Skip to main content
Open Research Europe logoLink to Open Research Europe
. 2022 Jun 21;2:25. Originally published 2022 Feb 24. [Version 2] doi: 10.12688/openreseurope.14472.2

“Frenemies” of innovation: understanding the role of coopetition in service innovation in emerging markets

Sohaib S Hassan 1,a, Abiodun Egbetokun 2, Levan Bzhalava 3
PMCID: PMC10446029  PMID: 37645343

Version Changes

Revised. Amendments from Version 1

We have carefully examined all the concerns/observations of our respectable reviewers and the new version of our article contains the following:  1)We have added new and updated references to the manuscript; 2) we have added the debate concerning the relevance of coopetition for SMEs; 3) we have conducted additional estimations to include the SMEs from the manufacturing sector to observe some of the heterogeneities; and finally 4) We have corrected the typos/mistakes pointed out by the reviewers and provided additional data information.

Abstract

Coopetition is considered an important strategy for innovation. However, the literature provides limited evidence on how coopetition relates to innovation in service sector, particularly in emerging markets. Moreover, little is known about the effects of the formal and informal aspects of coopetition on innovation and how absorptive capacity of firm may influence this relationship. Against this background, using the official national innovation surveys of Nigeria (2008 and 2011), this study contributes to the ongoing debate by empirically examining the innovation endeavors of 421 Nigerian SMEs. The study employs logistic regression methods to model and explore the relationships between coopetition and innovation in the sample. The results show that that formal coopetition hinders innovation while informal coopetition supports it and absorptive capacity moderates these relationships. The study provides important insights about the concept of coopetition in emerging markets, especially vis-à-vis their institutional idiosyncrasies. Finally, the study highlights its implications and suggests some avenues for future research.

Keywords: Coopetition, Emerging Markets, Innovation, SMEs

2. Plain language summary

Firms innovate by collaborating within their networks and with partners. Sometimes though firms cooperate with their competitors to generate innovation, e.g., as in the case of open-source software and technologies. Such type of innovation is known as coopetition. Further, collaboration in coopetition could be through official channels (formal, e.g., contracts, agreements) or unofficial channels (informal, e.g., social gatherings). The literature has already shown how large companies in the advanced economies of the developed world use coopetition to increase their innovation output. However, we do not know much about coopetition among small firms of the developing/emerging markets. This study addresses this issue and carries out an empirical analysis in this regard. We use a survey of small and medium enterprises in Nigeria to see how innovation there is influenced by the official and unofficial channels of coopetition. Our results show that that formal coopetition hinders innovation while informal coopetition supports it and absorptive capacity (a firm’s ability to learn) moderates these relationships. We also discuss the implications and limitations of our study.

3. Introduction

Firms tend to collaborate externally due to the costs involved in internal knowledge creation and the locus of innovation being in networks rather than in individual firms ( Hagedoorn, 1993; Powell et al., 1996). The dynamics of inter-firm collaboration have long been viewed from the lens of business partnerships and alliances. The management research underscores that firms do not only cooperate with partners in a network, but also with rivals, the so-called “coopetition” ( Dagnino & Padula, 2002; Das & Tang, 2000; Nalebuff & Brandenburger, 1997).

The strategic management literature consistently suggests that coopetition can be good for innovation ( Quintana-García & Benavides-Velasco, 2004; Ritala, 2012; Tether, 2002), as competitors or “frenemies” 1 operate in similar parameters ( Bouncken & Kraus, 2013; Enberg, 2012). However, it is not yet clear how coopetition interplays with the prospects of innovation, particularly in relation to the different types of coopetitive interactions and the contextual factors that influence coopetition ( Bengtsson & Kock, 2014). Existing research suggests that coopetition between firms can either be through formal channels ( Brusoni et al., 2001; Hagedoorn et al., 2000; Tether, 2002) or informal channels ( Freeman, 1991; Tödtling et al., 2009). Further, the literature underscores that a firm’s absorptive capacity, similar to other collaboration processes, may define the extent of benefits a firm can gain through formal or informal coopetition ( Cohen & Levinthal, 1990; Ritala & Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2013; Zahra & George, 2002). Taken together, this highlights a gap in the literature and leads us to our main research question: how do formal and informal coopetition relate to innovation, and how does absorptive capacity moderate this relationship?

On one hand, much of the empirical literature on innovation concentrates on technological product and process innovation, with much less emphasis on service innovation ( Adeyeye et al., 2013). Service innovations, particularly in emerging countries, are driven by different needs than that of advanced economies ( Phills et al., 2008). On the other hand, the existing literature about coopetition focuses largely on understanding the influence of coopetition on innovation in high-technology sectors and knowledge intensive industries of advanced economies (e.g., Arranz & de Arroyabe, 2008; Hagedoorn & Schakenraad, 1992; Nieto & Santamaría, 2007), whereas the research about small and medium enterprises (SMEs) in emerging economies is rather limited ( Bengtsson & Johansson, 2014). SMEs tend to differ from large firms in terms of their competences and priorities. Further, due to their rather unsystematic structures, SMEs show relatively less interest in pursuing coopetition strategies to gain performance outcomes ( Morris et al., 2007; Roig-Tierno et al., 2018). However, while SMEs are generally market oriented and tend to mainly focus on growth and developing their core businesses, they need to be innovative in competitive markets to overcome their liabilities of smallness ( Bengtsson & Johansson, 2014; Roig-Tierno et al., 2018). Coopetitive alliances might facilitate their competitive advantage, access to new markets and survival ( Kraus et al., 2012; Morris et al., 2007). The existing research indeed has pointed to such practices among SMEs (e.g., Bouncken et al., 2015; Crick & Crick, 2021; Devece et al., 2019; Gernsheimer et al., 2021; Kraus et al., 2012), but the empirical evidence is rather limited in scope (sectoral and geographical).

Further, the existing research in this regard deals mostly either with the multinational organizations’ alliances with the local partners or governments in emerging markets ( Kedia et al., 2016) or with the performance related aspects of coopetition ( Shen et al., 2019). Thus, little research is available on the relationship between coopetition and innovation among the local SMEs. There is indeed an increasing debate about how contextual factors and institutional aspects might influence coopetition ( Barney et al., 2016; Dagnino et al., 2012). For instance, innovation in emerging markets is often idiosyncratic and closely connected to the social fabric of their respective societies. The results obtained from other contexts may therefore not be fully applicable to policy and practice in emerging contexts. By providing fresh empirical results on the service innovation of SMEs in an emerging economy, this paper makes valuable contributions to the innovation management literature. Our panel dataset of 421 service industry SMEs comes from Nigeria’s official innovation surveys of 2008 and 2011. The rest of this study proceeds as follows: we review the theoretical development and establish our hypotheses in the next section. In Section 3, we introduce the data used and the methodology adopted for this study. We present and discuss our empirical findings in Section 4 and we conclude in Section 5.

4. Theoretical background and hypotheses

Innovation is one of the key components of a firm’s strategy and is central to economic competition ( Schumpeter, 1934). In the extant scholarship, the resource-based view of the firm underscores that the firms gain competitive advantage through a combination (bundle) of generic, internal resources and production capabilities ( Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1995). Internal resources, both tangible and intangible ones are central and often unique to a firm. The exploitable nature of such resources, coupled with the aspects of organizational learning, determine the competitive positioning of a firm in imperfect markets ( Barney et al., 2011; Kogut & Zander, 1996). The knowledge-based view of the firm complements the notion of resources by identifying the strategic and central role of knowledge in shaping the competitive position of a firm through innovation and inimitable internal resources ( DeCarolis, 2002; Grant, 1997; Grant, 2002; Spender & Grant, 1996; Subramaniam & Youndt, 2005).

However, contrary to physical resources, the knowledge required for innovation is costly to create internally and its rather intangible nature makes it very difficult to acquire through market transactions ( Shelanski & Klein, 1995). Firms then have the option of accessing external knowledge assets to complement their internal capabilities through cooperation with other firms ( Brusoni et al., 2001). While, cooperation between firms is traditional and logically entails the collaboration between partners in achieving similar objectives, scholars in management research have pointed out the potential of cooperation between competing firms (henceforth, coopetition) for innovation ( Bengtsson & Kock, 1999; Bengtsson & Kock, 2014; Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1996; Tether, 2002).

A number of studies have demonstrated that firms, instead of working alone, tend to engage in inter-firm cooperation with their competitors to create value and resources ( Bengtsson & Kock, 2014; Tether, 2002; Zineldin, 2004). Similarly, network theory accentuates that cooperation with competitors does not only provide firms with the opportunities to learn about and from the competitors, but also enables them to benefit from the pool of collective resources within a network ( Lado et al., 1992; Lado et al., 1997). The underlying logic is that competitors work within similar technological and knowledge paradigms as well as along similar trajectories leading them to cooperate and compete with each other at the same time ( Bengtsson & Kock, 2000; Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1996). Thus, they tend to hold similar fundamental knowledge endowments; and similarity in their knowledge base is conducive to knowledge sharing and knowledge integration ( Bouncken & Kraus, 2013).

Competitors in partnerships are believed to benefit from the synergies created through the collaboration among firms which complement each other’s resources and capabilities, and thus generate innovation ( Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1996; Carayannis & Alexander, 1999; Quintana-García & Benavides-Velasco, 2004; Tether, 2002). However, research in evolutionary economics, while broadly agreeing with the above ( Gnyawali & Park, 2009; Nelson, 1990), raises concerns about the benefits of coopetition. In particular, the innovation potential of cooperation is shown to reduce with similarity in the knowledge bases of the partners. More specifically, the greater the cognitive proximity between partners, the more they tend to understand each other and share knowledge but the less the potential of their cooperation to generate novelty. A trade-off therefore arises between technological/cognitive overlap and technological/cognitive distance ( Egbetokun & Savin, 2015; Gilsing et al., 2008; Mowery et al., 1998; Nooteboom et al., 2007; Wuyts et al., 2005).

2.1 Coopetition channels, innovation and SMEs

The literature identifies two channels through which coopetition can take place: formal and informal ( Brusoni et al., 2001). Formal coopetition, like any other official inter-firm collaboration, consists of legally binding commitments and contracts between the signatories. Such contracts are focused on certain procedures through which competitors make an alliance or partnership to pursue specific objectives, such as technology-sharing agreements, joint research initiatives or product development ( Hagedoorn, 2002; Tether, 2002). Informal coopetition consists of information exchange through unofficial networking events, such as in meetings, exhibitions and conferences ( Pyka, 1997; Tödtling et al., 2009). The existing research underscores that while both the channels lead to positive innovation outcomes, informal coopetition tend to be more frequent due to their convenient, cost-effective less explicit nature ( Egbetokun, 2015; Pyka, 1997).

Coopetition contains certain inherent disadvantages such as imitation risk, unintentional knowledge spill-overs and inconducive trust-deficit between the participating agents ( Bouncken & Kraus, 2013; Jaffe et al., 1993; Phene & Tallman, 2014; Ritala & Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2013). In formal coopetition, firms employ different legal appropriability mechanisms (e.g., patents, trademarks etc.) to protect their core competences from their rivals and to reduce the risks of imitation ( Somaya, 2003). Similarly, formal coopetition is associated with a delicate balance of reciprocal knowledge transfer, i.e., between acquiring new knowledge, while at the same time, safeguarding firms’ own knowledge resources ( Fehr & Gächter, 2000; Hamel et al., 1989b; Kogut & Zander, 1996; Levy et al., 2003; Loebecke et al., 1999). When it comes to coopetition for innovation, the risks of unintentional knowledge leakage, opportunism and imitation are much higher ( Hamel et al., 1989a; Kogut & Zander, 1996; Loebecke et al., 1999; Ritala & Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2009). Larger firms can act proactively against the unintended leakage of information to their competitors and establish agreements that entail strict mechanisms of knowledge sharing; however, strict appropriability mechanisms may limit the willingness of smaller firms to collaborate with larger partners ( Liebeskind, 1997). However, such reciprocity-related risks may be absent in informal cooperation even when the partner is a competitor.

Two factors are relevant in explaining the choice of firms between formal and informal coopetition. First, the size of organization matters, as the larger organizations, because of their resources, can offset the costs and risks involved in formal knowledge sharing mechanisms with their competitors in regional and international markets ( Luo, 2005). The literature on the dynamics of inter-firm collaboration focuses mainly on large organizations as their international relocation of resources often requires them to be part of alliances and partnerships with local partners and competitors to mitigate their foreignness ( Akdoğan & Cingšz, 2012; Kedia et al., 2016; Luo, 2007). Second, the quality of institutions also plays an important role. Formal coopetition thrives in countries with better institution and legal infrastructure, where formal agreements are overlooked and supported by the responsible agencies ( Kylänen & Rusko, 2011). Consequently, much of the existing research focuses on large organizations and multinationals from the advanced countries and high-tech manufacturing, while the focus on SMEs and the service sector is rather unexplored ( Luo, 2005; Thomason et al., 2013), although as highlighted earlier, coopetition indeed offers some benefits to SMEs too ( Bengtsson & Johansson, 2014).

Building upon the foregoing, we argue that formal coopetition agreements can be costly in emerging markets because of weak institutions. SMEs in emerging markets are more exposed to institutional deficits because of their limited resources, liability of smallness as well as their strong focus on traditional industrial activities, and this leads them to prefer informal interactions where mutual trust and commitments substitute the institutional deficiencies ( Biggs & Shah, 2006; Oyelaran-Oyeyinka & Banji, 2006). Further, the social networks in the emerging economies should be conducive to informal exchange of information for innovation activities between the competitors because the inherent element of trust vis-à-vis the informal networks favors complementary knowledge sharing ( Murphy, 2002; Thomason et al., 2013).

This discussion leads to our first set of hypotheses:

  • Hypothesis 1a: Formal coopetition is negatively associated with the probability to innovate in SMEs in an emerging economy

  • Hypothesis 1b: Informal coopetition is positively associated with the probability to innovate in SMEs in an emerging economy

2.2 Moderating role of absorptive capacity

A firm could either benefit or lose from inter-firm collaboration and coopetition, and this can be affected by the internal organizational structure of the firm ( Foss et al., 2013; Ritala & Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2013). One way by which firms manage the coopetition cost–benefit trade-off is to accumulate absorptive capacity which enhances knowledge search, valuation, assimilation and appropriation ( Cohen & Levinthal, 1990; Zahra & George, 2002). The concept of absorptive capacity is rooted in the individual cognitive dimensions for problem solving, learning new competences to generate new ideas and cumulative learning of firms ( Cohen & Levinthal, 1989; Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). This capacity, for instance, can be developed through investments in R&D ( Cohen & Levinthal, 1989) and human capital ( Cohen & Levinthal, 1994). As indicated by recent research, absorptive capacity indeed widens and lengthens the reach of collaboration such that firms can collaborate with distant partners ( Berchicci et al., 2016; de Jong & Freel, 2010; Drejer & Vinding, 2007) and even internationally ( Ebersberger & Herstad, 2013).

The absorptive capacities of firms vary according to their previous knowledge stock and capacities to identify and assimilate knowledge flows ( Cohen & Levinthal, 1989; Cohen & Levinthal, 1990; King & Lakhani, 2011; Quintana-García & Benavides-Velasco, 2004). When firms cooperate with each other, the diffusion of knowledge across individuals’ and firms’ boundaries is considered essential for the development of innovation capacities and the profit maximizations of firms ( Grossman & Helpman, 1991). Similarly, since firms in coopetition alliances often share a common knowledge base and cognitive proximities relative to each other, they are able to communicate efficiently and increase their absorptive capacities over time ( Knoben & Oerlemans, 2006). However, the extent to which firms will benefit from the knowledge exchange to innovate depends on their respective absorptive capacities. Firms with higher absorptive capacities are better off in building on their existing competences within an alliance, relative to the firms with lower levels of absorptive capacities. ( Boschma, 2005; Cohen & Levinthal, 1994; Dussauge et al., 2000; Ritala & Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2013). Moreover, firms with higher level of previous knowledge accumulation, experience and greater capacities to assimilate new knowledge make their employee better informed, more innovation oriented, and increasingly capable of knowledge and information assimilation, compared to the firms with lower levels of absorptive capacities ( García-Morales et al., 2012).

Firms competing and cooperating at the same time are prone to the risk of opportunism on the part of their competitors ( Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1996; Quintana-García & Benavides-Velasco, 2004; Tether, 2002). One way to mitigate this risk is to formalize the coopetition alliance. In a formal coopetition partnership, firms with higher absorptive capacities are better prepared to counter the risk of opportunism due to their higher level of absorptive capacities. Moreover, the absorptive capacities are believed to influence the coopetition management between firms. Firms with higher absorptive capacities are in a better position to strategically manage their knowledge sharing mechanisms and set out the rules of the game and prevent their competitors against unnecessary opportunism and have a chance to learn from their competitors, even opportunistically ( Levy et al., 2003). This debate leads to our second set of hypotheses:

  • Hypothesis 2a: Absorptive capacity positively moderates the association between formal coopetition and innovation

  • Hypothesis 2b: Absorptive capacity negatively moderates the association between informal coopetition and innovation

5. Methods

Data and sample

Our data comes from the two waves of Nigeria’s official national innovation surveys that are available: the first wave covering 2005–2007 was completed in 2008 and the second wave covering 2008–2010 was completed in 2011. The surveys are based on the Oslo Manual and, hence, share the core set of questions with the Community Innovation Surveys (CIS) of Europe. The datasets, which are openly available online ( https:/doi.org/10.17632/37pys4vxt4.1), include information on the innovation investments, sources, obstacles, and outcomes in the firms as well as detailed firm characteristics including size, human capital, age, location and export status. The datasets have been widely applied in recent research ( Edeh & Acedo, 2021; Medase, 2020; Medase & Wyrwich, 2021) which provide more specific details on the survey methodology.

The two waves of the survey represent two repeated cross sections of firms selected by stratified random sampling across the manufacturing and services sectors at the two-digit ISIC level (see A. Egbetokun, 2017). Although it was ensured that every firm that responded in the first wave was contacted for the second wave, the response was particularly low, necessitating a re-sampling following the procedure just described. Consequently, the final sample size across both waves of the survey is not the same and only about 2.5% of the firms appear in both cross sections. For this reason, we are unable to perform a longitudinal analysis. Nonetheless, the amount of information contained in the datasets and their comparability with data from other countries make them very useful for rigorous empirical analyses. The full dataset includes 1359 firms from both waves of the survey, of which 469 (34.5%) are from the services sector. Our final sample includes 421 firms (179 firms in the first wave and 242 in the second wave) because the remaining 48 did not perform any innovation and thus, were not eligible to respond to the cooperation and information sources questions in the survey. A more detailed sectoral breakdown of the sample, using two-digit ISIC classification, is presented in Table 1.

Table 1. Sectoral distribution of sample.

Two-digit ISIC sector Number
of firms
Percentage
of sample
Health, cultural and social work 117 27.79
Trade, repairs, and rentals 61 14.49
Other business activities 46 10.93
Hotels and restaurants 40 9.50
Transport services 40 9.50
Computer and related activities 35 8.31
Insurance and pension funding 26 6.18
Financial intermediation 20 4.75
Real estate activities 16 3.80
Post and telecommunications 11 2.61
Education 9 2.14
Total 421 100.00

Variables and descriptive statistics

Dependent variables. To understand the influence of coopetition and absorptive capacity on innovation, we use two binary measures of Product innovation and Process innovation as our dependent variables. The variables contain the information whether a firm introduced an innovation (product, process) during the reference period. This information is the best available in the survey and it is the standard way of measuring innovation in CIS-type innovation surveys.

Independent variables. We use a binary measure for our explanatory variable of Formal coopetition, that is, whether a firm collaborated with a competitor during the reference period or not. Similarly, we use a binary measure for our explanatory variable of Informal coopetition. Further, we use Staff quality and Staff training as the proxies for absorptive capacity of a firm, that is, a firm’s ability to benefit from the inter-firm collaboration.

Control variables. We also use several control variables, traditionally associated with firms’ collaboration for innovation. A detailed list of names, description and measurements of variables is provided in Table 2.

Table 2. Description of variables.

Variable Description Measure
Dependent variables
Product innovation Binary measure of whether a firm introduced a new product between 2005–2007 or
2008–2010
=1 if Yes; 0 if No
Process innovation Binary measure of whether a firm introduced a new product between 2005–2007 or
2008–2010
=1 if Yes; 0 if No
Independent variables
Formal coopetition Binary measure of whether a firm collaborated with a competitor during the reference
period
=1 if Yes; 0 if No
Informal coopetition Binary measure of whether a firm used a competitor as source of innovation information
during the reference period
=1 if Yes; 0 if No
Staff quality Percent of staff with at least a bachelor’s degree Continuous
between 0 and 1
Staff training Binary measure of whether the firm officially organizes periodic staff training =1 if Yes; 0 if No
Controls
Other collaboration
partners
Binary indicator of whether the firm had any other partner during the reference period
apart from competitors
=1 if Yes; 0 if No
Size Number of employees Continuous
Age Number of years since establishment of the firm Continuous
Location Binary measure of whether the firm is located in Lagos, the major commercial hub of Nigeria =1 if Yes; 0 if No
Group Binary measure of whether the firm is part of a group of companies =1 if Yes; 0 if No
Export Binary measure of whether the firm is an exporter =1 if Yes; 0 if No

Estimation method

We employ a simplified economic model to predict the likelihood of innovation outcomes in our sample. We assume that the probability of innovation is the function of formal coopetition and informal coopetition and absorptive capacity of an SME should moderate this relationship. Our model is presented in the specification I below:

Yit=f(Xit1,β)(I)

In our specification I, the dependent variable ( Y it ) is either the probability of product innovation or the process innovation outcome of an SME “ i” in time “ t”. Further, ( X it-1) is a vector of independent variables (main explanatory and control variables) and “ β” is a vector of estimation parameters in the preceding year time ( t-1).

Given the binary nature of the dependent variables, a discrete choice model is the most appropriate to estimate their response to the explanatory variables. We estimate a bivariate probit equation to elicit the relationship between coopetition and innovation (product and process) in the Nigerian service sector.

The implementation of one type of innovation is associated with the likelihood of the other types ( Egbetokun, 2015). Consequently, if separate equations are estimated for each innovation type, the error terms from the independent equations are likely to be pairwise correlated, leading to biased and possibly inconsistent point estimates. This is a problem ignored in some studies such as the one by Carvalho et al. ( Carvalho et al., 2013).

By estimating a simultaneous system of two equations and allowing the error terms to be freely correlated across equations, the bivariate probit makes it possible to obtain unbiased estimates when the dependent variables in a set of equations are potentially interdependent ( Freedman & Sekhon, 2010). A similar approach has been used extensively in previous studies ( e.g., Egbetokun, 2015; Freitas et al., 2011).

Table 3 reports the descriptive statistics and the correlation matrix. We check the issue of multicollinearity by computing the variance inflation factor (VIF) before and after the estimations. The mean VIF (1.21) was well below the acceptable threshold of 10 ( Neter et al., 1985). These values indicate that the estimation data do not suffer from serious problems of multicollinearity.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix.

Variable N Min Max Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Dependent variables
Product innovation 421 0 1 0.613 0.488
Process innovation 421 0 1 0.694 0.462
Independent variables
1. Formal coopetition 421 0 1 0.14 0.348 1
2. Informal coopetition 421 0 1 0.648 0.478 0.269* 1
3. Staff quality 421 0 1 0.562 0.28 0.049 0.134* 1
4. Other collaboration
partners
421 0 1 0.945 0.288 0.007 -0.002 -0.061 1
5. Staff training 421 0 1 0.648 0.478 0.183* -0.448* 0.084 -0.046 1
6. Size 421 2.197 8.854 3.653 1.297 0.019* -0.059* 0.188* -0.089 -0.059 1
7. Age 421 0 4.852 2.326 0.878 0.083 0.077 0.026 -0.054 0.017 0.213* 1
8. Location 421 0 1 0.62 0.486 0.062 0.089 0.192* -0.124* 0.076 0.103* 0.04 1
9. Group 421 0 1 0.238 0.426 0.016 0.119* 0.114* 0.036 0.096* 0.228* 0.084 -0.038 1
10. Export 421 0 1 0.188 0.391 -0.089 0.099* 0.088 -0.125* 0.044 0.229* 0.172* 0.094* 0.171* 1
Mean (max) VIF = 1.21 (1.59)

6. Results

Descriptive results

We first examine the distribution of cases for our dependent variables as a function of the main independent variables. The results of this univariate analysis are presented in Table 4. Significant Z-test scores for both the product and process innovation variables suggest that we reject the null hypotheses 1a and 1b.

Table 4. Univariate analysis of the relationship between innovation and coopetition.

Formal coopetition Informal coopetition
Rate of innovation Yes No Comparison
(z-tests)
Yes No Comparison
(z-tests)
Product (%) 69.4 59.9 1.39 * 73.9 37.8 7.27 **
Process (%) 81.3 67.4 2.16 ** 86.4 37.8 10.33 **

*Significant at 10% **significant at 5%

Table 5 details the share of innovative manufacturing and service firms that respectively engage in formal and informal coopetition. From the table we see that the share of service firms that innovated and engaged in formal coopetition is comparable to the share of manufacturing firms that did the same, across all innovation types. However, a significantly higher percentage of innovative service firms engaged in informal coopetition, compared to their manufacturing counterparts. This difference is most pronounced across process and marketing innovation where 11% more innovative service firms engaged in informal coopetition than in manufacturing.

Table 5. Industrial share of the sample according to coopetition types.

Innovation Formal coopetition Informal coopetition
Service Manufacturing Service Manufacturing
Product 15.5 14.89 78.29 70.42
Process 16.1 14.09 80.82 69.39
Marketing 13.84 11.1 69.18 57.45
Organizational 13.77 12.16 65.56 57.88

Bold values are significantly different across rows at 5%.

Table 6 further demonstrates that a comparable share of service and manufacturing firms engaged in formal or informal collaboration with any type of actor. However, the share of service firms that collaborated with their competitors is 7% points more than the share of manufacturing firms. This difference is statistically significant at the 5% level.

Table 6. Industrial comparison of the sample.

Service (n=469) Manufacturing (n=890)
Formal cooperation 32.2 30.9
Informal cooperation 78.89 75.96
Service (n=421) Manufacturing (n=797)
Formal coopetition 13.78 11.92
Informal coopetition 64.61 57.21

Bold values are significantly different across rows at 5%.

In terms of absorptive capacity, Table 7 shows that service firms appear superior to the manufacturing firms. The average share of employees with a university degree is twice as high among the service firms compared to their manufacturing counterparts. We also found that service firms that engage in informal coopetition have significantly higher absorptive capacity (60% employees with university degree) compared to those that did not coopete informally (49% employees with university degree). This difference is not found among service firms that engage in formal coopetition nor among manufacturing firms in general.

Table 7. Industrial comparison of the sample.

Percent of graduate staff Mean SD
Service 0.56 0.28
Manufacturing 0.28 0.26

Taken together, the above presented results suggest that service firms show some substantial difference from their manufacturing counterparts in terms of coopetition, particularly of the informal type. The effects of coopetition in services, therefore, seems to merit a closer look.

Estimation results

Table 8 reports the results for our bivariate probit model for product (Model 1) and process innovation (Model 2). The results reveal that Formal coopetition is negatively and significantly associated with the likelihood of product innovation ( p<0.05), whereas its effect on the probability of process innovation is statistically insignificant (see Model 1 and 2 of Table 8, respectively). Our hypothesis 1a predicts that formal coopetition is negatively associated with the probability of innovation. However, these results only support our hypothesis for product innovation (Model 1) and do not lend any support to our hypothesis for process innovation (Model 2). The effects of Informal coopetition are significant and positive for the probability of product innovation (p<0.01) in Model 1 and the probability of process innovation (p<0.01) in Model 2. We posited in our hypothesis 1b that informal coopetition is positively associated with the probability of innovation, and our results support this argument. The results further indicate that out of our two proxies for the absorptive capacity of a firm, Staff quality, has no statistically significant effect on the probability of product innovation, whereas it shows a significant negative effect on the probability of process innovation (p<0.1). Furthermore, Staff training shows significant positive effects on the probabilities of product innovation and process innovation.

Table 8. The relationship between coopetition and innovation in Nigerian service firms (bivariate logit estimations, 2005–2007; 2008–2010).

(1) (2)
Product
innovation
Process
innovation
Formal coopetition −1.234 ** −0.881
(0.626) (0.711)
Informal coopetition 1.929 *** 1.999 ***
(0.410) (0.452)
Staff quality 0.397 −0.962 *
(0.491) (0.523)
Staff training 1.281 *** 1.899 ***
(0.263) (0.277)
Formal coopetition*staff quality 1.059 −0.298
(0.664) (0.761)
Informal coopetition*staff quality −1.593 *** 0.481
(0.587) (0.634)
Formal coopetition*staff training 0.394 1.067 *
(0.549) (0.569)
Informal coopetition*staff training −0.762 ** −1.749 ***
(0.351) (0.403)
Other collaboration partners −0.233 0.258
(0.343) (0.377)
Size 0.083 0.109
(0.068) (0.070)
Age 0.123 0.092
(0.096) (0.089)
Location 0.311 ** −0.180
(0.157) (0.176)
Group 0.398 ** 0.265
(0.177) (0.189)
Export 0.055 0.006
(0.216) (0.230)
Year −0.563 *** −0.319
(0.211) (0.217)
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Observations 421
Log likel. −349.854
Chi sq. 330.964 ***
Rho 0.321 ***

Standard errors in parentheses; * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

The coefficients of interaction variables in Models 1 and 2 depict the moderating effects of absorptive capacity ( Staff quality and Staff training) on Formal coopetition and Informal coopetition through the effects of interaction terms in relation to the likelihood of product and process innovation, respectively. The results in Model 1 reveal that the absorptive capacity of a firm, when Staff quality is considered , negatively moderates (p<0.01) the probability of product innovation through informal coopetition (Model 1).

Further, the coefficients of the interaction effects of Staff training demonstrate that the absorptive capacity of a firm positively moderates (p<0.1) the probability of process innovation through formal coopetition and negatively moderates both the probabilities of product (p<0.05) and process innovation (p<0.01) through informal coopetition. According to our hypotheses 2a and 2b, we expected a positive moderating effect of absorptive capacity on the association of formal coopetition and innovation (product and process), and a negative moderating effect on the association of informal coopetition and innovation. However, our hypothesis 2a holds only in case of Staff training for process innovation, and our hypothesis 2b holds except in the case of Staff quality for process innovation. In terms of control variables, the coefficients of Location and Group are positive and significant for product innovation, whereas, insignificant for process innovation.

Discussion and conclusion

In this study, we analyze the role of formal and informal coopetition in the innovation activities of SMEs in Nigeria, as well as the moderating effect of the absorptive capacities on the prospects of coopetition. Our results indicate that informal coopetition has a significant and positive effect on innovation, both product and process innovations, whereas we find that formal coopetition effects only the output of product innovation. Studies in innovation cooperation endorse the similar findings ( e.g., Bönte & Keilbach, 2005). Moreover, our findings also support the argument that absorptive capacity moderates the relationships between coopetition and innovation.

Our study contributes to the literature on coopetition in the following ways. First, the study enhances our understanding of the concept of coopetition in the context of an emerging economy, Nigeria. Although a number of studies have addressed the feature of coopetition in advanced economies ( Arranz & de Arroyabe, 2008; Nieto & Santamaría, 2007), little attention has been paid to the effect of coopetition on innovation in developing and emerging countries. Second, this study focused on a largely understudied aspect of coopetition: that is, the nature of interaction among firms in coopetition. This aspect becomes more relevant to the institutional and the cultural contexts of the emerging economies of Africa and Asia, where social capital plays an important role in business dynamics. Finally, we base our empirical analysis on data of service firms. This provides us with valuable insights on how the coopetition relates to the activities of service firms.

Building on existing debate about coopetition in management and innovation literature, this study increases our understanding of how formal and informal coopetition interplay among the “frenemies” of innovation in Nigeria. In this study, we argue that the formal coopetition is a risky process due to the risk of reciprocal knowledge transfer and double coincidence of wants, whereas informal coopetition can mitigate these risks and leads to innovation. Moreover, since the innovation is an interactive mechanism and coopetition is inherently risky, the internal capabilities of firms define their potential success in such collaboration, and therefore, absorptive capacity of a firm plays an important role in the interactions of innovations.

Despite its contributions, our study has some limitations. First, due to the data limitations and data collection issues in developing countries, we are not able to include market-specific contextual factors in our analysis. Second, the nature of our survey limits our methodological prospects (e.g., mostly binary variables). Finally, on the similar grounds, our dataset does not allow us to fully address the size-, ownership, and industry-specific heterogeneities. Along these lines, the future research should focus on including more contextual elements to research. It would be interesting to investigate deeply if context plays a role in managing coopetition relationships beyond the nature of interactions, and what would be some new and novel theoretical insights that could be generated in this regard. Moreover, since binary variables do not fully capture the potential of heterogeneity, future research should complement the data with other secondary information to have meaningful insights. Another important avenue for future research could be the comparison of the issue of coopetition and innovation in advanced economies and transforming economies. Similarly, although we have addressed the issue of endogeneity between coopetition and innovation to an extent in our analysis, future research should focus on richer analyses of more detailed data to isolate the role of coopetition in innovation activities of SMEs.

Data availability

Underlying data

Data are from the Nigerian innovation survey data, collected with NEPAD support, prepared with PEDL funding and are publicly available at https:/doi.org/10.17632/37pys4vxt4.1

Data are available under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 International license (CC-BY 3.0).

Funding Statement

This project has received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under the Marie Skłodowska-Curie grant agreement No 832862 (Smart Specialization Strategy Tools with Big Data (SSST-BD)).

The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

[version 2; peer review: 2 approved]

Footnotes

1 Here the term “frenemies” is a contraction of two words: “friends” and “enemies”. The term reflects that the same actors could simultaneously be both friends (supporting) and enemies (inhibiting) of innovation in a coopetition scenario.

References

  1. Adeyeye AD, Jegede OO, Akinwale YO: The impact of technology innovation and R&D on firms’ performance: An empirical analysis of Nigeria’s service sector. Int J Technol Learn Innov Dev. 2013;6(4):374–395. 10.1504/IJTLID.2013.060873 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  2. Akdoğan AA, Cingšz A: An Empirical Study on Determining the Attitudes of Small and Medium Sized Businesses (SMEs) Related to Coopetition. Proc - Soc Behv. 2012;58:252–258. 10.1016/j.sbspro.2012.09.999 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  3. Arranz N, de Arroyabe JCF: The choice of partners in R&D cooperation: An empirical analysis of Spanish firms. Technovation. 2008;28(1–2):88–100. 10.1016/j.technovation.2007.07.006 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  4. Barney J: Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. J Manage. 1991;17(1):99–120. 10.1177/014920639101700108 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  5. Barney JB, Dagnino GB, Corte VD, et al. : Management and organization review special issue ‘Coopetition and innovation in transforming economies.’ Manage Organ Rev. Blackwell Publishing Ltd.2016;12(2):417–420. 10.1017/mor.2016.15 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  6. Barney JB, Ketchen DJ Jr, Wright M, et al. : The future of resource-based theory: Revitalization or decline? J Manage. 2011;37(5):1299–1315. 10.1177/0149206310391805 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  7. Bengtsson M, Johansson M: Managing coopetition to create opportunities for small firms. Int Small Bus J. 2014;32(4):401–427. 10.1177/0266242612461288 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  8. Bengtsson M, Kock S: Cooperation and competition in relationships between competitors in business networks. J Bus Ind Mark. 1999;14(3):178–194. 10.1108/08858629910272184 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  9. Bengtsson M, Kock S: ”Coopetition” in Business Networks—to Cooperate and Compete Simultaneously. Ind Market Manag. 2000;29(5):411–426. 10.1016/S0019-8501(99)00067-X [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  10. Bengtsson M, Kock S: Coopetition-Quo vadis? Past accomplishments and future challenges. Ind Market Manag. 2014;43(2):180–188. 10.1016/j.indmarman.2014.02.015 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  11. Berchicci L, de Jong JPJ, Freel M: Remote collaboration and innovative performance: The moderating role of R&D intensity. Ind Corp Change. 2016;25(3):429–446. 10.1093/icc/dtv031 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  12. Biggs T, Shah MK: African SMES, networks, and manufacturing performance. J Bank Financ. 2006;30(11):3043–3066. 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.05.004 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  13. Bönte W, Keilbach M: Concubinage or marriage? Informal and formal cooperations for innovation. Int J Ind Organ. 2005;23(3–4):279–302. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.01.007 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  14. Boschma RA: Proximity and innovation: A critical assessment. Reg Stud. 2005;39(1):61–74. 10.1080/0034340052000320887 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  15. Bouncken RB, Gast J, Kraus S, et al. : Coopetition: a systematic review, synthesis, and future research directions. Rev Manag Sci. 2015;9(3):577–601. 10.1007/s11846-015-0168-6 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  16. Bouncken RB, Kraus S: Innovation in knowledge-intensive industries: The double-edged sword of coopetition. J Bus Res. 2013;66(10):2060–2070. 10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.02.032 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  17. Brandenburger A, Nalebuff B: Co-opetition. Doubleday.1996. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  18. Brusoni S, Prencipe A, Pavitt K: Knowledge Specialization, Organizational Coupling, and the Boundaries of the Firm: Why Do Firms Know More Than They Make? Admin Sci Quart. 2001;46(4):597–621. 10.2307/3094825 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  19. Carayannis EEG, Alexander J: Winning By Co-Opeting In Strategic Government-University-Industry R&D Partnerships: The Power Of Complex, Dynamic Knowledge Networks. J Technol Transfer. 1999;24:197–210. 10.1023/A:1007855422405 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  20. Carvalho L, Costa T, Caiado J: Determinants of innovation in a small open economy: a multidimensional perspective. J Bus Econ Manag. 2013;14(3):583–600. 10.3846/16111699.2012.701225 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  21. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA: Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R & D. Econ J. 1989;99(397):569–596. 10.2307/2233763 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  22. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA: Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation. Admin Sci Quart. 1990;35(1):128–152. 10.2307/2393553 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  23. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA: Fortune Favors the Prepared Firm. Manage Sci. 1994;40(2):169–284. 10.1287/mnsc.40.2.227 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  24. Crick JM, Crick D: Coopetition and family-owned wine producers. J Bus Res. 2021;135:319–336. 10.1016/j.jbusres.2021.06.046 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  25. Dagnino GB, Di Guardo MC, Padula G: Coopetition: Nature, challenges, and implications for firms’ strategic behavior and managerial mindset. In: G. B. Dagnino (Ed.), Handbook of research on competitive strategy.Edward Elgar Publishing Inc.2012;492–511. 10.4337/9780857938688.00033 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  26. Dagnino GB, Padula G: Coopetition Strategy. Towards a New Kind of Interfirm Dynamics? EURAM. 2002. [Google Scholar]
  27. Das TK, Teng BS: A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. J Manage. 2000;26(1):31–61. 10.1177/014920630002600105 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  28. de Jong JPJ, Freel M: Absorptive capacity and the reach of collaboration in high technology small firms. Res Policy. 2010;39(1):47–54. 10.1016/j.respol.2009.10.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  29. DeCarolis DM: The role of social capital and organizational knowledge in enhancing entrepreneurial opportunities in high-technology environments. In: C. W. Choo & N. Bontis (Eds.), The strategic management of intellectual capital and organizational knowledge.Oxford University Press,2002;699–709. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  30. Devece C, Ribeiro-Soriano DE, Palacios-Marqués D: Coopetition as the new trend in inter-firm alliances: literature review and research patterns. Rev Manag Sci. 2019;13:207–226. 10.1007/s11846-017-0245-0 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  31. Drejer I, Vinding AL: Searching near and far: Determinants of innovative firms’ propensity to collaborate across geographical distance. Ind Innov. 2007;14(3):259–275. 10.1080/13662710701369205 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  32. Dussauge P, Garrette B, Mitchell W: Learning from competing partners: Outcomes and durations of scale and link alliances in Europe, North America and Asia. Strateg Manage J. 2000;21(2):99–126. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  33. Ebersberger B, Herstad SJ: The relationship between international innovation collaboration, intramural R&D and SMEs’ innovation performance: a quantile regression approach. Appl Econ Lett. 2013;20(7):626–630. 10.1080/13504851.2012.724158 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  34. Edeh JN, Acedo FJ: External supports, innovation efforts and productivity: Estimation of a CDM model for small firms in developing countries. Technol Forecast Soc Change. 2021;173(C):121189. 10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121189 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  35. Egbetokun A: Nigerian innovation survey data, collected with NEPAD support, prepared with PEDL funding.2017;1. 10.17632/37PYS4VXT4.1 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  36. Egbetokun AA: Interactive learning and firm-level capabilities in latecomer settings: The Nigerian manufacturing industry. Technol Forecast Soc Change. 2015;99:231–241. 10.1016/j.techfore.2015.06.040 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  37. Egbetokun A, Savin I: Absorptive Capacity and Innovation: When Is It Better to Cooperate?In: Andreas Pyka & J. Foster (Eds.), The Evolution of Economic and Innovation Systems. Economic Complexity and Evolution.Springer,2015;373–399. 10.1007/978-3-319-13299-0_16 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  38. Enberg C: Enabling knowledge integration in coopetitive R&D projects - The management of conflicting logics. Int J Proj Manag. 2012;30(7):771–780. 10.1016/j.ijproman.2012.01.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  39. Fehr E, Gächter S: Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity.In: SSRN.2000. 10.2139/ssrn.229149 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  40. Foss NJ, Lyngsie J, Zahra SA: The role of external knowledge sources and organizational design in the process of opportunity exploitation. Strateg Manag J. 2013;34(12):1453–1471. 10.1002/smj.2135 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  41. Freeman C: Networks of innovators: A synthesis of research issues. Res Policy. 1991;20(5):499–514. 10.1016/0048-7333(91)90072-X [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  42. Freedman DA, Sekhon JS: Endogeneity in probit response models. Polit Anal. 2010;18(2):138–150. 10.1093/pan/mpp037 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  43. Freitas IMB, Clausen TH, Fontana R, et al. : Formal and informal external linkages and firms' innovative strategies. A cross-country comparison. J Evol Econ. 2011;21:91–119. 10.1007/s00191-010-0188-y [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  44. García-Morales VJ, Jiménez-Barrionuevo MM, Gutiérrez-Gutiérrez L: Transformational leadership influence on organizational performance through organizational learning and innovation. J Bus Res. 2012;65(7):1040–1050. 10.1016/j.jbusres.2011.03.005 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  45. Gernsheimer O, Kanbach DK, Gast J: Coopetition research - A systematic literature review on recent accomplishments and trajectories. Industrial Marketing Management. 2021;96:113–134. 10.1016/j.indmarman.2021.05.001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  46. Gilsing V, Nooteboom B, Vanhaverbeke W, et al. : Network embeddedness and the exploration of novel technologies: Technological distance, betweenness centrality and density. Res Policy. 2008;37(10):1717–1731. 10.1016/j.respol.2008.08.010 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  47. Gnyawali DR, Park BJ: Co-opetition and Technological Innovation in Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises: A Multilevel Conceptual Model. J Small Bus Manag. 2009;47(3):308–330. 10.1111/j.1540-627X.2009.00273.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  48. Grant RM: The knowledge-based view of the firm: Implications for management practice. Long Range Planning. 1997;30(3):450–454. 10.1016/S0024-6301(97)00025-3 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  49. Grant RM: The Knowledge-Based View of the Firm.In: C. W. Choo & B. Nick (Eds.), The strategic management of intellectual capital and organizational knowledge. Oxford University Press.2002;133–148. [Google Scholar]
  50. Grossman GM, Helpman E: Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press.1991. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  51. Hagedoorn J: Understanding the rationale of strategic technology partnering: Interorganizational modes of cooperation and sectoral differences. Strateg Manag J. 1993;14(5):371–385. 10.1002/smj.4250140505 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  52. Hagedoorn J: Inter-firm R&D partnerships: an overview of major trends and patterns since 1960. Res Policy. 2002;31(4):477–492. 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00120-2 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  53. Hagedoorn J, Link AN, Vonortas NS: Research partnerships. Res Policy. 2000;29(4–5):567–586. 10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00090-6 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  54. Hagedoorn J, Schakenraad J: Leading companies and networks of strategic alliances in information technologies. Res Policy. 1992;21(2):163–190. 10.1016/0048-7333(92)90039-7 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  55. Hamel G, Doz YL, Prahalad CK: Collaborate with you Competitors - and Win. Harv Bus Rev. 1989a. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  56. Hamel G, Doz Y, Prahalad CK: Collaborate with Your Competitors—and Win. Harv Bus Rev. 1989b;67(1):133–139. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  57. Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R: Geographic Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations. Q J Econ. 1993;108(3):577–598. 10.2307/2118401 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  58. Kedia BL, Rhew ND, Gaffney NT, et al. : Emerging Market Multinationals: Coopetition for Global Growth. Thunderbird Int Bus Rev. 2016;58(6):515–526. 10.1002/tie.21758 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  59. King AA, Lakhani KR: The Contingent Effect of Absorptive Capacity: An Open Innovation Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal. 2011. 10.2139/ssrn.1802696 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  60. Knoben J, Oerlemans LAG: Proximity and inter-organizational collaboration: A literature review. Int J Manag Rev. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.2006;8(2):71–89. 10.1111/j.1468-2370.2006.00121.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  61. Kogut B, Zander U: What Firms Do? Coordination, Identity, and Learning. Organ Sci. 1996;7(5):502–518. 10.1287/orsc.7.5.502 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  62. Kraus S, Pohjola M, Koponen A: Innovation in family firms: an empirical analysis linking organizational and managerial innovation to corporate success. Rev Manag Sci. 2012;6(3):265–286. 10.1007/s11846-011-0065-6 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  63. Kylänen M, Rusko R: Unintentional coopetition in the service industries: The case of Pyhä-Luosto tourism destination in the Finnish Lapland. Eur Manag J. 2011;29(3):193–205. 10.1016/j.emj.2010.10.006 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  64. Lado AA, Boyd NG, Hanlon SC: Competition, cooperation, and the search for economic rents: A syncretic model. Acad Manage Rev. 1997;22(1):110–141. 10.2307/259226 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  65. Lado AA, Boyd NG, Wright P: A Competency-Based Model of Sustainable Competitive Advantage: Toward a Conceptual Integration. J Manage. 1992;18(1):77–91. 10.1177/014920639201800106 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  66. Levy M, Loebbecke C, Powell P: SMEs, co-opetition and knowledge sharing: the role of information systems. Eur J Inf Syst. 2003;12(1):3–17. 10.1057/palgrave.ejis.3000439 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  67. Liebeskind JP: Keeping organizational secrets: Protective institutional mechanisms and their costs. Ind Corp Chang. 1997;6(3):623–663. 10.1093/icc/6.3.623 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  68. Loebecke C, Van Fenema PC, Powell P: Co-opetition and knowledge transfer. ACM SIGMIS Database 1999;30(2):14–25. 10.1145/383371.383373 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  69. Luo Y: Toward coopetition within a multinational enterprise: a perspective from foreign subsidiaries. J World Bus. 2005;40(1):71–90. 10.1016/j.jwb.2004.10.006 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  70. Luo Y: A coopetition perspective of global competition. J World Bus. 2007;42(2):129–144. 10.1016/j.jwb.2006.08.007 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  71. Medase SK: Employees’ Heterogeneous Qualifications, Internal R&D, Formal Training And Innovation Performance. Int J Innov Manag. 2020;25(1):2150011. 10.1142/S1363919621500110 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  72. Medase SK, Wyrwich M: The role of innovation for employment growth among firms in developing countries: Evidence from Nigeria. African J Sci Technol Innov Dev. 2021;14(3):610–619.. 10.1080/20421338.2021.1877417 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  73. Morris M, Koc ¸ak A, O ¨ zer A: Coopetition as a small business strategy: implications for performance. J Small Bus Strategy. 2007;18(1):35–55. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  74. Mowery DC, Oxley JE, Silverman BS: Technological overlap and interfirm cooperation: Implications for the resource-based view of the firm. Res Policy. 1998;27(5):507–523. 10.1016/S0048-7333(98)00066-3 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  75. Murphy JT: Networks, trust, and innovation in Tanzania’s manufacturing sector. World Dev. 2002;30(4):591–619. 10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00131-0 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  76. Nalebuff BJ, Brandenburger AM: Co-opetition: Competitive and cooperative business strategies for the digital economy. Strategy Leadersh. 1997;25(6):28–33. 10.1108/eb054655 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  77. Nelson RR: U.S. technological leadership: Where did it come from and where did it go? Res Policy. 1990;19(2):117–132. 10.1016/0048-7333(90)90042-5 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  78. Neter J, Wasserman W, Kutner MH: Applied linear statistical models : regression, analysis of variance, and experimental designs.R.D. Irwin.1985. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  79. Nieto MJ, Santamaría L: The importance of diverse collaborative networks for the novelty of product innovation. Technovation. 2007;27(6–7):367–377. 10.1016/j.technovation.2006.10.001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  80. Nooteboom B, Van Haverbeke W, Duysters G, et al. : Optimal cognitive distance and absorptive capacity. Res Policy. 2007;36(7):1016–1034. 10.1016/j.respol.2007.04.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  81. Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, Banji: Learning in Local Systems and Global Links: The Otigba Computer Hardware Cluster in Nigeria. MERIT Working Papers.2006. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  82. Phene A, Tallman S: Knowledge spillovers and alliance formation. J Manag Stud. 2014;51(7):1058–1090. 10.1111/joms.12088 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  83. Phills JA, Deiglmeier K, Miller DT: Rediscovering social innovation. Stanf Soc Innov Rev. 2008. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  84. Powell WW, Koput KW, Smith-Doerr L: Interorganizational Collaboration and the Locus of Innovation: Networks of Learning in Biotechnology. Adm Sci Q. 1996:41(1):116–145. 10.2307/2393988 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  85. Pyka A: Informal networking. Technovation. 1997;17(4):207–220. 10.1016/S0166-4972(96)00105-8 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  86. Quintana-García C, Benavides-Velasco CA: Cooperation, competition, and innovative capability: A panel data of European dedicated biotechnology firms. Technovation. 2004;24(12):927–938. 10.1016/S0166-4972(03)00060-9 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  87. Ritala P: Coopetition Strategy - When is it Successful? Empirical Evidence on Innovation and Market Performance. Br J Manag. 2012;23(3):307–324. 10.1111/j.1467-8551.2011.00741.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  88. Ritala P, Hurmelinna-Laukkanen P: What’s in it for me? Creating and appropriating value in innovation-related coopetition. Technovation. 2009;29(12):819–828. 10.1016/j.technovation.2009.07.002 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  89. Ritala P, Hurmelinna-Laukkanen P: Incremental and radical innovation in coopetition-the role of absorptive capacity and appropriability. J Prod Innov Manage. 2013;30(1):154–169. 10.1111/j.1540-5885.2012.00956.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  90. Roig-Tierno N, Kraus S, Cruz S: The relation between coopetition and innovation/entrepreneurship. Rev Manag Sci. 2018;12(2):379–383. 10.1007/s11846-017-0266-8 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  91. Schumpeter J: The theory of economic development - An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. In Regional Studies.1934. Reference Source [Google Scholar]
  92. Shelanski HA, Klein PG: Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Review and Assessment. J Law Econ Organ. 1995;11(2):335–361. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a036875 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  93. Shen H, Gao Y, Zhang C: Managing conflict and trust as coopetition within alliance partnerships in an emerging economy. South African J Bus Manag. 2019;50(1):a467. 10.4102/sajbm.v50i1.467 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  94. Somaya D: Strategic determinants of decisions not to settle patent litigation. Strateg Manag J. 2003;24(1):17–38. 10.1002/smj.281 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  95. Spender JC, Grant RM: Knowledge and the firm: Overview. Strateg Manag J. 1996;17(S2):5–9. 10.1002/smj.4250171103 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  96. Subramaniam M, Youndt MA: The influence of intellectual capital on the types of innovative capabilities. Acad Manage J. Academy of Management.2005;48(3):450–463. 10.5465/AMJ.2005.17407911 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  97. Tether BS: Who co-operates for innovation, and why: An empirical analysis. Res Policy. 2002;31(6):947–967. 10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00172-X [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  98. Thomason SJ, Simendinger E, Kiernan D: Several determinants of successful coopetition in small business. J Small Bus Entrep. 2013;26(1):15–28. 10.1080/08276331.2012.761800 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  99. Tödtling F, Lehner P, Kaufmann A: Do different types of innovation rely on specific kinds of knowledge interactions? Technovation. 2009;29(1):59–71. 10.1016/j.technovation.2008.05.002 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  100. Wernerfelt B: The resource‐based view of the firm: Ten years after. Strateg Manag J. 1995;16(3):171–174. 10.1002/smj.4250160303 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  101. Wuyts S, Colombo MG, Dutta S, et al. : Empirical tests of optimal cognitive distance. J Econ Behav Organ. 2005;58(2):277–302. 10.1016/j.jebo.2004.03.019 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  102. Zahra SA, George G: Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Acad Manage Rev. 2002;27(2). 10.5465/amr.2002.6587995 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  103. Zineldin M: Co-opetition: The organisation of the future. Mark Intell Plan. Emerald Group Publishing Limited.2004;22(7):780–790. 10.1108/02634500410568600 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
Open Res Eur. 2022 Jul 8. doi: 10.21956/openreseurope.16082.r29566

Reviewer response for version 2

Elvis Avenyo 1

Thanks to the authors for considering my earlier comments. I am satisfied with the attempt made to incorporate the comments despite their data constraints.

If applicable, is the statistical analysis and its interpretation appropriate?

Partly

Is the study design appropriate and is the work technically sound?

Yes

Is the work clearly and accurately presented and does it engage with the current literature?

Yes

Are the conclusions drawn adequately supported by the results?

Partly

Are sufficient details of methods and analysis provided to allow replication by others?

Yes

Are all the source data and materials underlying the results available?

No

Reviewer Expertise:

My related focus areas of research are on innovation in African firms, technological change, industrial policy, among

I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard.

Open Res Eur. 2022 Apr 1. doi: 10.21956/openreseurope.15625.r28648

Reviewer response for version 1

Elvis Avenyo 1

The article focuses on understanding the relationship between coopetition and the likelihood of innovation using data on 421 SMEs in Nigeria. The data is a repeated cross-section collected in 2008 and 2011.

In general, the paper is well-written with very sound motivation and structure. The paper is also succinct and the authors seem well vested in the literature.

However, there are major methodological gaps some of which I highlight below.

  • While cooperation between competing firms is an interesting concept and may raise issues around collusion, this is not expected among SMEs given the size and market shares of SMEs. A question however is how the benefits of innovation are appropriated, and if this endogenously influences coopetition and innovation. 

  • Also, the nature of the collaborations matter. Given that firms are competitors, one can assume that they are similar on several dimensions, and the nature of coopetition and innovation may differ across sectors and firm sizes.

If this holds, it may be interesting to know what drives this kind of heterogeneous cooperation in SMEs, and if smaller firms benefit from such coopetitions.

Authors can conduct split sample analysis to observe some of these heterogeneities if they exist.

These could be an even more interesting angle to the paper beyond the formal and informal coopetiton analysis.

  • Hypotheses 1 should be rephrased as: ..... 'probability to innovate'

  • The authors indicate that they use data on 469 SMEs across two periods. Good to indicate the distributions across the two periods.

  • One can argue that the real effect of coopetition is not expected to be seen on the probability of innovation, but on how these innovations perform. Product innovation in markets given that these firms compete for market size once innovation occurs. Could this analysis be done for at least on product innovation given that this is mostly measured in CIS-like datasets?

  • In emerging markets where there is high informality, it may be critical to examine the type of competitor, be it formal or informal SMEs. There is empirical literature that shows that informal and formal competitions generate different innovation outcomes in SMEs in developing countries.

  • On page 7, the authors present and compare descriptive stats on both services and manufacturing SMEs. Could the authors explain the purpose for the comparison if the focus is on service firms?

If data exist on manufacturing firms, why is the analysis not covering both sectors, and possibly examining whether coopetition happens in service and manufacturing firms differently? 

I am a bit unclear why the focus is on service firms. I would suggest the analysis is expanded to include manufacturing firms

  • In the analysis, the authors introduced both types of coopetiton separately into the model; is it possible that competition (computed as whether you engage in formal and/or informal), in general, generates positive innovation outcomes even before this decomposition? Also, firms may engage in both formal and informal coopetiton in SMEs, particularly in emerging markets. It is important to consider the complementary effects of this in the analysis.

  • In addition, the analysis makes little attempt to control for endogeneity between innovation and coopetition - firms may coopete to innovate or otherwise, and may also innovate in order to engage in beneficial coopetition. The results may be driven largely by this bidirectional relationship.

Minor:

typo on page 6: 'whether' instead of 'weather'

If applicable, is the statistical analysis and its interpretation appropriate?

Partly

Is the study design appropriate and is the work technically sound?

Yes

Is the work clearly and accurately presented and does it engage with the current literature?

Yes

Are the conclusions drawn adequately supported by the results?

Partly

Are sufficient details of methods and analysis provided to allow replication by others?

Yes

Are all the source data and materials underlying the results available?

No

Reviewer Expertise:

My related focus areas of research are on innovation in African firms, technological change, industrial policy, among

I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard, however I have significant reservations, as outlined above.

Open Res Eur. 2022 Apr 23.
Sohaib S Hassan 1

Dear Reviewer, Thank you for your valueable feedback. We are working on addressing all your concerns. We'll submit a revised version with a detailed response soon. Thank you one again. Best Regards, Sohaib & Co-Authors

Open Res Eur. 2022 Jun 13.
Sohaib S Hassan 1

Dear Dr. Avenyo ,   Thank you very much for sparing time to review our manuscript. Indeed, your observations about our paper are quite relevant and we intend to address your concerns in the new version of our study.  We have carefully examined all your observations and prepared our response below and edited the manuscript where necessary. Should you want us to make additional changes, we would be happy to comply.   Thank you very much once again.   Yours sincerely,

Sohaib & Co-Authors _______________________________________________________________   Reviewers’ Comments and responses   The article focuses on understanding the relationship between coopetition and the likelihood of innovation using data on 421 SMEs in Nigeria. The data is a repeated cross-section collected in 2008 and 2011.

In general, the paper is well-written with very sound motivation and structure. The paper is also succinct and the authors seem well vested in the literature.

However, there are major methodological gaps some of which I highlight below.

  • While cooperation between competing firms is an interesting concept and may raise issues around collusion, this is not expected among SMEs given the size and market shares of SMEs. A question however is how the benefits of innovation are appropriated, and if this endogenously influences coopetition and innovation. 

  • Also, the nature of the collaborations matter. Given that firms are competitors, one can assume that they are similar on several dimensions, and the nature of coopetition and innovation may differ across sectors and firm sizes.

  • If this holds, it may be interesting to know what drives this kind of heterogeneous cooperation in SMEs, and if smaller firms benefit from such coopetitions.

    Authors can conduct split sample analysis to observe some of these heterogeneities if they exist.

    These could be an even more interesting angle to the paper beyond the formal and informal coopetiton analysis.

 

  • One can argue that the real effect of coopetition is not expected to be seen on the probability of innovation, but on how these innovations perform. Product innovation in markets given that these firms compete for market size once innovation occurs. Could this analysis be done for at least on product innovation given that this is mostly measured in CIS-like datasets?

 

  • In emerging markets where there is high informality, it may be critical to examine the type of competitor, be it formal or informal SMEs. There is empirical literature that shows that informal and formal competitions generate different innovation outcomes in SMEs in developing countries.

Response: Thank you very much for your comments. We agree with your comments and thus, we have provided the related debate in the manuscript. Please see below: The research about coopetition among organizations largely focuses on large organization, as SMEs tend to differ from large firms in terms of their competences and priorities. Further, due to their rather unsystematic structures, SMEs show relatively less interest in pursuing coopetition strategies to gain performance outcomes (Morris et al. 2007; Roig-Tierno et al. 2018). However, while SMEs are generally market oriented and tend to mainly focus on growth and developing their core businesses, they need to be innovative in competitive markets to overcome their liabilities of smallness (Bengtsson and Johansson, 2014; Roig-Tierno et al. 2018). Coopetition alliances might facilitate their competitive advantage, access to new markets and survival (Morris et al. 2007; Kraus et al. 2012). The existing research indeed has pointed to such practices among SMEs (e.g., Kraus et al. 2012; Bouncken et al. 2015; Devece et al. 2017; Crick and Crick, 2021; Gernsheimer et al. 2021), but the empirical evidence is rather limited in scope (sectoral and geographical). Our study addresses this limitation of the literature by providing empirical evidence pertaining to the role of coopetition in innovation among SMEs in a large developing country. We also underscore that in an emerging country settings SMEs may not collude, but they engage in coopetition. This is especially true in large developing countries like Nigeria where most of the firms are SMEs. Sometimes, the only way they manage to survive and compete in the potentially oligopolistic market is through partnerships. Your observation also alludes to the issue of appropriability and radical innovations which, while very relevant, is beyond the scope of our study and also limited by our data structure. As for the size specific heterogeneity and innovation types, your concerns are quite apt. However, we find no evidence of size heterogeneity in a preliminary analysis including an interaction term of the main explanatory variables with size. Thus, our results are not meaningful in this regard. We are convinced that this is because most of the firms are small and so will not necessarily vary based on size in the nature and benefits of coopetition. Besides, our small sample size does not allow us to examine such heterogeneities.   ______________________________________________________________  

  • On page 7, the authors present and compare descriptive stats on both services and manufacturing SMEs. Could the authors explain the purpose for the comparison if the focus is on service firms?

  • If data exist on manufacturing firms, why is the analysis not covering both sectors, and possibly examining whether coopetition happens in service and manufacturing firms differently? 

I am a bit unclear why the focus is on service firms. I would suggest the analysis is expanded to include manufacturing firms

  • In the analysis, the authors introduced both types of coopetiton separately into the model; is it possible that competition (computed as whether you engage in formal and/or informal), in general, generates positive innovation outcomes even before this decomposition? Also, firms may engage in both formal and informal coopetiton in SMEs, particularly in emerging markets. It is important to consider the complementary effects of this in the analysis.

  • In addition, the analysis makes little attempt to control for endogeneity between innovation and coopetition - firms may coopete to innovate or otherwise, and may also innovate in order to engage in beneficial coopetition. The results may be driven largely by this bidirectional relationship.

Response: We have noticed some typos in the ORE formatted version of our manuscript. Please excuse our oversight in this regard. We have corrected the tables to reflect the correct information. Overall, Since the focus of this research is on rather the underexplored industrial dimension (service sector) of coopetition in emerging markets, we had excluded the manufacturing sector from our main analysis. However, to demonstrate how there exist some differences between service and manufacturing sectors vis-à-vis the types of coopetition, we include this feature in our analysis. The information in Table 4 and Table 5 (corrected versions. See here: https://s3-eu-west-1.amazonaws.com/openreseurope/linked/199849.Tables_4%2C5%2C6.docx ) highlight some of the differences between the service and manufacturing sectors which, in our opinion, warranted our sole focus on the service sector. Generally, we find informal channel of coopetition to be significant for all types of innovation in our sample SMEs albeit the practice is statistically significantly more divergent among the service sectors SMEs. The tables are reproduced below. A significantly higher percentage of innovative service firms engaged in informal coopetition, compared to their manufacturing counterparts. This difference is most pronounced across process and marketing innovation where 11% more innovative service firms engaged in informal coopetition than in manufacturing. Thus, this justifies, to an extent, our focus on the service sector SMEs. We have estimated our model for the manufacturing SMEs. The results are presented in the Table A . Further, please see results for the combined effect in the Table B (See here for Tables A & B https://s3-eu-west-1.amazonaws.com/openreseurope/linked/199850.Tables_A%2C_B.docx ). It is indeed true that both formal and informal coopetition are often used together, and, in combination, they generate positive effects on both product and process innovation. However, the distinction we make between both types in our analyses allow us to uncover which type may have a stronger effect on innovation. The issue of endogeneity is a quite relevant one. Although we have aimed to reduce the issue of endogeneity with our econometric modelling, one cannot deny the technical aspect of it. However, contextually speaking, it is almost impossible in a business environment like Nigeria where innovation is very expensive due to institutional, infrastructural and credit deficits that a firm would innovate just because it wants to coopete. We have nonetheless included this limitation of our study in the last section of the manuscript to highlight the issue. ____________________________________________________________ Minor Comments:             Hypotheses 1 should be rephrased as: ..... 'probability to innovate' Response: We have edited it as advised.

The authors indicate that they use data on 469 SMEs across two periods. Good to indicate the distributions across the two periods. Response: The information has been indicated in the sub-section: “Data and Sample” under the section: “Methods” typo on page 6: 'whether' instead of 'weather' Response: Corrected _______________________________________________________________   New References:

  • Crick, J. M., & Crick, D. (2021). Coopetition and family-owned wine producers. Journal of Business Research, 135, 319-336.

  • Gernsheimer, O., Kanbach, D. K., & Gast, J. (2021). Coopetition research-A systematic literature review on recent accomplishments and trajectories. Industrial Marketing Management, 96, 113-134.

  • Roig-Tierno N, Kraus S, Cruz S (2018) The relation between coopetition and innovation/entrepreneurship. Rev Manag Sci 12(2):379–383

  • Bengtsson M, Johansson M (2014) Managing coopetition to create opportunities for small firms. Int Small Bus J 32(4):401–427

  • Kraus S, Pohjola M, Koponen A (2012) Innovation in family firms: an empirical analysis linking organizational and managerial innovation to corporate success. Rev Manag Sci 6(3):265–286

  • Devece C, Ribeiro-Soriano DE, Palacios-Marqués D (2017) Coopetition as the new trend in inter-firm alliances: literature review and research patterns. Rev Manag Sci.

  • Morris M, Koc ¸ak A, O ¨ zer A (2007) Coopetition as a small business strategy: implications for performance. J Small Bus Strategy 18(1):35–55

  • Bouncken, R.B., Gast, J., Kraus, S. and Bogers, M. (2015), “Coopetition: a systematic review, synthesis, and future research directions”, Review of Managerial Science, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 577-601.

 

Open Res Eur. 2022 Feb 25. doi: 10.21956/openreseurope.15625.r28652

Reviewer response for version 1

Shoaib Abdul Basit 1,2

Very interesting research problem. The introduction section is well structured and clearly written in academic language. More recent literature needs to be cited in the theoretical framework to support your argument. As a general comment, note that although there are some references for 2014 or 2016, most are prior to 2012 and it would be useful to review and update the theoretical framework with recent literature.

The study provides contributions to the current literature. The research method is well designed, and the appropriate analysis is performed. Further, the results and interpretations are written very well. The authors need to elaborate more on their findings in the discussion section and link them with the previous studies.

Overall, the paper is well structured. I recommend this paper for indexing after making the minor changes.

If applicable, is the statistical analysis and its interpretation appropriate?

Yes

Is the study design appropriate and is the work technically sound?

Yes

Is the work clearly and accurately presented and does it engage with the current literature?

Yes

Are the conclusions drawn adequately supported by the results?

Yes

Are sufficient details of methods and analysis provided to allow replication by others?

Yes

Are all the source data and materials underlying the results available?

Yes

Reviewer Expertise:

Innovation and Management Strategies, Economics of Innovation, Entrepreneurship, Knowledge Sources, Open Innovation, Market Environment, Economic Development, International Trade and Public Policy, Sustainability Management

I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard.

Open Res Eur. 2022 Apr 23.
Sohaib S Hassan 1

Dear Reviewer, Thank you for your valueable feedback. We are working on addressing all your concerns. We'll submit a revised version with a detailed response soon. Thank you one again. Best Regards, Sohaib & Co-Authors

Open Res Eur. 2022 Jun 7.
Sohaib S Hassan 1

Dear Dr. Abdul Basit, Thank you very much for your review. We have now revised our mansucript and updated the newer version on the platform. We have addressed your concern regarding the newer references. We have added newwer and more relevant references in our manuscript.   Thank you very much once again.   Best Regards,

Sohaib & Co-Authors

Associated Data

    This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

    Data Availability Statement

    Underlying data

    Data are from the Nigerian innovation survey data, collected with NEPAD support, prepared with PEDL funding and are publicly available at https:/doi.org/10.17632/37pys4vxt4.1

    Data are available under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 International license (CC-BY 3.0).


    Articles from Open Research Europe are provided here courtesy of European Commission, Directorate General for Research and Innovation

    RESOURCES