QAT GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Romania ROU SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Russian Federation RUS OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI
Rwanda RWA OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Senegal SEN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Serbia SRB SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Sierra Leone SLE OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Singapore SGP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Slovak Republic SVK SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Slovenia SVN SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
South Africa ZAF GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Spain ESP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Sri Lanka LKA GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Sudan SDN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Sweden SWE GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Switzerland CHE SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Tajikistan TJK OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Tanzania TZA OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Thailand THA GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Togo TGO OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Trinidad and Tobago TTO OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
Tunisia TUN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Turkey TUR SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Turkmenistan TKM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Uganda UGA OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Ukraine UKR OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
United Arab Emirates ARE GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
United Kingdom GBR GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV
United States USA OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Uruguay URY OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI SHI
Uzbekistan UZB OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Venezuela, RB VEN OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Vietnam VNM OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP OOP
Zambia ZMB GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV OOP OOP OOP OOP GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV GOV

Note: The table shows the predominant HFS for all countries, across years.

Source: Authors' elaboration.

In the below Table we present, for Year 2017 and all countries, SHI as % of THE, OOP as % of THE, government financing as % of THE, and voluntary health insurance as % of THE, the predominant HFS defined using clustering, and the predominant HFS defined as the HFS with the largest % of THE. Countries in which there is a difference between the two HFS definitions are noted in italic (9 cases, 6% of total country observations in 2017).

Country Country code Year SHI as % THE Government financing as % of THE OOP as % of THE VHI as % of THE Predominance defined by clustering Predominance as "largest as % of THE"
Angola AGO 2017 0 47 34 6 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
United Arab Emirates ARE 2017 0 72 19 8 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Argentina ARG 2017 43 30 15 9 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Armenia ARM 2017 0 14 84 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Australia AUS 2017 0 65 18 10 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Austria AUT 2017 44 30 19 5 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Azerbaijan AZE 2017 0 15 84 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Burundi BDI 2017 1 47 25 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Belgium BEL 2017 56 21 18 5 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Benin BEN 2017 2 39 45 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Burkina Faso BFA 2017 0 61 32 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Bangladesh BGD 2017 0 19 74 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Bulgaria BGR 2017 43 9 47 1 SHI predominant OOP predominant
Bahrain BHR 2017 0 58 31 11 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Bosnia and Herzegovina BIH 2017 68 2 29 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Belarus BLR 2017 0 70 28 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Bolivia BOL 2017 30 40 25 3 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Brazil BRA 2017 0 42 27 29 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Bhutan BTN 2017 0 79 13 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Botswana BWA 2017 0 78 3 9 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Central African Republic CAF 2017 0 19 31 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Canada CAN 2017 1 69 14 10 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Switzerland CHE 2017 42 22 29 7 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Chile CHL 2017 58 2 34 6 SHI predominant SHI predominant
China CHN 2017 38 18 36 5 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Cote d'Ivoire CIV 2017 2 35 39 8 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Cameroon CMR 2017 0 18 71 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Congo, Dem. Rep. COD 2017 1 30 40 3 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Congo, Rep. COG 2017 0 36 48 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Colombia COL 2017 68 6 16 10 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Comoros COM 2017 3 16 75 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Costa Rica CRI 2017 72 3 21 3 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Cuba CUB 2017 0 89 10 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Cyprus CYP 2017 0 42 45 12 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Czech Republic CZE 2017 69 13 15 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Germany DEU 2017 78 6 13 1 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Djibouti DJI 2017 11 43 27 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Denmark DNK 2017 0 84 14 2 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Dominican Republic DOM 2017 25 21 45 8 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Algeria DZA 2017 26 40 33 1 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Ecuador ECU 2017 24 29 39 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Egypt, Arab Rep. EGY 2017 4 29 60 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Eritrea ERI 2017 0 38 59 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Spain ESP 2017 4 66 24 5 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Estonia EST 2017 64 10 24 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Ethiopia ETH 2017 0 45 34 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Finland FIN 2017 14 62 20 2 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Fiji FJI 2017 0 67 16 13 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
France FRA 2017 78 5 9 7 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Gabon GAB 2017 24 39 25 9 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
United Kingdom GBR 2017 0 79 16 3 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Georgia GEO 2017 0 37 55 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Ghana GHA 2017 10 30 40 2 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Guinea GIN 2017 2 29 57 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Gambia, the GMB 2017 0 41 22 4 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Guinea‐Bissau GNB 2017 1 14 72 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Equatorial Guinea GNQ 2017 1 19 77 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Guatemala GTM 2017 17 18 54 4 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Guyana GUY 2017 2 61 32 2 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Honduras HND 2017 12 33 49 5 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Croatia HRV 2017 76 6 11 4 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Haiti HTI 2017 2 12 40 5 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Hungary HUN 2017 61 8 27 2 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Indonesia IDN 2017 23 26 35 4 OOP predominant OOP predominant
India IND 2017 5 23 62 5 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Ireland IRL 2017 0 73 12 13 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Iran, Islamic Rep. IRN 2017 32 14 42 7 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Israel ISR 2017 48 16 22 11 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Italy ITA 2017 0 74 23 2 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Jamaica JAM 2017 6 61 17 16 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Jordan JOR 2017 16 34 30 15 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Japan JPN 2017 76 9 13 2 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Kazakhstan KAZ 2017 0 62 33 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Kenya KEN 2017 8 42 24 10 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Kyrgyz Republic KGZ 2017 7 35 56 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Cambodia KHM 2017 0 23 60 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Korea, Rep. KOR 2017 49 10 34 7 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Kuwait KWT 2017 0 87 13 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Lao PDR LAO 2017 2 36 46 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Lebanon LBN 2017 24 25 33 16 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Liberia LBR 2017 0 32 46 7 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Sri Lanka LKA 2017 0 44 50 2 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Lesotho LSO 2017 0 68 17 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Lithuania LTU 2017 58 9 32 1 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Latvia LVA 2017 0 57 42 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Morocco MAR 2017 20 25 54 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Moldova MDA 2017 50 2 44 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Madagascar MDG 2017 0 54 25 3 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Mexico MEX 2017 28 24 41 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
North Macedonia MKD 2017 63 5 32 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Mali MLI 2017 10 34 35 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Myanmar MMR 2017 1 17 76 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Mongolia MNG 2017 23 41 32 0 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Mozambique MOZ 2017 2 52 7 2 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Mauritania MRT 2017 10 34 50 2 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Mauritius MUS 2017 0 43 49 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Malawi MWI 2017 0 50 11 3 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Malaysia MYS 2017 1 50 38 10 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Namibia NAM 2017 0 48 8 38 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Niger NER 2017 1 44 48 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Nigeria NGA 2017 1 14 77 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Nicaragua NIC 2017 24 40 33 1 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Netherlands NLD 2017 75 6 11 6 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Norway NOR 2017 0 85 14 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Nepal NPL 2017 0 25 58 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
New Zealand NZL 2017 9 69 14 5 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Oman OMN 2017 0 88 7 3 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Pakistan PAK 2017 1 29 60 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Panama PAN 2017 28 33 33 6 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Peru PER 2017 30 33 28 7 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Philippines PHL 2017 12 23 53 11 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Papua New Guinea PNG 2017 0 76 9 0 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Poland POL 2017 59 10 23 6 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Portugal PRT 2017 1 65 28 4 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Paraguay PRY 2017 17 28 44 10 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Qatar QAT 2017 0 81 9 9 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Romania ROU 2017 63 15 20 1 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Russian Federation RUS 2017 36 21 40 2 SHI predominant OOP predominant
Rwanda RWA 2017 17 52 6 2 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Sudan SDN 2017 11 8 72 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Senegal SEN 2017 4 34 52 8 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Singapore SGP 2017 8 40 32 3 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Sierra Leone SLE 2017 0 27 50 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
El Salvador SLV 2017 29 35 29 6 OOP predominant Government financing predominant
Serbia SRB 2017 54 3 42 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Slovak Republic SVK 2017 78 2 19 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Slovenia SVN 2017 69 3 12 14 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Sweden SWE 2017 0 84 15 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Eswatini SWZ 2017 0 49 10 11 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Chad TCD 2017 0 21 58 4 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Togo TGO 2017 3 25 58 7 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Thailand THA 2017 11 68 11 7 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Tajikistan TJK 2017 0 33 63 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Turkmenistan TKM 2017 0 22 73 5 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Trinidad and Tobago TTO 2017 0 53 40 7 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Tunisia TUN 2017 31 27 39 3 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Turkey TUR 2017 56 22 17 2 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Tanzania TZA 2017 8 62 24 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Uganda UGA 2017 0 20 39 2 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Ukraine UKR 2017 0 45 52 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Uruguay URY 2017 50 17 18 11 SHI predominant SHI predominant
United States USA 2017 58 26 11 0 SHI predominant SHI predominant
Uzbekistan UZB 2017 0 45 53 0 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Venezuela, RB VEN 2017 6 10 63 21 OOP predominant OOP predominant
Vietnam VNM 2017 23 27 45 1 OOP predominant OOP predominant
South Africa ZAF 2017 0 43 8 36 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant
Zambia ZMB 2017 0 56 12 1 Government financing predominant Government financing predominant

APPENDIX 4. Full baseline results, and heterogeneity within HFS groups

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log THE per capita Imm, index LE Log U5M Log MM CHE10
Variables FE FE FE FE FE FE
Predominant government financing 0.043 3.804 1.341** −0.083** −0.040 −3.256***
(0.041) (2.921) (0.579) (0.036) (0.040) (0.931)
Predominant SHI 0.117*** −1.486 −0.128 0.051 0.034 6.467***
(0.035) (1.606) (0.395) (0.037) (0.067) (1.129)
Log GDP per capita (PPP) 0.698*** 3.591 1.038 −0.315*** −0.515*** 1.230
(0.093) (3.776) (0.643) (0.097) (0.178) (2.073)
Corruption control 0.099** 3.783* −0.087 −0.058 0.029 2.662**
(0.041) (2.225) (0.577) (0.043) (0.079) (1.140)
Government effectiveness 0.030 −1.636 0.125 −0.088** −0.041 1.968
(0.044) (1.874) (0.350) (0.038) (0.068) (2.521)
% of population above 65 0.000 −0.389 −0.263* 0.022* 0.049 −0.020
(0.019) (0.954) (0.156) (0.013) (0.035) (0.453)
% population below 14 −0.017* 0.645** 0.335*** −0.029*** −0.035** 0.224
(0.009) (0.321) (0.074) (0.008) (0.016) (0.235)
Urbanization (%) −0.009 0.364** 0.073 0.003 0.005 0.175
(0.006) (0.164) (0.055) (0.006) (0.013) (0.176)
Access to drinking water (% population) −0.003 0.474 0.150*** −0.007 0.002 0.074
(0.005) (0.298) (0.042) (0.004) (0.012) (0.080)
Enrollment to primary school (gross, % population −0.002 0.035 0.019 0.002 −0.001 −0.080*
(0.002) (0.075) (0.017) (0.001) (0.002) (0.040)
Gini index 0.005 0.259* −0.009 0.004 0.006 0.018
(0.004) (0.152) (0.035) (0.003) (0.004) (0.099)
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R2 0.869 0.177 0.752 0.879 0.646 0.224
Observations 950 970 970 970 970 407
Number of countries 124 124 124 124 124 111

Notes: FE estimates are the result of Equation (1). Robust SEs, clustered at country‐level, in parentheses. Details on HFS switches are detailed in Appendix 3. All models control for all variables listed as “control” in Table 2. p‐values for two‐sided t‐tests are reported as: ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Source: Author elaboration.

The results below are for the following equation: Yit=α+ρ1SHI%THEit+ρ2GOV%THEit+ρ3OOP%THEit+γXit+Tt+Ci+εit, for the subsample of country‐year observations that belong to the HFS‐predominant group noted in the column of each model, for column 1–18. For column 19–36, only SHI as percentage of THE is used for the SHI‐predominant HFS group, OOP expenditures as percentage of THE is used for the OOP‐predominant HFS group, and government financing as % of THE is used for the government financing predominant HFS group.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17) (18)
Ln THE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% Ln THE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% Ln THE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10%
FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE
HFS group → variables ↓ GOV group GOV group GOV group GOV group GOV group GOV group OOP group OOP group OOP group OOP group OOP group OOP group SHI group SHI group SHI group SHI group SHI group SHI group
Government financing % −0.002 0.000 0.049 −0.000 0.002 0.001* −0.001 0.001 −0.018 0.003 −0.004 −0.003* 0.003 0.001 −0.034** 0.001 0.005 −0.001
(0.006) (0.001) (0.051) (0.003) (0.005) (0.001) (0.004) (0.002) (0.025) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.001) (0.013) (0.003) (0.005) (0.002)
SHI financing % −0.005 0.004 0.151 0.009 0.019* −0.000 0.012*** −0.001 −0.007 0.005 −0.004 −0.001 −0.002 −0.001 −0.014 0.000 0.004 0.000
(0.013) (0.002) (0.093) (0.007) (0.011) (0.002) (0.004) (0.002) (0.026) (0.003) (0.004) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.011) (0.002) (0.005) (0.000)
OOP financing % −0.003 0.001 0.030 −0.001 −0.006 0.002*** −0.000 0.001 0.010 0.005* −0.003 −0.002 0.002 −0.000 0.021 −0.001 0.011 0.001
(0.006) (0.002) (0.051) (0.003) (0.008) (0.001) (0.004) (0.002) (0.022) (0.003) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.015) (0.003) (0.007) (0.001)
Observations 265 271 271 271 271 116 398 407 407 407 407 193 287 292 292 292 292 98
R‐squared 0.875 0.145 0.811 0.940 0.842 0.528 0.875 0.359 0.816 0.922 0.733 0.404 0.959 0.281 0.925 0.873 0.745 0.400
Number of ID 45 46 46 46 46 39 69 69 69 69 69 60 31 31 31 31 31 23
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R^2 0.861 0.0417 0.788 0.933 0.823 0.376 0.865 0.310 0.802 0.916 0.713 0.302 0.954 0.202 0.917 0.859 0.716 0.168
(19) (20) (21) (22) (23 (24) (25) (26) (27) (28) (29) (30) (31) (32) (33) (34) (35) (36)
Ln THE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% Ln THE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% Ln THE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10%
FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE FE
Variables GOV group GOV group GOV group GOV group GOV group GOV group OOP group OOP group OOP group OOP group OOP group OOP group CHI group CHI group CHI group CHI group CHI group CHI group
Government financing % 0.000 −0.001 0.020 0.000 0.004 0.000
(0.003) (0.001) (0.035) (0.002) (0.004) (0.000)
SHI financing % −0.003 −0.001 −0.008 −0.000 −0.001 0.000
(0.002) (0.001) (0.009) (0.002) (0.003) (0.000)
OOP financing % −0.003 0.001 0.022 0.002 0.000 −0.000
(0.003) (0.001) (0.016) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)
Observations 265 271 271 271 271 116 287 292 292 292 292 98 398 407 407 407 407 193
R‐squared 0.875 0.142 0.808 0.939 0.835 0.418 0.958 0.280 0.918 0.873 0.733 0.379 0.858 0.353 0.815 0.920 0.730 0.337
Number of ID 45 46 46 46 46 39 31 31 31 31 31 23 69 69 69 69 69 60
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R^2 0.861 0.0463 0.787 0.932 0.817 0.248 0.954 0.207 0.910 0.860 0.705 0.163 0.848 0.307 0.802 0.914 0.710 0.233

Notes: this table present the results of the fixed effects (FE) Equation (1), restricting the sample to the sub‐group of “countries within the government‐, SHI‐ or OOP‐predominant group”. All the controls variables and FE (time and country FE) used in the main models are also used here. The independent variable of interest is the percentage of THE channelled via government schemes, SHI schemes and OOP schemes. In the first table, all three percentages have been used. In the second table, only the percentage of THE channelled via OOP schemes has been used for the OOP‐predominant group, the percentage of THE channelled via SHI schemes for the SHI‐predominant group, and the percentage of THE channelled via government schemes for the government‐predominant group.

Source: Author elaboration. Datasets discussed in Section 4.

APPENDIX 5. FE estimates of augmented model with interaction terms (Equation 4), Section 5.3. Results in italic when observations are not enough.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
Interaction terms ↓ // Dependent variables → Imm. Index LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% GGHE % GGE Imm index LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% GGHE % GGE
Government‐predominant & informal sector size −0.198* −0.009 0.000 0.002 1.585*** 0.034
(0.098) (0.021) (0.002) (0.002) (0.005) (0.047)
SHI‐predominant & informal sector size −0.221** −0.001 0.006*** −0.002 −0.021
(0.088) (0.014) (0.002) (0.002) (0.048)
Government‐predominant & logged GDP per capita (PPP) −0.470 0.372 −0.090* −0.174 1.341 −0.693
(2.491) (0.559) (0.046) (0.119) (0.820) (0.478)
SHI‐predominant & logged GDP per capita (PPP) 5.847** −0.260 −0.006 −0.007 −2.469 0.220
(2.367) (0.454) (0.058) (0.081) (2.045) (0.604)
Observations 184 184 184 184 50 184 970 970 970 970 407 970
Number of ID 34 34 34 34 26 34 124 124 124 124 111 124
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R 2 0.216 0.851 0.952 0.844 1 0.474 0.199 0.754 0.880 0.648 0.189 0.172
(13) (14) (15) (16) (17) (18) (19) (20) (21) (22) (23) (24)
Interaction terms ↓//Dependent variables → Imm. Index LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% GGHE % GGE Imm index LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% GGHE % GGE
Government‐predominant & government effectiveness 1.662 1.391* −0.113* −0.167 −0.132 0.412
(3.198) (0.714) (0.063) (0.127) (2.943) (0.752)
SHI‐predominant & government effectiveness −1.362 −0.229 −0.073 0.006 −2.920 0.309
(3.867) (0.540) (0.052) (0.112) (4.440) (0.816)
Government‐predominant & control of corruption −2.015 1.659 −0.038 −0.174 −1.612 0.785
(2.575) (1.119) (0.062) (0.116) (2.124) (0.666)
SHI‐predominant & control of corruption −0.215 −0.277 −0.038 0.038 −4.538 1.00***
(2.330) (0.319) (0.033) (0.069) (3.359) (0.328)
Observations 970 970 970 970 407 970 970 970 970 970 407 970
Number of ID 124 124 124 124 111 124 124 124 124 124 111 124
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R 2 0.189 0.753 0.879 0.645 0.178 0.166 0.188 0.753 0.880 0.646 0.195 0.171
(25) (26) (27) (28) (29) (30) (31) (32) (33) (34) (35) (36)
Interaction terms ↓//Dependent variables → Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% GGHE % GGE Imm Idx LE ln U5M ln MM CAT 10% GGHE % GGE
Government‐predominant & GGE as % of GDP −0.036 0.012 0.001 −0.003 −0.055 −0.085**
(0.163) (0.030) (0.002) (0.004) (0.090) (0.038)
SHI‐predominant & GGE as % of GDP 0.084 0.013 0.005 −0.005 −0.172 −0.055
(0.230) (0.041) (0.004) (0.005) (0.202) (0.047)
Government‐predominant & labour‐tax as % of health revenues −0.015 0.035 −0.000 −0.002 −0.218 0.057**
(0.21) (0.036) (0.003) (0.003) (0.240) (0.024)
SHI‐predominant & labour‐tax as % of health revenues 0.174 −0.021 −0.005 −0.002 −0.019 −0.114***
(0.12) (0.027) (0.003) (0.005) (0.106) (0.042)
Observations 970 970 970 970 407 970 970 970 970 970 407 970
Number of ID 124 124 124 124 111 124 124 124 124 124 111 124
Country FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Adjusted R 2 0.191 0.756 0.881 0.649 0.179 0.244 0.192 0.755 0.881 0.646 0.184 0.213

Note: Datasets discussed in Section 4. This table present the results of the fixed effects (FE) with interaction terms, Equation (2). The interaction terms coefficient and p‐values are shown in the table. Results are in italics when observations are below 100.

Source: Author elaboration.

APPENDIX 6. Robustness checks

TABLE A1.

Robustness checks

Intermediate outcomes HEALTH system OUTCOMES
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log THE per capita Imm. coverage LE Log U5M Log MM CAT 10%
FE FE FE FE FE FE
PANEL A: BASELINE ESTIMATES
Predominant government 0.043 3.804 1.341** −0.083** −0.040 −3.256***
(0.041) (2.921) (0.579) (0.036) (0.040) (0.931)
Predominant SHI 0.117*** −1.486 −0.128 0.051 0.034 6.467***
(0.035) (1.606) (0.395) (0.037) (0.067) (1.129)
PANEL B: LMICs ONLY
Predominant government 0.040 3.416 1.366** −0.073* −0.042 −3.305***
(0.043) (3.133) (0.608) (0.037) (0.038) (0.923)
Predominant SHI 0.127*** −1.195 −0.220 0.093** 0.019 6.273***
(0.038) (2.337) (0.497) (0.039) (0.051) (1.297)
PANEL C: REMOVED OUTLIERS
Predominant government 0.018 2.894 1.062*** −0.066* −0.010 −2.764***
(0.041) (1.780) (0.323) (0.035) (0.032) (0.954)
Predominant SHI 0.119*** −1.766 −0.079 0.049 0.032 6.312***
(0.036) (1.552) (0.398) (0.037) (0.067) (1.094)
PANEL D: LAGGED HFS
Predominant government −0.0104 3.210 0.785* −0.075** −0.0148 −3.016***
(−0.27) (−0.99) (−1.94) (−2.07) (−0.36) (−3.35)
Predominant SHI 0.105*** −1.183 −0.170 0.062 0.0446 5.917***
(−2.84) (−0.63) (−0.41) (−1.24) (−0.65) (−6.04)
PANEL E: GENERAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE (%GDP) ADDED AS CONTROL
Predominant government 0.038 3.790 1.359** −0.082** −0.042 −3.312***
(0.043) (2.917) (0.570) (0.038) (0.042) (0.944)
Predominant SHI 0.099*** −1.537 −0.066 0.056 0.025 6.512***
(0.037) (1.596) (0.374) (0.036) (0.066) (1.123)
PANEL F: USE PERCENTAGES
% government −0.000 0.022 −0.004 −0.001 0.001 −0.130***
(0.002) (0.084) (0.018) (0.001) (0.003) (0.045)
% SHI 0.006** −0.033 −0.014 0.002 0.002 0.036
(0.003) (0.091) (0.020) (0.002) (0.004) (0.043)
PANEL G: DIFFERENTIAL (THE, U5M) AND RANDOM TREND (LE, CAT 10%) MODELS
Predominant government 0.051 0.129 −0.077** −1.102
(0.036) (0.134) (0.032) (1.092)
Predominant SHI 0.142*** −0.114 0.040 0.121
(0.033) (0.112) (0.039) (0.585)
PANEL H: NOT LOGGED MORTALITY OUTCOMES
Predominant government −9.496** −52.003
(4.066) (33.701)
Predominant SHI 2.335 8.218
(1.425) (7.773)
PANEL I: REMOVE GINI INDEX CONTROL VARIABLE TO MAXIMIZE NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS
Predominant government 0.014 0.984 0.979*** −0.065** −0.048 −1.814
(0.037) (1.556) (0.350) (0.029) (0.037) (1.226)
Predominant SHI 0.095** −2.759* −0.540* −0.016 −0.025 4.583***
(0.047) (1.665) (0.307) (0.040) (0.056) (0.996)
PANEL J: REMOVE CONTROLS TO HAVE ALL 147 COUTNRIES IN SAMPLE
Predominant government 0.010 1.861 0.840** −0.041 −0.032 −1.566
(0.034) (1.938) (0.337) (0.025) (0.032) (1.237)
Predominant SHI 0.086* −4.079** −1.205*** 0.001 0.049 3.523***
(0.046) (1.718) (0.325) (0.044) (0.076) (1.210)
PANEL K: ADD CONFOUNDERS ADJUSTMENT (ZELDOW AND HATFIELD, 2021)
Predominant government 0.038 5.416* 1.132*** −0.061* −0.042 −2.141**
(0.036) (2.844) (0.305) (0.034) (0.031) (1.024)
Predominant SHI 0.049 0.622 −0.299 0.071 0.089 4.167*
(0.034) (2.275) (0.254) (0.048) (0.069) (2.283)
PANEL L: ADD DEVELOPMENT ASSISTANCE FOR HEALTH (% THE) AS A CONTROL
Predominant government 0.050 3.691 1.254** −0.082** −0.038 −3.298***
(0.041) (2.936) (0.510) (0.036) (0.039) (0.944)
Predominant SHI 0.126*** −1.657 −0.260 0.053 0.036 6.427***
(0.037) (1.670) (0.377) (0.037) (0.067) (1.132)
PANEL M: USE LOG GDP DECILES AS CONTROL VARIABLE, INSTEAD OF LOG GDP
Predominant government 0.024 3.595 1.248** −0.077** −0.032 −3.047***
(0.048) (3.035) (0.557) (0.036) (0.046) (0.970)
Predominant SHI 0.155*** −1.247 −0.048 0.035 0.007 6.517***
(0.041) (1.650) (0.369) (0.038) (0.063) (1.071)

Note: Datasets discussed in Section 4. Models detail explained in the robustness checks section. Baseline model controls variable included in all models unless specified. In italic, in panel G, coefficients that are statistically different from the baseline model at the 10% level based on tests in Equations (4) and (9). Robust standard errors in parenthesis.

***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Source: Author elaboration.

TABLE A2.

Estimates using different definitions of “predominant HFS”

Intermediate OUTCOMES HEALTH system outcomes
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log THE per capita Imm. coverage LE Log U5M LogMM CAT 10%
FE FE FE FE FE FE
PANEL A: BASELINE ESTIMATES (HFS DEFINED BY CLUSTERING)
Predominant government 0.043 3.804 1.341** −0.083** −0.040 −3.256***
(0.041) (2.921) (0.579) (0.036) (0.040) (0.931)
Predominant SHI 0.117*** −1.486 −0.128 0.051 0.034 6.467***
(0.035) (1.606) (0.395) (0.037) (0.067) (1.129)
PANEL B: HFS DEFINED BY HIGHEST VALUE
Government financing (% of THE) highest value 0.009 1.332 0.474 −0.075*** −0.060 −1.700*
(0.038) (1.253) (0.296) (0.022) (0.040) (0.872)
SHI Financing (% of THE) highest value 0.041 0.210 −0.467* 0.050 0.114*** 3.782***
(0.042) (1.306) (0.250) (0.057) (0.041) (1.133)
PANEL C: OOP PREDOMINANT ONLY IF OOP‐%‐THE ABOVE 50%
Predominant government 0.101 14.911* 1.020*** −0.053 −0.094 −1.916
(0.065) (8.554) (0.359) (0.037) (0.076) (1.801)
Predominant SHI 0.373*** −3.737** 0.934** −0.048 −0.033 4.420**
(0.056) (1.805) (0.418) (0.039) (0.065) (2.092)
PANEL D: OOP PREDOMINANT ONLY IF OOP‐%‐THE ABOVE 45%
Predominant government −0.015 8.722** 0.519 −0.013 −0.032 −2.840***
(0.049) (3.799) (0.341) (0.025) (0.043) (1.082)
Predominant SHI 0.200*** −3.056** 0.424 0.043 −0.038 4.495***
(0.031) (1.193) (0.452) (0.036) (0.055) (1.431)
PANEL E: OOP PREDOMINANT ONLY IF OOP‐%‐THE ABOVE 40%
Predominant government −0.036 8.990** 0.818* −0.023 −0.051 −2.547***
(0.045) (3.522) (0.489) (0.024) (0.034) (0.938)
Predominant SHI 0.189*** −3.508*** 0.290 0.053 −0.022 5.295***
(0.025) (1.071) (0.467) (0.052) (0.059) (1.249)
PANEL F: OOP PREDOMINANT ONLY IF OOP‐%‐THE ABOVE 35%
Predominant government 0.032 3.813 0.757* −0.054 0.011 −2.136**
(0.036) (3.615) (0.430) (0.039) (0.034) (0.883)
Predominant SHI 0.163*** −3.411*** 0.244 0.049 0.001 4.996***
(0.028) (1.297) (0.438) (0.066) (0.046) (1.354)
PANEL G: OOP PREDOMINANT ONLY IF OOP‐%‐THE ABOVE 30%
Predominant government 0.047 4.360* 0.985*** −0.081*** −0.025 −2.691***
(0.034) (2.424) (0.284) (0.029) (0.028) (0.866)
Predominant SHI 0.139*** −2.883** 0.186 0.065 −0.024 6.548***
(0.033) (1.369) (0.382) (0.046) (0.048) (1.164)
PANEL H: USE ALL HF ARRANGEMENTS AS INPUT VARIABLES FOR CLUSTERING
Predominant government 0.030 4.922 1.103** −0.058** −0.058* −2.188**
(0.033) (3.400) (0.448) (0.027) (0.034) (0.856)
Predominant SHI 0.091*** −0.541 −0.227 0.060** 0.039 4.590***
(0.027) (1.487) (0.350) (0.029) (0.056) (1.333)
PANEL I: USE ALL HF ARRANGEMENTS and LN(THE PER CAPITA) AS INPUT VARIABLES FOR CLUSTERING
Predominant government 0.030 5.289 1.067** −0.055** −0.053 −2.188**
(0.033) (3.527) (0.466) (0.028) (0.036) (0.856)
Predominant SHI 0.091*** −0.763 −0.235 0.057** 0.033 4.590***
(0.027) (1.408) (0.355) (0.026) (0.053) (1.333)
PANEL J: SET THE NUMBER OF CLUSTERS TO FOUR
Predominant government −0.005 1.571 0.545 −0.041 −0.101 −3.032*
(0.067) (4.615) (0.810) (0.043) (0.103) (1.604)
Predominant OOP, but less predominant 0.072 −1.390 −0.324 0.028 −0.023 −1.633
(0.054) (1.138) (0.403) (0.028) (0.067) (1.371)
Predominant SHI 0.146** −1.474 −0.831 0.097** 0.065 3.205**
(0.072) (2.268) (0.679) (0.042) (0.098) (1.534)

Note: Datasets discussed in Section 4. Models detail explained in the robustness checks section. Baseline model controls variable included in all models unless specified. Robust standard errors in parenthesis.

***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Source: Author elaboration.

TABLE A3.

Robustness to different income sub‐groups

Intermediate OUTCOMES HEALTH system outcomes
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log THE per capita Imm. coverage LE Log U5M Log MM CAT 10%
FE FE FE FE FE FE
PANEL A: BASELINE ESTIMATES
Predominant government 0.043 3.804 1.341** −0.083** −0.040 −3.256***
(0.041) (2.921) (0.579) (0.036) (0.040) (0.931)
Predominant SHI 0.117*** −1.486 −0.128 0.051 0.034 6.467***
(0.035) (1.606) (0.395) (0.037) (0.067) (1.129)
PANEL B: SUB‐GROUP OF HIGH‐ AND MIDDLE‐ INCOME COUNTRIES
Predominant government 0.012 5.657* 0.903** −0.062 −0.021 −2.657***
(0.034) (3.250) (0.385) (0.039) (0.039) (0.854)
Predominant SHI 0.090** 0.111 −0.246 0.061** 0.074 5.268***
(0.041) (1.921) (0.432) (0.029) (0.066) (1.000)
PANEL C: SUB‐GROUP OF LOW‐ AND MIDDLE‐INCOME COUNTRIES
Predominant government 0.040 3.416 1.366** −0.073* −0.042 −3.305***
(0.043) (3.133) (0.608) (0.037) (0.038) (0.923)
Predominant SHI 0.127*** −1.195 −0.220 0.093** 0.019 6.273***
(0.038) (2.337) (0.497) (0.039) (0.051) (1.297)
PANEL D: SUB‐GROUP OF MIDDLE‐INCOME COUNTRIES
Predominant government −0.002 5.587 0.891** −0.043 −0.018 −3.071***
(0.035) (3.554) (0.404) (0.039) (0.042) (0.891)
Predominant SHI 0.119*** −0.341 −0.062 0.087** 0.018 5.665***
(0.041) (2.524) (0.539) (0.037) (0.057) (1.398)
PANEL E: INCLUDE ALL COUNTRIES
Predominant government −0.012 −3.902 −0.787 0.047 0.039 2.120***
(0.040) (3.538) (0.480) (0.032) (0.044) (0.740)
Predominant SHI 0.091* −4.297 −1.204* 0.126** 0.124 7.728***
(0.054) (3.222) (0.708) (0.049) (0.087) (1.213)
PANEL F: INCLUDE ALL COUNTRIES, USE HIGHEST VALUE FOR HFS DEFINITION
Government financing (% of THE) highest value 0.009 1.356 0.521* −0.083*** −0.065 −1.700*
(0.038) (1.255) (0.303) (0.023) (0.041) (0.871)
SHI Financing (% of THE) highest value 0.043 0.026 −0.473* 0.048 0.113*** 3.782***
(0.041) (1.290) (0.252) (0.057) (0.041) (1.133)

Note: Equation (1) is estimated using different income sub‐groups, including all countries available in the dataset, and finally including all countries and using a different definition for HFS (highest value), as detailed in the robustness checks section and in Appendix 2.

Source: Authors' elaboration. Datasets discussed in section 4.

TABLE A4.

Additional outcomes

Government‐predominant HFS SHI‐predominant HFS
# Dep. Variable Model
ρ2
SE ρ1 SE Obs. Coun‐tries Coun. FE Year FE Adj. R 2
HEALTH SYSTEM OUTCOMES (1) Ln U5M, DHS FE −0.080** 0.036 1.120*** 0.119 292 59 YES YES 0.045
(2) Ln IM, DHS FE −0.113** 0.042 0.969*** 0.114 291 59 YES YES 0.040
(3) AM, female FE −19.3** (9.417) −5.898 (8.310) 968 124 YES YES 0.607
(4) AM, male FE −20.1** (8.485) −0.909 (10.533) 968 124 YES YES 0.506
(5) MMR, national FE −182.28 (119.50) −10.011 (11.235) 262 124 YES YES 0.521
(6) CAT 25% FE −0.877*** (0.264) 0.899** (0.438) 407 111 YES YES 0.184
(7) Inc. Imp 3.10 FE −0.380** (0.163) −0.735*** (0.231) 407 111 YES YES 0.140
(8) Inc. Imp 1.90 FE −0.220 (0.183) −0.084 (0.182) 407 111 YES YES 0.315
INTERMEDIATE OUTCOMES (9) SBA % FE 1.208 (1.818) −2.501*** (0.770) 629 94 YES YES 0.471
(10) GGHE % GGE FE 0.895** (0.408) 1.047** (0.472) 970 124 YES YES 0.167
(11) THE % GDP FE 0.332 (0.298) 0.847** (0.349) 950 124 YES YES 0.290

Note: Equation (1) is estimated using additional outcomes, as detailed in the Results section. For DHS outcomes, fewer controls were used because otherwise the number of observations would drop below 100. The controls used were: GDP per capita, urbanization, control of corruption, government effectiveness, % population above 65 and % population below 14 years old, in addition to fixed effects. For DHS outcomes, under‐5 mortality and infant mortality is provided as “average for the 5 and 10‐year period before the survey”: when it was 5‐year, the observation year was recorded as “survey year minus three”, when it was 10 years, the year considered was “survey year minus five”. In other words, we attach the “past 5 and 10 years average reading” to the mid‐year of that same 5 or 10 year period. Robust standard errors reported, clustered at country‐level.

P < 0.1*, p < 0.05**, p < 0.01***.

Source: Author elaboration.

graphic file with name HEC-32-574-g010.jpg

Notes: these are event studies plots, for five outcomes out of six outcomes used for our main results. For CAT 10%, data limitations do not allow an event study. In the case of government financing, there are 30 countries switching between OOP and government financing predomaning HFSs. However, only 17 countries switch only once during the 2000–2018 study period. These 17 countries are included in the event study, while the remaining 13 countries who switch back‐and‐forth between OOP and government financing are excluded, as the interpretation of their coefficients is not possible.

The equation used for the above plots is: Yit=α+j=05ρjGOVitj+ρ2GOVit+2+γXit+Tt+Ci+εit

Adding further leads resulted in omitted variables, therefore we limited leads to only 2 years before the switch from OOP to government financing.

The baseline omitted case is the first lead, where k = 1.

graphic file with name HEC-32-574-g001.jpg

Notes: these are event studies plots, for five outcomes out of six outcomes used for our main results. For CAT 10%, data limitations do not allow an event study. In the case of government financing, there are eight countries switching between OOP and SHI predomaning HFSs. Seven countries switch only once during the 2000–2018 study period. These seven countries are included in the event study, while the remaining 1 countries who switch back‐and‐forth between OOP and SHI are excluded, as the interpretation of their coefficients is not possible.

The equation used for the above plots is: Yit=α+j=05ρjSHIitj+k=23ρkSHIit+k+γXit+Tt+Ci+εit

The baseline omitted case is the first lead, where k = 1.

APPENDIX 7. Health financing transitions in selected countries mentioned in the discussion section

graphic file with name HEC-32-574-g006.jpg

Source: Author elaboration. Descriptive data for selected variables, for Russia and Moldova, over time

Gabani, J. , Mazumdar, S. , & Suhrcke, M. (2023). The effect of health financing systems on health system outcomes: A cross‐country panel analysis. Health Economics, 32(3), 574–619. 10.1002/hec.4635

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Datasets are detailed in the data section, and corresponding links are in the references section. Datasets and Stata do files are available upon request to the corresponding author, and a replication package with all datasets and do files is also available at the Open Science Framework repository https://osf.io/snczj/.

REFERENCES

  1. Anderson, M. , Averi Albala, S. , Patel, N. , & Lloyd, J. (2018). Economic case for PHC. Available from http://www.who.int/docs/default‐source/primary‐health‐care‐conference/phc—economic‐case.pdf?sfvrsn=8d0105b8_2
  2. Angrist, J. D. , & Pischke, J. S. (2008). Chapter 3.2.3: Bad controls. In Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion (pp. 47–51).
  3. Angrist, J. D. , & Pischke, J. S. (2008). Chapter 5.2.1: Regression difference‐in‐difference. In Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion.
  4. Barasa, E. , Kazungu, J. , Nguhiu, P. , & Ravishankar, N. (2021). Examining the level and inequality in health insurance coverage in 36 sub‐Saharan African countries. BMJ Global Health, 6(4), e004712. 10.1136/bmjgh-2020-004712 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  5. Billor, N. , Hadi, A. S. , & Velleman, P. F. (2000). Bacon: Blocked adaptive computationally efficient outlier nominators. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 34(3), 279–298.  10.1016/S0167-9473(99)00101-2 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  6. Blundell, R. , & Costa Dias, M. (2009). Alternative approaches to evaluation in empirical microeconomics. Journal of Human Resources, 44(3), 565–640. 10.1353/jhr.2009.0009 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  7. Bokhari, F. A. S. , Gai, Y. , & Gottret, P. (2007). Government health expenditures and health outcomes. Health Economics, 16(3), 257–273. 10.1002/hec.1157 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  8. Carrin, G. , & James, C. (2005). Key performance indicators for the implementation of social health insurance. Applied Health Economics and Health Policy, 4(1), 15–22. 10.2165/00148365-200504010-00004 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  9. Clogg, C. C. , Petkova, E. , & Haritou, A. (1995). Statistical methods for comparing regression coefficients between models. American Journal of Sociology, 100(5), 1261–1293. 10.1086/230638 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  10. Erlangga, D. , Suhrcke, M. , Ali, S. , & Bloor, K. (2019). The impact of public health insurance on health care utilisation, financial protection and health status in low‐ and middle‐income countries: A systematic review. PLoS One, 14(8), e0219731. 10.1371/journal.pone.0219731 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  11. Fan, V. , & Savedoff, W. D. (2014). The health financing transition: A conceptual framework and empirical evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal. 10.2139/ssrn.2457240 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  12. Fan, V. Y. , & Savedoff, W. D. (2014). The health financing transition: A conceptual framework and empirical evidence. Social Science & Medicine, 105, 112–121. 10.1016/j.socscimed.2014.01.014 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  13. Filmer, D. , & Pritchett, L. (1999). The impact of public spending on health: Does money matter? Social Science & Medicine, 49(10),1309–1323.  10.1016/s0277-9536(99)00150-1 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  14. Goodman‐Bacon, A. (2018). Difference‐in‐Differences with variation in treatment timing.
  15. Gruber, J. , & Hanratty, M. (1995). The labor‐market effects of introducing national health insurance: Evidence from Canada. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 13(2), 163. 10.2307/1392370 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  16. Hsiao, W. C. , Shaw, R. P. , Fraker, A. , & Jowett, M. (2007). Social health insurance for developing nations (pp. 1–184). World Bank Institute development studies. [Google Scholar]
  17. Kreif, N. , Mirelman, A. J. , Love‐Koh, J. , Kim, S. , Moreno‐Serra, R. , Revill, P. , Sculpher, M. , & Suhrcke, M. (2021). From impact evaluation to decision‐analysis: Assessing the extent and quality of evidence on ‘value for money’ in health impact evaluations in low‐ and middle‐income countries. Gates Open Research, 5, 1. 10.12688/gatesopenres.13198.1 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  18. Kutzin, J. (2008). Health financing policy: A guide for decision‐makers.
  19. Le, N. , Groot, W. , Tomini, S. M. , & Tomini, F. (2019). Effects of health insurance on labour supply: A systematic review. International Journal of Manpower, 40(4), 717–767. 10.1108/ijm-02-2018-0038 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  20. Lozano, R. , Fullman, N. , Mumford, J. E. , Knight, M. , Barthelemy, C. M. , Abbafati, C. ,  Abbastabar, H. , Abd‐Allah, F. , Abdollahi, M. , Abedi, A. , Abolhassani, H. , Abosetugn, A. E. , Guimarães Abreu, L. , Abrigo, M. R. M. , Haimed, A. K. A. , Abushouk, A. I. , Adabi, M. , Adebayo, O. M. , Adekanmbi, V. , … Murray, C. J. L. (2020). Measuring universal health coverage based on an index of effective coverage of health services in 204 countries and territories, 1990–2019: A systematic analysis for the global burden of Disease study 2019. The Lancet, 396(10258), 1250–1284. Available from: http://www.thelancet.com/article/S0140673620307509/fulltext [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  21. MacQueen, J. (1967). Some methods for classification and analysis of multivariate observations. In Proceedings of the fifth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability.
  22. Makles, A . (2012). Stata tip 110: How to get the optimal k‐means cluster solution. Stata Journal, 12(2), 347–351. Available from: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/abs/10.1177/1536867X1201200213?journalCode=stja [Google Scholar]
  23. Moreno‐Serra, R. , & Smith, P. C. (2015). Broader health coverage is good for the nation’s health: Evidence from country level panel data. Journal Of The Royal Statistical Society Serious A Statistics in Society, 178(1), 101–124. 10.1111/rssa.12048 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  24. Nakamura, R. , Lomas, J. , Claxton, K. , Bokhari, F. , Moreno Serra, R. , & Suhrcke, M. (2016). Assessing the impact of health care expenditures on mortality using cross‐country data (pp. 1–57). Available from: https://pure.york.ac.uk/portal/en/publications/assessing‐the‐impact‐of‐health‐care‐expenditures‐on‐mortality‐using‐crosscountry‐data(f14bbcd4‐2f52‐4585‐ae90‐aeda23383c79).html
  25. OECD, Eurostat, WHO . (2017). A system of health accounts 2011: Revised edition. A System of Health Accounts 2011.
  26. Qin, V. M. , Hone, T. , Millett, C. , Moreno‐Serra, R. , McPake, B. , Atun, R. , & Lee, J. T. (2019). The impact of user charges on health outcomes in low‐income and middle‐income countries: A systematic review. BMJ Global Health, 3(Suppl 3), e001087. 10.1136/bmjgh-2018-001087 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  27. Rajkumar, A. S. , & Swaroop, V. (2008). Public spending and outcomes: Does governance matter? Journal Of Development Economics, 86(1), 96–111.  10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.08.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  28. Rannan‐Eliya, R. P. (2008). National health accounts estimation methods: Household out‐of‐pocket spending in private expenditure. WHO monographs.
  29. Savedoff, W. D. (2004). Is there a case for social insurance? Health Policy and Planning, 19(3), 183–184. 10.1093/heapol/czh022 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  30. Savedoff, W. D. , & Yazbeck, A. S. (2020). Four reasons why labor taxes are not a good way to finance healthcare [Internet]. [cited 2020 Nov 6]. Available from: https://blogs.iadb.org/salud/en/labor‐taxes‐finance‐healthcare/
  31. StataCorp . (2015). Stata statistical software: Release 14. StataCorp LLC. [Google Scholar]
  32. Sumriddetchkajorn, K. , Shimazaki, K. , Ono, T. , Kusaba, T. , Sato, K. , & Kobayashi, N. (2019). Universal health coverage and primary care, Thailand. Bull World Health Organ. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  33. van der Zee, J. , & Kroneman, M. W. (2007). Bismarck or Beveridge: A beauty contest between dinosaurs. BMC Health Services Research, 7(1), 94. Available from: /pmc/articles/PMC1934356/. 10.1186/1472-6963-7-94 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  34. Wagstaff, A. (2009a). Social health insurance vs. Tax‐financed health systems—evidence from the OECD [Internet]. World Bank Working Papers. [cited 2020 Jul 22]. Available from: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/545121468028868365/pdf/WPS4821.pdf
  35. Wagstaff, A. (2009b). Social health insurance vs. Tax‐financed health systems—evidence from the OECD. World Bank Working Papers.
  36. Wagstaff, A. (2010). Social health insurance reexamined. Health Economics. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  37. Wagstaff, A. (2013). Universal health coverage: Old wine in a new bottle? If so, is that so bad? [Internet]. [cited 2021 Apr 12]. Available from: https://blogs.worldbank.org/developmenttalk/universal‐health‐coverage‐old‐wine‐in‐a‐new‐bottle‐if‐so‐is‐that‐so‐bad
  38. Wagstaff, A. , Flores, G. , Hsu, J. , Smitz, M. F. , Chepynoga, K. , Buisman, L. R. , van Wilgenburg, K. , & Eozenou, P. (2018). Progress on catastrophic health spending in 133 countries: A retrospective observational study. Lancet Global Health, 6(2), e169–e179. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  39. Wagstaff, A. , & Moreno‐Serra, R. (2009a). Europe and central Asia’s great post‐communist social health insurance experiment: Aggregate impacts on health sector outcomes. Journal of Health Economics, 28(2), 322–340. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.10.011 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  40. Wagstaff, A. , & Moreno‐Serra, R. (2009b). Social health insurance and labor market outcomes: Evidence from central and Eastern Europe, and Central Asia. Advances in Health Economics and Health Services Research, 21, 83–106. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  41. Wagstaff, A. , & Neelsen, S. (2020). A comprehensive assessment of universal health coverage in 111 countries: A retrospective observational study. Lancet Global Health, 8(1), e39–e49. 10.1016/s2214-109x(19)30463-2 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  42. WHO . (2019). Global health expenditure Database [Internet]. [cited 2019 Nov 25]. Available from: https://apps.who.int/nha/database
  43. World Bank . (2019a). Health equity and financial protection indicators (HEFPI) | data catalog [Internet]. [cited 2020 Mar 22]. Available from: https://datacatalog.worldbank.org/dataset/hefpi
  44. World Bank . (2019b). WGI 2019 [Internet]. cited 2020 Mar 22]. Available from: https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/
  45. World Bank . (2019c). World Development Indicators [Internet]. [cited 2019 Nov 25]. Available from: https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world‐development‐indicators
  46. World Health Organization . (2019). Global spending on health: A world in transition [Internet]. [cited 2020 Dec 22]. Available from: https://www.who.int/health_financing/documents/health‐expenditure‐report‐2019.pdf
  47. World Health Organization . (2020). Universal health coverage (UHC) [Internet]. [cited 2020 Feb 17]. Available from: https://www.who.int/news‐room/fact‐sheets/detail/universal‐health‐coverage‐(uhc)
  48. Xu, K. , Evans, D. B. , Kawabata, K. , Zeramdini, R. , Klavus, J. , & Murray, C. J. L. (2003). Household catastrophic health expenditure: A multicountry analysis. Lancet. 362(9378), 111–117. 10.1016/S0140-6736(03)13861-5 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  49. Yazbeck, A. S. , Savedoff, W. D. , Hsiao, W. C. , Kutzin, J. , Soucat, A. , Tandon, A. , Wagstaff, A. , & Chi‐Man Yip, W. (2020). The case against labor‐tax‐financed social health insurance for low‐ and low‐middle‐income countries. Health Affairs, 39(5), 892–897. 10.1377/hlthaff.2019.00874 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  50. Zeldow, B. , & Hatfield, L. A. (2021). Confounding and regression adjustment in difference‐in‐differences studies. Health Services Research, 56(5), 932–941. Available from: https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/full/10.1111/1475‐6773.13666 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Data Availability Statement

Datasets are detailed in the data section, and corresponding links are in the references section. Datasets and Stata do files are available upon request to the corresponding author, and a replication package with all datasets and do files is also available at the Open Science Framework repository https://osf.io/snczj/.


Articles from Health Economics are provided here courtesy of Wiley

RESOURCES