Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2024 Mar 15;19(3):e0298355. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0298355

An evolutionary analysis of supply chain collaborative information sharing based on prospect theory

Meng Liu 1,2, Luyu Zhai 3, Hongcheng Gan 1,2,*
Editor: Bo Huang4
PMCID: PMC10942068  PMID: 38489344

Abstract

In order to delve into the dynamic evolution process and influencing factors of information sharing decisions among stakeholders under supply chain collaboration, this study constructs an evolutionary game model with suppliers and retailers as the primary entities. Within this model, a combined approach of game theory and prospect theory is employed, integrating prospect value functions and weight functions to create an information sharing prospect value matrix. A comprehensive analysis is conducted on the strategic choices and benefits of entities considering the psychological perception of information sharing, and critical factors influencing the stability of information sharing evolution results are explored through numerical simulations using Matlab. The key findings of this study are as follows: Firstly, from the perspective of supply chain collaboration, the probability of entities evolving into information sharing is negatively correlated with the cost of information sharing and positively correlated with the benefits generated by information coordination. Secondly, looking at supply chain collaboration, entities are more likely to engage in information sharing behavior when they exhibit a lower level of risk aversion, indicating greater rationality, when facing profits; conversely, they are more likely to participate in information sharing when they display a higher degree of risk preference, indicating less rationality, in the face of losses. Furthermore, the lesser sensitivity of suppliers and retailers to losses is more likely to drive the system towards an information-sharing state. Based on the primary findings mentioned above, this study offers recommendations for enhancing trust, constructing information exchange platforms, and adjusting psychological awareness. These suggestions contribute to improving information sharing among entities within the supply chain, thus enhancing the overall efficiency and collaboration of the supply chain.

1. Introduction

In light of the shifting market landscape and intensifying global competition, supply chain collaboration has emerged as a pivotal means for enterprises to enhance their competitiveness and operational efficiency [1, 2]. It has progressively evolved into a central and critical topic within modern supply chain management [3]. Its primary objective is to elevate the efficiency and benefits of the entire supply chain through effective information sharing and collaborative decision-making [4, 5]. Information sharing among supply chain members can effectively alleviate the bullwhip effect and double marginalization effect caused by asymmetric information among members [6, 7], thereby further achieving supply chain collaboration [8], thus enhancing the overall competitiveness of the supply chain. Effective information sharing mechanisms can help supply chains achieve supply chain collaboration and stability, which is currently the goal of supply chain management.

However, in practice, supply chain information sharing still faces numerous challenges, such as willingness to share information, asymmetric information [9], information matching, and varying abilities of shared entities to absorb and utilize information [10]. This complexity necessitates critical deliberation among supply chain entities regarding whether to engage in information sharing. To explore the underlying decision-making mechanisms, this study constructs a game model composed of suppliers and retailers. The aim is to investigate how various factors influence the information sharing decisions of these entities.

In recent years, numerous scholars have analyzed and summarized the information sharing behavior from the perspective of supply chains. Sheng has constructed an information sharing model based on blockchain to solve the asymmetric information in the supply chain transaction process [7]. Dan et al. [11] focusing on fresh agricultural products supply chain, explored the optimal pricing and preservation efforts under different information sharing strategies and studied the information sharing strategies of retailers. Liao et al. [12] studied a secondary supply chain consisting of manufacturers with production capacity constraints and two retail markets with differing demand, exploring the value creation and willingness to share demand information in the presence of capacity constraints and various allocation methods. These studies are mostly based on the "rational economic man" hypothesis of conventional economic theory, which assumes that people are completely rational, selfish, and pursue maximum benefits. However, with the rise of behavioral economics, people have gradually realized the shortcomings of the "rational economic man" hypothesis in traditional economics [13]. Behavioral economics believes that people’s psychological factors cannot be ignored when making decisions. Many studies have also shown that the psychological factors of supply chain members will affect their decision-making and the overall efficiency of the supply chain, and their behavior is significantly different from the predicted results of the standard economic model [14, 15]. Therefore, the psychological perception of the subjects is an important behavior factor that cannot be ignored in the study of supply chains, and it is urgent to consider the subjective psychological factors of the subjects in supply chain information sharing.

At present, many scholars have incorporated the subjective psychological perception factor of the subject into the behavior decision-making of supply chain members. Numerous scholars observed that supply chain members have a great concern for fairness, namely, fairness concern [1618]. Scholars believe that under the influence of fairness concern, people are likely to take action at the cost of their own interests to punish the other party when they feel unfair. Fairness concern is inconsistent with the traditional expected utility theory, which violates the rational person hypothesis. Many empirical or experimental studies have confirmed the existence of this behavioral tendency [19]. The above research is mostly based on psychological considerations of gains. In other words, the above research is mostly based on the subject’s psychological perception of "gain". However, prospect theory [20] tells us that losing has a greater impact on psychology than gaining, and people generally have a mentality of loss aversion [21, 22]. Given the greater influence of "loss" on psychological perception, scholars consider loss aversion. Wang et al. [23] based on the problem of supply chain financing strategy under random demand situations, considering the impact of loss aversion of fund-constrained retailers on supply chain operation decision-making and financing strategies. Qiu [24] analyzed the impact of consumer service loss aversion on enterprise pricing decisions and profits in the case of jointly building a multi-channel supply chain by manufacturers and retailers. The results show that the service loss aversion of consumers leads to a decrease in retail prices, online sales prices, and wholesale prices. Chen et al. [25] studied the ordering decision-making problem of loss-averse salespeople under option contracts and analyzed in detail the impact of parameters such as loss aversion coefficient of salespeople, retail price, and execution price on their ordering decisions.

Compared to the above literatures, the difference in this paper is that the literatures mostly study the subject’s information sharing behavior decision-making from the perspective of the supply chain and less from the perspective of supply chain collaboration. The difference between the two is that information sharing in the supply chain is only a conventional form of supply chain cooperation. At present, with the changing market environment and the increasing global competition, supply chain collaboration has become an important means to improve enterprise competitiveness and operational efficiency. In previous research, some scholars have also contended that trust mechanisms, collaborative decision-making, and supply chain visibility are vital determinants of supply chain collaboration. Nevertheless, information sharing has often been considered as the fundamental prerequisite for supply chain collaboration in numerous studies, sometimes even synonymous with collaboration itself. Consequently, in the interest of model simplification, this study exclusively investigates scenarios where supply chain collaboration is achieved through information sharing alone. Achieving supply chain collaboration through information sharing has become an important goal of supply chain management at present. Viewing information sharing behavior from the perspective of supply chain collaboration will be more in line with the current research background, but it also increases the difficulty of decision-making. Moreover, at present, there are relatively few studies on the considerations of gains and losses that decision-making subjects feel when sharing information from the perspective of supply chain collaboration, and there is a lack of relevant quantitative research.

Based on the above business observations and literatures review, this study will mainly explore the following issues: 1. From the perspective of supply chain collaboration, explore the influence of various factors on information sharing behavior decision-making; 2. Considering that the behavior characteristics of supply chain subjects are not completely rational, integrate prospect theory into the analysis to assess how the psychological perception of information sharing subjects regarding gains and losses influences their decisions.

In light of the aforementioned limitations, this study, grounded in the perspective of supply chain collaboration, seeks to uncover the latent psychological and behavioral factors in supply chain information sharing decision-making. Specifically, drawing from the assumption of bounded rationality in game theory [26] and combining it with prospect theory, the study examines how the perception of value and risk aversion by game players influence the patterns of system evolution and stability. Through these investigations, we aim to provide a deeper understanding for enterprises and supply chain practitioners, enabling them to refine their decision-making and practices. Furthermore, we hope this research contributes to enriching the foundational theoretical framework of supply chain collaboration and offers new perspectives and scientific methods to researchers in the field.

The main contributions of this study are as follows: 1. It analyzes the behavioral decisions of supply chain decision-makers from the perspective of supply chain collaboration, offering a novel viewpoint. 2. By introducing prospect theory into the domain of supply chain collaboration management, the study provides a fresh theoretical framework that elucidates the evolutionary process of information sharing in supply chains, enriching the existing supply chain theory. 3. This research can assist supply chain decision-makers in better understanding the impact of psychological factors on their decision-making, providing effective guidance for practice. 4. The study also presents research insights and future prospects, serving as a reference and offering suggestions for related researchers.

2. Information sharing evolution model under supply chain collaboration

2.1 Model assumptions

  1. This study aims to analyze the information sharing behavior among supply chain partners from the perspective of supply chain collaboration. To achieve this, a two-player evolutionary game model based on game theory will be constructed. The rationale for this is as follows: 1. Game theory is an intuitive and effective tool in economics for solving problems related to behavioral choice of agents; 2. Agents engaging in information sharing behavior make choices based on limited information and their own costs; 3. The interests of these entities are influenced by their behavioral choices, aligning with the typical characteristics of game theory [27]. In this study, we present a simplified model, assuming a two-tier supply chain comprising suppliers and retailers with bounded rationality. Since the two parties are influenced by different environments and corporate cultures, they are under conditions of incomplete information when making decisions. Additionally, their bounded rationality means that they will gradually move towards the optimal state through continuous learning and strategy adjustment. Furthermore, both have only two choices: information sharing or non-sharing.

  2. The information shared among the entities in the supply chain encompasses elements such as market demand forecasting, inventory data, as well as transportation and logistics information, all of which contribute to optimizing decision-making for both parties. However, it does not include information concerning each entity’s core competitive advantages. Moreover, the act of information exchange between these entities is imbued with numerous uncertainties, including factors like the market environment, uncertainties about the long-term benefits of information sharing, and the costs associated with information maintenance. When making decisions within the context of this game, the agents base their choices not on anticipated utility values, but rather on their own perceptions of how strategies ultimately generate value. According to the cumulative prospect theory [20] proposed by Amos and Daniel, the perceived value of the information sharing entities can be measured by the prospect value V, which is determined by the value function vx) and weight function w(p), that is V=v(Δx)w(p). Substituting Prospect Theory function for the expected utility function aligns more closely with reality.
    w(pi)=piγ(piγ+(1pi)λ)1γv(Δx)={(Δx)α,Δx0λ(Δx)β,Δx<0
    where p represents the objective probability that i occurs. The weight function w(pi) reflects the impact of pi on the overall effect, which has a shape of inverted “S”, and the larger the γ value, the smaller the curvature of the function curve. In general, people assign a weight of 1 to events with extremely high probability and assign a weight of 0 to events with extremely low probability, that is w(1) = 1 and w(0) = 0. We tend to underestimate events with medium and high probability and overestimate events with low probability in the actual decision-making process. Δxi is the difference between the actual benefit of the decision-making group and the reference point after the decision-making event occurs. vx) refers to the subjective feeling value of the decision-making subject after the decision-making event occurs. Assuming that the supplier and the retailer exhibit risk aversion degrees α1, α2∈(0,1) when facing gains and risk preference degree β1, β2∈(0,1) when confronting losses. λ(λ≥1) denotes the loss aversion coefficient, where a higher value signifies that the game agents are more sensitive to losses compared to gains. Additionally, we posit that one party’s information sharing strategy will not influence the psychological state of the other party. The reference point selection is also very important, because it is used to judge the gains and losses of the decision-making subject. In this study, the benefits obtained when all supply chain information sharing subjects choose not to share information are taken as the reference point; that is, the perceived value is 0.
  3. Literatures [7, 11, 28] are used as key references for parameter assumptions. We assume that the initial gains for both to be 0 when neither the supplier nor the retailer shares information. Suppliers and retailers are participants, and their respective amount of information sharing are b1 and b2. Since this study exclusively examines cases where supply chain collaboration is achieved through information sharing, we assume that when both parties engage in information sharing, suppliers and retailers attain collaboration through information sharing and generate collaborative gains [29]. However, scholars only assume the collaborative benefit as a fixed value. In contrast, this study contends that the magnitude of collaborative gains depends on the complementarity and volume of shared information. We assume that the complementarity is t1 and t2 respectively, and the amount of information sharing is b1 and b2 respectively, the collaborative benefits obtained by both parties are t1b1 and t2b2 respectively. However, suppliers and retailers cannot fully absorb the received information when they are receivers [30]. Assume that their respective information absorption and conversion capability coefficients are e1 and e2, and information sharing costs are c1and c2. The cost refers to the information investment cost, information security cost, and information maintenance cost of the database or information system for the connection and upgrading when the participants share information [31]. Assume that the additional benefits brought about by long-term information sharing between supplier and retailer (such as increased reputation in the industry and increased market share) are m and n.

  4. (In the game, the probability that the supplier chooses information sharing is x(0≤x≤1), and the probability for choosing the information non-sharing is 1−x; the probability that the retailer chooses information sharing is y(0≤y≤1), and the probability for choosing the information non-sharing is 1−y.

2.2 Model building and solution

Based on the above assumptions regarding collaborative information sharing in supply chains, this study constructs the following game matrix for the information sharing problem within the supply chain collaboration context. Combining this with prospect theory, we obtain the prospect matrix for information sharing, as shown in Table 1 below.

Table 1. Information sharing prospect matrix.

Retailer
Information sharing y Information non-sharing 1−y
Supplier Information sharing x mα1λc1β1+(e1b2)α1+(t1b2)α1, λc1β1, (e2b1)α2
nα2λc2β2+(e2b1)α2+(t2b1)α2
Information non-sharing 1−x (e1b2)α1, λc2β2 0, 0

Based on the values in the table, the following calculations can be performed:

The expected prospect value and the average prospect value of the supplier under the two strategies of information sharing and information non-sharing are respectively:

U1=y[mα1λc1β1+(e1b2)α1+(t1b2)α1]+(1y)(λc1β1) (1)
U2=y(e1b2)α1+(1y)0 (2)
Ux=xU1+(1x)U2 (3)

The dynamic replication equation for the suppliers is:

F(x)=dxdt=x(U1Ux)=x(1x)[ymα1+y(t1b2)α1λc1β1] (4)

Similarly, the expected prospect value and the average prospect value of the retailer under the two strategies of information sharing and information non-sharing are respectively:

U3=x[nα2λc2β2+(e2b1)α2+(t2b1)α2]+(1x)(λc2β2) (5)
U4=x(e2b1)α2+(1x)0 (6)
Uy=yU3+(1y)U4 (7)

The dynamic replication equation for the retailer is:

F(y)=dydt=y(U3Uy)=y(1y)[xnα2+x(t2b1)α2λc2β2] (8)

Make these two dynamic replication equations a simultaneous equation and set F(x) = 0 and F(y) = 0, the equilibrium points of the game system are obtained as O(0,0), A(1,0), B(0,1), C(1,1) and D(x*,y*). If and only if 0λc2β2nα2+(t2b1)α2=x*1 and 0λc1β1mα1+(t1b2)α1=y*1 hold, D(x*,y*) is also the equilibrium point of the game system.

2.3 Stability analysis of equilibrium point

It can be concluded from the above results that there are five possible local equilibrium points of the game in the system: O(0,0), A(1,0), B(0,1), C(1,1) and D(x*,y*). In order to determine the evolutionary stable strategy point of the system, it is necessary to determine the local equilibrium point. Friedman proposed that when det(J)>0 and tr(J)<0 hold at the same time, the equilibrium point will gradually tend to the local stable state of the system, and the signs of the two can be used to judge whether the system is in an evolutionary stable state. According to the group dynamics of the supplier and the retailer, the Jacobian matrix J is J=[F(x)xF(x)yF(y)xF(y)y], where

F(x)x=(12x)[ymα1+y(t1b2)α1λc1β1], F(x)y=x(1x)[mα1+(t1b2)α1] F(y)x=y(1y)[nα2+(t2b1)α2], F(y)y=(12y)[xnα2+x(t2b1)α2λc2β2] According to the Jacobian matrix, the corresponding determinant and trace are:

det(J)=(12x)(12y)[ymα1+y(t1b2)α1λc1β1][xnα2+x(t2b1)α2λc2β2]xy(1x)(1y)[mα1+(t1b2)α1][nα2+(t2b1)α2] (9)
tr(J)=(12x)[ymα1+y(t1b2)α1λc1β1]+(12y)[xnα2+x(t2b1)α2λc2β2] (10)

The determinant and trace of the Jacobian matrix corresponding to the calculation system at the local equilibrium point O(0,0), A(1,0), B(0,1), C(1,1) and D(x*,y*) are shown in Table 2 below.

Table 2. Jacobian matrix of the game model for the supplier and the retailer.

Equilibrium point det(J) tr(J)
O(0,0) λ2c1β1c2β2 λc1β1λc2β2
A(1,0) λc1β1[nα2+(t2b1)α2λc2β2] λc1β1+[nα2+(t2b1)α2λc2β2]
B(0,1) [mα1+(t1b2)α1λc1β1]λc2β2 [mα1+(t1b2)α1λc1β1]+λc2β2
C(1,1) [mα1+(t1b2)α1λc1β1][nα2+(t2b1)α2λc2β2] [mα1+(t1b2)α1λc1β1][nα2+(t2b1)α2λc2β2]
D(x*,y*) λ2c1β1c2β2[mα1+(t1b2)α1λc1β1][nα2+(t2b1)α2λc2β2][mα1+(t1b2)α1][nα2+(t2b1)α2] 0

It can be seen from Table 2 that the stability of the system is related to many parameters, and the system will be affected by the different values of each parameter. The local stability of the system has the following four cases, and the judgment results of the system equilibrium point in each case are shown in Table 3.

Table 3. Stability analysis of equilibrium point in each case.

Case Restrictions Equilibrium point O(0,0) A(1,0) B(0,1) C(1,1) D(x*,y*)
1 mα1+(t1b2)α1>λc1β1 nα2+(t2b1)α2>λc2β2 det(J) + + + + +
tr(J) - + + - 0
Stability ESS Unstable point Unstable point ESS Saddle point
2 mα1+(t1b2)α1>λc1β1 nα2+(t2b1)α2<λc2β2 det(J) + - + - +
tr(J) - +/- + +/- 0
Stability ESS Saddle point Unstable point Saddle point Disequilibrium point
3 mα1+(t1b2)α1<λc1β1 nα2+(t2b1)α2<λc2β2 det(J) + + - - +
tr(J) - + +/- +/- 0
Stability ESS Unstable point Saddle point Saddle point Disequilibrium point
4 mα1+(t1b2)α1<λc1β1 nα2+(t2b1)α2<λc2β2 det(J) + - - + -
tr(J) - +/- +/- + 0
Stability ESS Saddle point Saddle point Unstable point Saddle point

2.4 Analysis of evolution results

According to the analysis of Jacobian matrix above, the evolution dynamic phase diagram of the information sharing game between supplier and retailer in different cases (Fig 1). It can clearly show the evolutionary stability strategy of the system in different cases.

Fig 1. Phase diagram of the system in different cases.

Fig 1

In case 1, there are two evolutionary stable strategy points in the system, which are O(0,0) and C(1,1), and in cases 2–4, there is only one evolutionary stable strategy point in the system: O(0,0).

In order to explore the influencing factors of the evolutionary stable state in case 1, the evolution dynamic phase diagram of case 1 was analyzed. In Case 1, the plane is divided into two parts by the broken line ADB (the critical line where the system converges to different states). The system will converge to a state of (sharing, sharing) in the ADBC portion and converge to a state of (non-sharing, non-sharing) in the ADBO portion. According to the set probability, the probability that the system converges to the state of (sharing, sharing) is:

P=(1x*)(1y*)+x*(1y*)2+y*(1x*)2=1x*2y*2
=1λc2β22[nα2+(t2b1)α2]λc1β12[mα1+(t1b2)α1] (11)

Supplier and retailer, as decision-makers, are mainly influenced by factors such as costs of information sharing, collaboration benefits and additional benefits of information sharing. In reality, decision makers are limited rationality when making decisions about information sharing, especially under the influence of various uncertainties. They are risk-averse in the face of gains, and risk-appetizing when faced with losses, and their perception of losses is stronger. The main factors that affect the convergence of the system to the optimal desired strategy (sharing, sharing) are analyzed below.

Proposition 1: When both the supplier and the retailer choose information sharing, the higher the cost of information sharing, the smaller the probability that the system will converge to the stable strategy (sharing, sharing).

Proof: Calculating the first-order partial derivatives of c1 and c2 in Formula (11), Pc1=λβ1c1β112[mα1+(t1b2)α1]<0 and Pc2=λβ2c2β212[nα2+(t2b1)α2]<0 can be obtained. Thus, the higher the cost of information sharing, the more unfavorable it is for supplier and retailer to carry out information sharing and cooperation.

Proposition 2: The higher the additional income of long-term information sharing for supplier and retailer, the greater the probability that the system will converge to the stable strategy (sharing, sharing).

Proof: Calculating the first-order partial derivatives of m and n in Formula (11), Pm=λc1β1(2α1mα1/m)[2mα1+2(t1b2)α1]2>0 and Pn=λc2β2(2α2nα2/n)[2nα2+2(t2b1)α2]2>0 can be obtained. Thus, if suppliers and retailers can feel the improvement of reputation and increase of market share when they choose information sharing strategies, they will further information sharing.

Proposition 3: The collaboration benefits of information sharing between supplier and retailer will be influenced by the complementarity of knowledge and the amount of information sharing. The greater the collaborative benefits obtained by both parties, the greater the probability that the system converges to the stable strategy (sharing, sharing).

Proof: Pt1=λc1β1[2α1(t1b2)α1/t1][2mα1+2(t1b2)α1]2>0, Pt2=λc2β2[2α2(t2b1)α2/t2][2nα2+2(t2b1)α2]2>0, Pb1=λc2β2[2α2(t2b1)α2/b1][2nα2+2(t2b1)α2]2>0 and Pb2=λc1β1[2α2(t1b2)α1/b2][2nα1+2(t1b2)α1]2>0. Thus, the higher the amount of information shared by supplier and retailer and the degree of complementarity of the shared information, the more favorable it is to promote information sharing between the two decision-making subjects.

Proposition 4: The larger the loss sensitivity coefficients λ of supplier and retailer, the smaller the probability that the system converges to the stable strategy (sharing, sharing).

Proof: Pλ=c2β22[nα2+(t2b1)α2]c1β12[mα1+(t1b2)α1]<0. Thus, there is a negative correlation between P and λ. This shows that the more sensitive supplier and retailer are to losses, the more unfavorable it is for information sharing.

Proposition 5: The less risk-averse the supplier and retailer are in the face of revenue (that is, the larger αi(i = 1,2) is), the greater the probability that the system will converge to the stable strategy (sharing, sharing).

Proof: Pα1=λc1β1[2mα1ln(m)+2(t1b2)α1ln(t1b2)][2mα1+2(t1b2)α1]2>0 and Pα2=λc2β2[2nα2ln(n)+2(t2b1)α2ln(t2b1)][2nα2+2(t2b1)α2]2>0. Thus, there is a positive correlation between P and αi. This shows that the greater the degree of risk appetite (that is, the more rational) supplier and retailer show in the face of benefits, the more conducive to the occurrence of information sharing behavior.

Proposition 6: The smaller the risk preference of supplier and retailer in the face of losses (that is, the larger βi(i = 1,2) is), the smaller the probability that the system will converge to the stable strategy (sharing, sharing).

Proof: Pβ1=λβ1c1β112[mα1+(t1b2)α1]<0 and Pβ2=λβ2c2β212[nα2+(t2b1)α2]<0. Thus, there is a negative correlation between P and βi. This shows that the greater the degree of risk appetite (that is, the more irrational) supplier and retailer show in the face of losses, the more conducive to the occurrence of information sharing behavior.

The reason why the information sharing system is difficult to reach the optimal state is analyzed as follows:

  1. This study is based on the analysis of the two-stage supply chain. However, there are multiple suppliers and retailers in the actual market. The market is complex and has many uncertainties, and there is information asymmetry among multiple parties, which makes decision-making subjects such as suppliers and retailers in the supply chain have cognitive biases. That is to say, they will underestimate the potential benefits of information sharing (increasing of market share and reputation), and overestimate the maintenance costs of information sharing.

  2. Information sharing under supply chain collaboration involves many stakeholders, and the degree of trust among them is low. The subjects know little about each other’s ability and moral level in the initial stage of the formation of the supply chain.

  3. Based on the limited rationality of decision makers in reality and the utility of the prospect theory, when the information sharing subject faces loss and gain, the negative utility brought by the loss is greater than the positive utility brought by the gain. Moreover, the decision-making subject will overestimate the loss utility of maintenance costs and underestimate the benefit utility of information collaboration to a certain extent.

  4. Finally, the uncertainty in the environment in which the supply chain operates may also play a role. Information collaboration benefits depend not only on the amount of information shared and the information absorption and transformation capabilities of both parties but are also influenced by external turbulent environments. However, uncertain environmental factors can have both positive and negative effects, making it difficult to intuitively assess their impact on the system’s evolutionary outcomes. Addressing this potential factor is a focus of future research for the author.

3. Influencing factors of behavior evolution and simulation analysis

To provide a more intuitive analysis of the impact of factors such as information sharing costs, additional gains, collaborative gains, and loss aversion coefficients on the evolutionary game results of suppliers and retailers under the conditions of prospect theory, we utilized MATLAB software for simulation modeling. MATLAB, recognized as a sophisticated mathematical computing and programming environment, finds extensive application across scientific, engineering, data analysis, and machine learning domains. Its robust mathematical computing capabilities, coupled with an array of rich toolboxes, enable parallel processing. Furthermore, its potent graphical and visualization functions were pivotal in selecting it as the primary software for simulation analysis in this study.

Literatures [11, 32] were referenced for parameter setting. We referred to existing literature for the following reasons: 1. The parameter settings in the literature are founded on established theories, with authors validating the effectiveness of these parameters. 2. The literature we consulted exhibits a degree of relevance to our research, offering valuable insights for parameter configuration. 3. These parameter configurations yield optimal visual analytical outcomes. In addition, the data has been adjusted repeatedly to achieve a good visual analysis effect. Consequently, the loss aversion coefficient is λ = 2.25, risk coefficients are α1 = α2 = β1 = β2 = 0.88, amount of information shared by suppliers and retailers are b1 = b2 = 250, complementarity coefficients are t1 = t2 = 0.5, information sharing costs are c1 = c2 = 30, additional benefits are m = n = 100, initial information sharing probability of the supplier is x = 0.5 and initial information sharing probability of the retailer is y = 0.5.

  1. The evolutionary behavior path of game subjects

    The impact of different initial probabilities on the final decision of supplier and retailer and the dynamic replication system is analyzed by simulating their decision-making process under different initial probabilities. It can be seen that when the parameter values satisfy the corresponding constraints, no matter how the initial probability changes between 0 and 1, the game subject will choose the behavior strategy that can maximize the benefit (Fig 2A). In this case, the system will eventually stabilize at an equilibrium state of (non-sharing, non-sharing) and (sharing, sharing). The probability x of the supplier choosing the information sharing strategy is fixed at 0.5, and the corresponding probability y of the retailer is fixed at 0.5 to explore the impact of the initial probability change on their decision-making. It can be observed that the higher initial probabilities for suppliers and retailers expedite the rate of convergence toward cooperation (Fig 2B and 2C). This outcome underscores that when the willingness of both parties for initial information sharing is low, it hampers inter-enterprise information sharing. Hence, whether acting as a supplier or retailer, proactive engagement in constructive information exchange with supply chain counterparts, the establishment of trust mechanisms, and the actualization of information sharing are advisable.

  2. The impact of the change in the information sharing cost c1 on the evolution result

    The gradual increase of the information sharing cost c1, the result of x converging to 1 gradually changes to converging to 0. In addition, there is a critical value of information sharing cost, which is between 40 and 50. When the information sharing cost is less than this critical value, x converges to 1. The smaller the value of ci, the faster the convergence speed (Fig 3). Hence, elevated information sharing costs serve as a deterrent to inter-enterprise information sharing. As costs rise, enterprises become less inclined to engage in information sharing. At this juncture, it is imperative to harness advanced technologies such as 5G, artificial intelligence, and the Internet of Things (IoT) to reduce costs. This, in turn, ensures mutual information sharing and fosters supply chain collaboration. In summary, there exists an inverse correlation between the probability of system convergence to sharing and information sharing costs. Lowering information sharing costs and enhancing efficiency can encourage proactive information sharing among decision-makers.

  3. The impact of the change in the additional benefit m on the evolution result

    The gradual increase of the additional benefit m, the result of x and y converging to 0 gradually changes to converging to 1. In addition, there is a critical value of additional benefit, which is between 20 and 40. When the additional benefit is less than this critical value, x converges to 0. When the additional benefit is greater than this critical value, x converges to 1. The smaller the value of m, the faster the convergence speed (Fig 4). This outcome signifies that when supply chain enterprises anticipate higher additional gains from information sharing, they are more inclined to partake in it. Information sharing within the supply chain grants retailers access to precise market demand information, given their proximity to the market, while suppliers hold inventory, transportation, and logistics data. The exchange of information between both parties further augments market share, thereby increasing additional gains. Consequently, supply chain enterprises should promptly share information conducive to enhancing market share, including market demand forecasts, inventory information, transportation, and logistics data, among others. This sharing, however, should exclude information pertaining to each entity’s core competitive advantages.

  4. The impact of changes in collaborative benefits on the evolution result

    The collaboration benefit is determined by the amount of information shared by both parties b1 and b2, and the coefficient of complementarity t1 and t2. According to the above analysis, the amount of information sharing and the coefficient of complementarity have the same effect on the trend of evolution results in terms of collaboration benefits. In this study, the supplier is taken as the object for analysis, the complementarity coefficient t1 is fixed at 0.5 and the amount of information sharing b2 is changed for a more intuitive observation. It can be seen from Fig 5 that with the gradual increase of the amount of information sharing, the result of x converging to 0 gradually changes to converging to 1. In addition, there is a critical value between 100 and 150. When the value is less than this critical value, x converges to 0. When the value is greater than this critical value, x converges to 1. The larger the amount of the information sharing, the faster the convergence speed (Fig 5). Thus, there is a positive correlation between the probability that the system converges to sharing and the amount of information sharing. This underscores that for supply chain enterprises aiming to maximize profits and market share, increasing the quantity and frequency of information sharing is imperative. This information should encompass market demand forecasts, inventory data, transportation, logistics information, and other insights conducive to optimizing decision-making. However, it should exclude details pertaining to each entity’s core competitive strengths.

  5. The impact of the change in the loss sensitivity coefficient λ on the evolution result

    According to the prospect theory, most people are more sensitive to loss than income, and the sensitivity coefficient is greater than 1. The gradual increase of λ, the result of x converging to 1 gradually changes to converging to 0. There is a critical value between 3 and 3.5. When the loss sensitivity coefficient is less than the critical value, x converges to 1. The smaller the value, the faster its convergence speed (Fig 6). It can be seen from the results that the smaller the loss sensitivity coefficient of the information sharing subject, the easier it is to share information and achieve information collaboration. The results emphasize that when supply chain enterprises engage in information sharing, they should strive to mitigate their sensitivity to losses. The focus should remain on long-term gains and development, without undue concern for short-term cost investments. Attention to long-term returns and growth should take precedence over heightened sensitivity to initial costs.

  6. The impact of the change in risk aversion coefficient facing benefits α1on the evolution result

    According to the prospect theory, most people tend to avoid risks in the face of benefits. The smaller the value of α1, the greater the degree of risk aversion. The gradual increase of α1, the result of x converging to 0 gradually changes to converging to 1. In addition, there is a critical value between 0.8 and 0.88. When the value is less than this critical value, x converges to 0. When the value is greater than this critical value, x converges to 1. The larger the value of α1, the faster the convergence speed (Fig 7). Therefore, the more rational the information sharing parties show in the face of benefits, the easier it is to choose "information sharing". The findings suggest that when supply chain enterprises engage in information sharing and stand to gain from it, they should not solely focus on short-term gains. Instead, they should prioritize long-term gains and development. In situations involving potential gains, they should further invest effectively to maximize returns.

  7. The impact of the change in risk aversion coefficient facing losses β1 on the evolution result

    According to the prospect theory, most people are risk appetite in the face of losses. The smaller the value of β1, the more inclined to risk preference. The gradual increase of the value, the result of x converging to 1 gradually changes to converging to 0. In addition, there is a critical value between 0.88 and 0.95. When the value is less than this critical value, x converges to 1. When the value is greater than this critical value, x converges to 0. The larger the value of β1, the faster the convergence speed (Fig 8). These findings underscore that, when supply chain enterprises engage in information sharing that might result in losses, they should strive to temper their emotional response to such losses. While risk aversion can stimulate the occurrence of information-sharing behaviors, it may inadvertently lead to the neglect of larger potential losses stemming from unforeseen risks. To address this, the implementation of risk-sharing mechanisms can serve as a more effective means of risk management.

Fig 2.

Fig 2

a. Effect of different initial probabilities on the stability of the system. b. The impact of retailer’s initial probability change on supplier’s strategy selection. c. The impact of supplier’s initial probability change on retailer’s strategy selection.

Fig 3. The impact of information maintenance cost c1 on the evolution result.

Fig 3

Fig 4. The impact of the additional benefit m on the evolution result.

Fig 4

Fig 5. The impact of the amount of information sharing b2 on the evolution result.

Fig 5

Fig 6. The impact of the loss sensitivity coefficient λ on the evolution result.

Fig 6

Fig 7. The impact of the risk aversion coefficient α1 on the evolution result.

Fig 7

Fig 8. The impact of the risk aversion coefficient β1 on the evolution result.

Fig 8

4. Conclusion and management implications

This study reveals that previous research has predominantly focused on constructing payoff matrices based on objective gains, overlooking the influence of psychological perceptions of supply chain collaborative decision-making entities on their choices [11, 33, 34]. Supply chain decision-making entities’ judgments of the probability of future events, benefits, or losses and their attitudes towards risk will differ due to the complex decision-making environment and uncertainty, and subjective psychological perceptions will affect strategies. Hence, this paper combines the prospect theory and game theory under the bounded rationality hypothesis with the relevant research foundation of predecessors, constructs game theory model based on information sharing behavior of secondary supply chain entities, and conducts simulation research. The following conclusions and implications were obtained:

4.1 Research conclusion

The study found that the decision-making of information sharing behavior among supply chain collaborative entities under information sharing costs, collaborative benefits, and the psychological perception of decision-makers facing benefits and losses are influenced by various factors. The probability of the decision-making process under information sharing behavior of supply chain collaborative entities is negatively related to information sharing costs, and positively related to the collaborative benefits generated by information sharing. At the same time, under information sharing in supply chain collaboration, the smaller the degree of risk aversion facing the benefit risk of supply chain decision-making entities, the more rational they are and the more favorable it is for information sharing behavior to occur. The greater the risk preference facing loss, the more irrational they are, and the more favorable it is for information sharing behavior to occur. The smaller the sensitivity of the supply chain decision-making entity to losses, the more favorable it is for the system to evolve to the state of information sharing.

4.2 Management implications

This paper proposes the following management implications:

  1. Information sharing among supply chain entities is influenced by a multitude of factors, including members’ knowledge acquisition capabilities, partner relationships, digitalization levels, and information heterogeneity. To enhance the benefits derived from inter-enterprise information sharing, there should be a strengthening of inter-firm collaborations and a concerted effort to enhance the learning and information integration abilities of supply chain members.

  2. Recognizing the pivotal role of information sharing in supply chain collaboration, management should foster an open information flow between suppliers and retailers to bolster cooperation and overall supply chain efficiency.

  3. High information maintenance costs can impede information sharing within collaborative supply chains. To mitigate these costs, such as communication overheads, advanced technologies like 5G, artificial intelligence, and the Internet of Things (IoT) can be employed to establish collaborative information sharing platforms. This, in turn, can stimulate a proactive approach to information exchange and cultivate a spirit of mutual cooperation.

  4. Notably, the research underscores differences in organizational behavior psychology regarding losses and gains among members. Therefore, it is advisable to engage professionals versed in organizational behavior psychology and risk analysis to provide training and elevate employees’ psychological resilience. This, in turn, would reduce their sensitivity to losses.

  5. In the pursuit of effective supply chain collaboration, a keen focus should be placed on the information integration and collection capabilities of potential partners during the partner selection phase. Improved communication, facilitated by efficient information sharing, can be instrumental in resolving challenges encountered during collaboration.

  6. Effective information sharing strategies hinge on trust among supply chain partners. Management efforts should concentrate on fostering trust through shared success stories, transparent contracts, and commitments.

Therefore, to achieve the optimal state of supply chain collaborative information sharing, it is necessary to consider and address the aforementioned factors and challenges, improve the level of trust and understanding among all entities, rectify decision makers’ cognitive biases, and adapt to the dynamic and uncertain market environment.

4.3 Prospects for future research

This study has solely addressed the supply chain partnership between a single supplier and a single retailer. In practice, scenarios involving multiple suppliers and retailers are prevalent, each entailing intricate dynamics of interests. Among these, the behavior of information sharing warrants deeper exploration. While this study assumed the independence of various factors influencing information-sharing behaviors among supply chain entities, it’s crucial to further investigate potential interconnections or constraints between these factors. Moreover, these factors may exert differing degrees of influence on information-sharing decisions, necessitating future research to encompass this aspect as well.

Furthermore, the supply chain environment is inherently uncertain, with environmental factors capable of both positive and negative impacts. These uncertainties can significantly affect system evolution outcomes, although discerning their precise influence can prove challenging. Future research endeavors may delve into the realm of uncertainty theory and methods to shed light on environmental uncertainties.

Supporting information

S1 File

(DOCX)

pone.0298355.s001.docx (21.8KB, docx)

Data Availability

All relevant data are in the manuscript and its Supporting Information files.

Funding Statement

The author(s) received no specific funding for this work.

References

  • 1.Cao M, Zhang QY. Supply chain collaboration: impact on collaboration advantage and firm performance. Journal of Operations Management. 2010; 29(3):163–180. 10.1016/j.jom.2010.12.008. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Zacharia ZG, Nix NW, Lusch RF. Capabilities that enhance outcomes of an episodic supply chain collaboration. Journal of Operations Management. 2011; 29(6):591–603. doi: 10.1016/j.jom.2011.02.001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Ma SQ, Li Hao, Aloysius JA. Women are an advantage in supply chain collaboration and efficiency. Production and Operations Management. 2020; 30(5):1427–1441. doi: 10.1111/poms.13329 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Xiao Q, Ma SH. Mechanism of supplier collaborative product design based on information sharing. Systems Engineering. 2015;33 (06):10–16. http://doi.org/CNKI:SUN:GCXT.0.2015-06-002. [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Jain A. Sharing demand information with retailer under upstream competition. Management Science. 2021; 68 (7):4983–5001. doi: 10.1287/mnsc 2021. 4116. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Fiala P. Information sharing In supply chains. 0mega. 2005; 33(5):419–423. doi: 10.1016/j.omega.2004.07.006 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Sheng SY. Research on supply chain information resource sharing model construction based on blockchain technology. Information Science. 2021; 39(07):162–168. 10.13833/j.issn.1007-7634.2021.07.022. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Hou YM, Wei FF, Li SSX, Huang ZM, Allan A. Coordination and performance analysis for a three-echelon supply chain with a revenue sharing contract. International Journal of Production Research. 2016; 55(1):202–227. 10.1080/00207543.2016.1201601. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Syed ARK, Muhammad T, Zhang Yu. Investigating recycling decisions of internet recyclers: A step towards zero waste economy. Journal of Environmental Management, 2023; 340:117968–117968. 10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.117968. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Riikka K, Jan H, Johanna S, Risto R. Information sharing for sales and operations planning: Contextualized solutions and mechanisms. Journal of Operations Management. 2017; 52(1):15–29. doi: 10.1016/j.jom.2017.04.001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Dan B, Ma SX, Liu ML. Research on information sharing of fresh agricultural products supply chain considering 3PL preservation efforts. Chinese Journal of Management Science. 2023; 1–16. http://kns.cnki.net/kcms/detail/11.2835.g3.20220304.1735.002.html. [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Liao N, Zhang ZJ, He Y. Value creation and willingness of information sharing in supply chain considering capacity constraint and distribution mode. Statistics & Decision. 2017; 485(17): 47–52. 10.13546/j.cnki.tjyjc.2017.17.010. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Shlomo B, Richard HT. Behavioral economics and the retirement savings crisis. Science. 2013; 339(6124):1152–1153. 10.1126/science.1231320. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Du SF, Nie TF, Chu CB, Yu YG. Newsvendor model for a dyadic supply chain with Nash bargaining fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Research. 2014; 52(17):5070–5085. doi: 10.1080/00207543.2014.895446 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Qin YH, Shao YF. Supply chain decisions under asymmetric information with cost and fairness concern[J]. Enterprise Information Systems.12019; 3(10):1347–1366. 10.1080/17517575.2019.1638974. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Pan KW, Cui ZB, Xing AX, Lu QH. Impact of fairness concern on retailer-dominated supply chain. Computers & Industrial Engineering. 2020; 139(C):106209.1–106209.9. 10.1016/j.cie.2019.106209. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Xiao QZ, Chen L, Xie M, Wang C. Optimal contract design in sustainable supply chain: Interactive impacts of fairness concern and overconfidence. Journal of the Operational Research Society. 2020; 72(7):1505–1524. 10.1080/01605682.2020.1727784. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Erin NM, Jared LC, Nicholas ZM, Inês MLA, Allen LR. Quantifying the social equity state of an energy system: environmental and labor market equity of the shale gas boom in Appalachia. Environmental Research Letters. 2019; 14(12). 10.1088/1748-9326/ab59cd. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Güth W, Schmittberger R, Schwarze B. An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 1982; 3(4). [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Amos T DANIEL K. Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 1992; 5(4), 297–323. [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Schweitzer ME, Gérard P. Cachon. Decision bias in the newsvendor problem with a known demand distribution: experimental evidence. Management Science. 2000; 46(3):404–420. 10.1287/mnsc.46.3.404.12070. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Dou YD, Sun XL, Ji AK, Wang YN, Xue XL. Development strategy for prefabricated construction projects: a tripartite evolutionary game based on prospect theory. Engineering, Construction and Architectural Management. 2023; 30(1):105–124. 10.1108/ECAM-05-2021-0455. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Wang WL, Wang ZH, Zhang SX, Liu Q. Financing Strategy for a Dual-channel Supply Chain that Faces Loss-averse Retailers and Stochastic Demands. Management Review. 2023; 35(05): 267–279. doi: 10.14120/j.cnki.cn11-5057/f.20221229.005 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Qiu GB. Study on Game of Multichannel Supply Chain Based on Service-loss Averse Consumer. 2019; 27(01): 108–114. [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Chen X, Hao G, Li L. Channel coordination with a loss-averse retailer and option contracts. International Journal of Production Economics. 2014; 150: 52–57. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2013.12.004 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Yu Zhang, Syed ARK. Evolutionary game analysis of green agricultural product supply chain financing system: COVID-19 pandemic. International Journal of Logistics Research and Applications 2021; (4): 1–21. 10.1080/13675567.2021.1879752. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Andrzej R. Supply chain decision making with use of game theory. Procedia Computer Science. 2022; 207:3988–3997. [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Sun M, Li L, Sun X. A study on national intelligence information sharing based on the evolutionary game theory. Journal of Intelligence. 2019; 38(11), 19–24+42. [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Du ZP, Qu YX. Research on information synergy mechanism of cross-border logistics alliance based on three-party evolutionary game. Chinese Journal of Management Science. 2023; 31(04):228–238. 10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2020.0416. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Morrakot R, William GF. Information sharing in supply chain collaboration. Computers & Industrial Engineering. 2016;126:269–281. 10.1016/j.cie.2018.09.042. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Zhang XF, Li G, Zheng H. Research on the cost information sharing strategy of supply chain channels under the risk of market invasion. Journal of Industrial Engineering and Engineering Management.2023; 37(05):230–237. 10.13587/j.cnki.jieem.2023.05.019. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Liu NN, Zhou GH. Evolutionary analysis of resource sharing of collaborative innovation in major infrastructure projects based on prospect theory. Journal of Industrial Engineering and Engineering Management. 2023; 37(03):69–79. 10.13587/j.cnki.jieem.2023.03.007. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Tsunoda YS, Zennyo Y. Platform information transparency and effects on third‐party suppliers and offline retailers. Production and Operations Management. 2021; 30(11): 4219–4235. 10.1111/poms.13518. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Li F, Qian XY, Kong J, Luo ZCY. Evolutionary game analysis of information sharing among closed-loop supply chain members in cloud environment. Arabian Journal for Science and Engineering. 2022; 47(3):3945–3961. 10.1007/s13369-021-06264-5. [DOI] [Google Scholar]

Decision Letter 0

Syed Abdul Rehman Khan

6 Sep 2023

PONE-D-23-26347Analysis of the Evolutionary Process of Multi-agent Information Sharing Behavior under Supply Chain CollaborationPLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Gan,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

Dear authors,

Thank you for choosing PLOS ONE as an outlet for your paper publication. We have received evaluations from experts. The reviewers have highlighted several issues which need to be answered and strengthen the quality of this draft.

Authors should take these comments into account and adjust the manuscript content accordingly.

1. The draft needs to be significantly improved. In addition to the improvements requested by Reviewers, you should expand them in line with the PLOS ONE guidelines and revise the abstract accordingly.

2. Reviewers highlight several issues concerning the introduction, literature review, and conclusion sections. Therefore, Revising these sections to meet the publication criteria of PLOS ONE is suggested.

3. This article requires proofreading to enhance the linguistic quality further. Also, please update the reference list, preferably referencing recent works published in top leading journals.

4. I suggest authors ensure that all the cited articles should be properly listed in the reference section.

Please submit your revised manuscript by Oct 21 2023 11:59PM. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at plosone@plos.org. When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols. Additionally, PLOS ONE offers an option for publishing peer-reviewed Lab Protocol articles, which describe protocols hosted on protocols.io. Read more information on sharing protocols at https://plos.org/protocols?utm_medium=editorial-email&utm_source=authorletters&utm_campaign=protocols.

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Syed Abdul Rehman Khan, PhD

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal Requirements:

1. When submitting your revision, we need you to address these additional requirements. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=wjVg/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=ba62/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf 2. Please note that PLOS ONE has specific guidelines on code sharing for submissions in which author-generated code underpins the findings in the manuscript. In these cases, all author-generated code must be made available without restrictions upon publication of the work. Please review our guidelines at https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/materials-and-software-sharing#loc-sharing-code and ensure that your code is shared in a way that follows best practice and facilitates reproducibility and reuse. 3. We note that the grant information you provided in the ‘Funding Information’ and ‘Financial Disclosure’ sections do not match.  When you resubmit, please ensure that you provide the correct grant numbers for the awards you received for your study in the ‘Funding Information’ section.  4. In your Data Availability statement, you have not specified where the minimal data set underlying the results described in your manuscript can be found. PLOS defines a study's minimal data set as the underlying data used to reach the conclusions drawn in the manuscript and any additional data required to replicate the reported study findings in their entirety. All PLOS journals require that the minimal data set be made fully available. For more information about our data policy, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability. Upon re-submitting your revised manuscript, please upload your study’s minimal underlying data set as either Supporting Information files or to a stable, public repository and include the relevant URLs, DOIs, or accession numbers within your revised cover letter. For a list of acceptable repositories, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-recommended-repositories. Any potentially identifying patient information must be fully anonymized. Important: If there are ethical or legal restrictions to sharing your data publicly, please explain these restrictions in detail. Please see our guidelines for more information on what we consider unacceptable restrictions to publicly sharing data: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-unacceptable-data-access-restrictions. Note that it is not acceptable for the authors to be the sole named individuals responsible for ensuring data access. We will update your Data Availability statement to reflect the information you provide in your cover letter. 5. PLOS requires an ORCID iD for the corresponding author in Editorial Manager on papers submitted after December 6th, 2016. Please ensure that you have an ORCID iD and that it is validated in Editorial Manager. To do this, go to ‘Update my Information’ (in the upper left-hand corner of the main menu), and click on the Fetch/Validate link next to the ORCID field. This will take you to the ORCID site and allow you to create a new iD or authenticate a pre-existing iD in Editorial Manager. Please see the following video for instructions on linking an ORCID iD to your Editorial Manager account: https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=_xcclfuvtxQ

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

2. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

3. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

4. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

5. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: This study conducted on the Analysis of the Evolutionary Process of Multi-agent Information Sharing Behavior under Supply Chain Collaboration. I found the article required significant improvement in revision phase. Following are my suggestions:

1. Title of this article is fine but it would be better to make it more attractive.

2. Abstract needs to be revise and further include the key findings of this study.

3. Introduction section is not properly covering all the parameters of this study. Therefore, I recommend to include clearly "Research objective" . it will be better to include a subheading of "Research objective" in introduction section and explain the research objective.

4. Authors should include and cite the up-to-date relevant articles published in top ranked journals. Also, it would be better to include the published articles, which adopted same methodology in the domain of supply chain. Following articles can be considered:

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.procs.2022.09.461

https://doi.org/10.1080/13675567.2021.1879752

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.117968

5. Managerial implications are not sufficient. Please extend it and further include new implications.

6. This article required English proofread.

Reviewer #2: This study aims to explore the dynamic evolution process and influencing factors of multi-agent information sharing behavior decision-making under supply chain collaboration. This paper constructed an evolutionary game model with suppliers and retailers as the main subjects, using a combination of game theory and prospect theory, and constructed an information sharing prospect value matrix by combining prospect value functions and weight functions. The study is interesting. However, there are some issues that need to be revised. My specific comments are as follows:

1. Overall, the writing could be further improved. There are some grammatical errors/typos to be aware of. Please revise them carefully. e.g.

“However, in this study, it is believed that its value depend on …”

Inconsistent formatting of formula numbering.

2. The motivation and contribution of this study should be clearly highlighted in the introduction. The current statement in this portion is too weak.

3. As stated by the authors, this study distinguishes from existing research by the subjects' behavioral decisions on information sharing from the perspective of supply chain cooperation. Then, the authors should explain in detail in the manuscript how this study embodies supply chain collaboration in addition to information sharing and what collaboration factors are considered.

4. The picture of fig. 1 should be on the same page as the figure notes.

5. The authors should describe the compilation environment used for the simulation experiment.

6. The authors should explain why the parameter settings in literature [14,38] are used.

7. How the uncertainty of the environment is represented in the study.

8. The authors should analyze the results of the experiment to help readers understand the meaning and results of the experiment, rather than just describing the content of the picture.

**********

6. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article (what does this mean?). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: No

**********

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

PLoS One. 2024 Mar 15;19(3):e0298355. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0298355.r002

Author response to Decision Letter 0


16 Oct 2023

Response to Reviewers

Dear Syed Abdul Rehman Khan, PhD

Academic Editor, PLOS ONE

Title:An Evolutionary Analysis of Supply Chain Collaborative Information Sharing Based on Prospect Theory

Authors:Meng Liu, Luyu Zhai, Hongcheng Gan

Dear Syed Abdul Rehman Khan, PhD

We would like to thank you for the prompt review of our paper and for the opportunity to respond to Academic Editor, Reviewers #1, #2. All reviewers provided us with insightful and valuable comments. We have revised our paper and addressed all of the issues raised by all reviewers, based on their comments and suggestions. We have attached a point by point response for the reviewers. Please see the details bellow. Thank you again for giving us the opportunity to revise the paper. Suggestions and comments from the reviewers have further significantly improved our paper.

Sincerely,

The Authors

Encl.

(1) Responses to comments of Academic Editor

(2) Responses to comments of Reviewer #1

(3) Responses to comments of Reviewer #2

Responses to Comments of Academic Editor

We would like to thank you for your time spent in reviewing our paper and for providing us with valuable comments and suggestions. We also appreciate your positive view on our results and hope that this version has fully addressed your concerns. To make it easy to follow, we first show (in italic) your comment and then present our response (in normal font).

Comments

1. The draft needs to be significantly improved. In addition to the improvements requested by Reviewers, you should expand them in line with the PLOS ONE guidelines and revise the abstract accordingly.

2. Reviewers highlight several issues concerning the introduction, literature review, and conclusion sections. Therefore, Revising these sections to meet the publication criteria of PLOS ONE is suggested.

3. This article requires proofreading to enhance the linguistic quality further. Also, please update the reference list, preferably referencing recent works published in top leading journals.

4. I suggest authors ensure that all the cited articles should be properly listed in the reference section.

Response/Revision: Firstly,We have made revisions as per the reviewer's request to the abstract, introduction, literature review, and conclusion sections, and have improved the language quality of the article. Additionally, we have updated the references, adding recent publications from top leading journals and removing some references to ensure that all referenced articles are correctly listed in the reference section. We have made modifications to meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. We have removed incorrect funding numbers and have decided not to include related funding information. Since our data involves assigning values to certain parameters, and these values are already provided in the article, they were referenced from data in previously published literature, and we have explained the reasons for referencing these publications. The corresponding authors have also registered their ORCID iD, which has been validated in Editorial Manager.

Thank you again for the suggestions and comments, which have further improved our paper.

Responses to Comments of Reviewer #1

We would like to thank you for your time spent in reviewing our paper and for providing us with valuable comments and suggestions. We also appreciate your positive view on our results and hope that this version has fully addressed your concerns. To make it easy to follow, we first show (in italic) your comment and then present our response (in normal font).

Comments

Comment #1 1. Title of this article is fine but it would be better to make it more attractive.

Response/Revision: Thanks for the comment, and it is a very correct suggestion.In this revision, I've changed the title of the article to "An Evolutionary Analysis of Supply Chain Collaborative Information Sharing Based on Prospect Theory".

Comment #2 Abstract needs to be revise and further include the key findings of this study.

Response/Revision: Thanks for pointing out! Following your suggestion, Thank you for your suggestions. I have already revised the abstract section of the article and have further include the key findings of this study. Please see the details bellow.

“Abstract

In order to delve into the dynamic evolution process and influencing factors of information sharing decisions among stakeholders under supply chain collaboration, this study constructs an evolutionary game model with suppliers and retailers as the primary entities. Within this model, a combined approach of game theory and prospect theory is employed, integrating prospect value functions and weight functions to create an information sharing prospect value matrix. A comprehensive analysis is conducted on the strategic choices and benefits of entities considering the psychological perception of information sharing, and critical factors influencing the stability of information sharing evolution results are explored through numerical simulations using Matlab. The key findings of this study are as follows: Firstly, from the perspective of supply chain collaboration, the probability of entities evolving into information sharing is negatively correlated with the cost of information sharing and positively correlated with the benefits generated by information coordination. Secondly, looking at supply chain collaboration, entities are more likely to engage in information sharing behavior when they exhibit a lower level of risk aversion, indicating greater rationality, when facing profits; conversely, they are more likely to participate in information sharing when they display a higher degree of risk preference, indicating less rationality, in the face of losses. Furthermore, the lesser sensitivity of suppliers and retailers to losses is more likely to drive the system towards an information-sharing state. Based on the primary findings mentioned above, this study offers recommendations for enhancing trust, constructing information exchange platforms, and adjusting psychological awareness. These suggestions contribute to improving information sharing among entities within the supply chain, thus enhancing the overall efficiency and collaboration of the supply chain.”

Comment #3 Introduction section is not properly covering all the parameters of this study. Therefore, I recommend to include clearly "Research objective" . it will be better to include a subheading of "Research objective" in introduction section and explain the research objective.

Response: Thanks for your comments! In the introduction section of the article, I have added relevant descriptions of the research objectives and contributions in the introduction, and provided further explanations of the research objectives and contributions (In lines 118-136). Please see the details bellow.

“In light of the aforementioned limitations, this study, grounded in the perspective of supply chain collaboration, seeks to uncover the latent psychological and behavioral factors in supply chain information sharing decision-making. Specifically, drawing from the assumption of bounded rationality in game theory[32] and combining it with prospect theory, the study examines how the perception of value and risk aversion by game players influence the patterns of system evolution and stability. Through these investigations, we aim to provide a deeper understanding for enterprises and supply chain practitioners, enabling them to refine their decision-making and practices. Furthermore, we hope this research contributes to enriching the foundational theoretical framework of supply chain collaboration and offers new perspectives and scientific methods to researchers in the field.

The main contributions of this study are as follows: 1. It analyzes the behavioral decisions of supply chain decision-makers from the perspective of supply chain collaboration, offering a novel viewpoint. 2. By introducing prospect theory into the domain of supply chain collaboration management, the study provides a fresh theoretical framework that elucidates the evolutionary process of information sharing in supply chains, enriching the existing supply chain theory. 3. This research can assist supply chain decision-makers in better understanding the impact of psychological factors on their decision-making, providing effective guidance for practice. 4. The study also presents research insights and future prospects, serving as a reference and offering suggestions for related researchers.”

Comment #4 Authors should include and cite the up-to-date relevant articles published in top ranked journals. Also, it would be better to include the published articles, which adopted same methodology in the domain of supply chain. Following articles can be considered:

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.procs.2022.09.461

https://doi.org/10.1080/13675567.2021.1879752

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.117968

Response/Revision: Thanks for comments! We have cited the up-to-date relevant articles published in top ranked journals.And citing the articles you recommended, the relevant articles have already been indicated in the references section.

Comment #5 Managerial implications are not sufficient. Please extend it and further include new implications.

Response/Revision: Thanks for the comment! This is a very good suggestion. We have revised the relevant managerial implications and expanded to further include new implications (In lines 500-529). Please see the details bellow.

“4.2 Management implications

This paper proposes the following management implications:

(1)Information sharing among supply chain entities is influenced by a multitude of factors, including members' knowledge acquisition capabilities, partner relationships, digitalization levels, and information heterogeneity. To enhance the benefits derived from inter-enterprise information sharing, there should be a strengthening of inter-firm collaborations and a concerted effort to enhance the learning and information integration abilities of supply chain members.

(2) Recognizing the pivotal role of information sharing in supply chain collaboration, management should foster an open information flow between suppliers and retailers to bolster cooperation and overall supply chain efficiency.

(3) High information maintenance costs can impede information sharing within collaborative supply chains. To mitigate these costs, such as communication overheads, advanced technologies like 5G, artificial intelligence, and the Internet of Things (IoT) can be employed to establish collaborative information sharing platforms. This, in turn, can stimulate a proactive approach to information exchange and cultivate a spirit of mutual cooperation.

(4) Notably, the research underscores differences in organizational behavior psychology regarding losses and gains among members. Therefore, it is advisable to engage professionals versed in organizational behavior psychology and risk analysis to provide training and elevate employees' psychological resilience. This, in turn, would reduce their sensitivity to losses.

(5) In the pursuit of effective supply chain collaboration, a keen focus should be placed on the information integration and collection capabilities of potential partners during the partner selection phase. Improved communication, facilitated by efficient information sharing, can be instrumental in resolving challenges encountered during collaboration.

(6) Effective information sharing strategies hinge on trust among supply chain partners. Management efforts should concentrate on fostering trust through shared success stories, transparent contracts, and commitments.

Therefore, to achieve the optimal state of supply chain collaborative information sharing, it is necessary to consider and address the aforementioned factors and challenges, improve the level of trust and understanding among all entities, rectify decision makers' cognitive biases, and adapt to the dynamic and uncertain market environment.”

Comment #6 This article required English proofread.

Response/Revision: Thanks for the comment! This is a very good suggestion. We have thoroughly proofread the entire English text.

Thank you again for the suggestions and comments, which have further improved our paper.

Responses to Comments of Reviewer #2

We would like to thank you for your time spent in reviewing our paper and for providing us with valuable comments and suggestions. We also appreciate your positive view on our results and hope that this version has fully addressed your concerns. To make it easy to follow, we first show (in italic) your comment and then present our response (in normal font).

Comments

Comment #1 Overall, the writing could be further improved. There are some grammatical errors/typos to be aware of. Please revise them carefully. e.g.

“However, in this study, it is believed that its value depend on …”

Inconsistent formatting of formula numbering.

Response/Revision: Thanks for the comment! This is a very good suggestion. We have thoroughly proofread the entire English text. We have already changed the formula numbering

Comment #2 The motivation and contribution of this study should be clearly highlighted in the introduction. The current statement in this portion is too weak.

Response: Thanks for your comments! In the introduction section of the article, I have added relevant descriptions of the research motivation and contributions in the introduction, and provided further explanations of the research motivation and contributions (In lines 118-136). Please see the details bellow.

“In light of the aforementioned limitations, this study, grounded in the perspective of supply chain collaboration, seeks to uncover the latent psychological and behavioral factors in supply chain information sharing decision-making. Specifically, drawing from the assumption of bounded rationality in game theory[32] and combining it with prospect theory, the study examines how the perception of value and risk aversion by game players influence the patterns of system evolution and stability. Through these investigations, we aim to provide a deeper understanding for enterprises and supply chain practitioners, enabling them to refine their decision-making and practices. Furthermore, we hope this research contributes to enriching the foundational theoretical framework of supply chain collaboration and offers new perspectives and scientific methods to researchers in the field.

The main contributions of this study are as follows: 1. It analyzes the behavioral decisions of supply chain decision-makers from the perspective of supply chain collaboration, offering a novel viewpoint. 2. By introducing prospect theory into the domain of supply chain collaboration management, the study provides a fresh theoretical framework that elucidates the evolutionary process of information sharing in supply chains, enriching the existing supply chain theory. 3. This research can assist supply chain decision-makers in better understanding the impact of psychological factors on their decision-making, providing effective guidance for practice. 4. The study also presents research insights and future prospects, serving as a reference and offering suggestions for related researchers.”

Comment #3 As stated by the authors, this study distinguishes from existing research by the subjects' behavioral decisions on information sharing from the perspective of supply chain cooperation. Then, the authors should explain in detail in the manuscript how this study embodies supply chain collaboration in addition to information sharing and what collaboration factors are considered.

Response/Revision: We are grateful for your approval of this paper. I explain this issue as follows. In previous research, some scholars have also contended that trust mechanisms, collaborative decision-making, and supply chain visibility are vital determinants of supply chain collaboration. Nevertheless, information sharing has often been considered as the fundamental prerequisite for supply chain collaboration in numerous studies, sometimes even synonymous with collaboration itself. Consequently, in the interest of model simplification, this study exclusively investigates scenarios where supply chain collaboration is achieved through information sharing alone. Your comments have provided the author with valuable insights. Considering other collaborative factors and the interaction between factors is part of the author's future research plans.And we have provided corresponding explanations in the text (In lines 99-105). Please see the details bellow.

“In previous research, some scholars have also contended that trust mechanisms, collaborative decision-making, and supply chain visibility are vital determinants of supply chain collaboration. Nevertheless, information sharing has often been considered as the fundamental prerequisite for supply chain collaboration in numerous studies, sometimes even synonymous with collaboration itself. Consequently, in the interest of model simplification, this study exclusively investigates scenarios where supply chain collaboration is achieved through information sharing alone. ”

Comment #4 The picture of fig. 1 should be on the same page as the figure notes.

Response/Revision: Thanks! I have already restructured the images.

Fig 1. Phase diagram of the system in different cases

Comment #5 The authors should describe the compilation environment used for the simulation experiment.

Response/Revision: Thanks for comments! We have provided a detailed description of the compilation environment used for the simulation experiment (In lines 344-349). Please see the details bellow.

“MATLAB, recognized as a sophisticated mathematical computing and programming environment, finds extensive application across scientific, engineering, data analysis, and machine learning domains. Its robust mathematical computing capabilities, coupled with an array of rich toolboxes, enable parallel processing. Furthermore, its potent graphical and visualization functions were pivotal in selecting it as the primary software for simulation analysis in this study.”

Comment #6 The authors should explain why the parameter settings in literature [14,38] are used.

Response/Revision: Thanks for comments! We have provided a detailed explanation for the use of parameter settings from references [11, 32] (In lines 350-356). Due to the reorganization of the references, the numbering has changed. Please see the details bellow.

“Literatures [11, 32] were referenced for parameter setting. We referred to existing literature for the following reasons: 1. The parameter settings in the literature are founded on established theories, with authors validating the effectiveness of these parameters. 2. The literature we consulted exhibits a degree of relevance to our research, offering valuable insights for parameter configuration. 3. These parameter configurations yield optimal visual analytical outcomes.In addition, the data has been adjusted repeatedly to achieve a good visual analysis effect.”

Comment #7 How the uncertainty of the environment is represented in the study.

Response/Revision: Thanks for comments! In this paper, uncertainty is primarily explored during simulations by assigning different initial values. Additionally, the paper includes descriptions of uncertainty and outlines future research directions (In lines 332-338) (In lines 539-543). Please see the details bellow.

“Finally, the uncertainty in the environment in which the supply chain operates may also play a role. Information collaboration benefits depend not only on the amount of information shared and the information absorption and transformation capabilities of both parties but are also influenced by external turbulent environments. However, uncertain environmental factors can have both positive and negative effects, making it difficult to intuitively assess their impact on the system's evolutionary outcomes. Addressing this potential factor is a focus of future research for the author.

Furthermore, the supply chain environment is inherently uncertain, with environmental factors capable of both positive and negative impacts. These uncertainties can significantly affect system evolution outcomes, although discerning their precise influence can prove challenging. Future research endeavors may delve into the realm of uncertainty theory and methods to shed light on environmental uncertainties.”

Comment #8 The authors should analyze the results of the experiment to help readers understand the meaning and results of the experiment, rather than just describing the content of the picture.

Response/Revision: Thanks for comments! In the simulation section, we have added descriptions of the experimental results to assist readers in understanding the significance and outcomes of the experiments (In lines 370-376) (In lines 387-394) (In lines 402-411) (In lines 426-431) (In lines 441-445) (In lines 455-459) (In lines 468-473). Please see the details bellow.

“It can be observed that the higher initial probabilities for suppliers and retailers expedite the rate of convergence toward cooperation (Figs 2b and 2c). This outcome underscores that when the willingness of both parties for initial information sharing is low, it hampers inter-enterprise information sharing. Hence, whether acting as a supplier or retailer, proactive engagement in constructive information exchange with supply chain counterparts, the establishment of trust mechanisms, and the actualization of information sharing are advisable.

Hence, elevated information sharing costs serve as a deterrent to inter-enterprise information sharing. As costs rise, enterprises become less inclined to engage in information sharing. At this juncture, it is imperative to harness advanced technologies such as 5G, artificial intelligence, and the Internet of Things (IoT) to reduce costs. This, in turn, ensures mutual information sharing and fosters supply chain collaboration. In summary, there exists an inverse correlation between the probability of system convergence to sharing and information sharing costs. Lowering information sharing costs and enhancing efficiency can encourage proactive information sharing among decision-makers.

This outcome signifies that when supply chain enterprises anticipate higher additional gains from information sharing, they are more inclined to partake in it. Information sharing within the supply chain grants retailers access to precise market demand information, given their proximity to the market, while suppliers hold inventory, transportation, and logistics data. The exchange of information between both parties further augments market share, thereby increasing additional gains. Consequently, supply chain enterprises should promptly share information conducive to enhancing market share, including market demand forecasts, inventory information, transportation, and logistics data, among others. This sharing, however, should exclude information pertaining to each entity's core competitive advantages.

This underscores that for supply chain enterprises aiming to maximize profits and market share, increasing the quantity and frequency of information sharing is imperative. This information should encompass market demand forecasts, inventory data, transportation, logistics information, and other insights conducive to optimizing decision-making. However, it should exclude details pertaining to each entity's core competitive strengths.

The results emphasize that when supply chain enterprises engage in information sharing, they should strive to mitigate their sensitivity to losses. The focus should remain on long-term gains and development, without undue concern for short-term cost investments. Attention to long-term returns and growth should take precedence over heightened sensitivity to initial costs.

The findings suggest that when supply chain enterprises engage in information sharing and stand to gain from it, they should not solely focus on short-term gains. Instead, they should prioritize long-term gains and development. In situations involving potential gains, they should further invest effectively to maximize returns.

These findings underscore that, when supply chain enterprises engage in information sharing that might result in losses, they should strive to temper their emotional response to such losses. While risk aversion can stimulate the occurrence of information-sharing behaviors, it may inadvertently lead to the neglect of larger potential losses stemming from unforeseen risks. To address this, the implementation of risk-sharing mechanisms can serve as a more effective means of risk management.”

Thank you again for the suggestions and comments, which have further improved our paper.

Attachment

Submitted filename: Response to Reviewers.docx

pone.0298355.s002.docx (67.2KB, docx)

Decision Letter 1

Bo Huang

23 Jan 2024

An Evolutionary Analysis of Supply Chain Collaborative Information Sharing Based on Prospect Theory

PONE-D-23-26347R1

Dear Dr. Hongcheng Gan,

We’re pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been judged scientifically suitable for publication and will be formally accepted for publication once it meets all outstanding technical requirements.

Within one week, you’ll receive an e-mail detailing the required amendments. When these have been addressed, you’ll receive a formal acceptance letter and your manuscript will be scheduled for publication.

An invoice for payment will follow shortly after the formal acceptance. To ensure an efficient process, please log into Editorial Manager at http://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/, click the 'Update My Information' link at the top of the page, and double check that your user information is up-to-date. If you have any billing related questions, please contact our Author Billing department directly at authorbilling@plos.org.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper to help maximize its impact. If they’ll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team as soon as possible -- no later than 48 hours after receiving the formal acceptance. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

Kind regards,

Bo Huang

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. If the authors have adequately addressed your comments raised in a previous round of review and you feel that this manuscript is now acceptable for publication, you may indicate that here to bypass the “Comments to the Author” section, enter your conflict of interest statement in the “Confidential to Editor” section, and submit your "Accept" recommendation.

Reviewer #1: All comments have been addressed

**********

2. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: Yes

**********

3. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

Reviewer #1: Yes

**********

4. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

Reviewer #1: Yes

**********

5. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

Reviewer #1: Yes

**********

6. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: This article is ready for publication.

**********

7. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article (what does this mean?). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy.

Reviewer #1: No

**********

Acceptance letter

Bo Huang

7 Mar 2024

PONE-D-23-26347R1

PLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Gan,

I'm pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been deemed suitable for publication in PLOS ONE. Congratulations! Your manuscript is now being handed over to our production team.

At this stage, our production department will prepare your paper for publication. This includes ensuring the following:

* All references, tables, and figures are properly cited

* All relevant supporting information is included in the manuscript submission,

* There are no issues that prevent the paper from being properly typeset

If revisions are needed, the production department will contact you directly to resolve them. If no revisions are needed, you will receive an email when the publication date has been set. At this time, we do not offer pre-publication proofs to authors during production of the accepted work. Please keep in mind that we are working through a large volume of accepted articles, so please give us a few weeks to review your paper and let you know the next and final steps.

Lastly, if your institution or institutions have a press office, please let them know about your upcoming paper now to help maximize its impact. If they'll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team within the next 48 hours. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

If we can help with anything else, please email us at customercare@plos.org.

Thank you for submitting your work to PLOS ONE and supporting open access.

Kind regards,

PLOS ONE Editorial Office Staff

on behalf of

Professor Bo Huang

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Associated Data

    This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

    Supplementary Materials

    S1 File

    (DOCX)

    pone.0298355.s001.docx (21.8KB, docx)
    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Response to Reviewers.docx

    pone.0298355.s002.docx (67.2KB, docx)

    Data Availability Statement

    All relevant data are in the manuscript and its Supporting Information files.


    Articles from PLOS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

    RESOURCES