Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2023 Nov 20.
Published in final edited form as: J Econ Perspect. 2022 Spring;36(2):149–174. doi: 10.1257/jep.36.2.149

Children and the US Social Safety Net: Balancing Disincentives for Adults and Benefits for Children

Anna Aizer 1, Hilary Hoynes 2, Adriana Lleras-Muney 3
PMCID: PMC10659762  NIHMSID: NIHMS1894449  PMID: 37986734

Abstract

A hallmark of every developed nation is the provision of a social safety net—a collection of public programs that deliver aid to the poor. Because of their higher rates of poverty, children are often a major beneficiary of safety net programs. Countries vary considerably in both the amount of safety net aid to children and the design of their programs. The United States provides less aid to families with children as a share of GDP (0.6 percent) than most countries: Among 37 OECD countries, only Turkey provides less, as shown in Figure 1. Countries that provide less aid to families with children have higher rates of child poverty. Among these same 37 countries, only Turkey and Costa Rica have higher child poverty rates than the United States. Why does the United States appear to be such an outlier in terms of the amount of aid it provides to families and child poverty rates? While there are likely multiple reasons, in this paper we focus on one possible explanation: Past emphasis on the negative behavioral effects of safety net programs for families over the benefits of such programs for children.


The negative behavioral effects derive from the design of the safety net. The design of the social safety net is characterized by 1) who receives the aid, given that some programs are universal while others are targeted to low-income families only; 2) how the aid is delivered, whether as cash or in-kind services such as housing subsidies or health insurance; and 3) whether the aid is conditional on some behavior such as work. When programs target low-income families, they deliver resources to those in greatest need. But this can potentially create negative incentive effects: for example, parents might change their behavior with respect to employment, marriage, or fertility to obtain or maintain eligibility. With respect to mode of delivery, economists tend to favor cash transfers because they are unconstrained and allow families to spend money to meet their greatest needs, but cash transfers can potentially result in spending on types of consumption that were not necessarily intended by the policymaker. This is particularly salient for programs that target children when parents are the recipients of the aid, because parents may not choose to spend the aid in ways that policymakers believe will improve the lives of their children, the intended target. Finally, safety net policies vary on whether aid is given based on certain conditions. In developing countries, conditional cash transfers often require parents to show that their children are attending school and/or receiving medical care. In the United States, the most common source of conditionality is work.

Since 1967, rates of child poverty in the United States have fallen considerably when measured using the Supplemental Poverty Measure, shown in Figure 2. This measure counts the fraction of children in poverty after accounting for social safety net transfers (both in cash and in kind). Therefore, this measure allows one to evaluate the effectiveness of the safety net in removing children from poverty. Secular trends in child poverty observed in Figure 2 are strongly related to employment conditions (for example, they fell sharply in the strong economies of the 1990s and the 2010s), but are also related to changes in the size and structure of the social safety net.

Figure 2.

Figure 2

Trends in Poverty and Child Poverty in the United States, 1967–2020

Source: Unpublished data from Trisi and Saenz (2021) and using the methods described therein. The Supplemental Poverty Rate (SPM) is based on a family resource measure that includes cash income plus the value of in-kind transfers (food and nutrition and housing) minus taxes, selected work deductions, and out-of-pocket health payments. For detail, see Fox and Burns (2021).

Although the safety net for children in the United States has expanded over time, it has evolved away from unconditional cash transfers based on need to conditional transfers and to more in-kind benefits. A main objective of these changes has been to reduce negative behavioral responses on the part of the parents and to direct spending toward certain goods and services. Implicit or explicit work requirements, aimed to reduce the impact of the safety net programs on employment, have become increasingly common. However, this shift has the potential to reduce assistance to needy families. Indeed, many US families are either ineligible for safety net programs or fail to take up safety net programs for which they are eligible. Thus, while conditionality reduces disincentives and thus lowers costs, it also diminishes the ability of the safety net to reduce poverty among children. Additionally, it is not clear whether conditioning aid on work (or other behaviors) is beneficial to the children of recipients.

Nevertheless, concern with behavioral effects has dominated not only discussions among policymakers but also economic research on the safety net for children. But the economic research on the safety net has evolved significantly over time, moving away from a near-exclusive focus on the negative incentive effects of the safety net on employment, earnings, marriage, and fertility to include examination of the potential positive benefits of such programs to children.

In this paper, we describe the evolution of this shift in economic research on the safety net to include benefits to children and the factors that precipitated the shift. We focus on the major safety net programs for children in the United States: cash welfare, food stamps, health insurance, and tax credits, listed in Table 1. The new research has shown that there are large benefits of safety net programs to children over the long run, with many programs proving to be excellent public investments that have paid for themselves (Hendren and Sprung-Keyser 2020). These findings should prompt policymakers to reassess the tradeoff between disincentive effects for adults and benefits for children.

Table 1.

Major Safety Net Programs for Children in the United States

Program Description Share of caseload that is children Number of children served (2019, in millions)a Income eligibility Estimated annual expenditures on children (2019, in billions)b

Panel A. Major Programs (covered in this paper)
Medicaid/CHIP Health insurance 0.51 35.0 <185% FPL for pregnant women and infants, <133% FPL for children (varies by state) $115.4
EITC Tax credit for working families 0.74 33.0 (annual) <150–235% FPL (depends on # of kids) $56.6
Child Tax Credit Tax credit for families with children 1.00 $117.7
SNAP Food assistance through EBT card 0.44 19.9 <130% FPL $27.8
TANF Block grant 0.75 1.5 <16%–150% FPL (varies by state) $12.8c
AFDC (precursor to TANF, ended in 1995) Unconditional cash transfer 0.68 9.1 (1995) <185% of the state determined standard of need $40.0 (1996)
Panel B. Other Programs that Serve Children
Supplemental Security Income Cash transfer for aged and disabled 0.14 1.2 Countable income below $750/month $10.5
Public housingd Public housing and rental vouchers 0.45 4.5 (annual)e $8.5
Child Nutrition School meals programs 1.00 29.6f ≤130% FPL free and ≤185% FPL reduced price $22.3
Special
Supplemental
Food (WIC)
In-kind food assistance 0.76 4.8 <185% FPL for pregnant women and children <5 $4.8

Note: See online Appendix for sources.

a

Number of children served is average monthly in 2019 unless otherwise noted.

b

Annual expenditures equal federal spending on children, based on estimates in Hahn et al (2021), unless noted otherwise.

c

This spending is for the entire block grant. An estimated 26 percent of the block grant is spent on cash assistance (Bitler and Hoynes 2016).

d

Includes public housing and section 8 vouchers.

e

Includes all households, not limited to households with children.

f

Number of children served by school lunch program.

Background on the Safety Net

Improving child health and wellbeing was the main objective of the first wide-spread US safety net program, the Mothers’ Pension Program. In 1911, Illinois was the first state to enact such a program, with most states following soon thereafter, as illustrated by the timeline in Figure 3. These laws sought to provide mothers with dependent children (widows or those with incapacitated or incarcerated husbands) with an allowance that would enable children to remain at home and not be placed in institutional care or forced to work. Policymakers believed that this would, in turn, reduce child mortality and delinquency (Skocpol 1992).

Figure 3.

Figure 3

Evolution of Federal Anti-poverty Programs in the United States

Note: The Aid to Dependent Children Program’s name was changed to Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) in 1962.

During the Great Depression, states and counties were no longer able to fund their Mothers’ Pension programs. In response, as part of the Social Security Act of 1935, the federal government created the Aid to Dependent Children (ADC) program. This program became the template for what is known as “welfare” in the United States. Originally, the ADC program (renamed Aid to Families with Dependent Children, or AFDC, in 1962) gave mothers cash on the basis of the number and ages of their children, as well as on the perceived needs of the family, which were assessed by social workers with substantial discretion. In most states, women were required to stay home (and not work) as a condition of the transfers. This approach was eventually replaced with a more formal system that guaranteed a minimum income, not a minimum transfer. As a result, the transfer was phased out at a very steep rate (referred to as the “benefit reduction rate”) as beneficiaries earned income: The cash payments they received from the program decreased anywhere from 66 percent to 100 percent for every $1 of earnings. In practice, benefits varied substantially by state and were quite modest; for example, in 1996 (the last year of the AFDC program before it was restructured and renamed as Temporary Assistance for Needy Families) maximum benefits averaged 35 percent of the federal poverty line across states (Safawi and Reyes 2021).

The safety net expanded substantially in the 1960s with President Lyndon Johnson’s War on Poverty. Two additional in-kind programs to help the poor were established: food stamps and Medicaid (Bailey and Danziger 2013). Food stamps were provided to poor families to guarantee access to appropriate nutrition. Medicaid established free health insurance for poor families with children (and through later expansions, to the near-poor). There were also changes to the ADC program beginning as early as the 1950s and continuing into the 1960s and 1980s, with a goal of promoting work among mothers and lowering welfare dependency.

In the 1990s, two important policy changes pushed the safety net even further towards more work-based assistance (Hoynes and Schanzenbach 2018). The first was the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996, commonly known as the welfare reform act, which replaced AFDC with Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) and significantly changed both the funding and requirements for the program. In the AFDC program, the federal government matched states’ spending on cash assistance (at 50 percent or higher rates), whereas the new TANF program provided states with a block grant that was fixed in nominal terms and did not increase with enrollment (or prices). States have great flexibility in how to spend these funds. Finally, TANF imposed federal lifetime limits of 60 months for cash assistance and instituted work and training requirements for recipients, though states can choose longer or, more commonly, shorter lifetime limits.

The second major change was the significant expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) in the early to mid-1990s and the creation of the Child Tax Credit in 1997. The EITC, first established in 1975, is a refundable tax credit for low-income working families with both eligibility and benefits increasing with the number of dependent children. Families with earned income pay lower taxes as a result and receive refund checks if their credit exceeds taxes owed. Families without earned income are not eligible. The program grew considerably in both eligibility and benefit levels starting in 1987 and accelerating during the 1990s. As a result of the expansion of the EITC and with the introduction of TANF, the cash-based social safety net became conditional on work. Like the EITC, the Child Tax Credit is a conditional tax credit received annually when individuals pay taxes. Individuals with little or no tax liability must have at least $2,500 of annual earned income to qualify for the refundable portion of the credit.

Overall, the changes in cash assistance and the growth of the tax-based social safety net in the 1990s shifted focus from income support toward work-based assistance, and consequently the distribution of households receiving assistance moved away from the poorest households toward the near-poor (Hoynes and Schanzenbach 2018).

The Child Safety Net Today

Today, the largest safety net program for children is Medicaid, which currently provides health insurance to 35 million low-income children at an estimated cost of $115 billion. (This total includes the Children’s Health Insurance Program, introduced in 1996, which is targeted toward poor children.) Like AFDC and TANF, Medicaid is a state program that is regulated and partly funded at the federal level. Because the program covers health care costs, the actual value of the transfer to children varies greatly depending on the extent to which they use health care resources and how states determine eligibility and generosity.

The EITC is the second largest safety net program for children, providing an estimated $56 billion in tax credits for families with children. It currently serves 33 million children in families with at least one working parent, transferring an annual credit worth $3,204 on average. The Child Tax Credit is also large in terms of dollars spent, but most of the funds go to children that are not in poor families.

Next in size is the food stamp program—renamed as the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP) program in 2008—which serves roughly 20 million children at a cost of $30 billion. SNAP average monthly benefits are about $130 per person.1 The United States spends another $45 billion on other in-kind programs for poor children, including housing, nutrition, and help for the disabled, as shown in Panel B of Table 1.

The traditional welfare program (TANF) is very modest today, currently serving 1.5 million children at a cost of about $13 billion for the federal block grant. Both expenditures and caseloads for this program are lower today than in 1995 (as shown in Table 1). Moreover, there has been a movement away from cash assistance, with only 22 percent of TANF funds in 2020 being spent in this way, compared with 71 percent in 1997, pre-TANF (Bitler and Hoynes 2016; Safawi and Reyes 2021). The reductions in caseloads cannot be explained by reductions in the number of poor children: in 2019, for every 100 families with children in poverty, 23 participated in TANF, compared with 68 prior to TANF. The median monthly maximum benefit for a single-parent family of three is $498 (about 30 percent of the poverty level). In practice, many poor families receive less than the maximum.

Evolution of Research on the Safety Net for Households with Children

The policy changes we have discussed were accompanied (or perhaps influenced) by important trends in the research on the impact of safety net programs. To characterize this evolution, we created a database of all articles employing empirical analyses of our core safety net programs (those listed in Panel A of Table 1) and published in the top general interest and field journals in economics since 1968. We identified 239 articles on the topic that we classify as estimating either negative incentive effects or benefits.2 Of all the safety net programs, Medicaid received the most attention from economists, accounting for 41 percent of all articles, followed by traditional welfare programs (AFDC/TANF) at 34 percent, and SNAP at 18 percent. Overall, only 40 percent of papers estimated benefits from these programs.

Figure 4 summarizes the number of papers published by decade and by objective. From the 1970s through the 2000s, the focus of economic research was the incentive effects of programs: prior to 2010, less than 27 percent of all articles documented benefits. Strikingly, in the last decade the research on benefits of safety net programs has taken off, with 2.5 articles on benefits for every article on incentives. This section describes the factors that led to this evolution.

Figure 4.

Figure 4

Research Articles on Incentive and Benefit Effects of Anti-Poverty Programs

Note: Data compiled by the authors. 2010 includes publications through 2020. See notes to Appendix Table 1 for details.

Early Research on Safety Net Programs: Emphasis on Negative Incentive Effects

The optimal welfare program balances the benefits of increased consumption against the cost of the work disincentives it creates (Mirrlees 1971). For decades, in fact since the creation of the Mothers’ Pension programs, concerns have been expressed by politicians and academics that welfare programs create disincentives for maintaining “traditional” family structures of marriage and work. Indeed, the theoretical predictions from standard economic models are unambiguous: The availability of a minimum “guarantee” of income and a benefit reduction rate is predicted to reduce employment and hours worked among female-headed households. Moreover, because the benefit increased with the number of dependent children in the household and declined with the presence of a married partner, this benefit schedule also created incentives to remain single and to have more children.

These concerns increased in the post-World War II years as a result of three broader demographic changes. First, the fraction of children growing up in single-parent households increased dramatically from 9 percent in 1960 to 20 percent in 1980 (US Census Bureau 2021). An increasingly large share of recipients were mothers who had never married (rather than divorced or widowed). Second, a larger share of recipients were Black, in part because many Black people migrated North, where welfare programs were more generous, and also because civil rights efforts were undertaken to increase access to welfare programs that had been systematically denied to Black people (Nadasen 2007). In contrast, prior to World War II, most recipients were white widows. In 1938, 48 percent of children on ADC were living with widowed mothers; by 1961 only 8 percent were. In 1938, 14 percent of the recipients were Black, but this share rose to 38 percent by 1956 and 44 percent by 1961 (Soule and Zylan 1997). Many observers believed that this growth in single-headed families was directly related to the incentives and generosity of AFDC in particular, a program whose expenditures and roles grew dramatically in the postwar years. Third, female labor-force participation among women with children rose steadily, in what Goldin (2006) labeled “the quiet revolution.” This shift raised the possibility that women with children could be self-sufficient and less dependent on a safety net but were not doing so because of the incentives imbedded in the welfare programs.

One major effort to assess the validity of these concerns was the “income maintenance experiments,” four large-scale randomized experiments designed to assess the work disincentives of increasing the benefits and the benefit reduction rate of the AFDC program: in New Jersey (1968–72); North Carolina and Iowa (1969–73); Gary, Indiana (1971–74); and Seattle and Denver (1971–1982). These experiments, which economists were influential in designing and evaluating, randomized the income guarantee and the benefit reduction rate to a subset of families for three to ten years and tracked the resulting labor supply of the recipients. The experiments also included randomized subsidies for counseling and training. Although the results generally confirmed the predictions of economic theory that larger benefits and higher implicit tax rates lowered work, the estimated effects were surprisingly modest (for example, Robins 1985).

By 1992, the accumulated empirical evidence on the negative incentive effects of welfare was the subject of a review and synthesis in the Journal of Economic Literature (Moffitt 1992). Moffitt motivated the review with a reference in the introduction to the concerns of policymakers and the general public: “The US welfare system has been considered by many observers to be in a state of crisis since the late 1960s.” He cites two proximate causes of this crisis: the large growth in caseloads; and the implications of the growth “for possible long-term welfare dependency” and marriage disincentives that were seen as likely responsible for the growth in poor single-parent households over this period.

The available research at that time showed that the AFDC program generated “nontrivial” disincentives to work. For every $1 in additional AFDC benefits, earnings were reduced by 37 cents. Though these disincentives seem strong, Moffitt (1992) concludes “the work disincentives of the program have little effect on the size of the caseload itself.” That is, even in the absence of the AFDC program, most women would have earnings that lie below the eligibility threshold. It is unclear why the labor supply responses to the negative work incentive in the welfare program are not as large as economists predicted. With respect to incentive effects regarding marriage and fertility, the results seem weak. As Moffitt (1992) summarizes: “The failure to find strong [cash] benefit effects is the most notable characteristic of this literature.”

Incorporating Benefits to Children in the Short Run

Absent from the Moffitt (1992) review is any reference to the potential benefits of cash assistance to the children of the recipients.3 The only reference to impacts on children in the review is to a small number of studies that estimate intergenerational welfare dependency. Indeed, the literature at the time included very few papers on the question, as Figure 4 shows. In our database, only two studies investigated effects of the influential income maintenance experiments on children in the 1970s (Maynard 1977; Maynard and Murnane 1979). Although these studies found that the experiment increased the education of children and young adults (at least in some samples), these findings were mostly ignored by policymakers and researchers alike. Perhaps economists ignored these because the popular Mirrlees (1971) framework is static, only considering the immediate consumption value of the transfers and ignoring any potential long-term benefits for children.

Starting in the mid-1990s, however, economists began to widen the focus of research on safety net programs to consider effects on household members, particularly children. One of the first papers in this new line of inquiry was “Welfare and Child Health: The Link between AFDC Participation and Birth Weight” (Currie and Cole 1993). As in Moffitt’s (1992) review, the authors motivate the paper with a reference to policy-making. They mention that many states had recently sought either to freeze or reduce payments in their AFDC programs, but were doing so “in a vacuum, because the effects of maternal participation on the wellbeing of their children has received little attention” (p. 971). Using a newly available data source containing information on welfare participation and child health—the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth panel—Currie and Cole (1993) estimated that AFDC benefits during pregnancy increased birth weights.

A second early example of research on the benefits of the social safety net to children comes from Medicaid. This too was motivated by policy debate: national health insurance reform was being debated in the United States in the mid-1990s. To shed light on the potential benefits of legislation that would expand health insurance universally, Currie and Gruber (1996a, b) studied the impact of the expansions in the Medicaid program in the 1980s which made more women and children eligible for the program. They found that increases in Medicaid coverage for pregnant women reduced infant mortality and the share of babies born of low birth weight (below 2,500 grams). These Medicaid expansions, which doubled the number of children eligible for Medicaid between 1984 and 1992, increased medical utilization and lowered child mortality. Since then, researchers have documented positive benefits of other safety net programs (the EITC and SNAP) during pregnancy on birth outcomes (for example, Strully, Rehkopf, and Xuan 2010; Hoynes, Miller, and Simon 2015; Almond, Hoynes, and Schanzenbach 2011).

Yet another set of early studies was made possible because of a series of randomized control trials of state welfare reforms in the early 1990s. Prior to the federal welfare reform that replaced AFDC with TANF in 1996, many states received waivers to reform their AFDC programs. Randomized control trials were used to examine impacts of these state reforms (Karoly and Grogger 2005). While the first reports focused on effects on earnings and welfare participation, several papers extended that work to examine impacts of welfare reform on children, including health and school achievement (Gennetian et al. 2002; Morris, Gennetian, and Duncan 2005; Duncan, Morris, and Rodrigues 2011).

Linking Early Childhood with Long-Run Outcomes

Early work on how safety net programs like AFDC, Medicaid, food stamps, and the Earned Income Tax Credit affected child outcomes focused on birth outcomes, possibly because of data availability (birth weight and infant death are reported for all births in the vital registration systems) and also because it is easier to identify the effects of events that take place during the short gestation period. Advances in three areas of research helped to spur researchers’ interest in examining the long-run effects of safety net use in childhood: research examining the long-run effects of preschool programs, examination of the long-run effects in utero and early-life circumstances, and work documenting low levels of economic mobility in the United States. We discuss each of these in turn.

Two influential and highly studied randomized control trials of preschool programs were conducted by psychologists in the 1960s and 1970s: the Perry Preschool Project and Abecedarian. These programs randomized children from disadvantaged households to high-quality preschool programs and followed them for 21 (Abecedarian) or 40 years (Perry Preschool). Both studies found substantial effects on academic achievement among children in the K–12 period, though these were not always statistically significant. Studies investigating participants as adults, however, showed a broad range of long-run benefits: Children randomized into the high-quality preschool program were more likely to complete high school, earn a bachelor’s degree, and earn more in the labor market (Berruetta-Clement et al. 1984; Schweinhart and Weikart 1997a, b; Schweinhart et al. 2005; Heckman et al. 2010). Based on these long-run findings, cost-benefit analyses implied returns on investment on the order of 7–10 percent (Heckman et al. 2010). Importantly, many of the largest effects were not on educational outcomes, but on health and behavioral outcomes, with two-thirds of the financial returns coming from a reduction in criminal activity (Belfield et al. 2006). However, there were legitimate concerns over the generalizability of these findings. They had small sample sizes—around 100 participants in each study—all drawn from very poor families and with low cognitive test scores at baseline.

Following this work, several studies emerged evaluating the Head Start program, a program that provides free preschool for poor children, also pioneered by psychologists. Like the work estimating the impact of AFDC and Medicaid participation on birth outcomes, the work on Head Start also begins with a discussion of policymakers’ desires to increase funding for Head Start even though “a careful reading of the literature reveals that credible studies demonstrating the lasting effects of Head Start are limited” (Currie and Thomas 1995, p. 341). The initial research documented short-term benefits as measured by improved test scores for children who participated compared to their siblings who did not (Currie and Thomas 1995). Interestingly, studies document significant fading of gains in the medium term (Puma et al. 2012), but significant long-term gains in educational attainment and earnings (Deming 2009; Garces, Thomas, and Currie 2002; Bailey et al. 2020).

A number of influential lessons emerged from this literature. First, there can be long-term positive benefits associated with high-quality preschool programs, even if short- or medium-run effects are small or statistically insignificant. Second, we need to broaden our understanding of outcomes beyond a narrow focus on cognitive skills (like test scores) when considering child development, as there are large sizable returns to other forms of human capital. Third, accounting for both long-term effects and effects across a range of outcomes changes our evaluation of the desirability of these programs.

Similar lessons emerged from a different literature. In the early 2000s, economists began generating evidence linking in utero conditions, and birth weight, to long-term outcomes of social and economic significance. In particular, a seminal paper by Almond (2006) investigated whether children in the womb during the 1918 Spanish flu pandemic suffered negative consequences as a result of exposure to the virus in utero. Though epidemiologists had previously linked negative in utero environments and lower birth weight with worse health later in life (Barker et al. 1989), Almond (2006) showed that in utero flu exposure also lowered individuals’ economic well-being as measured by educational attainment, disability, and earnings later in life. Many subsequent papers (reviewed in this journal by Almond and Currie 2011) have confirmed that exposure to the negative shocks in utero had negative long-term consequences for economic outcomes in adulthood.

A related line of research established a causal relationship between neonatal health and long-run outcomes using exogenous variation in birth weight within pairs of twins raised in the same household (Behrman and Rosenzweig 2004; Black, Devereux, and Salvanes 2007). The latter found that the effects of increased birth weight on newborn babies were much smaller than the long-term impacts on IQ, education, and earnings. This difference in findings (small short-run effects, but considerable long-run effects) further underscores the importance of examining multiple outcomes at different points in time to better understand how environments in early life influence child development.

This literature coincided with a third strand of research examining the relationship between paternal and child income. This work exploited new sources of data and documented much greater intergenerational correlations in earnings than had previously been estimated (Solon 1992): children of rich parents were much more likely to grow up to be rich than the children of poor parents. This research, since confirmed using new and better data, including that derived from IRS tax data (Chetty et al. 2014), implied lower rates of economic mobility in the United States, providing even more impetus for researchers to better understand how economic conditions in childhood shaped future outcomes.

Overall, this literature has led to a large number of papers investigating not only in utero shocks, but also how parental circumstances and policies in childhood affect economic and long-term well-being. In their extensive recent review, Almond, Currie, and Duque (2018) discuss the evidence on the long-term effects of childhood conditions, including the effects of policies and parental behaviors, not just external disease or environmental insults. This extended beyond programs like Head Start, explicitly targeting human capital investments, to include social safety net programs such as food stamps, cash assistance, and the EITC, in which the primary recipient was an adult or family.

Recent Evidence on the Long-Run Benefits of Safety Net Programs for Children

New studies on the long-run impact of safety net programs have been made possible by advances in data collection and greater availability of data linking participation in safety net programs during childhood with long-term outcomes.

In an example of creatively accessing administrative data, Brown, Kowalski, and Lurie (2020) exploit tax data to estimate the long-term impact of Medicaid eligibility in childhood for children born 1981–1984 on a host of outcomes measured at ages 19–28. The authors find that those eligible for Medicaid in childhood enroll in college at higher rates, delay their fertility, experience reduced mortality, collect fewer EITC benefits, and pay higher taxes. Based only on the increased tax revenue, the authors estimate the government recoups roughly $0.58 for every dollar spent on Medicaid eligibility in childhood. These findings were confirmed by Goodman-Bacon (2021), who finds that children who gained eligibility for Medicaid when the program was first introduced (1966–70) had better health and improved economic outcomes as adults. He concludes: “Childhood Medicaid coverage for these cohorts has therefore saved more than twice its cost.”4

Other work that uses existing data creatively to estimate long-term benefits of a safety net program on children is that of Hoynes, Schanzenbach, and Almond (2016) and Bailey et al. (2020). Hoynes, Schanzenbach, and Almond (2016) link existing data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics on individuals born 1956–1981 with information on the staggered roll-out of the food stamp program across counties between 1961 and 1974. The authors estimate that gaining eligibility for food stamps during childhood improved long-term adult health and increased economic self-sufficiency among women. Bailey et al. (2020) use a similar identification strategy and take advantage of new linking technologies and data available at the US Census Bureau. They find that access to food stamps in early childhood leads to increases in completed education, earnings, neighborhood quality, and home ownership as well as reductions in poverty, mortality, and incarceration. In both these studies, the gains are large and increasing in length of exposure between conception and age five, after which there appear to be few effects, suggesting that early childhood may be a sensitive window for nutritional inputs.

Finally, Aizer et al. (2016) is an example of recent research that relies on the development of a new dataset to estimate the long-term impact of safety net programs. The authors collected and digitized data from historical archives that included information on all applicants to the Mothers’ Pension (1991–1935) program, and linked this information with mortality data, the 1940 Census, and World War II enlistment records for each boy in the sample. They estimate a positive long-term impact of the original welfare program on children’s longevity, educational attainment, and earnings in young adulthood.

A number of other recent papers document these kinds of long-term benefits. How does this new information affect our evaluation of safety net programs? Recent work by Hendren and Sprung-Keyser (2020) systematically estimates the marginal value of public funds, taking into account the multiple long-term fiscal consequences of safety net programs. They document that programs targeted toward children have very large returns and essentially pay for themselves, in contrast to policies that target adults.

Implications for Policy-Making: Congressional Budget Office Scoring

How does research on the safety net translate into policy-making? Consider how the Congressional Budget Office scores policy proposals: Since 1975, every major piece of federal legislation has been evaluated by the CBO in an effort “to assess the effects on the economy of ‘major’ legislation that Congressional authorizing committees approve and to incorporate those effects into the agency’s 10-year cost estimates” [emphasis added]. To do so, the CBO generates predictions for the overall cost of the legislation:

Cost estimates show how federal outlays and revenues would change if legislation was enacted and fully implemented as proposed—compared with what future spending and revenues would be under current law. Each estimate also includes a statement about the costs of any new federal mandates that the legislation would impose on state, local, or tribal governments or on the private sector.”5

This estimate—known as the CBO score—considers behavioral responses of individuals, firms, and local governments to the proposed legislation in calculating outlays and revenue.

A March 2015 report, “The Effects of Potential Cuts in SNAP Spending on Households with Different Amounts of Income,” illustrates the approach of the Congressional Budget Office to evaluating different policy options regarding a major safety net program, the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program—also known as “food stamps.” The main objective of this CBO (2015) analysis was to understand how three policies (reducing the maximum benefit by 13 percent, increasing the benefit reduction rate from 30 to 49 percent, and reducing the monthly income limit for eligibility from 130 to 67 percent of the federal poverty line), would affect outlays (costs) and household income, with the latter also potentially affecting tax revenue.

In the analysis, the CBO considered how a reduction in food stamp benefits would reduce direct outlays and affect parental labor supply. In predicting that labor supply would increase in response to benefit reductions, the CBO report cited Hoynes and Schanzenbach (2012), showing that after the food stamp program was introduced, female single heads of households worked fewer hours.

The Congressional Budget Office report did not, however, incorporate any predictions regarding changes in the benefits of participation associated with reducing SNAP participation. The CBO (2015) report concludes: “Participation in SNAP may have other consequences, such as effects on recipients’ health or nutrition, but evidence has so far been inconclusive” (p. 6). At the time of the report, however, evidence that participation in the food stamp program decreased the probability of low birth weight by between 5–11 percent did exist (Almond, Hoynes, and Schanzenbach 2011).

Why wasn’t this information included in the Congressional Budget Office report, given what we know about the short- and long-run benefits of reducing low birth weight on a number of important social and economic outcomes, including employment and earnings? A number of factors likely contribute to the omission. First, the CBO (as well as most economics researchers, historically) maintains a more narrow view of human capital that focuses on education and job training, areas in which the research linking skills with earnings is better developed. While the concept of “skills” with returns in the labor market expanded to include physical health, mental health, and other soft skills and behaviors in economics research, these concepts do not yet seem to have been fully incorporated into CBO estimation. One reason may be that measuring the exact rate of return to these other aspects of human capital is more complicated than measuring the private return to an additional year of schooling, which is now well established (Card 1999).

Second, the evidence presented in Almond, Hoynes, and Schanzenbach (2011), Hoynes, Schanzenbach, and Almond (2016), and Bailey et al. (2020) is based on historical data from the 1960s and 1970s. This generates concerns about generalizability to the present.

Third, and perhaps most importantly, the Congressional Budget Office is tasked with producing estimates over a ten-year window. Many of the returns to investments in children are not realized for many years, once the children complete their education, attain young adulthood, and enter the labor market. Thus, even if there were consensus on the long-run benefits of a program (which might need to be predicted if a program is new), the long-run benefits outside the ten-year window would not be included in the CBO scoring. In contrast, the costs of the program do register in the ten-year scoring window, as do any potential parental work disincentives. In sum, we capture the short-run costs but omit the long-term benefits to children because of the ten-year scoring window.6 This structure inhibits the ability of policymakers to take full advantage of recent advances in the economic research exploring and documenting the long-run benefits of safety net programs, which often exceed their short-run costs by a wide margin (Hendren and Sprung-Keyser 2020).

A comparison of the estimated marginal value of public funds for the first welfare program in the United States, the Mothers’ Pension program, in the short- and long-run provides an illustrative example of how time horizon influences this calculation. (The “marginal value of public funds” of a policy or program is calculated by estimating the benefits of the policy or program to recipients, measured as their willingness to pay, divided by the policy’s net cost including long-term impacts on the government’s budget.) The main estimated benefits of the Mothers’ Pension program were increases in completed schooling and earnings in early adulthood as well as increases in longevity, which are not realized until many years after benefit receipt. In contrast, the main costs of the program are realized earlier in the form of direct outlays and delayed time to remarriage among the mothers. If one only considers the latter, the marginal value of public funds calculation is below 1 (at 0.84), suggesting that the costs of the program exceed its benefits. However, once benefits to children are considered, the marginal value of public funds rises to more than 5, suggesting that the program generates substantial benefits relative to the costs (Aizer, Eli, and Lleras-Muney 2020). The benefits are large, in part, because they accrue over many years and because there are substantial health benefits in addition to labor market benefits. Similarly, for the food stamp program, if one were only to consider the impact on adults, the marginal value of public funds would be 0.54. But once one considers evidence that food stamps increase the earnings and life expectancy and reduce incarceration of children, the marginal value of public funds including these impacts on children rises to 56 (Bailey et al. 2020).

In sum, these programs represent investments in the human capital of children, not simply transfers to adults that increase consumption. The returns of these investments, like those of other investments in human capital, can only be properly measured over the entire lifetime of the recipients and should be comprehensive in nature, including gains to schooling, health, and other aspects of human well-being.

How to Make Research More Informative for Policy-Making

There are two key areas in which future economic research can help improve the design and scope of the safety net for children in the United States: understanding why the estimated impacts of various programs on children seem to differ across settings; and shedding light on whether and how evidence based on short-term impacts can be used to predict long-term outcomes. We discuss each in turn.

Understanding Why Estimated Treatment Effects Differ across Settings

The effects of safety net programs on children’s outcomes often vary based on population and environment. This makes it difficult for policymakers to generalize or extrapolate from one setting to another, and it impairs their ability to target programs to those likely to benefit the most. For instance, we have highlighted work showing a positive impact of cash transfers through the safety net on child outcomes. But not all research finds positive effects of cash or in-kind transfers to the poor in the long run. For example, Price and Song (2018) find no long-term effects of the Seattle-Denver Income Maintenance Experiment on children’s longevity or on economic outcomes in adulthood. But it is not clear why.

Documenting heterogeneity in the effects of the programs across settings should be accompanied by an exploration of its sources. A first likely source of heterogeneity is differences in the counterfactual environment faced by families eligible for safety net programs. For example, the benefits to children from participation in Head Start have been shown to depend on what the alternative source of care is, with the benefits of Head Start increasing for those whose alternative environment is more deprived or of lower quality (Kline and Walters 2016; Cascio 2021). Likewise, Medicaid expansions are more effective for the lowest-income mothers, which likely reflects the fact that higher-income mothers were more likely to have had earlier access to private insurance which Medicaid crowded out (Currie and Gruber 1996a).

A second potential source of heterogeneous effects is complementarities across multiple programs (program complementarity, the idea that one program is more effective if a child is also participating in another program), or across investments early and later in life (dynamic complementarity), for which the evidence is scant (Almond, Currie, and Duque 2018). Generating empirical evidence of complementarities across environments or programs is challenging due to the difficulty of obtaining plausibly exogenous variation in multiple inputs across time or programs. Johnson and Jackson (2019) make such an attempt and find that school finance reform is far more effective at raising student test scores if students had access to Head Start programming, and also that Head Start is more effective if followed by resource-rich educational programming. This might help explain why Black children have been found, in general, to benefit less in the long run than other groups from anti-poverty programs: If Black families are more likely to attend under-resourced or segregated schools, they may receive lower levels of complementary investments (for example, Garces, Thomas, and Currie 2002; Bailey et al. 2020).

Treatment effects may also vary because of interaction effects with labor market conditions or the housing market. For some children, this means that discrimination may also play an important role. Discrimination in the housing market, for example, could hinder the ability of Black and Latino families to leave high-poverty/high-crime neighborhoods with under-resourced schools. Discrimination in the labor market can reduce the returns to skills developed in childhood for Black and Latino youth. Discrimination may reduce access to safety net programs. A better understanding of observed differences by race and the role of discrimination is needed.

Recent work has attempted to better understand treatment effect heterogeneity by pooling results of similar experiments across settings in the spirit of meta-analysis (for example, Dehejia, Pop-Eleches, and Samii 2021; Meager 2019; Page 2021). These efforts highlight the difficulty of conducting such assessments. Two barriers include non-standard measurement of outcomes across studies and lack of adequate information to allow researchers to pool the results across studies.7 Thus, standardized measurement of outcomes and providing more information about sample characteristics would help. Another strategy is to leverage newly available administrative data sets. Large samples allow researchers to estimate treatment effects more precisely for different subgroups. New machine learning methods designed to work with large data, such as those in Wager and Athey (2018), can be used to investigate heterogeneity systematically. Machine learning techniques allow researchers with large datasets to uncover new patterns of heterogeneity that are not obvious in advance in a statistically sound way.

Projecting Long-Term Treatment Effects from Short-Term Evidence

Some childhood shocks appear to have effects that “fade out” initially, only to re-appear later in life (Almond, Currie, and Duque 2018). An important next step for research is to improve our understanding of the extent to which evidence on short- and medium-term outcomes can be used to make long-term projections. This issue is particularly important given the short-term incentives inherent in policymaking. Programs that show no benefits in the short run tend to be eliminated, but these programs may ultimately “pay for themselves” if they generate long-term benefits. Conversely, programs with short-term benefits receive more political support, even if these benefits turn out to be short-lived. An exciting econometric development in this area is the use of new techniques that combine short-term evidence from randomized trials with long-term observational data to project long-run outcomes (Athey, Chetty, and Imbens 2020; Aizer, Eli, and Lleras-Muney 2021; García et al. 2020).

A related need is to develop a better understanding of what explains these dynamic effects. Estimated effects may “appear” at different points in time either because of dynamics in the underlying process of skill production (for example, a common pattern is that risky behavior does not manifest until adolescence and then declines in adulthood) or because data limitations prevent researchers from effectively measuring outcomes at different points in time. For example, measures of noncognitive skills are often crude, like measures of criminal involvement, or based on subjective measures, like answers on a questionnaire used to develop a behavioral problem index. As Guttmannova, Szanyi, and Cali (2008) discuss, these behavioral checklists often do poorly at characterizing the behavior of racial minorities and low-income children. To address this, economic research may benefit from insights from psychology or neurobiology regarding the timelines of child development. This can serve as a basis for collection of data on outcomes that better reflect the underlying developmental process.

A complementary effort is the development and empirical assessment of models that can generate the types of dynamic treatment effects that are observed in the data. The most important work in this area comes from the model of Cunha and Heckman (2007), which codified a number of existing insights and generated new ones about the formation of skill. Most notably their model allows for “sensitive windows,” during which certain skills are best produced, and for “dynamic complementarities,” where skills produced at an early stage raise the productivity of investment at subsequent stages. Another recent example comes from Lleras-Muney and Moreau (2020), who provide a model of health and mortality at the population level, where in utero shocks or differences in socioeconomic status throughout life can result in treatment effects that are U-shaped over time, as the literature has documented. This model accurately predicts the dynamic long-term effects of graduating in a recession on mortality (Schwandt and von Wachter 2019). Parallel models could be developed for other types of interventions and outcomes. Most importantly, empirical evidence in support of these models is needed.

Why Is the US Child Poverty Rate Still So High and What Can We Do about It?

The growth of the social safety net (particularly through tax credits and in-kind transfers) has played an important role in reducing child poverty but has not eliminated it, as shown earlier in Figure 2. In order to have large impacts on child poverty, a better understanding of the causes of poverty and how safety net programs influence poverty is needed.

There are multiple candidate explanations for the continued high rate of child poverty. The first and most obvious is that the United States spends less on assistance for families with children than other high-income countries, as discussed previously. The question is why. It’s not necessarily that the United States is unwilling to spend on social programs: The United States spends considerably more on the elderly than on children—7 percent of GDP for 54 million seniors compared with 0.5 percent of GDP for 73 million children—and indeed spends more on seniors (as a percent of GDP) than many other OECD countries. Moreover, the main programs for the elderly (Social Security retirement benefits and Medicare) are universal, while child benefits are income-targeted and include conditionality (such as work requirements). Indeed, initial estimates suggest that the United States reduced child poverty significantly in 2020 and 2021 through the expanded Child Tax Credit and other efforts related to pandemic relief, but the relief is temporary, with most of it expiring after 2021 (Urban Institute 2021; CCPSP 2021).

Several factors may explain the disparity in US public funding between children and the elderly. The first is “senior power,” which refers to the political influence of the elderly. Seniors vote in large numbers—71 percent voter turnout in the 2016 election compared with 46 percent for ages 18 through 29—and are very well organized. The American Association of Retired People (AARP) boasted 38 million members and $1.7 billion in revenue in 2019. It constitutes a powerful lobby. On the other hand, children do not vote and there is no organization that represents the needs of children to rival the AARP. The Children’s Defense Fund, one of the major groups advocating for children in the United States, reported revenue of $17.8 million in 2019, just 1 percent of AARP revenue.

The second factor may be the racial and ethnic composition of the two populations. The elderly population in the United States is 77 percent white non-Hispanic, in contrast to children, who are slightly less than half white nonHispanic. From the onset, the generosity and universality of anti-poverty programs have been a function of the racial composition of potential recipients. In the Mothers’ Pension program, only 3 percent of all families receiving aid were Black, which was far less than what one would have predicted if aid were based solely on need (US Children’s Bureau 1933). Many New Deal safety net programs of the 1930s explicitly excluded workers in industries with high Black employment shares (Katznelson 2005). This bias persisted throughout the 20th century. The 1996 welfare reform, which gave states considerable discretion over spending, led to lower levels of cash assistance in states with higher shares of Black residents (Hardy, Samudra, and Davis 2019). Today, states with large Black populations have substantially less generous welfare programs (Urban Institute 2021). This evidence is consistent with the conclusion of Alesina, Sacerdote, and Glaeser (2001) that race is the “single most important predictor of support for welfare” in the United States (see also Luttmer 2001). This combination of lack of political power and racial and ethnic discrimination have likely influenced the divergence in public priority and policy for these two groups.

A third reason is likely tied to the complexity of the safety net today. Children from low-income US households are often served by more than one program, and these programs are not well-coordinated. For example, 92 percent of children on food stamps participate in at least one other program and one-third participate in two other safety net programs (King and Giefer 2021). A call to coordinate and streamline eligibility for multiple safety net programs is not new (Currie 2006). A coordinated and comprehensive approach could work in a US context. It is notable that two of the most prominent and successful early education interventions (the Abecedarian and Perry School programs) provided a comprehensive set of services to children and their families.

Fourth, it may well be that even though the safety net has benefitted children, this complicated set of policies is not the best approach to lowering child poverty. Poverty rates for children are responsive to business cycles, with strong demand for labor and rising rates of employment and wages resulting in significant declines in child poverty. Perhaps labor market policies that increase the earned income of poor families, such as raising the minimum wage (Derenoncourt and Montialoux 2021), could prove to be as (or more) successful as direct aid. Another fruitful direction for research is to assess the relative cost-effectiveness of multiple approaches to lowering child poverty.

Conclusion

The emphasis of economic research on disincentives may have adversely influenced policy. Economic research on the effects of safety net programs has been and continues to be extremely influential in policy-making. For many years, this research focused primarily on documenting the potential negative behavioral impacts of these programs, even if small. Policymakers responded by attempting to minimize these behavorial impacts. The same focus on quantifying negative incentive effects has also historically dominated the study of social insurance programs, such as health insurance and unemployment insurance. The economic research on these programs has likewise evolved to include benefits as well as costs. A new focus on the benefits of safety net programs on children—the intended beneficiaries of these programs—that incorporates evidence on their many long-term benefits can contribute to the design of better policies going forward.

Supplementary Material

Appendix Table 1

Figure 1.

Figure 1

Child Poverty Rates and Public Spending on Families in OECD Countries

Source: Data come from the OECD database and use the latest information available mostly from 2017–2019. Poverty Rate Data (OECD 2022b) are available at https://data.oecd.org/inequality/poverty-rate.htm. Family Spending Data (OECD 2022a) are available at https://data.oecd.org/socialexp/family-benefits-public-spending.htm.

Acknowledgments

We thank Raheem Chaudhry, Sungwoo Cho, and Ray Huang, who provided excellent research assistance. We also thank Janet Currie, Greg Duncan, Shari Eli, Peter Germanis, and Robert Moffitt for helpful comments on an earlier draft.

Footnotes

1

These figures are available from the US Department of Agriculture at https://www.fns.usda.gov/pd/supplemental-nutrition-assistance-program-snap.

2

See notes to online Appendix Table 1 for details on journals included and selection criteria.

3

The same evolution of the research, with an initial focus on the effects on work, occurred for analysis of the Earned Income Tax Credit. Initial studies examined impacts on work and marriage, with little focus on effects on children (Hotz and Scholz 2003; Nichols and Rothstein 2016).

4

Other recent work showing long term economic benefits of health insurance provision for children includes Cohodes et al. (2016), Miller and Wherry (2018), and Thompson (2017).

5

Accessed at CBO “Frequently Asked Questions About CBO Estimates” https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/ce-faq.

6

There are examples of programs that generated short-run effects that faded over the medium term, only to re-emerge when long-run outcomes were measured. This adds uncertainty to long-term projections.

7

Card, Kluve, and Weber (2018) make similar observations about the difficulty of conducting such research in their paper, which combines the results of 207 papers to investigate the effects of work training programs. Galama, Lleras-Muney, and van Kippersluis (2018) report similar difficulties when attempting to explain the heterogeneity in the estimates of the causal effects of education on health.

Contributor Information

Anna Aizer, Professor of Economics, Brown University, Providence, Rhode Island..

Hilary Hoynes, Professor of Economics and Public Policy, Goldman School of Public Policy, University of California at Berkeley, Berkeley, California..

Adriana Lleras-Muney, Professor of Economics, University of California Los Angeles, Los Angeles, California..

References

  1. Aizer Anna, Eli Shari, Ferrie Joseph, and Lleras-Muney Adriana. 2016. “The Long-Run Impact of Cash Transfers to Poor Families.” American Economic Review 106 (4): 935–71. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  2. Aizer Anna, Eli Shari, and Lleras-Muney Adriana. 2020. “The Incentive Effects of Cash Transfers to the Poor.” NBER Working paper 27523. [Google Scholar]
  3. Aizer Anna, Eli Shari, Lleras-Muney Adriana, and Lee Keyoung. 2020. “Do Youth Employment Programs Work? Evidence from the New Deal.” NBER Working Paper 27103. [Google Scholar]
  4. Alesina Alberto, Sacerdote Bruce, and Glaeser Edward. 2001. “Why Doesn’t the United States Have a European-Style Welfare State?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 32 (2): 187–278. [Google Scholar]
  5. Almond Douglas. 2006. “Is the 1918 Influenza Pandemic Over? Long-Term Effects of In Utero Influenza Exposure in the Post-1940 U.S. Population.” Journal of Political Economy 114 (4): 672–712. [Google Scholar]
  6. Almond Douglas, and Currie Janet. 2011. “Killing Me Softly: The Fetal Origins Hypothesis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 (3): 153–72. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  7. Almond Douglas, Currie Janet, and Duque Valentina. 2018. “Childhood Circumstances and Adult Outcomes: Act II.” Journal of Economic Literature 56 (4): 1360–446. [Google Scholar]
  8. Almond Douglas, Hoynes Hilary, and Schanzenbach Diane. 2011. “Inside the War on Poverty: The Impact of Food Stamps on Birth Outcomes.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 93 (2): 387–403. [Google Scholar]
  9. Athey Susan, Chetty Raj, and Imbens Guido. 2020. “Combining Experimental and Observational Data to Estimate Treatment Effects on Long Term Outcomes.” Unpublished. [Google Scholar]
  10. Bailey Martha J., and Danziger Sheldon, eds. 2013. Legacies of the War on Poverty. National Poverty Center Series on Poverty and Public Policy. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  11. Bailey MJ, Hilary W. Hoynes, Maya Rossin-Slater, and Reed Walker. 2020. “Is the Social Safety Net a Long-Term Investment? Large-Scale Evidence from the Food Stamps Program.” NBER Working Paper 26942. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  12. Barker DJ, Winter PD, Osmond C, Margetts B, and Simmonds SJ 1989. “Weight in Infancy and Death From Ischaemic Heart Disease.” Lancet 334 (8663): 577–80. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  13. Behrman Jere R., and Rosenzweig Mark R. 2004. “Returns to Birthweight.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (2): 586–601. [Google Scholar]
  14. Belfield CR, Nores M, Barnett S, and Schweinhart LJ 2006. “The High/Scope Perry Preschool Program: Cost-Benefit Analysis Using Data from the Age-40 Followup.” Journal of Human Resources 41 (1): 162–90. [Google Scholar]
  15. Berrueta-Clement JR, Schweinhart LJ, Barnett WS, Epstein AE, and Weikart DP 1984. Changed Lives: The Effects of the Perry Preschool Program on Youths through Age 19. Monographs of the High/Scope Educational Research Foundation. Ypsilanti: High/Scope Press. [Google Scholar]
  16. Bitler Marianne, and Hoynes Hilary. 2016. Strengthening Temporary Assistance for Needy Families. Washington, DC: The Hamilton Project. [Google Scholar]
  17. Black Sandra, Devereux Paul, and Salvanes Kjell G. 2007. “From the Cradle to the Labor Market? The Effect of Birth Weight on Adult Outcomes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (1): 409–39. [Google Scholar]
  18. Brown David W., Kowalski Amanda E., and Lurie Ithai Z. 2020. “Long-Term Impacts of Childhood Medicaid Expansions on Outcomes in Adulthood.” Review of Economic Studies 87 (2): 792–821. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. Card David. 1999. “The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3, Part A, edited by Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card, 1801–63. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Science. [Google Scholar]
  20. Card David, Kluve Jochen, and Weber Andrea. 2018. “What Works? A Meta Analysis of Recent Active Labor Market Program Evaluations.” Journal of the European Economic Association 16 (3): 894–931. [Google Scholar]
  21. Cascio Elizabeth U. 2021. “Early Childhood Education in the United States: What, When, Where, Who, How, and Why.” NBER Working Paper 28722. [Google Scholar]
  22. Columbia Center on Poverty and Social Policy (CCPS). 2021. Research Roundup of the Expanded Child Tax Credit: The First 6 Months. New York: Columbia Center on Poverty and Social Policy. [Google Scholar]
  23. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities (CBPP). 2021. Policy Basics: Temporary Assistance for Needy Families. Washington, DC: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. [Google Scholar]
  24. Chetty Raj, Hendren Nathaniel, Kline Patrick, Saez Emmanuel, and Turner Nicholas. 2014. “Is the United States Still a Land of Opportunity? Recent Trends in Intergenerational Mobility.” American Economic Review 104 (5): 141–47. [Google Scholar]
  25. Cohodes Sarah R., Grossman Daniel S., Kleiner Samuel A., and Lovenheim Michael F. 2016. “The Effect of Child Health Insurance Access on Schooling: Evidence from Public Insurance Expansions.” Journal of Human Resources 51 (3): 727–59. [Google Scholar]
  26. Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2015. The Effects of Potential Cuts in SNAP Spending on Households with Different Amounts of Income. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office. [Google Scholar]
  27. Cunha Flavio, and Heckman James. 2007. “The Technology of Skill Formation.” American Economic Review 97 (2): 31–47. [Google Scholar]
  28. Currie Janet. 2006. The Invisible Safety Net: Protecting the Nation’s Poor Children and Families. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  29. Currie Janet, and Cole Nancy. 1993. “Welfare and Child Health: The Link between AFDC Participation and Birth Weight.” American Economic Review 83 (4): 971–85. [Google Scholar]
  30. Currie Janet, and Gruber Jonathan. 1996. “Health Insurance Eligibility, Utilization of Medical Care, and Child Health.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (2): 431–66. [Google Scholar]
  31. Currie Janet, and Gruber Jonathan. 1996. “Saving Babies: The Efficacy and Cost of Recent Changes in the Medicaid Eligibility of Pregnant Women.” Journal of Political Economy 104 (6): 1263–96. [Google Scholar]
  32. Currie Janet, and Thomas Duncan. 1995. “Does Head Start Make a Difference?” American Economic Review 85 (3): 341–64. [Google Scholar]
  33. Dehejia Rajeev, Christian Pop-Eleches, and Cyrus Samii. 2021. “From Local to Global: External Validity in a Fertility Natural Experiment.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 39 (1): 217–43. [Google Scholar]
  34. Deming David. 2009. “Early Childhood Intervention and Life-Cycle Skill Development: Evidence from Head Start.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1 (3): 111–34. [Google Scholar]
  35. Derenoncourt Ellora, and Montialoux Claire. 2021. “Minimum Wages and Racial Inequality.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 136 (1): 169–228. [Google Scholar]
  36. Doyle Joseph J. Jr. 2007. “Child Protection and Child Outcomes: Measuring the Effects of Foster Care.” American Economic Review 97 (5): 1583–610. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  37. Duncan Greg J., Morris Pamela A., and Rodrigues Chris. 2011. “Does Money Really Matter? Estimating Impacts of Family Income on Young Children’s Achievement with Data from Random-Assignment Experiments.” Developmental Psychology 47 (5), 1263–79. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  38. Fox Liana, and Burns Kalee. 2021. The Supplemental Poverty Measure: 2020. Washington, DC: United States Census Bureau. [Google Scholar]
  39. Galama Titus, Adriana Lleras-Muney, and Hans van Kippersluis. 2018. “The Effect of Education on Health and Mortality: A Review of Experimental and Quasi-Experimental Evidence.” In Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance. [Google Scholar]
  40. Garces Eliana, Thomas Duncan, and Currie Janet. 2002. “Longer-Term Effects of Head Start.” American Economic Review 92 (4): 999–1012. [Google Scholar]
  41. García Jorge Luis, Heckman James, Duncan Ermini Leaf, and María José Prados. 2020. “Quantifying the Life-Cycle Benefits of an Influential Early-Childhood Program.” Journal of Political Economy 128 (7): 2502–41. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  42. Garfinkel Irwin, Sariscsany Laurel, Ananat Elizabeth, Collyer Sophie, and Wimer Christopher. 2021. “The Costs and Benefits of a Child Allowance.” Center on Poverty and Social Policy, February 18. www.povertycenter.columbia.edu/publication/2021/child-allowance/cost-benefit-analysis-discussion. [Google Scholar]
  43. Gennetian Lisa A., Duncan Greg J., Knox Virginia W., Vargas Wanda G., Clark-Kauffman Elizabeth, and London Andrew S. 2002. How Welfare and Work Policies for Parents Affect Adolescents: A Synthesis of Research. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation. [Google Scholar]
  44. Goldin Claudia. 2006. “The Quiet Revolution That Transformed Women’s Employment, Education, and Family.” American Economic Review 96 (2) 1–21. [Google Scholar]
  45. Goodman-Bacon Andrew. 2021. “The Long-Run Effects of Childhood Insurance Coverage: Medicaid Implementation, Adult Health, and Labor Market Outcomes.” American Economic Review 111 (8): 2550–93. [Google Scholar]
  46. Gruber Jonathan. 2003. “Medicaid.” In Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, edited by Moffitt Robert A., 15–77. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  47. Guttmannova Katarina, Szanyi Jason M., and Cali Philip W. 2008. “Internalizing and Externalizing Behavior Problem Scores: Cross-Ethnic and Longitudinal Measurement Invariance of the Behavior Problem Index.” Educational and Psychological Measurement 68 (4): 676–94. [Google Scholar]
  48. Hardy Bradley L., Samudra Rhucha, and Davis Jourdan A. 2019. “Cash Assistance in America: The Role of Race, Politics, and Poverty.” Review of Black Political Economy 46 (4): 306–24. [Google Scholar]
  49. Heckman James J., Seong Hyeok Moon, Rodrigo Pinto, Savelyev Peter A., and Yavitz Adam. 2010. “The Rate of Return to the HighScope Perry Preschool Program.” Journal of Public Economics 94 (1–2): 114–28. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  50. Hendren Nathaniel, and Sprung-Keyser Ben. 2020. “A Unified Welfare Analysis of Government Policies.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 135 (3): 1209–318. [Google Scholar]
  51. Hotz V. Joseph, and John Karl Scholz. 2003. “The Earned Income Tax Credit.” In Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, edited by Moffitt Robert A. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  52. Hoynes Hilary, Miller Doug, and Simon David. 2015. “Income, the Earned Income Tax Credit, and Infant Health.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7 (1): 172–211. [Google Scholar]
  53. Hoynes H, and Schanzenbach DW 2018. “Safety Net Investments in Children.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 89–150. [Google Scholar]
  54. Hoynes Hilary, Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach, and Douglas Almond. 2016. “Long-Run Impacts of Childhood Access to the Safety Net.” American Economic Review 106 (4): 903–34. [Google Scholar]
  55. Hoynes Hilary W., and Schanzenbach Douglas. 2009. “Consumption Responses to In-Kind Transfers: Evidence from the Introduction of the Food Stamp Program.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1 (4): 109–39. [Google Scholar]
  56. Hoynes Hilary W., and Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach. 2012. “Work Incentives and the Food Stamp Program.” Journal of Public Economics 96 (1–2): 151–62. [Google Scholar]
  57. Johnson Rucker C., and Jackson C. Kirabo. 2019. “Reducing Inequality through Dynamic Complementarity: Evidence from Head Start and Public School Spending.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 11 (4): 310–49. [Google Scholar]
  58. Karoly Lynn A., and Grogger Jeffrey. 2005. Welfare Reform: Effects of a Decade of Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
  59. Katznelson Ira. 2005. When Affirmative Action Was White: An Untold History of Racial Inequality in TwentiethCentury America. New York: Norton. [Google Scholar]
  60. King Michael D., and Giefer Katherine. 2021. Nearly a Third of Children Who Receive SNAP Participate in Two or More Additional Programs. Washington, DC: United States Census Bureau. [Google Scholar]
  61. Kline Patrick, and Walters Christopher R. 2016. “Evaluating Public Programs with Close Substitutes: The Case of Head Start.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (4): 1795–848. [Google Scholar]
  62. Lleras-Muney Adriana, and Moreau Flavien E. 2020. “A Unified Model of Cohort Mortality for Economic Analysis.” NBER Working Paper 28193. [Google Scholar]
  63. Luttmer Erzo F. 2001. “Group Loyalty and the Taste for Redistribution.” Journal of Political Economy 109 (3): 500–28. [Google Scholar]
  64. Mallar C. 1977. “The Educational and Labor Supply Responses of Young Adults on the Urban Graduated Work Incentive Experiment.” In The New Jersey Income Maintenance Experiment: Expenditures, Health, and Social behavior; and the Quality of the Evidence, Vol. III, edited by Watts HW and Rees A, 163–184. New York: Academic Press. [Google Scholar]
  65. Maynard Rebecca A. 1977. “Some Aspects of Income Distribution: The Effects of the Rural Income Maintenance Experiment on the School Performance of Children.” American Economic Review 67 (1): 370–75. [Google Scholar]
  66. Maynard Rebecca A., and Murnane Richard J. 1979. “The Effects of a Negative Income Tax on School Performance: Results of an Experiment.” Journal of Human Resources 14 (4): 463–76. [Google Scholar]
  67. Meager Rachael. 2019. “Understanding the Average Impact of Microcredit Expansions: A Bayesian Hierarchical Analysis of Seven Randomized Experiments.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 11 (1): 57–91. [Google Scholar]
  68. Miller Sarah, and Wherry Laura R. 2018. “The Long-Term Effects of Early Life Medicaid Coverage.” Journal of Human Resources 54 (3): 785–824. [Google Scholar]
  69. Mirrlees JA 1971. “An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation.” Review of Economic Studies 38 (2): 175–208. [Google Scholar]
  70. Moffitt Robert. 1992. “Incentive Effects of the U.S. Welfare System: A Review.” Journal of Economic Literature, 30 (1): 1–61. [Google Scholar]
  71. Morris Pamela A., Gennetian Lisa A., and Duncan Greg J. 2005. “Effects of Welfare and Employment Policies on Young Children: New Findings on Policy Experiments Conducted in the Early 1990s.” Social Policy Report 19 (2): 3–18. [Google Scholar]
  72. Nadasen Premilla. 2007. “From Widow to ‘Welfare Queen’: Welfare and the Politics of Race.” Black Women, Gender + Families 1 (2): 52–77. [Google Scholar]
  73. Nichols Austin, and Rothstein Jesse. 2016. “The Earned Income Tax Credit.” In Economics of Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, Vol. 1, edited by Moffitt Robert A. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  74. OECD. 2022a. “Family Benefits Public Spending (indicator).” OECD Data. doi: 10.1787/8e8b3273-en (accessed March 29, 2022). [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  75. OECD. 2022b. “Poverty Rate (indicator).” OECD Data. doi: 10.1787/0fe1315d-en (Accessed on March 29, 2022). [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  76. Page M. 2021. “What Have Economists Learned about Whether Money Matters to Child Well-Being?” Unpublished. [Google Scholar]
  77. Price David J., and Song Jae. 2018. “The Long-Term Effects of Cash Assistance.” Princeton University Working Paper 621. [Google Scholar]
  78. Puma Michael, Bell Stephen, Cook Ronna, Heid Camilla, Broene Pam, Jenkins Frank, Mashburn Andrew, and Downer Jason. 2012. Third Grade Follow-Up to the Head Start Impact Study. Washington, DC: Office of Planning, Research and Evaluation, Administration for Children and Families, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. [Google Scholar]
  79. Robins Philip. 1985. “A Comparison of the Labor Supply Findings from the Four Negative Income Tax Experiments.” Journal of Human Resources 20 (4): 567–82. [Google Scholar]
  80. Safawi Ali, and Reyes Cindy. 2021. States Must Continue Recent Momentum to Further Improve TANF Benefit Levels. Washington, DC: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities.. [Google Scholar]
  81. Schwandt Hannes, and Till von Wachter. 2019. “Unlucky Cohorts: Estimating the Long-Term Effects of Entering the Labor Market in a Recession in Large Cross-Sectional Data Sets.” Journal of Labor Economics 37 (S1): S161–S198. [Google Scholar]
  82. Schweinhart Lawrence J., Montie Jeanne, Xiang Zongping, W. Steven Barnett, Belfield Clive R., and Nores Milagros. 2005. Lifetime Effects: The High/Scope Perry Preschool Study Through Age 40. Monographs of the High/Scope Educational Research Foundation. Ypsilanti: High/Scope Press. [Google Scholar]
  83. Schweinhart Lawrence J., and Weikart David P. 1997. “The High/Scope Preschool Curriculum Comparison Study Through Age 23.” Early Childhood Research Quarterly 12: 117–43. [Google Scholar]
  84. Schweinhart Lawrence J., and Weikart David P. 1997. Lasting differences: The High/Scope Preschool Curriculum Comparison Study Through Age 23. Monographs of the High/Scope Educational Research Foundation. Ypsilanti: High/Scope Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  85. Skocpol Theda. 1992. Protecting Soldiers and Mothers: The Political Origins of Social Policy in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
  86. Solon Gary. 1992. “Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States.” American Economic Review 82 (3): 393–408. [Google Scholar]
  87. Soule Sarah A., and Zylan Yvonne. 1997. “Runaway Train? The Diffusion of State-Level Reform in ADC/AFDC Eligibility Requirements, 1940–1967.” American Journal of Sociology 103 (3). [Google Scholar]
  88. Strully Kate W., Rehkopf David H., and Xuan Ziming. 2010. “Effects of Prenatal Poverty on Infant Health: State Earned Income Tax Credits and Birth Weight.” American Sociological Review 75 (4): 534–62. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  89. Trisi Danilo, and Saenz Matt. 2021. Economic Security Programs Reduce Overall Poverty, Racial and Ethnic Inequities. Washington, DC: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. [Google Scholar]
  90. Urban Institute. 2021. 2021 Poverty Projections: Assessing the Impact of Benefits and Stimulus Measures. Washington, DC: Urban Institute. [Google Scholar]
  91. US Children’s Bureau. 1933. Mother’s Aid, 1931. Bureau Publication 220. Washington: US Govt. Print. Off. [Google Scholar]
  92. US Census Bureau. 2021. “Historical Living Arrangements of Children.” Current Population Survey. https://www.census.gov/data/tables/time-series/demo/families/children.html (accessed on January 1, 2022). [Google Scholar]
  93. Wager Stefan, and Athey Susan. 2018. “Estimation and Inference of Heterogeneous Treatment Effects Using Random Forests.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 113 (523): 1228–42. [Google Scholar]

This article has been cited by:

  • 1.Schanzenbach Diane Whitmore. 2023. Understanding SNAP: An overview of recent research. Food Policy 114, 102397. [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Gornick Janet C., Maldonado Laurie C., Sheely Amanda. 2022. Effective Policies for Single-Parent Families and Prospects for Policy Reforms in the United States: Concluding Reflections. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 702:1, 236–251. [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Appendix Table 1

RESOURCES