Abstract
Persistent institutionalized inequality (PII) emerged at the Bridge River site by ca 1200–1300 years ago. Research confirms that PII developed at a time of population packing associated with unstable fluctuations in a critical food resource (anadromous salmon) and persisted across multiple generations. While we understand the demographic and ecological conditions under which this history unfolded, we have yet to address details of the underlying social process. In this paper, we draw on Bridge River's Housepit 54 to examine two alternative hypotheses. Hypothesis 1, mutualism, suggests that household heads signalled to maintain and attract new members as a means of supporting the demographic viability of the house. Inequality is indicated by variation in prestige markers but less obviously in economic fundamentals. Hypothesis 2, coercion, asserts that the more successful households developed control over access to critical food resources, forcing others into the choice between emigration and subjugation. Inequality is indicated by inter-family differences in prestige markers and economic fundamentals. Results suggest that inequality emerged under a mutualism scenario but persisted for subsequent generations under more coercive conditions.
This article is part of the theme issue ‘Evolutionary ecology of inequality’.
Keywords: wealth-based inequality, Pacific northwest region, Bridge River site, managerial mutualism, coercion
1. Introduction
Evolution of persistent institutionalized social inequality (PII) has become a critical topic in anthropological research [1–3]. Consequently, we have gained significant understandings of variability in forms of inequality and their associated underlying conditions. Borgerhoff Mulder et al. [1] recognize that among multiple forms of wealth (material, relational and embodied), highly transmissible material wealth best predicts high levels of inequality in diverse human communities. Wealth-based inequality is common in agricultural and pastoralist societies given that these groups rely upon densely concentrated defensible economic resources [4]. However, it is also clear that certain hunter–gatherer populations (so-called complex fisher-hunter–gatherers) can fall into this category given their reliance on similarly dense resources such as anadromous salmon [5]. Archaeologists have created hypotheses about emergent inequality in hunter–gatherer contexts drawing upon these kinds of assumptions, focusing on optimal fishing (e.g. [6–9]) and hunting [10,11] locales. Despite widespread understanding of the underlying conditions favouring the development of material wealth-based inequalities, we remain challenged to fully understand the critical tipping points where institutionalized strategies of egalitarianism give way to inequalities. Two general classes of models have been widely discussed emphasizing mutualism versus coercion [12].
One collection of models predicts inequality emerging out of mutualistic arrangements between groups and individuals. Under Johnson's [13] influential model, scalar stress associated with growing population and increasingly complicated logistics for moving goods to consumers favours the establishment of new forms of leadership that benefit all by facilitating the functioning of these systems. Ames [14] argues that population growth in constrained environments of the Northwest Coast of North America favoured increasing logistical organization (per [15]), which in turn complicated household economies and created conditions whereby managers could facilitate better organization and in turn reap rewards. Friesen [16] sees benefits in the scalar stress model for understanding social changes in Inuit societies during the rise of umialiit (whaling boat owners) associated with increased hunting of bowhead whales. Smith & Choi [17] build a variant of this model that they call managerial mutualism, in which managers are permitted to profit after absorbing costs of punishing free-riders as a solution to a collective action problem. They note, however, based on modelling results, that such a scenario might be more difficult to achieve than patron–client relationships given narrow ranges on conditioning variables (one manager per group, low mortality rate, high reproductive rate, adequate value [though not too high] of collective good, low goods production cost, cost of enforcement relatively low and management fee neither too high or low). Nonetheless, the model makes sense in light of other scholarship. For example, Hooper et al. [18] argue that leadership can be rewarded as an alternative to lower overall productivity in an unsupervised group.
Under the coercion or patron–client scenario, highly heterogeneous environments favour inequality in access to resources thus leading to uneven local subsistence incomes and the development of potential patron and client relationships if need becomes strong enough among those in less productive patches [19]. As modelled by Smith & Choi [17], demographic and ecological factors will affect the rates by which these relationships develop. High mortality and/or low rates of reproduction allow patrons to become common and to control patches. Homogeneous environments retard rates by which patron–client relationships develop ([17], p. 111). An extreme version of the coercion model, outlined by Kennett et al. [20], suggests that under an Ideal Despotic Distribution model, better competitors will push less competitive groups into more marginal habitats thus favouring structural inequalities tied to extreme resource heterogeneity. Such competitive situations are also predicted by demographic ecological models examining the effects of Malthusian cycles [21]. Boone [22] notes that under heterogeneous conditions where demographic stress (impacts of imbalance between population needs and resource production leading to either a stable ceiling or catastrophic loss) impacts all populations, some better-off groups may employ signalling strategies to attract followers. These models are in line with our understanding of the demographic histories of long-lived House groups on the Northwest Coast of North America, where demographic crises occur with some regularity and require proactive strategies for recruitment and stabilization of domestic economies [23]. Similarly, these predictions appear to be confirmed in the histories of some Polynesian Islands where demographic crises lead to severe re-arrangements of social relations and periods of violence [24].
In this paper we conduct a fine-grained test of these two models drawing upon data from Housepit 54 at the Bridge River site (indigenous name: K'etxelknaz) in British Columbia (figure 1). The archaeological record of this house permits an examination of socio-economic and political change on an intergenerational basis during the time when village-wide inequality in material wealth appeared [25–27]. We accomplish this by developing new independent tests of material wealth and subsistence inequality. Specific to the Pacific Northwest region where inequality often manifested at the scales of inter-family relations within Houses, between houses, and even between clans [28], the coercion model reflects situations whereby established House groups accept or otherwise recognize members who are in effect tenants whose work benefits the larger group in terms of overall production of food and goods. In return, these persons receive shelter and protection while not necessarily gaining access to the most prestigious goods or highest quality food items displayed and consumed by chiefly families (e.g. [29]). By contrast, the mutualism model suggests that equally well-off families within a given House might permit one or more groups rights to acquire and display excess material wealth if their actions enhanced the general health of the overall House by organizing and managing productive ventures such as trade ventures, hunts and feasting and gifting events (e.g. [30]). Thus, our logic is that within the Mid-Fraser context, conditions of coercion would favour inequality in both wealth markers and access to food under conditions of economic stress, whereas mutualism would include inequality in wealth markers but not necessarily food under conditions of rising population though not necessarily severe economic stress. Analytical results suggest that while mutualism was important to the initiation of inequality, coercion may also have played a role in later generations.
2. Examining material wealth-based inequality in the Mid-Fraser context
The Indigenous people of the Mid-Fraser Canyon area of British Columbia are known as the St’át'imc or Upper Lillooet [31,32]. St’át'imc social life was organized across several scales. Clans were distributed across one or more villages such that a large village might include residences of House groups associated with two or more clans [32]. Clan chiefs were chosen from the highest-ranking House groups and were responsible for decisions regarding access to clan hunting, berry collecting and fishing places. Maintenance of chiefly status depended upon wisdom and generosity as provided in community potlatches and feasts [30]. House groups controlled access to specific fishing sites within clan territory. Membership of these groups generally consisted of brothers and their wives and children [32]. Within this system high status could be achieved or inherited. Thus, while some were born into high-ranking families, others could gain influence and respect through successful hunting, warfare and potlatching [30–32]. Inequality was therefore a byproduct of clan and village membership, House status and individual achievement. Thus, traditional St’át'imc society could have social distinctions based upon hereditary position and achievement in a variety of pursuits that manifested on inter-family, House and potentially clan group [33]. Patron–client scenarios could be manifested in individuals and families relying upon more wealthy families for access to food and non-food resources [30,32]. Given the foundation of the society on inter-family relations, inequality is best understood in its manifestations within multi-family Houses. Archaeologists can measure variation between family groups based upon spatial arrangements of redundant domestic areas on house floors [34–36]. Wealth distinctions between domestic groups, when present, appear not to have been kept hidden as wealth-related items (prestige objects and raw materials) are commonly found on house floors [37]. Teit [38] provides an account of Nlaka'pamux people sitting over trap doors covering caches of food. However, it is not clear how common this practice was or if it was employed in the St'át'imc area where Bridge River and Keatley Creek are located.
Evolution of this system that included this pattern of inequality has been subject to debate and revisions by archaeologists. Hayden [34,39–41] argues that the large houses within the dense aggregate villages of the Mid-Fraser, especially at the Keatley Creek site (Indigenous name: Tl'atl'lh; figure 1), were built as early as ca 2600 cal. BP and persisted without significant change until catastrophic abandonment at ca 1000 cal. BP. Thus, inequality between house groups was the byproduct of a long-lived political ecological strategy predicated on a simple assumption that aggregated human groups supported by abundant resources inevitably lead some personalities to engage in self-aggrandizing strategies thus leading to the pattern of inequality documented by ethnography (e.g. [32]). Anadromous salmon (Oncorhynchus sp.) runs were likely very productive in the Fraser and Columbia River systems during the period of ca 2500–3500 cal. BP [42,43]. However, more extensive dating of deeply buried house features at Keatley Creek revealed that the village was likely less than 1800 years old [44] and that inequality developed after ca 1300 cal. BP [45]. This chronology of village establishment, growth and social change was confirmed at the nearby Bridge River village (figure 1) [25,46] and extrapolated to the wider Mid-Fraser area [9]. These outcomes required that we rethink the conditions and underlying causes by which inequality developed in the Mid-Fraser.
Prentiss et al. [45] provide data from the rim midden of Housepit 7 at Keatley Creek suggesting that at peak village population (ca 1200–1300 cal. BP) salmon production declined and was accompanied by subsistence strategies that sought a wider diet requiring more extensive hunting and gathering on local landscapes. Inequality thus appeared under conditions of subsistence intensification under demographic pressure. Prentiss et al. [45] draw from Boone [19] to argue that inequality at Keatley Creek may have developed under patron–client conditions as members of economically weaker houses sought support from economically better-off houses (Housepit 7). Prentiss et al. [9,25] relied upon inter-house data from the Bridge River site that recognized a similar transition to that seen at Keatley Creek. Here, salmon and artiodactyls (deer [Odocoileus sp.] and bighorn sheep [Ovis canadensis]) elements declined, while processing intensity increased between the BR2 (1300–1600 cal BP) and BR3 (1000–1300 cal BP) periods. Interhouse inequality developed during the BR3 period, as indicated by significant distinctions between houses measured in prestige artefacts (e.g. stone beads, pendants, bowls and figurines), non-local raw materials and prestige raw materials (nephrite jade, steatite and obsidian) [25]. Further, select houses (e.g. Housepit 24) raised and consumed dogs [47], maintained unique and costly tool forms (e.g. sawed and ground slate scrapers [48]) and hosted feasts, while others (e.g. Housepit 16) had no indicators of dogs, relied upon chipped slate tools and did not leave any evidence of feasting [9,25]. Prentiss et al. [9] argue that the Bridge River sequence is best understood in light of a Malthusian demographic model [21] in which BR3 represents a Malthusian ceiling in which significant population–resource imbalance occurred, leading to competition between Houses over rights to resources and persons to support household production activities. In this scenario, inequality is still the result of the formation of patron–client relationships within and between Houses, as facilitated by social signalling via feasts held by the larger and more successful Houses.
Prentiss et al. [26,27,49] add nuance to the Malthusian model at Bridge River, drawing upon the lengthy floor sequence at Housepit 54. The 15-floor sequence dated ca 1100–1460 cal. BP (figure 2) provides support for earlier conclusions that the village persisted through two complete Malthusian cycles [26,46]. An early slow growth (copial) period during BR1 (ca 1600–1800 cal BP) to mid-BR2 favoured growth of the village that was interrupted by the first Malthusian period, which led to substantial abandonment during late BR2. Rapid growth occurred during early BR3 before the second Malthusian period developed, with its pattern of subsistence resource intensification and inter-house social inequality. Housepit 54 inhabitants persisted across the first Malthusian period by engaging in higher rates of winter residential mobility, while nearly all other houses in the village were abandoned [26,49]. Housepit 54 then grew substantially during early BR3 as the rest of the village was re-populated. By ca 1200–1250 cal. BP intra-house inequality emerged under conditions of population packing and intensive harvest and processing of fish and artiodactyl resources and persisted for four generations. Prentiss et al. [27,49] argue that this pattern of PII was favoured by the socio-economically competitive conditions of the second Malthusian period. However, given that it was initiated at the BR3 demographic peak under apparently highly productive resource conditions, they are unable to reject the scalar-stress/managerial mutualism hypothesis.
3. Material and methods
Housepit 54 at the Bridge River site continues to provide opportunities for unique insights into socio-economic and political process in an Indigenous pithouse village on the western Canadian Plateau [36]. Housepit formation processes can be complex and involve cycles of construction, demolition and reconstruction [34,50]. In brief, semi-subterranean houses were often occupied across multiple generations. This required establishing floors with associated cooking, storage and sleeping features with a post and beam roof [32,51]. After about a generation (20–25 years), roofs were removed and/or burned and a new floor and roof established [52]. Some groups would remove the old roof and floor when reestablishing the house, as for example at the large housepits of Keatley Creek [34,44]. Other groups, such as at Bridge River, would remove the roof with minimal disturbance to the floor and simply add a new layer of silty-loam over the old floor, effectively starting the cycle again [37]. If the house persists across enough generations under the Bridge River formation processes model, then the housepit accumulates a record of long-term persistence and change stored on superimposed anthropogenic floors as opposed to a record of redeposited floors and roofs in middens surrounding the house. Housepit 54 at Bridge River provides the most extreme example of the former scenario.
Housepit 54 accumulated 15 intact anthropogenic floors (termed IIa-IIo) and five partial roof deposits pre-dating ca 1100 cal. BP [26]. Later reoccupations included a brief period of use during ca 900–1000 cal. BP (IIa1 floor) and a substantial Fur Trade period floor and roof dating to the mid-ninteenth century CE [53]. The IIa1 floor was largely removed by occupants of the Fur Trade floor. The earliest three floors (IIm–o) were not fully excavated as portions of each fell outside of excavation blocks. However, these earliest floors appear to have been small and thus likely representative of single family houses (probably 5–7 persons). Floors IIf–IIl reflect a larger rectangular-shaped house (occupied by populations that could have ranged between about 10 and 30), while floors IIa–IIe represent the house at full size, an approximate 13 m diameter oval, with house populations estimated between about 25 and 45 [26,37]. Prentiss et al. [54] provide a phylogenetic model suggesting that rules for social interactions evolved from a communalistic (IIh–IIl) to a more collectivist (IIa–IIg) social strategy. This suggests that over time families shifted from communal cooking and sharing of other work (communalist) to separation into distinct family work spaces (collectivist).
Prentiss et al. [27] tested for the emergence of material wealth-based inequality between domestic activity areas across a 12 floor sequence (IIa–IIl). They accomplished this by first measuring inequality with three wealth-based variables (prestige-related artefact, prestige lithic raw material and non-local lithic raw material density) and two measures of hunting success (biface and hide scraper density). The latter measures are based upon ethnographic research that suggests successful hunting brought recognition and wealth to house groups [55]. A principal components analysis (PCA) was run for these five variables across the activity areas (measured as the contents of each excavation Block) for the 12 floors, resulting in a single significant component capturing 74% of the variance with significant positive loadings on all variables. Component scores were saved to measure the contribution of each case (activity areas [measured in excavation blocks] across the 12 floors) and results suggest that only the Block D floors (IIb–IIe) achieved consistently high scores, raising the possibility that the family residing in this position had not only consistently better access to food resources but also maintained consistently strong access to a variety of prestige and non-local lithic items and materials. Finally, Prentiss et al. calculated sample variances for the component scores for each floor, concluding that the widest variance was clearly on the IIb–IIe floors. The analysis thus suggests that material wealth-based inequality emerged and persisted across four generational floors (estimated 96 years).
Here we replicate the procedure followed by Prentiss et al. [27] but with some changes. Most fundamentally, we run two independent PCAs separating measures of wealth items from subsistence decision making. Wealth items include prestige item density (beads, pendants, stone bowls, nephrite jade items and figurines) and four measures of non-local and prestigious lithic raw materials (Hat Creek jasper, Fountain pisolite, obsidian and nephrite/steatite density). Subsistence measures include canid, artiodactyl, sockeye salmon and formal biface and projectile point density. Canids were an important dietary item used in Mid-Fraser villages and would have been an important resource for Housepit 54 groups [47]. Artiodactyls provided a significant alternative to fish during annual subsistence cycles [55] and were also important feasting items [30]. Bifaces and projectile points provide an independent measure of hunting preparation [25,45,49]. Sockeye salmon were the keystone food resource to all Mid-Fraser peoples [56,57]. We measure degree of inequality by assessment of component scores on domestic activity areas for each Block in all 12 floors. We further examine these relationships with sample variance scores for each floor [27]. All raw data are provided in the electronic supplementary materials.
The coercion hypothesis suggests that inequality would emerge as those worse-off in an expanding economic crisis would seek shelter with those who had better access to resources, thus establishing patron–client relationships. From the standpoint of a single multi-generational house, we could imagine scenarios where inequality is triggered by acceptance of new residents from elsewhere (Teit [32] notes brothers and their families co-resided in houses) or shifts in the social status of longer-standing residents. Therefore, at the initiation of inequality we would expect strong distinctions between residential groups within the house in terms of both wealth items and access to food. Thus, one group might mark success with investment in prestige items and non-local lithic source material while also maintaining subsistence distinctions, as might occur when lower-status people had to wait while higher-ranked families completed their use of the best fishing, hunting and/or gathering places [56,58]. By contrast, the mutualism model raises the possibility that in a growing community, people might be attracted to a new social arrangement with strong leadership and the possibility of socio-economic opportunity. In this scenario we would expect emergent inequality to be marked by material wealth distinctions but little difference in access to fundamental subsistence items. This might occur if House leadership chose to fully share subsistence resource access points while maintaining elite-associated production and exchange relationships. It was not uncommon elsewhere in the Pacific Northwest for those of chiefly status to obtain portions of returns (derived from House-owned economic landscapes) from all House members, which could in turn be used in feasts or in support of other ventures (e.g. [29,59]).
4. Results
The PCA (both PCAs run using SPSS Statistics v. 27 [60]) for wealth measures resulted in two significant components, with the first capturing 59% of the variance (see electronic supplementary materials). All variables load strongly positive on component one of the component loadings matrix (electronic supplementary materials), thus confirming this component as a strong measure of household wealth. Component scores are strongly positive in Block D for floors IIb–IIe, although an additional significant positive score is present in Block C for floor IIb (table 1). We calculated sample variances for the component scores on each floor, and results (table 1, figure 3) strongly support the previous argument [27] that inequality abruptly emerged on floor IIe and persisted through IIb. The strong positive component score on Block C of floor IIb raises the possibility that egalitarianism might have been returning at this time. Indeed, by the IIa floor, inhabitants of Housepit 54 filled the Block D area with rim fill and did not permit anyone to occupy this portion of the house prior to its abandonment.
Table 1.
block | block | block | block | sample | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
floor | A | B | C | D | variance |
IIa | −0.56908 | −0.30598 | −0.43101 | 0.01732 | |
IIb | −0.6795 | −0.6957 | 1.07959 | 0.61277 | 0.820524 |
IIc | 0.07424 | 0.11191 | 0.09938 | 1.52487 | 0.554215 |
IId | 0.58135 | 0.1055 | −0.35427 | 1.65181 | 1.011429 |
IIe | 0.74064 | −0.5803 | 0.01453 | 4.5187 | 6.256973 |
IIf | 0.24798 | −0.0227 | 0.025376 | ||
IIg | 0.45008 | 0.38308 | 0.002245 | ||
IIh | −0.3097 | 0.30616 | 0.000627 | ||
IIi | 0.52485 | 0.46233 | 0.001954 | ||
IIj | 0.23557 | −0.3803 | 0.010473 | ||
IIk | 0.80381 | 0.24436 | 0.156492 | ||
IIl | 0.21009 | 0.09691 | 0.006405 |
Our PCA for subsistence measures returned a single significant component capturing approximately 65% of the variance (electronic supplementary materials). The component loading vector includes significant positive loadings on all variables (electronic supplementary materials), suggesting that household wherewithal integrated multiple food sources including major mammalian and piscine prey items. The component scores matrix (table 2) includes significant positive loadings on all Block D floors (IIb–IIe), but also on Blocks B and C for IIe, Block C on IIg and Block A on IIh. Sample variance scores (table 2; figure 3) are extremely high only for floors IIc and IId. These outcomes suggest to us that inequality in subsistence is only identifiable on floors IIc and IId and thus, did not coincide with the first generation of material wealth-based inequality.
Table 2.
block | block | block | block | sample | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
floor | A | B | C | D | variance |
IIa | −0.53296 | −0.89011 | 0.01309 | 0.206916 | |
IIb | 0.57808 | 0.48943 | 0.22905 | 0.85254 | 0.434573 |
IIc | 0.54051 | 0.48294 | 0.26112 | 3.78248 | 4.446944 |
IId | 0.50278 | 0.85289 | 0.47889 | 2.20841 | 2.017226 |
IIe | 0.60195 | 1.07744 | 0.70681 | 1.30606 | 0.72687 |
IIf | 0.43373 | 0.06803 | 0.125882 | ||
IIg | 0.58488 | 0.50143 | 0.590035 | ||
IIh | 0.89903 | 0.46599 | 0.93164 | ||
IIi | 0.58026 | 0.84943 | 0.036226 | ||
IIj | 0.12154 | 0.81053 | 0.237354 | ||
IIk | 0.91919 | 0.02566 | 0.446371 | ||
IIl | 0.50089 | 0.46525 | 0.000635 |
5. Discussion
We proposed two alternative models to better our understanding of the transition from relative egalitarianism to persistent material wealth-based inequality. The coercion model is widely recognized to be associated with the establishment of unequal patron–client relationships [19]. We expected that a patron–client scenario specific to the Mid-Fraser area would include wealth and subsistence differentiation. The mutualism model, in contrast, is recognized to occur in different ways but generally assumes that positive resource management would lead to attractive opportunities for supporting and growing group membership while permitting managers to retain payments and thus achieve higher wealth differentials [17]. We think this would be reflected in the Mid-Fraser context by emergent strong House groups, with material-wealthy leadership accompanied by a broadly well-fed house membership. We tested these hypotheses with data on material wealth and subsistence from 12 anthropogenic floors from Housepit 54 at the Bridge River site in British Columbia. Multivariate analysis confirms that wealth inequality appeared abruptly on the IIe floor and persisted across four generations. By contrast, subsistence inequality occurred a generation later and only lasted two generations.
We suggest that the mutualism hypothesis is the better explanation for the initial onset of material wealth-based inequality at Housepit 54. This Housepit had doubled in physical size by the start of the IIe floor. Its population had also peaked at an estimated 44 people and storage capacity measured in relatively volume of cache pits was also at its high [26]. Subsistence resources were productive, as indicated by peak returns on salmon and continued high returns on artiodactyls [49]. Thus, it would appear that during that brief generation, Housepit 54 was highly successful and that success was felt at the level of family subsistence economies throughout the house, while one family group also exhibited signs of significant material wealth. Thus, coercion seems like an unlikely scenario for growth, subsistence success and emergent wealth differentiation on floor IIe. The economic situation on the IIe floor would have been highly attractive to prospective new household members. Indeed, during the life of IIe, the spatial arrangement of features shifted from three domestic areas (Blocks A, C and D) with one area (Block B) set aside for pit storage to a situation where all block areas were structured as general domestic areas, thus implying the addition of one or more families before the close of that floor. We cannot yet determine if these new residents were kin or non-kin. The IIe floor does appear to loosely meet expectations of Smith and Choi's [17] simulation model for managerial mutualism given the apparent appearance of one higher wealth group during a time of population growth with moderate increases in the rate of goods production [37]. Unfortunately, some aspects of their model (enforcement cost and management fee, for example) are very hard to measure with archaeological data.
This leaves us with the challenge of understanding the fact of both wealth and subsistence inequality on IIc and IId. Estimated populations on IIc and IId are approximately 50% of the population on IIe and relative cache pit volume also drops by about 50% [26]. Density of salmon remains drops by 50–75%, respectively, on IIc and IId, while artiodactyl remains are down by about 25% on both floors [49]. All things considered, it would appear that the house suffered severe economic stress leading to a near catastrophic drop in population under conditions of major reductions in access to keystone resources (especially salmon). This suggests to us that mutualism gave way to competitive conditions and some degree of exclusionary resource rights between families within this collectivist House.
We can gain a better understanding of this process in light of models derived from demographic ecology [61]. In Puleston et al.'s [21] model, rapid growth copial periods can lead to short-lived transitions and the sudden onset of Malthusian conditions. The data from floor IIe at Housepit 54 appear to indicate a single generation demographic peak that resembles the transition stage in the Puleston et al. [21] model. At this point, the entire village was rapidly growing, as indicated by the multitude of new houses established after ca 1300 cal. BP and the growth in size of select houses such as Housepit 54. Under conditions of economic productivity and population packing there may have been a strong payoff for taking up or maintaining residence in particularly productive Houses with effective leadership. Housepit 54 was only one of three houses (current data) to persist across the BR2 to BR3 transition and that would likely have been widely known. The rapid demographic downturn under conditions of resource scarcity are exactly what we would expect if the House (and likely village [9]) experienced the onset of a Malthusian period. Within that scenario, mutualism could have given way to coercion as resources grew tight for all House groups. Thus, now packed residents may have had to wait for access to best fishing, hunting and gathering places, virtually guaranteeing lowered returns. Poor or at least unpredictable subsistence returns would have been disastrous, especially during late winter when stores ran low [51,56,58,62]. This in turn would have led to loss of life and/or risky movement away from the aggregated village. If this model is correct then inequality at Bridge River began in a voluntary situation predicted by mutualism, but evolved into more of a coercion scenario under a persistent Malthusian period.
These outcomes offer implications for other contexts of emergent inequality. For example, Ritchie & Lepofsky [63] document a similar process of social change in Coast Salish settlement and social relationships during the period of ca 1000–1500 cal. BP. These cases provide likely scenarios where mutualistic arrangements may have facilitated social changes that included persistent institutionalized inequality. Future research is required to assess such developments in enough spatio-temporal detail that models can actually be tested. Critically, scholars need to explore options that include not just cooperation but the effects of competition and coercion as in the Bridge River case where this clearly played a role over time.
Acknowledgements
We thank Eric Smith, Jennifer Smith and Brian Codding for inviting us to submit this manuscript. We thank Xwísten, the Bridge River Indian Band for partnering with us in this long-term study of Housepit 54. We thank in particular, Ina Williams, Gerald Michel, Gary Forsyth, Christina LeDoux, Bonnie Michel, Bradley Jack and Josh Jack. Any views, findings, conclusions or recommendations expressed in this article do not necessarily represent those of the National Endowment for the Humanities. We thank the many excavators and laboratory workers associated with the Housepit 54 project. We thank the Phillip Wright Zoological Museum at the University of Montana for access to comparative collections. We thank two anonymous peer reviewers for their helpful comments.
Data accessibility
Raw data and additional data representing outcomes of multivariate statistical analyses are available as electronic supplementary material [64].
Authors' contributions
A.M.P.: conceptualization, data curation, formal analysis, funding acquisition, investigation, methodology, project administration, supervision, validation, visualization, writing—original draft, writing—review and editing; T.A.F.: conceptualization, formal analysis, methodology, writing—review and editing; A.H.: conceptualization, investigation, writing—review and editing; M.J.W.: conceptualization, methodology, writing—review and editing; M.D.: investigation, writing—review and editing; A.E.: investigation, writing—review and editing.
All authors gave final approval for publication and agreed to be held accountable for the work performed therein.
Conflict of interest declaration
We declare we have no competing interests.
Funding
Our 2012–2016 field seasons were supported by grants from the National Endowment for the Humanities (grant nos. RZ-51287–11 and RZ-230366-1). The 2008 and 2009 field seasons at Bridge River were supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation (grant no. BCS-0713013).
References
- 1.Borgerhoff Mulder M, et al. 2009. Intergenerational wealth transmission and the dynamics of inequality in small-scale societies. Science 326, 682-687. ( 10.1126/science.1178336) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 2.Flannery KV, Marcus J. 2012. The creation of inequality: how our prehistoric ancestors set the stage for monarchy, slavery, and empire. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 3.Kohler TA, Smith ME (eds) 2018. Ten thousand years of inequality: The archaeology of wealth differences. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. [Google Scholar]
- 4.Bowles S, Choi JK. 2013. Coevolution of farming and private property during the early Holocene. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. 110, 8830-8835. ( 10.1073/pnas.1212149110) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Smith EA, et al. 2010. Wealth transmission and inequality among hunter-gatherers. Curr. Anthropol. 51, 19-34. ( 10.1086/648530) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Arnold J. 1993. Labor and the rise of complex hunter-gatherers. J. Anthropol. Archaeol. 12, 75-119. ( 10.1006/jaar.1993.1003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Lepofsky D, Lertzman K, Hallett D, Mathewes R. 2005. Climate change and culture change on the southern coast of British Columbia 2400–1200 cal. B.P.: an hypothesis. Am. Antiq. 70, 267-294. ( 10.2307/40035704) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Marquardt WH, Walker KJ, Thompson VD, Savarese M, Roberts Thompson AD, Newsom L. 2022. Episodic complexity and the emergence of a coastal kingdom: climate, cooperation, and coercion in Southwest Florida. J. Anthropol. Archaeol. 65, 101364. ( 10.1016/j.jaa.2021.101364) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 9.Prentiss AM, Cail HS, Smith LS. 2014. At the Malthusian ceiling: subsistence and inequality at Bridge River, British Columbia. J. Anthropol. Archaeol. 33, 34-48. ( 10.1016/j.jaa.2013.11.003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Mason OK, Rasic JT. 2019. Walrusing, whaling, and the origins of the Old Bering Sea culture. World Archaeol. 51, 454-483. ( 10.1080/00438243.2019.1723681) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Zedeño MN, Ballenger JAM, Murray JR. 2014. Landscape engineering and organizational complexity among late prehistoric bison hunters of the Northwestern Plains. Curr. Anthropol. 55, 23-58. ( 10.1086/674535) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Mattison SM, Smith EA, Shenk M, Cochrane EE. 2016. The evolution of inequality. Evol. Anthropol. 25, 184-199. ( 10.1002/evan.21491) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Johnson GA. 1982. Organizational structure and scalar stress. In Theory and explanation in archaeology (eds Renfrew C, Rowlands MJ, Segraves BA), pp. 389-421. New York, NY: Academic Press. [Google Scholar]
- 14.Ames KM. 1985. Hierarchies, stress, and logistical strategies among hunter-gatherers in Northwestern North America. In Prehistoric hunter–gatherers; the emergence of cultural complexity (eds Price TD, Brown JD), pp. 155-180. Orlando, FL: Academic Press. ( 10.1016/B978-0-12-564750-2.50011-1) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Binford L. 1980. Willow smoke and dogs' tails: hunter-gatherer settlement systems and archaeological site formation. Am. Antiq. 45, 4-20. ( 10.2307/279653) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 16.Friesen TM. 1999. Resource structure, scalar stress, and the development of Inuit social organization. World Archaeol. 31, 21-37. ( 10.1080/00438243.1999.9980430) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Smith EA, Choi JK. 2007. The emergence of inequality in small scale societies: simple scenarios and agent based simulations. In The model-based archaeology of socio-natural systems (eds Kohler T, Van Der Leuw SE), pp. 105-120. Santa Fe: School of Advanced Research. [Google Scholar]
- 18.Hooper PL, Kaplan HS, Boone JL. 2010. A theory of leadership in human cooperative groups. J. Theor. Biol. 265, 633-646. ( 10.1016/j.jtbi.2010.05.034) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 19.Boone JL. 1992. Competition, conflict, and the development of social hierarchies. In Evolutionary ecology and human behavior (eds Smith EA, Winterhalder B), pp. 301-338. New York, NY: Aldine de Gruyter. [Google Scholar]
- 20.Kennett D, Anderson A, Winterhalder B. 2006. The ideal free distribution, food production, and the colonization of Oceania. In Behavioral ecology and the transition to agriculture (eds Kennett DJ, Winterhalder B), pp. 265-288. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. [Google Scholar]
- 21.Puleston C, Tuljapurkar S, Winterhalder B. 2014. The invisible cliff: abrupt imposition of Malthusian equilibrium in a natural-fertility, Agrarian Society. PLoS ONE 9, e87541. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0087541) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Boone JL. 1998. The evolution of magnanimity: when it is better to give than to receive? Hum. Nat. 9, 1-21. ( 10.1007/s12110-998-1009-y) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Ames KM. 2006. Thinking about household archaeology on the Northwest Coast. In Household archaeology on the northwest coast (eds Sobel EA, Ann Trieu Gahr D, Ames KM), pp. 16-36. Ann Arbor, MI: International Monographs in Prehistory, Archaeological Series 16. [Google Scholar]
- 24.Kirch PV. 1997. Microcosmic histories: island perspectives on global change. Am. Anthropol. 99, 30-42. ( 10.1525/aa.1997.99.1.30) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 25.Prentiss AM, Foor TA, Cross G, Harris LE, Wanzenried M. 2012. The cultural evolution of material wealth based inequality at Bridge River, British Columbia. Am. Antiq. 77, 542-565. ( 10.7183/0002-7316.77.3.542) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 26.Prentiss AM, Foor TA, Hampton A. 2018. Testing the Malthusian Model: population and storage at Housepit 54, Bridge River, British Columbia. J. Archaeol. Sci.: Rep. 18, 535-550. ( 10.1016/j.jasrep.2018.02.015) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Prentiss AM, Foor TA, Hampton A, Ryan E, Walsh MJ. 2018. The evolution of material wealth-based inequality: the evidence from Housepit 54, Bridge River, British Columbia. Am. Antiq. 83, 598-618. ( 10.1017/aaq.2018.56) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 28.Drucker P. 1955. Indians of the northwest coast. Anthropological handbook number Ten, American museum of natural history. New York, NY: McGraw Hill Book Company. [Google Scholar]
- 29.Drucker P. 1951. The Northern and Central Nootkan tribes. Bureau Am. Ethnol. Bull. 144, 1-480. [Google Scholar]
- 30.Kennedy DID, Bouchard R. 1978. Fraser River Lillooet: an ethnographic summary. In Reports of the lillooet archaeological project. Number 1. Introduction and setting (eds Stryd A, Lawhead S), pp. 22-55. Ottawa, Ontario: National Museum of Man, Mercury Series, Archaeological Survey of Canada paper No. 73. [Google Scholar]
- 31.Kennedy D, Bouchard RT. 1998. Lillooet. In Handbook of North American Indians: plateau (ed. Walker DE Jr), pp. 174-190. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution. [Google Scholar]
- 32.Teit J. 1906. The Lillooet Indians. Memoirs of the American Museum of Natural History, Jesup North Pacific Expedition 2, 193–300.
- 33.Prentiss AM, Williams-Larson A, Hampton A. 2023. Ethnography and the interpretation of ancient socio-political structure in the Middle Fraser Canyon, British Columbia. In Fisher-Hunter-Gatherer complexity in North America (ed. Sampson C.P), pp. 57-85. Gainesville, FL: University Press of Florida. ( 10.2307/jj.2990340) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 34.Hayden B. 1997. The pithouses of Keatley Creek. Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt Brace College Publishers. [Google Scholar]
- 35.Prentiss AM. 2023. Ancient and Pre-modern economies of North America's Pacific Northwest region. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ( 10.1017/9781009343480) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 36.Prentiss AM, Kuijt I. 2012. People of the Middle Fraser Canyon: an archaeological history. Vancouver, Canada: University of British Columbia Press. [Google Scholar]
- 37.Prentiss AM, Ryan E, Hampton A, Bobolinski K, Yu P-L, Schmader M, Edwards A. 2022. Household archaeology at the bridge river site (EeRl4), British Columbia: spatial distributions of features, lithic artifacts, and faunal remains on fifteen anthropogenic floors from housepit 54. Salt Lake City, UT: The University of Utah Press. [Google Scholar]
- 38.Teit J. 1898. Traditions of the Thompson River Indians of British Columbia. Boston, MA & New York, NY: Houghton, Mifflin & Co. [Google Scholar]
- 39.Hayden B. 1994. Competition, labor, and complex hunter-gatherers. In Key issues in hunter-gatherer research (eds Burch ES, Ellana LL), pp. 223-239. Oxford, UK: Berg Press. [Google Scholar]
- 40.Hayden B. 2000. The ancient past of Keatley Creek: Volume II, Socioeconomy. Burnaby, BC: Archaeology Press, Simon Fraser University. [Google Scholar]
- 41.Hayden B, Reinhardt GA, MacDonald R, Homberg D, Crellin D. 1996. Space per capita and the optimal size of housepits. In People who lived in Big houses: archaeological perspectives on large domestic structures (eds Coupland G, Banning E), pp. 151-164. Madison, WI: Prehistory Press. [Google Scholar]
- 42.Chatters JC. 1995. Population growth, climatic cooling, and the development of collector strategies on the Southern Plateau, Western North America. J. World Prehistory 9, 341-400. ( 10.1007/BF02221117) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 43.Chatters JC. 1998. Environment. In Handbook of North American Indians, volume 12, plateau (ed. Walker DE Jr), pp. 29-48. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution. [Google Scholar]
- 44.Prentiss WC, Lenert M, Foor TA, Goodale NB, Schlegel T. 2003. Calibrated radiocarbon dating at Keatley Creek: the chronology of occupation at a complex hunter-gatherer community. Am. Antiq. 68, 719-735. ( 10.2307/3557069) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 45.Prentiss AM, Lyons L, Harris LE, Burns MRP, Godin TM. 2007. The emergence of status inequality in intermediate scale societies: a demographic and socio-economic history of the Keatley Creek Site, British Columbia. J. Anthropol. Archaeol. 26, 299-327. ( 10.1016/j.jaa.2006.11.006) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 46.Prentiss AM, Cross G, Foor TA, Markle D, Hogan M, Clarke DS. 2008. Evolution of a Late Prehistoric winter village on the interior olateau of British Columbia: geophysical investigations, radiocarbon dating, and spatial analysis of the Bridge River site. Am. Antiq. 73, 59-82. ( 10.1017/S0002731600041287) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 47.Prentiss AM, Walsh MJ, Foor TA, O'Brien H, Cail HS. 2021. The record of dogs in traditional villages of the Mid-Fraser Canyon, British Columbia: ethnological and archaeological evidence. Hum. Ecol. 49, 735-753. ( 10.1007/s10745-021-00276-3) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 48.Prentiss AM, Goodale NB, Harris LE, Crossland N. 2015. The evolution of the ground slate tool industry at the Bridge River site, British Columbia. In Lithic technological systems and evolutionary theory (eds Goodale N, Andrefsky W Jr), pp. 267-292. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 49.Prentiss AM, Walsh MJ, Foor TA, Bobolinski K, Hampton A, Ryan E, O'Brien H. 2020. Malthusian cycles among semi-sedentary Fisher-Hunter-Gatherers: the socio-economic and demographic history of Housepit 54, Bridge River Site, British Columbia. J. Anthropol. Archaeol. 59, 101181. ( 10.1016/j.jaa.2020.101181) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 50.Alexander D. 2000. Pithouses on the interior plateau of British Columbia: ethnographic evidence and interpretation of the Keatley Creek site. In The ancient past of Keatley Creek, volume II: socioeconomy (ed. Hayden B), pp. 29-66. Burnaby, BC: Archaeology Press, Simon Fraser University. [Google Scholar]
- 51.Teit J. 1900. The Thompson Indians of British Columbia. Memoirs of the American Museum of Natural History, Jesup North Pacific Expedition 1, 63–392. [Google Scholar]
- 52.Prentiss AM, Edwards A, Hampton A, Ryan E, Bobolinski K, Vance E. 2021. Burned roofs and cultural traditions: renewing and closing houses in the ancient villages of the Middle Fraser Canyon, British Columbia. In Agent of change: the deposition and manipulation of Ash in the past (eds Roth B, Adams EC), pp. 94-112. New York, NY: Berghahn Books. [Google Scholar]
- 53.Prentiss AM. 2017. The archaeology of the Fur Trade Occupation at Housepit 54. In The last house at bridge river: The archaeology of an aboriginal household during the Fur trade period (ed. Prentiss AM), pp. 42-66. Salt Lake City, UT: The University of Utah Press. [Google Scholar]
- 54.Prentiss AM, Walsh MJ, Foor TA, Hampton A, Ryan E. 2020. Evolutionary household archaeology: inter-generational cultural transmission at Housepit 54, Bridge River site, British Columbia. J. Archaeol. Sci. 124, 105260. ( 10.1016/j.jas.2020.105260) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 55.Romanoff S. 1992. Fraser Lillooet Salmon Fishing. In A complex culture of the British Columbia plateau (ed. Hayden B), pp. 222-265. Vancouver, Canada: University of British Columbia Press. [Google Scholar]
- 56.Kennedy DID, Bouchard R. 1992. Stl’átl'imx (Fraser River Lillooet) Fishing. In A complex culture of the British Columbia plateau (ed. Hayden B), pp. 266-354. Vancouver, Canada: University of British Columbia Press. [Google Scholar]
- 57.Kew M. 1992. Salmon availability, technology, and cultural adaptation in the Fraser River watershed. In A complex culture of the British Columbia plateau: traditional Stl'atl'imx resource use (ed. Hayden B), pp. 177-221. Vancouver, BC: UBC Press. [Google Scholar]
- 58.Romanoff S. 1992. The cultural ecology of hunting and potlatches among the Lillooet Indians. In A complex culture of the British Columbia plateau (ed. Hayden B), pp. 470-505. Vancouver, Canada: University of British Columbia Press. [Google Scholar]
- 59.Barnett HG. 1955. The coast salish of British Columbia. Eugene: University of Oregon Monographs, Studies in Anthropology No. 4. [Google Scholar]
- 60.IBM Corporation. 2020. IBM SPSS Statistics for Windows (Version 27.0). [Computer software.]
- 61.Puleston C, Winterhalder B. 2019. Demography, Environment and Human Behavior. In Handbook of evolutionary research in archaeology (ed. Prentiss AM), pp. 311-336. New York, NY: Springer. [Google Scholar]
- 62.Hayden B. 1992. A complex culture of the British Columbia plateau: traditional Stl'atl'imx resource use (ed. Hayden B). Vancouver, BC: UBC Press. [Google Scholar]
- 63.Ritchie M, Lepofsky D. 2020. From local to regional and back again: social transformation in a Coast Salish Settlement, 1500–1000 BP. J. Anthropol. Archaeol. 60, 101210. ( 10.1016/j.jaa.2020.101210) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 64.Prentiss AM, Foor TA, Hampton A, Walsh MJ, Denis M, Edwards A. 2023. Emergence of persistent institutionalized inequality at the Bridge River Site, British Columbia: the roles of managerial mutualism and coercion. Figshare. ( 10.6084/m9.figshare.c.6662635) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Data Citations
- Prentiss AM, Foor TA, Hampton A, Walsh MJ, Denis M, Edwards A. 2023. Emergence of persistent institutionalized inequality at the Bridge River Site, British Columbia: the roles of managerial mutualism and coercion. Figshare. ( 10.6084/m9.figshare.c.6662635) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
Data Availability Statement
Raw data and additional data representing outcomes of multivariate statistical analyses are available as electronic supplementary material [64].