Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2023 Aug 4.
Published in final edited form as: Am Econ J Econ Policy. 2023 Aug;15(3):184–214. doi: 10.1257/pol.20200841

The Impact of Organizational Boundaries on Healthcare Coordination and Utilization

Leila Agha 1, Keith Marzilli Ericson 2, Xiaoxi Zhao 3,*
PMCID: PMC10403257  NIHMSID: NIHMS1868896  PMID: 37547426

Abstract

We measure organizational concentration—the distribution of a patient’s healthcare across organizations—to examine how firm boundaries affect healthcare efficiency. First, when patients move to regions where outpatient visits are typically concentrated within a small set of firms, their healthcare utilization falls. Second, for patients whose PCPs exit the market, switching to a PCP with 1 standard deviation higher organizational concentration reduces utilization by 21%. This finding is robust to controlling for the spread of healthcare across providers. Increases in organizational concentration predict improvements in diabetes care and are not associated with greater use of emergency department or inpatient care.

Keywords: organizations, fragmentation, healthcare, boundaries of the firm, transaction costs, communication

JEL Codes: I11, L14, D23


Transaction costs and imperfect information can make it difficult to coordinate production across firm boundaries (Coase 1937; Williamson 1985). The determinants of firm boundaries have been the subject of substantial theoretical and empirical investigation, particularly in the literature on vertical integration (Lafontaine and Slade 2007). Yet, we know less about how firm boundaries affect firm performance (Mullainathan and Scharfstein 2001), and empirical studies from different industries find mixed results.1

In healthcare, the challenges of cross-firm coordination are particularly salient; patient care is often produced with the input of many healthcare providers working in separate organizations. Geographically and over time, there is substantial variation in the organizational structures those providers operate in. An increasing fraction of US physicians is employed by large practices or hospitals (Welch et al. 2013), which may mitigate these coordination challenges. Integrated care organizations such as the Mayo Clinic, Intermountain Healthcare, and Kaiser Permanente are often held up as models of clinical efficiency and coordinated care (Enthoven 2009). Yet empirical evidence on how organizational boundaries affect healthcare delivery is limited.

In this paper, we investigate how organizational boundaries affect healthcare utilization. Existing evidence has shown that when coordination of care is more difficult, healthcare utilization tends to be higher. Higher utilization can be a sign of reduced efficiency, particularly when it is not accompanied by commensurate improvements in care quality. Coordination challenges can emerge when healthcare for an individual patient is spread across many individual providers (Agha et al. 2019; Frandsen et al. 2015), or when provider teams have fewer repeat interactions (Agha et al. forthcoming, Kim et al. 2020, Chen forthcoming). Cebul et al. (2008) argue that fragmentation across organizations may also be an important source of healthcare inefficiency. Organizational boundaries can affect coordination costs; e.g., healthcare firms often restrict information transmission to external providers by limiting transfer across electronic medical record systems. Providers may invest in firm-specific relationships and infrastructure that improve productivity (Huckman and Pisano 2006). Finally, organizational fragmentation can affect incentives for clinical process improvement and other efficiency-enhancing investments due to common agency problems and spillovers that prevent firms from reaping the full benefit of their investments (Frandsen et al. 2019).

We introduce the concept of “organizational concentration,” which measures the distribution of a patient’s outpatient visits across organizations. A patient’s healthcare has maximal organizational concentration if all of their outpatient care is billed by the same organization. This construct builds on earlier work studying provider concentration (Pollack et al. 2016; Agha et al. 2019). Organizational concentration describes the realized experience of a given patient, and so is distinct from market concentration measures used in antitrust research, which instead measure provider market power for pricing. Patients who receive all their healthcare from one firm will have high organizational concentration even if there are many firms in the market. Conversely, a patient may have low organizational concentration in a highly concentrated market if they receive healthcare from many different specialty practices, even if each practice has a monopoly in that specialty.

To our knowledge, we are the first paper to measure organizational concentration systematically, so we begin with a detailed descriptive analysis. Using insurance claims data for a 20% sample of Medicare fee-for-service enrollees from 2007-2016, we construct a measure of each patient’s experienced organizational concentration. There is substantial heterogeneity across regions in organizational concentration, even conditional on the spread of patient care across providers. Studying patients who move across regions, we find that moving to a location with a higher level of organizational concentration is associated with lower healthcare utilization. While these results suggest that organizational concentration leads to lower healthcare spending, they should be interpreted with caution because other attributes of regional practice style and place effects may be correlated with the level of organizational concentration.

To isolate variation in organizational concentration from other aspects of the local practice environment, we exploit quasi-experimental variation in patient assignment to physicians generated by physician exits. We examine the experiences of patients whose primary care provider (PCP) exits the local market, either due to a move or retirement, following recent work by Fadlon and Van Parys (2020) and Kwok (2019). Since patients may endogenously sort to new PCPs on the basis of changes in their health status, we use an instrumental variable strategy that leverages mean reversion to predict the change in a patient’s assigned PCP’s average organizational concentration, adapting the approach used by Laird and Nielsen (2017) and Abaluck et al. (2021). When PCPs with low organizational concentration exit the market, their patients switch to more typical PCPs with higher average concentration and subsequently experience lower healthcare utilization. Using this variation, we estimate that patients who switch to a PCP with 1 SD higher organizational concentration have approximately 21% lower healthcare utilization in our preferred, most controlled specification. This finding is robust to controlling for the number and types of providers that the patient visits.

Our results indicate that organizational boundaries contribute additional frictions that drive increased healthcare utilization, and this pattern does not simply reflect the challenges of spreading care across multiple providers. Although we cannot fully isolate a PCP’s tendency for organizational concentration from every other possible dimension of PCP practice style, our estimated effect remains large in specifications that control for the spread of patient care across providers, the size of the PCP’s practice group, as well as other PCP characteristics (residency training, experience, gender). To the extent that observable variables are informative about selection on unobservables, this supports the claim that organizational concentration is an important independent contributor to spending variation (Oster 2019).

Finally, we investigate how organizational concentration influences quality of care. We use several measures related to distinct dimensions of healthcare quality, spanning gaps in primary care, appropriate management of chronic conditions, and use of testing and imaging. We find no strong evidence that changes in PCP organizational concentration predict changes in inpatient or emergency department visits. For patients with a chronic condition (diabetes), switching to a PCP with higher levels of organizational concentration leads to better adherence to recommended care guidelines. This finding from diabetes care provides suggestive evidence that greater organizational concentration may facilitate improved management of chronic conditions.

Taken together, our findings suggest that lower organizational concentration worsens care efficiency: when patient care frequently crosses firm boundaries, utilization increases with no evidence of offsetting quality improvements. This pattern may be a sign of the coordination difficulties associated with low organizational concentration.

High levels of organizational concentration arise when most of the providers a patient consults are integrated within the same firm. Our research is motivated by earlier work finding the effects of firm integration on productive efficiency are theoretically ambiguous. Bringing transactions into the same firm could improve communication (Arrow 1975) and reduce contracting barriers (Hart and Moore 1990; Hart and Holmstrom 2010). On the other hand, integration may also lead resources within the firm to be allocated less efficiently (Alonso et al. 2008; Friebel and Raith 2010). Moreover, integration may improve coordination in stable environments but lead to worse adaptation to change (Dessein 2014).

Empirical evidence from other industries on how integration affects firm performance has found mixed results. Mullainathan and Scharfstein (2001), Seru (2014), and Pierce (2012) document downsides to integration including less efficient capacity management, lower innovation, and insufficient knowledge sharing. By contrast, Stroebel (2016), Forbes and Lederman (2010), Forman and Gron (2011) find benefits of firm integration including superior information, better performance, and faster technology adoption. Atalay et al. (2014) argue that integration facilitates the efficient intrafirm transfer of intangible inputs, such as high quality managerial oversight and planning. We build on this literature by studying how firm boundaries affect health care delivery, a setting where the potential benefits of improved coordination, knowledge-sharing, and management are high, and rich insurance claims data allows us to track the production process.

Within healthcare, there is limited evidence on how the integration of healthcare providers affects care delivery. Although large consolidated practice groups argue they can deliver lower cost, higher quality healthcare by improving coordination, leveraging returns to specialization, and facilitating fixed cost investments, empirical evidence of these benefits is limited (Cutler and Scott Morton 2013). Recent work suggests that hospital mergers and acquisitions of physician practices do not spur improvements in clinical quality or health outcomes (Beaulieu et al. 2020; Koch et al. 2018).2 We build on this research by studying changes in the extent to which individual patient care crosses firm boundaries, rather than focusing on short-run effects of mergers and acquisitions. Care coordination depends on the ease of communication across multiple providers who treat the same patient, but mergers may simply bring competing providers—who rarely would have treated the same patient—into the same firm. Further, the process of organizational transformation is often slow. Because this paper does not focus on short-run effects of mergers, the effects we study may reflect longer-run operational changes associated with integration.

This paper is also related to a growing literature investigating differences in practice patterns across individual physicians. Across a variety of care contexts, individual physician quality and practice style have important effects on care outcomes.3 Recent work by Kwok (2019) and Fadlon and Van Parys (2020) documents that primary care physicians in particular have substantial influence on patients’ healthcare spending. We build on this insight by investigating one important dimension of PCP practice environment and referral patterns, i.e. the PCP’s tendency to concentrate patient care within organizations.

The paper is organized as follows. Section I introduces our measure of organizational concentration. Section II describes our data and sample selection. Section III reports descriptive statistics on regional variation in organizational concentration and uses movers between regions to explore how regional variation in organizational concentration may contribute to regional variation in healthcare utilization. Section IV lays out our main empirical strategy exploiting PCP exits to explore the impact of organizational concentration. Section V presents the results on how healthcare utilization and quality outcomes change when a patient switches to a PCP with a different level of organizational concentration. Section VI concludes.

I. Defining Organizational Concentration

In this project, we study the coordination frictions that arise when healthcare is spread across organizational boundaries. To do so, we define organizational concentration, adapting a concentration index that has been used in prior literature to measure the spread of patient care across providers.4 Specifically, we use a Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) that calculates how outpatient healthcare received by a patient is spread across organizations. We measure organizational concentration using outpatient care, following previous literature defining continuity of outpatient care across individual physicians (Nyweide and Bynum 2017; Nyweide et al. 2013). This allows us to consider the impact of outpatient organizational concentration on the likelihood that a patient requires an emergency department visit or hospitalization.

We calculate patient i’s share of outpatient visits at each organization j, in a year t. Organizational concentration is then defined as the sum of squared shares across all the organizations:

OrgConcit=jshareijt2. (1)

In general, organizational concentration is higher when a patient visits fewer organizations. When a patient’s outpatient visits are uniformly distributed across N organizations, this measure is simply 1/N. When a patient receives all the visits from one organization, this concentration measure will be 1. Lower values correspond to patient care that is spread more diffusely across organizations.

Defining provider concentration

To distinguish our findings from prior analyses, we will study variation in organizational concentration conditional on provider concentration. Provider concentration measures the spread of patient healthcare across providers. Following Agha et al. (2019), we construct a measure of provider care concentration where the shareipt measures the share of patient i’s outpatient visits in year t for each provider p:

ProvConcit=pshareipt2. (2)

This measure will capture the challenges of coordinating healthcare across many providers, thus allowing us to distinguish them from the frictions that are specific to crossing organizational boundaries.

II. Data and Sample Construction

II.A. Patient sample selection

Our primary source of data is a 20% sample of Medicare Fee-For-Service (FFS) Part A and Part B claims data from 2007-2016. The 10-year panel data allows us to observe both patient moves and PCP exits. We use the Carrier, Inpatient, and Outpatient claims files to measure care utilization and spending.5 Patient demographics (age, sex, zip code) and chronic conditions are extracted from the Master Beneficiary Summary file with the Chronic Condition segment. In the remainder of this section, we describe the sample restrictions implemented to construct our main analytic samples.

Initial sample restrictions

We restrict our sample to Medicare beneficiaries who are 65–99 years old (inclusive) and continuously enrolled in Medicare FFS. After these restrictions, our data covers 9,675,113 beneficiaries. Our organizational concentration measure is defined based on Carrier file claims with an outpatient place of service; we drop 417,638 beneficiaries who did not have any visits of this type. This comprises our Broad Sample. From this Broad Sample, we define two separate analytic samples for different purposes. First, we define a “Patient Mover Sample” for a descriptive analysis studying regional variation in organizational concentration. Second, we define a “PCP Exit Sample” for our primary analysis studying the relationship between PCPs’ organizational concentration and patient care utilization. We describe each of these samples below.

Patient Mover Sample

We construct a Patient Mover Sample for our initial descriptive analysis. Sample restrictions defined here follow the construction process outlined in Agha et al. (2019). We assigned each patient to a hospital referral region (HRR) on an annual basis, using the zip code reported in the Beneficiary Summary File. Further, we require that the patient received at least 75% of billed claims within that HRR; we drop beneficiaries who do not meet this requirement. To be included as a mover, the patient’s HRR must have changed once (and only once) in our 10-year period. Further, the beneficiary must be continuously in the sample from two years before their move to two years after. Our sample includes all 25,814 moving patients who meet these criteria.

PCP Exit Sample

We construct a PCP Exit Sample for our main analysis. This analysis focuses on beneficiaries who change their attributed PCP due to the original PCP’s relocation or retirement. We attribute each patient to their plurality PCP in each year, defined as the internist, family practice physician, or medical specialist who bills a plurality of the patient’s Evaluation & Management (E&M) visits that year; ties are broken randomly. We exclude patients who have no E&M visits and thus cannot be matched to a provider, as well as patients whose plurality provider is a surgeon or non-physician. If a patient cannot be matched to a PCP according to this algorithm, they will be excluded from the PCP Exit Sample. For more details on the PCP attribution, see Appendix I.

We limit this analysis to patients whose initial attributed PCP either moved (i.e. relocated once to a different HRR) or retired (i.e. bills no further Medicare claims). We also exclude patients who move across HRRs themselves. We require that the patient have the same plurality PCP for four years prior to the PCP’s exit, limiting the sample to exits that occur in 2011–2016 to ensure four years of pre-exit observations. In addition to the four years of pre-exit observations for every patient, we also include up to four years of data following the exit. The PCP Exit Sample includes 51,570 beneficiaries. These patients are initially attributed to one of 25,650 exiting PCPs; including both the exiting PCPs and the destination PCPs, this sample covers 72,231 PCPs.

II.B. Measuring organizational concentration

Measuring Organizations

The next step is to construct our measure of organizational concentration. We begin by identifying provider organizations delivering outpatient care to each patient. We limit to provider services billed in the Carrier claims file and provided in an outpatient setting.6 We then define a visit by aggregating claims to a unique provider-date pair.

We use the federal tax ID numbers (TINs) associated with each Carrier file claim to identify provider organizations. Our sample covers 447,009 TINs. TINs provide a measure of financial organization, with integrated physician practices typically billing under a unique TIN, although some large provider groups may organize themselves into subsidiaries, billing under separate TINs (Baker et al. 2016). In these cases, TINs may still delineate organizational boundaries within the firm, even though they are not a perfect measure of firm boundaries.

We find that our baseline TIN-based measure of organizational concentration is highly correlated with an alternative definition based on physicians’ reported organizational ties in the CMS Physician Compare database. Physician Compare data is only available for the final three years of our sample (2014-2016), so we cannot use it as our baseline analysis, which tracks organizational concentration over a longer time period. In years where both measures are available, we use the affiliations reported in Physician Compare to construct an alternative measure of organizational ties, and compare this to our baseline TIN-based definition. The organizational concentration measures are correlated at 0.95 when averaged at the HRR level, and are correlated at 0.85 when averaged at the PCP level. For more detail comparing these measures of organizational ties, see Appendix II.

Earlier work by Baker et al. (2014), Austin and Baker (2015) and Baker et al. (2020) has also used TINs to measure local competition across physician provider groups. This research has shown that areas with higher market concentration pay higher prices for physician services. While this prior work suggests that providers sharing the same TINs are able to leverage oligopoly power in areas with high market concentration, our paper will test whether TIN-based measures of business organization are predictive of clinical integration that may yield offsetting benefits for patients and payers.

Aggregating organizational concentration to the PCP-level and HRR-level

Defining HRR-level concentration.

We calculate organizational concentration at the patient-year level following the definition in equation 1. To characterize the pattern of organizational concentration at the hospital referral region (HRR) level, we simply average the patient-level measures across all patients within the relevant region. To construct these regional averages, we use the broad sample excluding individuals who move between HRRs at any point.

Defining PCP-level concentration.

Our primary empirical strategy exploits variation in PCPs’ tendencies towards organizational concentration. To construct these PCP averages, we use the broad sample excluding individuals who do not match to a PCP.

To account for statistical noise in PCP organizational concentration, we apply a conventional empirical Bayes correction (Morris 1983). This correction shrinks the estimated PCP concentration towards the doctor’s mean, in proportion to the amount of estimation error.7 Since we require that patients match to their exiting PCP for four years prior to the exit, we use a four-year history to define the PCP’s organizational concentration style. The average patient in our broad sample is seen by a PCP who has 144 other attributed patients over the lookback period.

To investigate the degree of shrinkage, we calculate “pseudo shrinkage coefficients” for organizational concentration, defined as each physician’s demeaned Bayesian posterior divided by the demeaned raw (not shrunk) estimate. A coefficient of one implies no shrinkage. The median coefficient is 0.97, with the 10th percentile at 0.83. This distribution suggests relatively little shrinkage, consistent with the high correlation (0.98) between the raw and shrunk measures.

For regression analyses at the HRR and PCP level, we exclusively rely on jackknifed versions of these organizational concentration measures that omit the index patient to avoid bias driven by an individual patient’s need for more specialized care.

Paralleling the procedure for organizational concentration, we calculate HRR and PCP level measures of provider concentration to include in some regressions. This measure is also jackknifed, and the PCP level provider concentration is shrunk with an empirical Bayes procedure.

II.C. Outcome measures

Our primary outcome variable is a patient’s annual healthcare utilization, which aggregates a patient’s spending across the Medicare Inpatient, Outpatient and Carrier claim files. Utilization measures are constructed using a fixed set of annual Medicare prices expunged of regional price adjusters.8

We also study the relationship between organizational concentration and several utilization-based measures of healthcare quality. We study two measures related to the use of hospital care: a binary indicator for any inpatient hospitalization, and a binary indicator for any emergency department (ED) visit. We also examine the effects of organizational concentration on the indicators of healthcare quality for patients with diabetes: receipt of an HbA1c test and LDL test. These outcomes are only defined for the sub-sample of patients with diabetes, as defined by the Chronic Condition Warehouse; tests are identified with HCPCS codes. Finally, a potential cost of poorly coordinated care is low-value imaging and laboratory tests; we look at total utilization of these services. See Appendix I for further details on data construction.

III. Descriptive Evidence on Organizational Concentration

III.A. Summary statistics

Table 1 provides summary statistics for the Broad Sample (column 1), the Patient Mover Sample (column 2), and the PCP Exit Sample (column 3). The average level of organizational concentration is about 0.45 in all three samples, demonstrating that most patients regularly seek outpatient care across multiple organizations. The average level of provider concentration is slightly lower, which we would expect, given that patients will often see multiple providers within the same organization. In the Broad Sample and Patient Mover Sample, average care utilization is about $9000 per year; utilization is lower in the PCP Exit Sample, perhaps in part due to the disruptive impact of PCP exits. Patients in the Patient Mover and PCP Exit samples are older on average than in the Broad Sample, likely because they must be observed for a few years in sample prior to the move or exit event.

Table 1:

Summary statistics of different samples

(1)
Broad Sample
(2)
Patient Mover Sample
(3)
PCP Exit Sample
Organizational concentration 0.45 (0.27) 0.44 (0.26) 0.46 (0.25)
Provider concentration 0.38 (0.27) 0.36 (0.25) 0.38 (0.24)
Total utilization ($) 8696 (17,649) 8972 (16,239) 7517 (14,144)
Age 75.94 (7.53) 78.48 (7.46) 78.17 (6.96)
Sex: Female 0.58 0.66 0.62
Race: White 0.87 0.90 0.87
Has Diabetes 0.28 0.27 0.36
Has Hypertension 0.61 0.65 0.76
Has Heart disease 0.32 0.34 0.33
N patient-year obs 48,604,598 214,064 304,954
N patients 9,177,819 25,814 51,570
N assigned PCPs 72,231

Notes: This table reports means and then standard deviations in parentheses. Column 1 describes the Broad Sample. Column 2 describes the sample underlying our mover analysis; this sample restricts to patients who move across regions. Column 3 describes the sample underlying our analysis of PCP exits; this sample restricts to patients whose PCP exits the local market. The number of assigned PCPs in column 3 includes exiting PCPs as well as the PCPs patients switched to.

We use standard deviations of the patient-level, PCP level, and HRR level measures of organizational concentration to interpret the scale of our regression results. Appendix Table A1 further reports the mean and standard deviation of organizational concentration, provider concentration, and total utilization at these different levels. The raw standard deviation of organizational concentration across PCPs reported there (0.108) is slightly larger than the standard deviation after Empirical Bayes shrinkage (0.096); the estimates are very close, consistent with minimal shrinkage. To interpret the scale of our subsequent results, we reference the 0.1 estimated standard deviation of organizational concentration across PCPs.

We examine how organizational concentration varies across regions in Figure 1. Large variation between regions in healthcare usage suggests that some regions may be inefficient (Skinner 2011), and prior research has sought to explain why this variation exists (e.g. Cutler et al. 2019; Molitor 2018; Frakes 2013; Finkelstein et al. 2016). Our figure displays residual variation in organizational concentration across regions, after accounting for the role of provider concentration, age, sex, and race. As shown in the map, the West and Upper Midwest have higher organizational concentration than would be predicted by their provider concentration and demographics, while the South and Mid Atlantic have lower organizational concentration.

Figure 1: Variation in organizational concentration by region.

Figure 1:

Notes: This map shows the mean residuals of patients’ organizational concentration after regression adjustment for differences in average provider concentration and patient demographics (age, sex, and race). Hospital Referral Regions (HRRs) in darker gray have higher residual organizational concentration (see legend). Data: Broad Sample.

Figure 2 shows binned scatter plots relating organizational concentration and total healthcare utilization. Panel A shows the relationship between these variables averaged at the regional (HRR) level, while Panel B shows the relationship at the PCP-level. Panel A illustrates that regions with higher organizational concentration have lower levels of care utilization on average, while Panel B shows that patients of PCPs with higher organizational concentration have lower levels of healthcare utilization. The patterns shown in these graphs motivate our analytic approach, as they suggest a link between organizational concentration and care utilization. An alternative version of these graphs shown in Appendix Figure A1 demonstrates that the negative relationship between organizational concentration and utilization persists after controlling for provider concentration.

Figure 2: Relationship between organizational concentration and healthcare utilization.

Figure 2:

Notes: Binned scatterplots. Panel (A) shows the relationship between HRR organizational concentration and care utilization across regions. Patients are attributed to HRRs by their reported zipcode. Panel (B) shows the relationship between PCP organizational care concentration and patient utilization in the PCP Exit Sample. Patients are attributed to PCPs using the plurality assignment rule described in Section II.

III.B. Regional variation in organizational concentration and patient moves

Previous work has examined patients who move between regions to identify the effect of regional practice variation on spending (Finkelstein et al. 2016; Agha et al. 2019). Here, we use the same mover design to examine how changes in regional organizational concentration are associated with healthcare utilization of patients who move. When moving between regions, patients are exposed to a change in the local pattern of organizational concentration. Following prior work, we run regressions of the form:

Yit=λOΔOrgConciHRR×postit+λPΔProvConciHRR×postit+Xitγ+εit (3)

where Yit is the outcome of interest, ΔOrgConciHRR is the change in regional organizational concentration experienced when patient i moves, and ΔProvConciHRR is the change in regional provider concentration experienced when the patient moves. We include in Xit an individual fixed effect, ξi: γt, a year fixed effect; and τ(i,t), a vector of event-time fixed effects indicating the year relative to the patient move.

Figure 3 presents event study graphs. Panel A shows that when patients move to a region with higher average organizational concentration, they experience an immediate and persistent increase in their individual organizational concentration. Table 2 reports corresponding regression results, summarizing how changes in regional average organizational concentration translate into individual patients’ experiences when they move. If all regional variation were due to differences in the types of patients that lived in each region, then we would expect zero pass-through, while if movers fully adopted the average patterns of care in each region they lived, we would expect 100% pass-through. The regression in column 1 shows that about 80% of the regional difference in organizational concentration translates into patient-level changes in organizational concentration. These results are consistent with (Finkelstein et al. 2016), which found that place-based characteristics account for slightly more than half of regional variation in spending.

Figure 3: Event study figures for patients who move between regions.

Figure 3:

Notes: The two subplots show the estimates and 95% confidence intervals from two separate regressions. The dependent variable in Panel A is patients’ organizational concentration, and in Panel B is log utilization. The figure plots the coefficients on the change in regional organizational concentration interacted with year relative to move. Both regressions control for calendar year fixed effects, and patient fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at HRR and patient levels.

Table 2:

Patient movers and regional organizational concentration

(1) (2) (3)
OrgConcit Log(total utilization)it
ΔOrgConciHRR×postit 0.767 (0.028) −1.113 (0.123) −0.781 (0.142)
Regional provider concentration X

Notes: All regressions control for calendar year fixed effects, relative year fixed effects, and patient fixed effects. Regional organizational concentration and provider concentration are jackknifed. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the HRR and patient levels. Sample: Movers Analysis Sample, N=214,064 patient-year observations.

Figure 3 Panel B shows that when patients move to a region with higher average organizational concentration, they experience a decline in healthcare utilization. The final columns of Table 2 quantify this effect. Column 2 shows that moving to a region with 1 standard deviation (SD) greater regional organizational concentration (an increase of 0.05) is associated with a 5.6% decline in total utilization. However, we know that changes in regional organizational concentration are also correlated with changes in regional provider concentration. Column 3 adds a control for the region’s provider concentration, and finds that the relationship between organizational concentration and total utilization diminishes only slightly: a 1 SD increase in regional organizational concentration is associated with a 3.9% decline in total utilization. These results suggest that the spread of patient care across distinct organizations is an important predictor of regional variation in health care utilization.

IV. Identification Strategy: PCP Exits

IV.A. Motivation

In the previous section, we described how regional variation in organizational concentration predicts spending outcomes. A challenge for interpreting these findings is that regional organizational concentration may also be correlated with other features of the local healthcare environment. To address this concern, we study PCP exits. When a PCP exits a local market, due to a retirement or long-distance move, that PCP’s patients must find new care providers within their local market. This natural experiment allows us to study exogenous variation in PCP practice style holding constant many features of the local healthcare environment.

Organizational concentration may depend on a patient’s PCP as a result of the PCP’s referral decisions. PCPs may deliberately choose to refer preferentially to other providers within a multispecialty practice. In addition, PCPs themselves may be affiliated with a large organization that is tied to many local specialists, increasing the organizational concentration that would occur even without preferential referrals. We characterize each PCP’s practice pattern with their average organizational concentration. We then test what happens to patient-level organizational concentration and healthcare utilization when a PCP exit forces the patient to switch to a new PCP with a different level of organizational concentration.

Our study of PCP exits thus analyzes how a change in the organizational concentration of a patient’s assigned PCP affects the patient’s outcomes. Because we observe patients who switch PCPs, we can include patient fixed effects in our regression model to control for any fixed patient attributes that influence their healthcare utilization. However, patients may endogenously sort to new PCPs on the basis of changes in their demand for care. For instance, patients who have gotten sicker may deliberately seek out multispecialty practices or well-known health systems when their original PCP exits. This type of sorting would bias our estimation of how organizational concentration affects healthcare spending within a difference-in-differences framework, since patient fixed effects would not adequately capture changes over time. As a result, we focus our analysis on an instrumental variables strategy adapted from Laird and Nielsen (2017) and Abaluck et al. (2021).

Our instrumental variables (IV) approach exploits the statistical property of mean reversion to predict the change in the organizational concentration of a patient’s assigned PCP after their original PCP exits. Patients whose initial PCP was highly concentrated will, on average, experience a decrease in their PCP’s organizational concentration when they switch providers. Patients whose initial PCP had low concentration will, on average, experience an increase in their PCP’s organizational concentration.

Although the PCP exit strategy approach holds the regional practice environment fixed, PCP practice style is still multidimensional. A PCP’s organizational concentration may be correlated with other aspects of the PCP’s practice style. Prior research has documented that concentrating patient care within a narrow set of providers (provider concentration) is associated with lower levels of utilization (Agha et al. 2019; Hussey et al. 2014; Frandsen et al. 2015). To establish that the impact of organizational concentration is distinct from the well-studied phenomenon of provider concentration, our main regression specifications include both measures. We instrument for the change in provider concentration using an analogous approach to that used for organizational concentration: the provider concentration practice style of the exiting PCP.

IV.B. Estimating Equations

In this section, we lay out a formal instrumental variable econometric framework adapted from Abaluck et al. (2021). We are ultimately interested in λO, the causal effect of the PCP’s organizational concentration on patient utilization. Let OrgConcitPCP and ProvConcitPCP be the organizational and provider concentration of patient i’s PCP p in year t. These jackknifed concentration measures will reflect a combination of the causal effect of the PCP’s practice style on a patient’s concentration and the endogenous sorting of patients to PCPs.

We first specify the causal effect βpt of each patient’s PCP on their healthcare utilization Yipt, and then consider how this causal effect is related to organizational concentration. Let Dipt be a vector of dummy variables that report whether patient i is attributed to PCP p in year t. The following regression estimates the causal effect βpt of the PCPs themselves:

Yipt=pβptDipt+Xiptγ+ξi+εipt (4)

where ξi is an individual fixed effect, and εipt is an idiosyncratic error term. We have Xipt=θt+τ(i,t) , where θt are calendar year fixed effects, and τ(i,t) are event time fixed effects. In some specifications, Xipt further controls for PCP characteristics such as gender, experience, training, and the number of doctors and number of claims billed to the PCP’s tax ID number (as a proxy for organization size).

Then, we can write the relationship between the PCP’s causal utilization effect and our concentration measures as follows:

pβptDipt=λOOrgConcitPCP+λPProvConcitPCP+ηpt (5)

where λO tells us how much a PCP’s causal spending effect changes when PCP organizational concentration is higher, holding constant other PCP characteristics, and ηpt contains residual unobserved variation in PCP spending effects that is unrelated to PCP concentration measures or other observed PCP characteristics. When we substitute 5 into 4, we have:

Yipt=λOOrgConcitPCP+λPProvConitPCP+Xiptγ+ξi+ηpt+εipt (6)

Recall that ξi is a patient fixed effect (which we will estimate) and ηpt and εipt are unobserved error terms.

The endogeneity concern with a simple differences-in-differences approach is that εipt might be correlated with OrgConcitPCP (or ProvConcitPCP). For example, this correlation could arise if negative health shocks lead patients to switch to doctors with lower organizational concentration or provider concentration. To circumvent this endogeneity, we (1) select our sample to only include patients who are forced to switch providers because their original PCP retires or moves, and (2) instrument for the change in a patient’s PCP’s organizational concentration.

To account for this source of endogeneity, we instrument for PCP organization organizational concentration in equation 6 with the level of patient’s original PCP’s organizational concentration interacted with a post-exit indicator. Let the instrument be Z1it=OrgConci,origPCP×postit. We also instrument for the change in the PCP’s provider concentration, Z2it=ProvConci,origPCP×postit. Let Zit = [Z1it Z2it].

Our first stage equation is then:

OrgConcitPCP=ΠZZit+ΠXXipt+πi+νipt (7)

where the coefficients on the instrument, ΠZ, show how post-exit OrgConcitPCP is related to the patient’s original PCP’s concentration measures. We also estimate an additional parallel first stage equation for ProvConcitPCP.

IV.C. Identification assumptions

The conditions below are necessary for the IV strategy to be valid. We explore the evidence supporting these assumptions in Section V.A. To simplify notation, we define Z~1it be the residualized instrument Z1it after partialling out Xipt, patient fixed effects and Z2it; correspondingly, Z~2it is the residualized instrument after partialling out Xipt, patient fixed effects, and Z1it. Let Z~it=[Z~1itZ~2it].

  1. First Stage Relevance: Cov(Z~1it,OrgConcitPCP)0 and Cov(Z~2it,ProvConcitPCP)0. This is the assumption that the instruments predict the endogenous variables and satisfy the standard rank condition. In our case, we find patients whose PCPs exit switch to more typical PCPs; the first stage relationship is strong.

  2. No Differential Shocks: Cov(Z~1it,εipt)=0 and Cov(Z~2it,εipt)=0. This condition requires that patients whose original PCP had high organizational or provider concentration do not have different shocks in healthcare demand after the exit than patients whose original PCP had low concentration. In other words, unobserved patient-health demand shocks cannot be correlated with the instrument.

    This condition allows long-term patient health status to be correlated with the original PCP’s concentration measure, since we include an individual fixed effect. However, this condition may be violated if the initial PCP is selected in response to transient health shocks, and these transient shocks are autocorrelated across periods. The condition could also be violated if the initial PCP predicted long-run dynamic changes in patient healthcare demand, for example if a high concentration initial PCP generates improvements in health status that manifest in lower healthcare demand several year later.

    The assumption of no differential shocks is not directly testable, but event-study graphs are illuminating here, as they test whether patient-health utilization shocks in the years leading up to the exit are related to concentration levels of the exiting PCP.

  3. No Differential PCP Selection Cov(Z~1it,ηipt)=0 and Cov(Z~2it,ηipt)=0. The residual spending effect ηipt of patient i’s PCP p cannot be correlated with the instrument. In our context, this combines a familiar restriction— selection on observables only—plus the fallback condition described in Abaluck et al. (2021).

    The fallback condition is necessary to interpret λO as an estimate of the average relationship between PCP organizational concentration and patient care utilization in the population. This assumption requires that patients’ second-choice PCPs need to have similar relationship between organizational concentration and utilization as their first-choice PCPs and the choices of patients whose PCPs did not exit.9

    Selection on observables only is then necessary to interpret λO as the causal effect of PCP organizational concentration on spending: further factors (besides organizational concentration) that influence a PCP’s spending effect are uncorrelated with the instrument after residualizing observable control variables. It is sufficient that these characteristics be uncorrelated with PCP organizational concentration.

V. Results

Before discussing our IV results in detail, we begin by illustrating the variation that identifies our main finding. In Figure A2, we show that patients experience sizeable changes in PCP organizational and provider concentration after their initial PCP exits. The distribution of these changes is approximately symmetrically distributed, with similar numbers of patients experiencing increases and decreases in PCP concentration. 71% of patients in our sample switch to PCPs in a different organization when their original PCP exits. Even within firms, PCPs vary in their referral practices and their tendency to concentrate those referrals within their organization. On average, patients who switch to a new PCP organization experience a 0.075 absolute-value change in PCP organizational concentration, whereas patients who maintain the same PCP organization experience a 0.050 absolute-value change in PCP organizational concentration. This evidence suggests that much of the variation in PCP organizational concentration is at the PCP-level, and not solely a feature of firm structure.

Appendix Figure A3 builds intuition for our IV approach by showing a binned scatter plot where the x-axis is the patient’s origin PCP organizational concentration and the y-axis is the change in PCP organizational concentration after the exit. The graph shows the expected regression-to-the-mean pattern: patients whose origin PCP had high organizational concentration will, on average, experience a decline in organizational concentration after the first PCP exits.

Refining this analysis, Figure 4 provides a graphical look at our main IV specification. These binned scatterplots show the residualized value of the instrumental variable along the x-axis and residualized outcomes on the y-axis, after conditioning on our baseline set of control variables (patient fixed effects, year fixed effects, and event time fixed effects). Panel A corresponds to our first stage regression, showing that larger values of the residualized IV predict declines in PCP organizational concentration. Patients whose origin PCPs have high organizational concentration will on average switch to a lower-concentration PCP after the origin PCP exits, and conversely for patients with low-concentration origin PCPs. Panel B corresponds to our reduced form regression, showing that larger values of the IV correspond to increases in patient care utilization. Patients whose original PCPs have high organizational concentration tend to experience increases in health care utilization. The patterns in Panels A and B are approximately symmetric across high and low concentration origin PCPs, suggesting our results are driven by responses to both increases and decreases in PCP concentration. Panel C corresponds to a fallback test of assumption 3; we discuss this result in more detail below.

Figure 4: Binned scatterplots illustrating the PCP exit IV strategy.

Figure 4:

Notes: All panels residualize both dependent and independent variables to control for calendar year fixed effects, event time fixed effects, and patient fixed effects. Panel A illustrates the first stage: patients whose original PCP has higher organizational concentration on average experience a decrease in their PCP’s organizational concentration after the original PCP exits. Panel B illustrates the reduced form: patients whose original PCP had higher organizational concentration on average experience an increase in total utilization. Panel C illustrates the fallback condition: original PCP concentration is uncorrelated with the forecast residual. Sample size: 304,954.

V.A. Tests of IV assumptions

We will now describe the evidence supporting each of the IV assumptions laid out in Section IV.C.

First Stage Relevance:

First stage relevance, as required by Assumption 1, is shown in the bottom panel of Table 3, which shows first stage results from our three main specifications. Columns 5 and 6 have identical first stage equations, with PCP organizational concentration as the only endogenous variable. In column 7, we add PCP provider concentration as an additional endogenous variable, paralleling the setup in the previous section. In column 8, we control for additional PCP characteristics, including PCP gender, specialty training, and medical school graduation year. The first stage F-tests reported in Table 3 show that the instruments are strong in all specifications.

Table 3:

The effect of organizational concentration on utilization, identified from PCP exits

Second stage (1) (2) (3) (4)
OrgConcit Log(total utilization)it
OrgConcitPCP 0.583 (0.027) −2.120 (0.152) −1.625 (0.287) −2.385 (0.440)
First stage (5) (6) (7) (8)
OrgConcitPCP
OrgConci,origPCP×postit −0.349 (0.005) −0.349 (0.005) −0.249 (0.007) −0.203 (0.007)
F-statistic 33,199 33,199 8951 4648
PCP provider concentration X X
PCP characteristics, org. size X

Notes: Each column represents an instrumental variables regression. The instrument is the exiting PCP’s organizational concentration (jackknifed) multiplied by a post-exit indicator. Specification 1’s outcome variable is the individual patient’s realized organizational concentration. Specifications 2-4’s outcome variable is the patient’s log total utilization. All regressions control for calendar year fixed effects, relative year fixed effects, and patient fixed effects. Specifications (3) and (4) include PCP provider concentration as an additional endogenous variable, instrumented by the original PCP’s provider concentration multiplied by a post indicator. Specification (4) controls for PCP characteristics: gender, experience quartile indicators, residency training indicators (internal medicine vs. family practice), and the PCP’s organization size (log total number of claims billed to the PCP’s TIN, and the log number of unique providers billing to the PCP’s TIN). Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the PCP and patient levels. Cragg-Donald Wald F-test reported for first-stage. The PCP Exit Sample has 304,954 patient-year observations.

No Differential Shocks:

Recall that Assumption 2 requires that patients whose origin PCPs had different levels of concentration do not have different shocks to healthcare demand. This assumption is not directly testable, but we can explore its plausibility by investigating pre-trends in healthcare utilization. Specifically, we consider event study figures that allow us to assess whether patients whose origin PCP had higher organizational concentration experience different shocks to healthcare demand over the years leading up to the PCP exit. Results are shown graphically in Figure 5. These graphs exploit the same variation underlying our instrumental variables approach. The endogenous variables of interest are the interaction of these relative event time fixed effects with the change in PCP organizational concentration (in the year after minus the year before the exit). The instrumental variables are the vector of interactions between relative event time fixed effects and the original PCP’s organizational concentration.

Figure 5: Event study figures for patients whose PCP exits.

Figure 5:

Notes: The two panels show the estimates and 95% confidence intervals from two separate regressions. The dependent variable in Panel A is patients’ organizational concentration, and in Panel B is log utilization. The endogenous variables are the interaction of these relative event time fixed effects with the change in PCP organizational concentration (in the year after minus the year before the exit). The instrumental variables are the vector of interactions between relative event time fixed effects and the origin PCP’s organizational concentration. Both regressions control for calendar year fixed effects, event time fixed effects, and patient fixed effects. Because the partially treated event year 0 (year of PCP exit) is included in these specifications but excluded elsewhere, these regressions have 350,782 observations, slightly more than in Table 3. Standard errors are clustered at PCP and patient levels.

Figure 5 illustrates that when a patient’s PCP exits the local market, the patient’s care outcomes shift towards the practice style of their new PCP. In Panel A, we show that if the new provider is predicted to have higher organizational concentration (so their patients receive care at fewer distinct organizations), the patient’s experienced organizational concentration also increases. This establishes that PCP organizational concentration plays an important role in shaping patient-level organizational concentration, even when the patient remains in the same geographic location and maintaining the same insurance coverage. In Panel B, we show that if the new provider is predicted to have greater organizational concentration, the patient’s total healthcare utilization declines.

In both panels of this graph, we note an absence of pre-trends prior to the move. This demonstrates that patients whose original PCPs have different levels of organizational concentration are not on differential trends of care utilization prior to the original PCP’s exit. This pattern supports the validity of our IV strategy. We also see that in the year of the PCP exit and the year following, patients have the largest year-over-year changes on both experienced organizational concentration and utilization. The new PCP’s influence may grow over time, as they gradually shape the set of referred providers that the patient consults. In subsequent years 2 through 5, patients’ care evolves to conform more closely to the practice style of their new PCP.

Appendix Figure A4 replicates this finding, but splits the sample according to the origin PCP’s level of organizational concentration. Results are noisier in these subsamples, but generally consistent with the pooled results. Patients who are likely to experience a decrease in organizational concentration experience increases in care utilization (see Panel B); the converse result is shown in Panel A.

No Differential PCP Selection:

Next, we consider assumptions related to the sorting of patients to PCPs. Assumption 3 requires that further factors besides organizational and provider concentration that influence a PCP’s spending effect must be uncorrelated with the instrument. In the next section, we will discuss the robustness of our findings to adding controls for PCP characteristics and practice environment, including PCP gender, experience, residency training, and characteristics of the PCP’s practice organization. Larger firms may hire higher quality staff, have greater capital investment, or different managerial quality; by controlling for the size of the PCP’s practice organization, we can separate any general benefits of having a PCP who is employed by a large firm from the effects of organizational concentration. Our results remain consistent as we enrich the set of PCP characteristics included as control variables.

In addition, we explore the fallback test proposed by Abaluck et al. (2021). In the spirit of a conventional balance test, we can investigate the fallback assumption using a proxy for ηpt. In the broad sample, we regress patient spending on PCP characteristics (PCP gender, experience, residency training, and characteristics of the PCP’s practice organization), and calculate the fitted values. We then regress the fitted values (predicted PCP spending) on observational PCP organizational concentration. The residual of this regression (called the “forecast residual”) provides a proxy for ηpt, measuring residual variation in PCP utilization that is predictable by PCP characteristics but orthogonal to organizational concentration. In the PCP exit sample, we then use the forecast residual as an outcome variable in a regression that parallels our reduced form specification, testing whether the forecast residual is correlated with the instrumental variable. This will test whether second-choice PCPs have “atypical residuals” ηpt, i.e. high spending effects given their organizational concentration. Figure 4 Panel C shows no significant relationship between the forecast residual and the instrumental variable, conditional on patient fixed effects, year fixed effects, and event time fixed effects.

V.B. PCP organizational concentration and utilization

This section reports our main findings, applying the instrumental variables strategy to investigate how PCP organizational concentration affects healthcare utilization. After discussing our baseline findings, we consider several alternative specifications, and then explore the relationship between organizational concentration and care quality.

Our IV regressions in Table 3 show that the effects of organizational concentration on utilization are large and robust to accounting for other dimensions of PCP practice style, training, and practice setting. We instrument for PCP organizational concentration with the original PCP’s level of organizational concentration times a post-PCP-exit indicator. Corresponding reduced form regressions are reported in Appendix Table A2 Panel A. These reduced form regressions show a positive relationship between the instrumental variable and patient’s care utilization: patients whose original PCPs have higher organizational fragmentation experience an increase in their care utilization after the original PCP exits.

The estimated first stage equation in Table 3 specification 5 is strong, and shows that coming from an origin PCP with a 0.1 higher (one SD) organizational concentration predicts the patient will experience a 0.035 relative decline in PCP organizational concentration after the exit.10 The associated second stage with this specification in Column 1 finds that about 58% of the variation in PCP organizational concentration practice style translates into the patient’s individually experienced organizational concentration.

Columns 2-4 contain our main IV results relating organizational concentration to care utilization, while columns 6-8 contain the associated first stage equation.11 Column 2 shows that a 0.1 increase in organizational concentration leads to a 19% decline in healthcare utilization.12 Column 3 shows that this effect attenuates only slightly when provider concentration is included as an additional endogenous variable. Though the standard error on the estimate doubles, the relationship between organization concentration and care utilization remains large and statistically significant at the 1% level. This result shows that the frictions that arise when care crosses firm boundaries are distinct from previously studied concepts of provider concentration.

The main hurdle to interpreting this relationship as the causal effect of organizational concentration is that PCPs with more concentrated practice styles may differ along other dimensions besides their organizational concentration. By focusing on PCP exits experienced by patients who are not themselves moving, we are able to hold constant many features of the local healthcare environment. Nevertheless, PCPs’ training, organization size, and taste for aggressive care may covary with the PCP’s tendency to concentrate care within an organization. To address this concern, we introduce controls for PCP gender, residency training, and experience (based on medical school graduation year). Further, we control for the size of the PCP’s practice organization, as measured by the log number of distinct providers billing to the TIN, as well as the log number of claims billed to the TIN. By controlling for the organization size, we can account for the possibility that physicians working in larger practice groups have different quality, practice style, or access to capital inputs.

Reassuringly, we find no attenuation of the relationship between the PCP’s organizational concentration and patient utilization once we account for PCP characteristics and practice size. Our preferred, most controlled specification (Column 4) shows that a 0.1 increase in PCP organizational concentration is predicted to reduce health care spending by 21%. The robustness of our findings to these controls provides evidence that our results are driven by differences in organizational concentration, and are not an artifact of different practice settings, physician training, or experience.

V.C. Robustness and alternative specifications

Difference in differences results.

These findings can be contrasted with the difference-in-differences specifications reported in Appendix Table A2 Panel B. The difference-in-differences specification continue to include patient fixed effects and timing fixed effects. The key independent variable of interest is the change in PCP concentration (in the year after minus the year before the exit) interacted with a dummy for the post-PCP-exit period. Without the instrumental variable approach, we estimate a smaller effect of PCP organizational concentration on care utilization, although effects remain negative and statistically significant in all specifications. These results are likely attenuated due to confounding. Patients who find themselves in worsening health are more likely to seek out care at large, integrated practices that include a wide array of specialists. PCPs affiliated with these practices are likely to have higher organizational concentration, but the patients who endogeneously select them may have increasing demand for health care services. This comparison highlights the motivation behind the instrumental variables approach. Specifically, a patient’s choice of new PCP after their original PCP exits is likely to be endogenous to changes in the patients’ demand for care. By isolating the variation in PCP organizational concentration that is predictable due to mean reversion, the IV approach avoids relying on these endogenous selection patterns to estimate the impact of organizational concentration.

Exploring the role of PCP provider concentration.

Appendix Table A3 provides more detail on our results, specifically reporting our instrumental variable results on how PCPs’ provider concentration practice style affects care utilization. In column 2, we estimate an alternative specification that only includes PCP provider concentration as an endogenous variable, omitting organizational concentration from the model. As expected, patients whose PCPs tend to concentrate their patients’ care within a smaller set of providers also have lower spending. This finding corroborates the pattern found in the earlier literature on provider fragmentation (Agha et al. 2019; Frandsen et al. 2015; Austin and Baker 2015), and shows that the finding holds under a new identification strategy– our instrumental variables approach. However, once we add PCP organizational concentration as an additional endogenous variable in our IV framework, the estimated effect of provider concentration attenuates, as seen in columns 3 and 4. In our most controlled specification, we cannot reject a zero effect of provider concentration. These results suggest that some of the spending previously attributed to the spread of care across providers may have actually reflected the challenges of coordination across organizations. Accounting for the role of organizational coordination diminishes the role of provider concentration.

Alternative controls for PCP organizational structure.

One concern for interpreting our findings is that PCPs with high organizational concentration might practice in large, multispecialty firms, which may have better care or management quality for reasons unrelated to organizational concentration. In our baseline specifications, we control for log number of doctors in and log number of claims billed by the PCP’s organization, as proxies for organization size. In Appendix Table A4, we alternatively control for indicator variables for 5 quintiles of the organization’s number of doctors and number of claims (in columns 2 and 3), as well as an indicator for whether the PCP practices in a multi-specialty firm (in column 3). Our effect size remains similar in magnitude after the addition of these controls.

Accounting for patient demand for specialized care.

Appendix Table A5 establishes that the relationship we uncover is also robust to alternative approaches to accounting for the distribution of patient care across different providers. In column 2, we enrich our instrumental variable specification to include a quadratic function of PCP provider concentration as an endogenous variable (in addition to the existing linear term). To accommodate the additional endogenous variable, we also expand the set of instrumental variables to include a quadratic of origin PCP provider concentration multiplied by a post-exit indicator. This specification relaxes the functional form assumption modeling the relationship between PCP provider concentration and care utilization. The estimated relationship between PCP organizational concentration and care utilization remains nearly unchanged, compared to our baseline results.

In Appendix Table A5 column 3, we test an alternative approach to accounting for the spread of patient care across providers. This specification controls for splines in the number of generalist providers the patient sees, as well as the number of specialist providers the patient sees. The estimated effect of organizational concentration remains large and statistically significant; the point estimate is actually larger than that reported in Table 3. The larger coefficient suggests these results may in fact overstate the relationship between organizational concentration and care utilization. Specifically, patients with high organizational concentration PCPs who consult many doctors may have less underlying demand for care than patients who see more doctors with a low organizational concentration PCP. This could occur, for example, if large practices with greater organizational concentration (because they cover a wider breadth of specialists) also tend to rotate patients across providers more commonly.

V.D. Decomposing the effects on utilization and care quality

We have documented that switching to a PCP with higher organizational concentration increases care utilization. In this section, we consider what forms of utilization are most responsive to this change and explore how they relate to quality of care.

Utilization-based quality of care measures.

While the quality of ambulatory care is multidimensional and difficult to quantify empirically, we present evidence on a variety of measures related to the provision of high-value care (recommended monitoring of patients with diabetes), use of intensive care settings (inpatient or emergency department), and utilization of testing and imaging, which may signal deficiencies in outpatient care. Results are reported in Table 4. Regressions in this table use the most controlled specification from Table 3, including PCP provider concentration as an endogenous variable and controlling for the full set of PCP characteristics and PCP organization size.

Table 4:

Organizational concentration and quality-related utilization

(1)
Mean of
dependent variable
(2)
Coefficient on
OrgConcit
Dependent variable:
A. Hospital outcomes
 Any inpatient visit 0.145 −0.085 (0.137)
 Any emergency department visit 0.252 −0.273 (0.151)
B. Diabetes care outcomes
 Any HbA1C test 0.631 1.078 (0.264)
 Any LDL test 0.590 1.111 (0.276)
C. Imaging and testing outcomes
 Any outpatient testing or imaging 0.951 −0.313 (0.072)
 Log of outpatient testing & imaging utilization (if > 0) 6.092 −1.236 (0.533)

Notes: Each row corresponds to a regression. The specifications match that reported in column (4) of Table 3, but with different outcome variables. All regressions control for changes in PCP provider concentration, PCP characteristics, PCP organization size, as well as calendar year fixed effects, relative year fixed effects, patient fixed effects. Both changes in PCP organizational concentration and changes in PCP provider concentration are instrumented for using the exiting PCP’s practice style. Standard errors are clustered at the PCP and patient levels. Panel A uses the full PCP Exit Sample (304,954 patient-year observations). Panel B uses the subset of the PCP Exit Sample of patients identified with diabetes as chronic condition (106,614 patient-year observations). The first specification in Panel C uses the full PCP Exit Sample (304,954 observations), and the final specification has sample size of 289,979 (only observations with positive utilization of testing and imaging).

An important pathway by which organizational concentration could reduce total spending is by reducing the use of inpatient care. Recall that we define organizational concentration solely using outpatient provider interactions. As a result, there is no direct, mechanical relationship between organizational concentration and the PCP’s propensity to recommend hospitalization, since care delivered in the hospital setting will not contribute to the concentration measure. We do not find statistically significant effects of changes in organizational concentration on hospital-related outcomes, though standard errors are large: a one SD increase (0.1) in organizational concentration predicts a 0.85 percentage point decline in the probability of having any inpatient visit (95% CI: −3.6 to +1.9 percentage points).13

Heavy use of emergency departments (EDs) is sometimes interpreted as a sign of a weak primary care relationship, since patients may substitute ED care for services that could otherwise be provided more cheaply and efficiently in an office setting. Our estimates suggest that patients switching to high organizational concentration PCPs are less likely to visit the emergency department, although the effect is only statistically significant at the 10% level.

Next, we investigate process of care measures for patients with diabetes. We rely on two quality of care measures, adapted from the HEDIS guidelines: receiving a regular HbA1c test and LDL test. Switching to a physician with 0.1 higher organizational concentration leads to a 11 percentage point increase in HbA1c testing and a 11 percentage point increase in LDL tests; these relationships are statistically significant at the 1% level. Patients with diabetes are more likely to receive guideline-concordant care when their PCP has greater organizational concentration. Recall that this specification does not simply reflect the benefits of being treated in a large practice group (which might proxy for investment in clinical decision support or other electronic reminder system), because we control for the size of the PCP’s practice organization. Rather, this finding suggests that keeping the patient’s primary and specialty care integrated may lead to fewer gaps in care for chronically ill patients.

Finally, we turn to testing and imaging. Using claims from the Carrier and Outpatient files, we identify utilization of testing or imaging services in an outpatient setting. (For more details on construction of this measure see Appendix I.) Switching to a PCP with 0.1 higher organizational concentration reduces the likelihood of having any outpatient testing and imaging spending by 3 percentage points, and reduces total utilization in this category by 12% among patients with non-zero imaging or testing claims.

In Appendix Table A6, we investigate changes in repeated imaging, which we define as imaging of the same body part with the same imaging modality repeated within 30 days. This measure is limited because it captures only images billed through the Carrier claims; some repeated images might be performed in the Outpatient hospital setting, but due to the different coding conventions across these claims, we do not include them in our measure of repeated imaging. The coefficient on repeated imaging is very imprecisely estimated relative to the mean and not significantly different from zero. These findings suggest that while reduced imaging may contribute to the utilization reductions, these reductions are not primarily driven by changes to repeated imaging tests.

Preventive care services

Appendix Table A7 further investigates the relationship between organizational concentration and measures of preventive care provision, using measures of preventive care adapted from Curto et al. (2019). Three of these services are recommended for certain elderly patients by the US Preventive Services Task Force (USPSTF).14 Two of the recommended services (mammograms, prostate cancer screening) have no significant relationship with PCP organizational concentration. One recommended service (colorectal cancer screening) is performed less frequently when the patient’s PCP has higher organizational concentration; the implications of this finding for care quality are ambiguous, since colorectal cancer screening is not recommended at an annual frequency for all patients. We find no significant changes in pap smears or pelvic exams, two categories of care that the USPSTF does not recommend for patients over 65. We also find no relationship between PCP organizational concentration and flu vaccination or cardiovascular screenings, neither of which are covered by a USPSTF guideline.

Decomposing changes in care utilization.

To provide a more complete picture of the sources of utilization changes, Appendix Table A8 disaggregates our findings on the basis of the location and type of care delivered. We have defined categories of care utilization that cut across the three files from which we draw Medicare claims, aggregating institutional and provider billings where appropriate. The purpose of this decomposition is to construct five disjoint categories that together sum up to our total utilization amount: (1) care delivered in an inpatient setting, (2) care delivered in a doctor’s office or outpatient hospital setting, (3) outpatient laboratory tests and diagnostic imaging, (4) care delivered in an emergency department, (5) other provider-submitted bills (including home health, dialysis, rehabilitation centers, etc.). For more details on this decomposition, see Appendix I.

Point estimates in column 1 suggest that higher PCP organizational concentration leads to lower utilization across all five types of care, although only the effects on emergency department utilization and outpatient testing and imaging are statistically significant at the 5% level. Along the extensive margin, switching to a more concentrated PCP reduces the probability that a patient will have any outpatient testing or imaging. There is also a small effect on the propensity to have any outpatient office visits. Along the intensive margin, switching to a more concentrated PCP significantly reduces log utilization (among those with positive utilization in that category) for every type of care except inpatient hospitalizations.

Taken together, these findings suggest that the relationship between PCP organizational concentration and total utilization is driven in part by use of outpatient services, testing, imaging, and emergency department utilization. Point estimates suggest that reduced spending on inpatient care may also be an important part of the total effect, but inpatient utilization results are not precisely estimated. These patterns suggest that when outpatient providers are integrated within a firm, patients tend to receive fewer costly services, with no offsetting increase in inpatient hospitalizations.

VI. Conclusion

Coordination challenges arise when clinical care is split across firm boundaries. Firms may both facilitate informal relationships among care providers, as well as make firm-specific investments in coordination technology. In the healthcare setting, coordination technology could include messaging systems, investments in health information technology, and established norms for passing off patient information across providers.

Studying patients who move regions, we document that regions with higher levels of organizational concentration also have lower levels of care utilization. This pattern suggests a role for organizational concentration in explaining regional variation in healthcare spending.

Our main analysis studies patients who stay in the same area after their PCP exits the local market due to a retirement or move. Patients who switch to a PCP with higher organizational concentration experience reductions in care utilization, relative to patients who switch to a PCP with lower organizational concentration. These relationships persist after conditioning on detailed measures of how many generalist and specialist providers the patient sees, and how concentrated the patient’s care is across those providers. This evidence indicates that the organizational ties between a patient’s healthcare providers have an impact on their total healthcare utilization.

Our estimated effect (approximately a 20% decrease in utilization from a 1 SD increase in PCP organizational concentration) is large relative to other healthcare interventions. By way of comparison, Agha et al. (2019) find that moving to a region with 1 SD higher provider fragmentation increases care utilization by 10%. Clemens and Gottlieb (2014) estimate that a 2 percent increase in payment rates leads to a 3 percent increase in healthcare utilization. The introduction of a major policy initiative, Accountable Care Organizations and the Medicare Shared Savings Program, led to comparatively small reductions (less than 5%) in spending (McWilliams et al. 2018).

Although switching to a PCP with greater organizational concentration is associated with lower total utilization of physician services, we see no evidence that higher organizational concentration reduces quality of care. In fact, PCPs with greater organizational concentration perform better on these measures of effective care for patients with diabetes.

Taken together, these findings point to a potential mechanism by which higher organizational concentration lowers utilization. When providers share an organizational affiliation, they are likely to have lower barriers to information sharing and greater trust. These benefits may reduce gaps in care—e.g. resulting in better monitoring of diabetes patients—and improve hand-offs between providers. In turn, these improvements may allow providers to avoid unnecessary referrals, ensure that referred patients have already completed the requisite workup, and centralize follow-up care with the patient’s PCP. Each of these effects may reduce low-value visits that generate repeated contact with specialists.

It is also worth considering alternative explanations of these findings. Large organizations may hire higher-quality physicians. Alternatively, it may be more difficult to get a timely appointment in a large, multi-specialty practice. If this were the case, we would expect that our result would attenuate when we account for the size of the PCP’s organizational affiliation or an indicator for whether the PCP is part of a multispecialty practice, but our empirical estimates show no such attenuation. Even though PCPs with higher organizational concentration have lower use of outpatient services, testing, and imaging, we see no evidence of offsetting increases in inpatient or emergency department care.

While our results suggest potential savings associated with care delivered at integrated multispecialty practices, any gains from reduced utilization would need to be weighed against the higher prices likely paid by private insurance providers to larger practices that have more bargaining power. The Medicare claims we study are paid at administratively set prices, so an investigation of countervailing price effects is beyond the scope of this paper. Another consideration is that private insurance plans may use alternative approaches to care management (e.g. high deductibles or preauthorization requirements) that might limit the utilization of low organizational concentration PCPs, attenuating the relationship described here.

Our findings illuminate the role that firm boundaries play in organizing economic activity. These results raise the question of whether mergers that create multispecialty physician practices generate savings from reduced utilization. If these gains occur, they may take time to develop as providers adapt to changing communication systems and adopt new referral patterns. Future research examining the detailed mechanisms of how these boundaries affect teamwork and care coordination may be able to show how some of the benefits of organizational concentration could be replicated without financial integration– for example, through better integration of health information technology systems, or by co-locating distinct provider groups.

Supplementary Material

Online Appendix

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge research support by NIH grant P30AG012810. We thank Mohan Ramanujan, Len McCain and Elizabeth Adams for their assistance obtaining and managing the data. We thank Jason Abaluck, Amitabh Chandra, Kimberley Geissler, Thomas Koch, Jennifer Kwok, James Rebitzer, Adam Sacarny, Jonathan Skinner, Douglas Staiger, Jessica Van Parys, and Annetta Zhou for helpful comments.

Footnotes

2

These acquisitions may even raise healthcare spending, as physicians shift the site of care from doctors’ offices to hospital outpatient settings (Koch et al. 2017) and exploit reimbursement rules that allow hospital-owned physician practices to charge additional facility fees (Capps et al. 2018; Whaley et al. 2021).

4

Pollack et al. (2016) provides an overview and comparison of commonly used measures of care continuity.

5

The Inpatient file contains institutional inpatient claims, and the Outpatient file contains claims from institutional outpatient providers such as hospital outpatient departments or community mental health centers. The Carrier file contains non-institutional claims billed by individual providers such as physicians, and these claims can result from services provided at either outpatient or inpatient settings.

6

For details on how we identify relevant claims, see Appendix I.

7

To implement the empirical Bayes correction, we estimate a random effects model where patient-level organizational concentration depends on year fixed effects and PCP-year random effects. To achieve jackknifing, we omit the index patient from this regression. We recover empirical Bayes estimates of PCP-year organizational concentration as the sum of the year fixed effect and the best linear unbiased predictor of the PCP-year random effect.

8

Medicare prices include some regional adjustments on the basis of local wage indices, and we do not want this source of regional variation in wage indices to confound the relationship between organizational concentration and spending. Following Finkelstein et al. (2016), we adjust total spending to strip away variation that is due to regional price adjustments.

9

Note that with Abaluck et al. (2021)’s fallback condition embedded in the no differential PCP selection assumption, we do not require a monotonicity assumption. Abaluck et al. (2021) show that the fallback and monotonicity assumptions are non-nested, and that the fallback condition can be microfounded from standard discrete choice models. In our context, the alternative monotonicity assumption would require, for instance, that above-median organizational concentration PCPs receive a higher share of patients moving from above- versus below median-organizational concentration PCPs.

10

In order to interpret the first stage equation, recall that the equation contains an individual patient fixed effect. A coefficient of −1 would indicate that the predicted decline in PCP’s organizational concentration would move one-for-one with the origin PCP’s organizational concentration, as would occur if patients sorted randomly to PCPs.

11

Note that columns 5 and 6 share a common first stage since they differ only in the choice of the dependent variable, so column 6 simply repeats column 5.

12

To calculate this effect size, we use the slope coefficient of −2.120 in the following expression: 1 – e−2.120*.1 = 0.191.

13

Appendix Table A8 shows that a one SD increase in organizational concentration leads to an estimated $587 reduction in inpatient spending, (95%CI: −$1360 to $187).

14

For more details on the construction of these outcomes and the relevant USPSTF guidelines, see Appendix I.

Contributor Information

Leila Agha, Department of Economics, Dartmouth College, and NBER..

Keith Marzilli Ericson, Questrom School of Business, Boston University, and NBER..

Xiaoxi Zhao, Department of Economics, Boston University..

References

  1. Abaluck Jason, Caceres Bravo Mauricio M., Peter Hull, and Amanda Starc, “Mortality Effects and Choice Across Private Health Insurance Plans,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2021, 136 (3), 1557–1610. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  2. Agha Leila, Frandsen Brigham, and Rebitzer James B, “Fragmented division of labor and healthcare costs: Evidence from moves across regions,” Journal of Public Economics, 2019, 169, 144–159. [Google Scholar]
  3. — , Keith Marzilli Ericson, Geissler Kimberley H, and Rebitzer James B, “Team Relationships and Performance: Evidence from Healthcare Referral Networks,” Management Science, Forthcoming. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  4. Alonso Ricardo, Dessein Wouter, and Matouschek Niko, “When Does Coordination Require Centralization?,” American Economic Review, March 2008, 98 (1), 145–179. [Google Scholar]
  5. Arrow Kenneth J., “Vertical Integration and Communication,” The Bell Journal of Economics, 1975, 6 (1), 173–183. [Google Scholar]
  6. Atalay Enghin, Hortaçsu Ali, and Syverson Chad, “Vertical integration and input flows,” American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (4), 1120–48. [Google Scholar]
  7. Austin Daniel R and Baker Laurence C, “Less physician practice competition is associated with higher prices paid for common procedures,” Health Affairs, 2015, 34 (10), 1753–1760. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  8. Baker Laurence C., Bundorf M. Kate, and Royalty Anne, “Measuring Physician Practice Competition Using Medicare Data,” in Ana Aizcorbe, Colin Baker, Berndt Ernst R., and Cutler David M., eds., Measuring and Modeling Health Care Costs, University of Chicago Press, October 2016, pp. 351–377. [Google Scholar]
  9. — , — , and Kessler Daniel P., “Does Multispecialty Practice Enhance Physician Market Power?,” American Journal of Health Economics, 2020, 6 (3), 324–347. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  10. Baker Laurence C, Bundorf M Kate, Royalty Anne B, and Levin Zachary, “Physician practice competition and prices paid by private insurers for office visits,” JAMA, 2014, 312 (16), 1653–1662. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  11. Beaulieu Nancy D, Dafny Leemore S, Landon Bruce E, Dalton Jesse B, Kuye Ifedayo, and McWilliams J Michael, “Changes in Quality of Care after Hospital Mergers and Acquisitions,” New England Journal of Medicine, 2020, 382 (1), 51–59. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  12. Chan David C Jr, Gentzkow Matthew, and Chuan Yu, “Selection with Variation in Diagnostic Skill: Evidence from Radiologists,” Working Paper 26467, National Bureau of Economic Research November 2019. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  13. Capps Cory, Dranove David, and Ody Christopher, “The effect of hospital acquisitions of physician practices on prices and spending,” Journal of Health Economics, 2018, 59, 139–152. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  14. Cebul Randall D, Rebitzer James B, Taylor Lowell J, and Votruba Mark E, “Organizational fragmentation and care quality in the US healthcare system,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2008, 22 (4), 93–113. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  15. Chen Yiqun, “Team-Specific Human Capital and Team Performance: Evidence from Doctors,” American Economic Review, 2021, 111 (12), 3923–62. [Google Scholar]
  16. Clemens Jeffrey and Gottlieb Joshua D., “Do Physicians’ Financial Incentives Affect Medical Treatment and Patient Health?,” American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (4), 1320–49. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  17. Coase Ronald, “The theory of the firm,” Economica, 1937, 4 (16), 386–405. [Google Scholar]
  18. Currie Janet and MacLeod W Bentley, “Diagnosing expertise: Human capital, decision making, and performance among physicians,” Journal of labor economics, 2017, 35 (1), 1–43. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. — , — , and Van Parys Jessica, “Provider practice style and patient health outcomes: the case of heart attacks,” Journal of Health Economics, 2016, 47, 64–80. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  20. Curto Vilsa, Einav Liran, Finkelstein Amy, Levin Jonathan, and Bhattacharya Jay, “Health care spending and utilization in public and private Medicare,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2019, 11 (2), 302–32. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  21. Cutler David, Skinner Jonathan S, Stern Ariel Dora, and Wennberg David, “Physician beliefs and patient preferences: A new look at regional variation in health care spending,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2019, 11 (1), 192–221. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  22. Cutler David M and Scott Morton Fiona, “Hospitals, market share, and consolidation,” JAMA, 2013, 310 (18), 1964–1970. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  23. Dessein Wouter, “Incomplete Contracts and Firm Boundaries: New Directions,” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 2014, 30, i13–i36. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  24. Enthoven Alain C, “Integrated delivery systems: The cure for fragmentation,” American Journal of Managed Care, 2009, 15 (12), S284. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  25. Fadlon Itzik and Jessica Van Parys, “Primary care physician practice styles and patient care: Evidence from physician exits in medicare,” Journal of Health Economics, 2020, 71, 102304. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  26. Finkelstein Amy, Gentzkow Matthew, and Williams Heidi, “Sources of Geographic Variation in Health Care: Evidence From Patient Migration,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2016, 131 (4), 1681–1726. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  27. Forbes Silke J. and Lederman Mara, “Does vertical integration affect firm performance? Evidence from the airline industry,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 2010, 41 (4), 765–790. DOI: 10.1111/j.1756-2171.2010.00120.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  28. Forman Chris and Gron Anne, “Vertical Integration and Information Technology Investment in the Insurance Industry,” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 2011, 27 (1), 180–218. [Google Scholar]
  29. Frakes Michael, “The impact of medical liability standards on regional variations in physician behavior: Evidence from the adoption of national-standard rules,” American Economic Review, 2013, 103 (1), 257–76. [Google Scholar]
  30. Frandsen Brigham, Powell Michael, and Rebitzer James B, “Sticking points: common-agency problems and contracting in the US healthcare system,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 2019, 50 (2), 251–285. [Google Scholar]
  31. Frandsen Brigham R, Joynt Karen E, Rebitzer James B, and Jha Ashish K, “Care fragmentation, quality, and costs among chronically ill patients,” Am J Manag Care, 2015, 21 (5), 355–362. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  32. Friebel Guido and Raith Michael, “Resource Allocation and Organizational Form,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, May 2010, 2 (2), 1–33. [Google Scholar]
  33. Geissler Kimberley H, Lubin Benjamin, and Ericson Keith M Marzilli, “The role of organizational affiliations in physician patient-sharing relationships,” Medical Care Research and Review, 2020, 77 (2), 165–175. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  34. Gowrisankaran Gautam, Joiner Keith A, and Pierre-Thomas Léger, “Physician Practice Style and Healthcare Costs: Evidence from Emergency Departments,” Working Paper 24155, National Bureau of Economic Research December 2017. [Google Scholar]
  35. Hart Oliver and Holmstrom Bengt, “A Theory of Firm Scope,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 2010, 125 (2), 483–513. [Google Scholar]
  36. — and Moore John, “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, December 1990, 98 (6), 1119–1158. [Google Scholar]
  37. Huckman Robert S and Pisano Gary P, “The firm specificity of individual performance: Evidence from cardiac surgery,” Management Science, 2006, 52 (4), 473–488. [Google Scholar]
  38. Hussey Peter S, Schneider Eric C, Rudin Robert S, Fox D Steven, Lai Julie, and Pollack Craig Evan, “Continuity and the costs of care for chronic disease,” JAMA internal medicine, 2014, 174 (5), 742–748. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  39. Kim Song-Hee, Song Hummy, and Valentine Melissa, “Staffing Temporary Teams: Understanding the Effects of Team Familiarity and Partner Variety,” Working Paper 2020. [Google Scholar]
  40. Koch Thomas G, Wendling Brett W, and Wilson Nathan E, “How vertical integration affects the quantity and cost of care for Medicare beneficiaries,” Journal of Health Economics, 2017, 52, 19–32. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  41. — , — , and — , “The Effects of Physician and Hospital Integration on Medicare Beneficiaries’ Health Outcomes,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 2018, pp. 1–38. [Google Scholar]
  42. Kwok Jennifer H., “How Do Primary Care Physicians Influence Healthcare? Evidence on Practice Styles and Switching Costs from Medicare,” Working Paper, 2019. https://www.jenniferkwok.com/s/JenniferKwok_PrimaryCarePhysicians_JMP.pdf. [Google Scholar]
  43. Lafontaine Francine and Slade Margaret, “Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evidence,” Journal of Economic Literature, 2007, 45 (3), 629–685. [Google Scholar]
  44. Laird Jessica and Nielsen Torben, “Physician Prescribing Behaviors on Prescription Drug Use and Labor Supply: Evidence from Movers in Denmark,” Working Paper 2017. [Google Scholar]
  45. McWilliams J. Michael, Hatfield Laura A., Landon Bruce E., Hamed Pasha, and Chernew Michael E., “Medicare Spending after 3 Years of the Medicare Shared Savings Program,” New England Journal of Medicine, 2018, 379 (12), 1139–1149. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  46. Molitor David, “The evolution of physician practice styles: evidence from cardiologist migration,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2018, 10 (1), 326–56. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  47. Morris Carl N, “Parametric empirical Bayes inference: theory and applications,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 1983, 78 (381), 47–55. [Google Scholar]
  48. Mullainathan Sendhil and Scharfstein David, “Do Firm Boundaries Matter?,” American Economic Review, 2001, 91 (2), 195–199. [Google Scholar]
  49. Nyweide David J and Bynum Julie PW, “Relationship between continuity of ambulatory care and risk of emergency department episodes among older adults,” Annals of Emergency Medicine, 2017, 69 (4), 407–415. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  50. — , Anthony Denise L, Bynum Julie PW, Strawderman Robert L, Weeks William B, Casalino Lawrence P, and Fisher Elliott S, “Continuity of care and the risk of preventable hospitalization in older adults,” JAMA Internal Medicine, 2013, 173 (20), 1879–1885. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  51. Oster Emily, “Unobservable Selection and Coefficient Stability: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 2019, 37 (2), 187–204. [Google Scholar]
  52. Pierce Lamar, “Organizational Structure and the Limits of Knowledge Sharing: Incentive Conflict and Agency in Car Leasing,” Management Science, February 2012, 58 (6), 1106–1121. [Google Scholar]
  53. Pollack Craig Evan, Hussey Peter S, Rudin Robert S, Fox D Steven, Julie Lai, and Schneider Eric C, “Measuring care continuity: A comparison of claims-based methods,” Medical care, 2016, 54 (5), e30. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  54. Sahni Nikhil R, Dalton Maurice, Cutler David M, Birkmeyer John D, and Chandra Amitabh, “Surgeon specialization and operative mortality in United States: Retrospective analysis,” BMJ, 2016, 354, i3571. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  55. Seru Amit, “Firm boundaries matter: Evidence from conglomerates and R&D activity,” Journal of Financial Economics, February 2014, 111 (2), 381–405. [Google Scholar]
  56. Skinner Jonathan, “Causes and Consequences of Regional Variations in Health Care,” in Pauly Mark V., Mcguire Thomas G., and Barros Pedro P., eds., Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 2 of Handbook of Health Economics, Elsevier, January 2011, pp. 45–93. [Google Scholar]
  57. Stroebel Johannes, “Asymmetric Information about Collateral Values,” The Journal of Finance, 2016, 71 (3), 1071–1112. DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12288. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  58. Welch W Pete, Cuellar Alison Evans, Stearns Sally C, and Bindman Andrew B, “Proportion of physicians in large group practices continued to grow in 2009–11,” Health Affairs, 2013, 32 (9), 1659–1666. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  59. Whaley Christopher M, Zhao Xiaoxi, Richards Michael, and Damberg Cheryl L, “Higher Medicare Spending On Imaging And Lab Services After Primary Care Physician Group Vertical Integration: Study examines higher Medicare spending on imaging and lab services after primary care physician group vertical integration.,” Health Affairs, 2021, 40 (5), 702–709. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  60. Williamson OE, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, Free Press, 1985. [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Online Appendix

RESOURCES