Skip to main content
PLOS One logoLink to PLOS One
. 2024 May 10;19(5):e0296654. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0296654

How do e-commerce platforms and retailers implement discount pricing policies under consumers are strategic?

Hao Li 1,2, ZHe Chen 1,*
Editor: Vincenzo Basile3
PMCID: PMC11086857  PMID: 38728313

Abstract

In the era of the rapid development of e-commerce, many retailers choose to launch promotional activities to become consumers’ first choice for shopping. Since price discounts can greatly attract consumers, the e-commerce platforms have also begun to implement discount pricing. It is urgent for e-commerce platforms and retailers to formulate reasonable discount strategies to achieve sustainable business. In this paper, we construct a dynamic game model for implementing discount pricing on an e-commerce platform and two retailers, we study the market equilibrium between the two retailers and the e-commerce platform under various scenarios that considering consumers’ strategic waiting behavior and competition between the two retailers, we further discuss the effectiveness of retailer discount pricing and the double discount pricing of the platform and retailers. We show that the optimal pricing decreases as the difference in product quality narrows under both pricing strategies. Low-quality retailers implementing a double discount pricing strategy are in relatively higher demand only when the difference in product quality is small. High-quality retailers implementing the retailer discount pricing strategy are in relatively higher demand only when the product quality difference is large. Double discount pricing is desirable for both e-commerce platforms and retailers and can be used to effectively achieve Pareto improvement in the market by increasing their expected profit. Our results emphasize the role of product quality and the value of the double discount pricing strategy. The double discount pricing strategy weakens the profit advantage that retailers and platforms gain from it as the rebate intensity and rebate redemption rates increase.

1. Introduction

In recent years, the online sales model organized by large e-commerce platforms with the participation of many online retailers has had a significant positive impact on the global economy. According to the latest data from eMarketer, the total global e-commerce transactions amounted to 4.938 trillion dollars in 2022. Online sales usually take the form of discount sales at specific times, such as “Black Friday” and “Cyber Monday” in the United States, “Boxing Day” in Singapore, and “618” and “Double Eleven” in China. the purpose is to achieve customer penetration through shopping festivals. The emergence of these shopping seasons has greatly boosted the growth of product sales. For example, the huge consumer market in China has led to the rapid growth in online retail sales, which amounted to 2.56 trillion dollars accounting for 51.9% of the global sales. More than 300,000 brand retailers participated in Tmall “Double Eleven” in 2022, with sales exceeding 965.1 billion CNY on the day [1]. Online sales enable retailers to deal with customers more cost-effectively and efficiently than in traditional sales, while discount sales strategies under online sales provide e-commerce platforms and online retailers with a market means to enhance competitiveness, in order to improve market competitiveness under the network economy.

In the discount sales season, the product discounts enjoyed by consumers are often provided by e-commerce platforms or retailers in different forms on e-commerce platforms. In terms of online discount sales promotion, Amazon Japan launched promotional activities in advance of “Black Friday”, including “50% off the whole site+ reward points”, “free shipping” and “cash back”. Similarly, Pinduoduo, one of the most famous e-commerce platforms in China, launched a “Billions Subsidies Promotion” to discount more than 23,000 products in 2019, and sold 400,000 units of the iPhone 11 on “Double Eleven” resulting in a 20-fold increase in sales of the iPhone series compared to the same period in the previous year. Alibaba started the 2022 Double Eleven early on 24 October and warmed up comprehensively through various platforms such as TikTok and Weibo. Meanwhile, retailers on the e-commerce platform issue coupons in advance in order to promote their promotion information more widely to expand their brand influence, and increase consumers’ enthusiasm for participation, this includes “Full 300 minus 50”, “Two for One”, “Time-limited sec-killing”, etc. Therefore, consumers can enjoy single discounts from retailers or double discounts from e-commerce platforms and retailers. The double discount is enough to send consumers on a shopping spree and drive a large wave of online spending.

In practical terms, various discount sales have a significant impact on consumers, leading to consumers’ strategic waiting behavior. Currently, consumers are becoming more sophisticated and more strategic after years of discount sales. They tend to put their favorite products in their “shopping cart” before the sale and wait for discount to buy them to get a higher “thrill of the discount”. The impact of such strategic consumer behavior on the retailer’s profit performance can be highly detrimental, This strategic consumer behavior may have a very harmful impact on the profit performance of retailers, which may lead to many retailers sacrificing their participation in product profit for several months during discount sales to engage in price wars in exchange for increased sales, ultimately falling into a vicious cycle of “price reduction—price reduction”. According to the statistics of “People’s Daily Online of China”, more than 90% of participating retailers in the massive discount sales on e-commerce platforms are just “loss leaders” [2]. Meanwhile, consumers who wait until the double discount sale period are faced with various promotional activities and complicated promotional rules on e-commerce platforms, such as “Presale”, “Lazada bonus” and other prepurchase discount models as well as “Scratch cards”, “Refund of deposit” and other postpurchase cashback models. They need to know various promotional rules in advance to participate in promotional activities to obtain coupons, so as to purchase the cheap and cheerful products they have long wanted. However, consumers may experience a “slip” phenomenon in the postrebate model, that is, consumers need to make efforts to obtain rebates, but may not redeem the rebate after purchasing the product. As a result, many promotions\discounts do not convert well. This has important implications for e-commerce platforms and retailers with double discount sales strategies.

In the context of the existing discount sales, exploring the rules of discount pricing and breaking the plight of retailers’ bleak operation is the key to the successful operation of enterprises and the sustainable development of discount sales seasons such as internet shopping festivals. How should e-commerce platforms and retailers implement their discount strategies in the face of consumers with strategic waiting behavior? It is therefore desirable to endogenous the strategic waiting behavior of consumers, capturing its effect on the pricing strategies of e-commerce platforms and retailers. To this end, we establish a two-stage pricing game model between two retailers and between two retailers and an e-commerce platform, and use this model to solve the equilibrium problem of the two-stage model. We attempt to answer the following questions:1) How do two retailers set optimal product prices to balance regular sales periods and discount sales periods? 2) In the case of rebates on the e-commerce platform, how can retailers change the market price and sales strategy considering that consumers enjoy product rebates on e-commerce platform? 3) What conditions would e-commerce platforms choose to provide rebates when retailers engage in two-stage discount pricing sales?

To address these questions, we propose the double discount pricing strategy based on traditional retailer discount pricing strategies, which differs from the traditional retailer discount pricing strategy in that we consider both e-commerce platforms and retailers providing discount to consumers. We compare the retailer discount pricing strategy to the double discount pricing strategy. These strategies are as follows: First, only the retailer implements discount pricing with a price reduction in the next period. Second, on the basis of the discount pricing implemented by the retailer, the e-commerce platform offers a rebate discount to the consumer, who can enjoy double discounts, one from the retailer and one from the e-commerce platform. Finally, we obtain the relevant factors that affect the profits of retailers and e-commerce platforms, and the applicable conditions of the different discount pricing strategies through equilibrium analysis.

This study contributes to the current literature in several aspects. First, we introduce consumers’ strategic waiting behavior into pricing strategy research. We consider that some consumers may purchase products directly from manufacturers because they have a greater motivation to obtain products first. In contrast, some consumers may wait until the price of the product is reduced before purchasing the product. Second, we pay more attention to the actual competition situation of the platform, and competition problem between two retailers, we deeply explore the comparison between the discount pricing of the two retailers and the dual discount pricing of retailers and e-commerce platforms, we simplify the process of solving for the equilibrium profit of retailers and e-commerce platforms under different strategies, to clarify the optimal decision under different ranges. Third, since retailers’ discounts and e-commerce platform rebate decisions have a certain impact on revenue, we analyze the effectiveness of the double discount pricing strategy compared with the traditional retailer discount pricing strategy, we also consider the consumer rebate redemption rate in the double discount pricing strategy. This provides some guidance for the pricing decisions of retailers and e-commerce platforms.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the relevant literature. Section 3 introduces the model and parameters. Section 4 introduces and analyzes the two-period dynamic game model of discount pricing between retailers and considers the case of double discount pricing when retailers engage in discount pricing while e-commerce platforms offer rebates, and analyzes the double discount pricing strategy equilibrium. Section 5 reports the numerical results and management insights of our model and analysis. Section 6 summarizes and highlights some future research directions. All proofs are included in the S1 Appendix.

2. Literature review

Our paper belongs to the stream of management science literature that studies the effects of strategic consumer behavior in the context of revenue management. We provide a review of a representative group. To keep the review of related research papers concise and effective, we split the presentation into several key aspects, including pricing decisions by retailers under consumer strategic waiting behavior, discount pricing strategies by retailers, and double discount pricing strategies by e-commerce platforms and retailers. We review relevant literature from the combination of these aspects and position our work relative to the literature.

One key aspect we address in this paper is consumers’ strategic waiting behavior, a phenomenon that has been a topic of discussion in the behavioral economics and revenue management literature in recent years. Muth [3] and Coase et al. [4] demonstrate that it will contribute to a 20% increase in profits if the seller considers strategic consumer behavior in pricing decisions. Aviv [5], Otero [6], Li [7], Aflaki [8], and Zhang [9] focused on the pricing mechanism for retailers to deal with consumer strategic waiting behavior when there is only one price reduction point. These authors found that consumer strategic waiting behavior has a significant impact on retailers’ pricing decisions, and retailers need to consider differences in strategic waiting willingness among consumers to effectively respond to market competition. Elmaghrab et al. [10] and Levin et al. [11] extended the number of price reductions to a finite number of times, studied the multi period pricing equilibrium problem for retailers under consumer strategic behavior, and developed a multi period dynamic pricing model to achieve market Pareto improvement. Su and Zhang [12] and Liu and Zhang [13] explored the dynamic pricing equilibrium problem of perishable goods considering consumers′ price comparison behavior of intertemporal switching under a duopoly competition. Ozgun et al. [14] and Zhou et al. [15] studied pricing product decisions under strategic behavior and discussed the impact of this behavior on the performance of each node enterprise and supply chain performance.

The above studies fully illustrate the need for retailers to consider consumer strategic behavior in price strategies. Many retailers are beginning to attract consumers through price wars of discounted sales. Aviv and Pazgal [5] consider the problem of selling a fixed number of seasonal products to customers whose product valuations decline over time. Rhee and Thomadsen [16] found that if consumers offer sufficient discounts for future periods, companies at a competitive disadvantage will reward their customers, that is, if the difference in quality adjustment costs between the two companies is small, low-quality companies will reward their current customers, while if the cost difference is large, high-quality companies will reward their current customers. Jeong and Maruyama [17] found that a firm’s optimal discounting strategy is to offer discounts to new customers in markets with more inertial consumers and higher switching costs, while firms offer discounts to past customers in a market where there are more variety-seeking consumers with large staying costs. Mantin and Veldman [18] consider consumers with strategic behaviors, and in the case of process improvement efforts, such supplier-initiated efforts ultimately reduce production costs and may translate into lower wholesale prices and lower consumer prices. Yang et al. [19] compared a two-advance-order-discount model with a one-advance-order-discount model and found the optimal decisions of upstream firms. In recent years, the discount sales strategy of the e-commerce platform in the online shopping festival further exacerbates the strategic behavior of consumers. It is worth researching and paying attention to how the coordination of the normal sales seasons and the discount sales seasons between the platform and retailers can be achieved when the discount sales strategy of e-commerce platforms includes considerations of consumer strategic behaviors. Lu and Moorthy [20] discussed the equilibrium pricing strategies under the discount sales strategies of coupons and quantity rebates provided by e-commerce platforms, and compared the effectiveness of these two strategies in alleviating consumer strategic behavior, they found that consumers’ risk preference is positively correlated with the effectiveness of two discount sales strategies. Mu et al. [21] constructed a Stackelberg game model of an e-commerce platform and a retailer to study the optimal pricing strategies of the retailer and the e-commerce platform under two scenarios: the e-commerce platform does not provide consumer rebates and provides consumer rebates; they show that when the hassle cost of consumer redemption rebates is high, the profit is higher when the e-commerce platform offers rebates compared to when it does not offer rebates. Liang et al. [22] divided product sales into an original price stage and a discount price stage and proposed a product pricing algorithm based on consumer strategic behavior to improve retailer profit by constructing a discount pricing model for a two-stage e-commerce platform. Mu et al. [23] analyzed the optimal rebate decisions of retailers and e-commerce platforms under the commission-driven rebate model and the marketing rebate model, indicating that both models contribute to mitigating strategic consumer behavior, helping retailers expand their market and increasing profit. Nie et al. [24] explored the optimal rebate pricing strategies of retailers under monopoly and competition by establishing four rebate models: upfront rebate, later rebate, always rebate, and never rebate; they showed that retailers would always choose the upfront rebate strategy under monopoly, while all four equilibrium rebate strategies may be effective in the competition situation.

By modeling and analyzing the two discount pricing strategies, we study the following two questions. First, we provide insight into the effectiveness of the two pricing strategies in mitigating strategic consumer behavior based on the double discount pricing strategies. Second, we identify the conditions under which the two discount pricing strategies can be most effectively used to mitigate strategic consumer behavior. Although Liu and Zhang [12], Lu and Moorthy [20], and other literature have studied the competition between two retailers offering differentiated products, but have not considered the impact of e-commerce platform discounts on retailers. Although Mu et al. [21] studies a double discount pricing strategy, but only consider one retailer and one e-commerce platform, without considering the competition among multiple retailers in the platform. Based on the research of Mu et al. [21], we not only consider the competition between two retailers, but also the competitive cooperation relationship between retailers and platforms. We analyze the effects of factors such as retailer competition and double rebates on market equilibrium pricing, e-commerce platforms, and retailers’ expected profits under strategic consumer behavior. This approach can be used to better simulate market practices during the discounted sales season., to some extent, it further developed research on discount pricing strategies. In order to highlight the difference between retail discount pricing strategies and double discount pricing strategies, we reflect the rebate factor and the rebate exchange rate of consumers in the consumer utility function. To the best of our knowledge, few studies have simultaneously analyzed the impact of different discount pricing strategies on alleviating consumer strategic waiting behavior. Therefore, we consider retailers’ single discount pricing. Then, we attempt to determine the effectiveness of these two discount pricing strategies by depicting consumers enjoying double discounts through e-commerce platform rebates.

3. The model

Consider a market with two competing retailers, retailer H and retailer L, and an e-commerce platform E. These two retailers sell products to consumers on e-commerce platforms, which charge commissions from the retailer’s sales. The two retailers offer products that are perishable with differences in performance or service. The different products are characterized by a quality index qi(i = H,L), and we assume qH > qL throughout; therefore, product H has higher quality. Without loss of generality, we normalize (qH, qL) to (1, β) with β ∈ (0,1). Additionally, similar to Liu and Zhang [13] and Zhao [25], β can be expressed as the consumer’s evaluation of the differentiated product or product quality difference.

The selling season for the products is divided into two consecutive periods with the regular sales period (defined as Period 1) and the discount sales period (defined as Period 2). The products can be sold at different prices in different time periods. All customers arrive at the beginning of the sales season prior to Period 1. Retailers offer discounts and promotions on their products during the second period of price reduction. The total number of customers is normalized to 1, and customers purchase at most one during the entire selling season. Customers are intertemporal utility maximizers and have heterogeneous valuations of quality, which is denoted by v, we assume that v follows a uniform distribution on [0,1], which is common knowledge for the retailers and consumers. According to online shopping festival sales practices, there are two ways to provide discounts. One way is for retailers offer discounts to consumers, such as “get an extra 20% OFF” on the North Face outdoor brand and the Barbour windbreaker brand is offering a “up to 60% OFF” on Black Friday. The other is through e-commerce platforms providing consumers with various preferential rebate strategies in the practice of discount sales in addition to retailers; an example of this is the Zalora platform in Singapore, which offers “Rebate activities”, which means that consumers can still obtain rebates after confirming the receipt of products despite having received a discount. During “Double Eleven” in China, Taobao offered a cross-store discount, the Tmall platform for the total amount of shopping launched the “Full 300 minus 30” allowance, and “6.18” on the JD platform set the Koi card to divide millions of red packets, etc. Therefore, we consider these two sales practices separately, which are defined as retail discount pricing strategies, where only high-quality retailers provide discounts to consumers, and the double discount pricing strategy of e-commerce platforms and retailers, where retailers provide discounts to consumers while e-commerce platforms provide rebates to consumers. We explore the effectiveness of these two discount pricing strategies in different product sales environments. The decisions of the e-commerce platform and retailers under a realistic discount sales season are shown in S1 Fig.

The rate of commissions paid by the retailer to the e-commerce platforms is δ, which is mainly dependent on industry practices (Heese [26]); for example, the Shopee cross-border e-commerce platform sets a commission rate of 2%. The share that retailers receive from sales is 1-δ. And we denote the utility discount factor for strategic waiting by the parameter γ, γ∈[0,1], a higher γ means that larger values indicate greater intertemporal purchase utility and a higher willingness of consumers to wait until the discount sale period to purchase. Consumers have strategic behaviors and compare the utility of regular and discounted sales to make purchase choices. We need to consider the intertemporal choice behavior of consumers in a dynamic game framework, in which each customer decides on which product to purchase and when to purchase to maximize individual surplus. We can interpret γ as the level of strategic behavior (Liu and Zhang [13]).

We assume that λ is the rebate redemption rate. In reality, consumers who buy products due to rebate promotions may fail to get the rebates because they forget or miss the rebate period. Nowadays, the promotion methods of the platform are more diverse. For example, Tmall launched the pre-payment deposit booking product during the Double Eleven shopping festival. After paying the balance, consumers can directly apply for a refund of the deposit on the shopping details page to complete the rebate or “get coupon rebate for good reviews”, offers on Taobao; consumers who buy the products do not get the rebate because they forget to apply for no deposit or fill out positive reviews. According to the Japan Times survey, only 40% of consumers are successful in points rebate activities. So, not all consumers can receive rebates provided by e-commerce platforms, thus we assume a rebate redemption rate λ.

Consumers often need to spend time and search costs to obtain rebates after purchasing products. We assume that the effort costs paid by consumers to obtain rebates at the two retailers are simplified to c1 and c2, respectively. The retailers aim to maximize their total expected profit in two periods, and they determined the price of product as pti(t=1,2). The price p2i of the product purchased by consumers during the discount period is lower than the price p1i of the product purchased during the normal period, which means that consumers can enjoy the discount of 1p2ip1i. For example, the Chinese shopping festival "Double Eleven" refers to the price reduction sales starting on November 11th. Before November 11th, the price of the Arthur ASICS brand sports shoe Flux 4 was 559 CNY, and the price of the product was reduced to 332 CNY from 00:00 on November 11th, This means that consumers enjoy a 41% discount. Depending on the relationship between p1i and p2i and the values of β and λ, retailers face a demand of qti. The utility of the product purchased by the consumer in Period t is Uv,pti=vpti, and the value vT[0,1] is the valuation of a marginal customer who is indifferent toward purchasing in either Period 1 or Period 2. The total profit of the two retailers over the sales period is πi=t=12πti=t=12ptiqti, where I = H,L. We construct the dynamic pricing models for the two periods under retailer discount pricing and double discount pricing strategies for e-commerce platforms and retailers respectively, and the solution concept we adopt is the Markov perfect equilibrium (MPE), which is a profile of Markov strategies that is subgame perfect for each player. Let us define the strategy that only retailers conduct discount pricing in Period 2 as strategy E and the double discount pricing strategy that retailers provide discounts while e-commerce platforms provide rebates in Period 2 as strategy F.

4. Model analysis and results

Analysis of retailer discount pricing strategy

In strategy E, only the retailer offers the discount, so retailer L may or may not incur demand in Period 2. Let U2L=βv2Lp2L=0, v2L satisfies v2L=p2Lβ,v2L indicates that there is no difference in the utility between consumers who do not purchase products or purchase products from retailer L. When retailer L incurs positive demand, the marginal valuation is determined by comparing the surpluses of purchasing L in Period 1 and purchasing H in Period 2; that is, when U2L>U2H and U2L0, a customer with valuation vvT will purchase from retailer L. Similarly, a customer with valuation vvT purchases from retailer H when U2H>U2L and U2H0, Let vT* be the valuation that the utility of the product purchased by the consumer in the normal sales period and the discount sales period is equal. The indifference point of demand of two retailers in Period 2 satisfies U2H=U2L, that is v2H=p2Hp2L1β. The payoff function of retailer H and retailer L is:

π2H=p2HvTp2Hp2L1β (1)
π2L=p2Lp2Hp2L1βp2Lβ (2)

The following proposition characterizes the equilibrium in Period 2.

Proposition 1: Under the retailer discount pricing strategy, the equilibrium prices in Period 2 are p2H*=2(1β)vT4β and p2L*=β(1β)vT4β, respectively. The equilibrium expected profits of the two retailers and the e-commerce platform are given by π2H*=4(1β)(4β)2vT2, π2L*=(1β)β(4β)2vT2 and π2E*=δ43ββ2(4β)2vT2, respectively.

The proof of Proposition 1 is provided in the S1 Appendix. Recall that β is the relative quality level of the two products, and δ represents the rate of commissions. Proposition 1 demonstrates that the impact of β and δ on prices can lead to changes in equilibrium outcome.

Next, we analyze consumers who purchase a product from retailer H in Period 1, satisfying vp1Hβvp1L, vp1Hγvp2H*, vp1Hγβvp2L*. Similarly, consumers purchase a product from a retailer L, satisfying βvp1Lvp1H, βvp1Lγβvp2L*, βvp1Lγvp2H*. Therefore, the indifference point between consumer purchases at retailer H and retailer L in Period 1 is v1H=p1Hp1L1β. Let νT* be the valuation of a marginal customer who is indifferent toward purchasing in either Period 1 or Period 2, satisfying βvT*p1LγvT*p2H*i.e., vT*=p1L(4β)(4βγ)β2γ. The payoff functions of retailers H and L in Period 1 are:

πH=p2HvT*v2H+p1H1v1H (3)
πL=p2Lv2Hv2L+p1Lv1HvT* (4)

Proposition 2: Under the retailer discount pricing strategy, the equilibrium prices for the two retailers in Period 1 are given by:

p1H*=2(1β)6γ2+γβ2γβ315+4γ210γβ4γ2+8γβ4(2γ+8)β3+403γ2β260+12γ224γβ12γ2+32γ (5)
p1L*=(1β)β2(4γ)β+2γ2β4(2γ+8)β3+403γ2β260+12γ224γβ12γ2+32γ (6)

with the corresponding equilibrium profits of:π1H*=p1H*1p1H*p1L*1β+π2H*vT*,π1L*, π1L*=p1L*p1H*p1L*1βp1L*(4β)(4βγ)β2γ+π2L*vT*, π1E*=δπ1H*+π1L*.

The proof of Proposition 2 is provided in the S1 Appendix. Proposition 2 demonstrates the critical role that β and γ play in determining the equilibrium outcome. The detailed relationship between them can be found in numerical simulation.

Analysis of the double discount pricing strategy for retailers and e-commerce platforms

Consumers can enjoy double discounts at the same time. On the one hand, retailers themselves offer discounts on products, and on the other hand, the platform provides category coupons, which can be shared. For example, if the price of a T-shirt on Taobao is 100 CNY, the shop is holding a promotion of subtracting 20 CNY from 100 CNY, and the platform presents a coupon of subtracting 10 CNY from 100 CNY for the product, then the customer can enjoy both the retailer’s discount and the platform’s coupon. Therefore, retailers set preferential product prices and e-commerce platforms offer rebates to consumers under the double discount pricing strategy of e-commerce platforms and retailers. To simplify presentation, we define the decision variable under the double discount pricing strategy of the platform and the retailer is superscript “~”. And the rebate rate of the e-commerce platform as “f”, this means that consumers can enjoy a discount of (1-f) on the basis of the original pricing in Period 2, amounting to the actual price paid fp˜2i under both platform and retailer discounts. We directly reflect the rebate paid by the e-commerce platform on the price paid by consumers, so as to more intuitively show the changes in consumer spending before and after the platform rebate. These notations will be used throughout the paper.

In strategy F, the consumer utility considering the consumer rebate redemption rate is formulated as U˜=λv˜fp˜tict+(1λ)v˜p˜ti. Consumers purchase at retailer L in Period 2 if U˜2LU˜2H, that is, λβv˜fp2Lc2+(1λ)βv˜p˜2Lλv˜fp˜2Hc1+(1λ)v˜p˜2H, p˜2Hv˜Tβv˜T+p˜2Lλp˜2L+fλp˜2Lc1λ+c2λ1λ+fλ, p˜2H(1β)v˜Tc1c2λ1(1f)λ+p˜2L. Similarly, consumers purchase at retailer H in Period 2 if U˜2HU˜2L, i.e., p˜2Lp˜2H(1β)v˜Tc1c2λ1(1f)λ. Let v˜T be the valuation of a marginal customer who is indifferent toward purchasing in either Period 1 or Period 2. Let U˜2H=U˜2L, the point of indifference between consumers purchasing products from retailer H and retailer L is v2H=p˜2Hp˜2Lλ(1f)p˜2Hp˜2Lc1+c21β, and let U˜2L=0, the point of indifference between consumers buying products and not buying products at retailer L is v2L=(1λ+fλ)p˜2L+c2λβ. The profits of retailers H, L and the platform in Period 2 are:

π˜2H=p˜2Hv˜Tp˜2Hp˜2Lλ(1f)p˜2Hp˜2Lc1+c21β (7)
π˜2L=p˜2Lp˜2Hp˜2Lλ(1f)p˜2Hp˜2Lc1+c21β(1λ+fλ)p˜2L+c2λβ (8)
π˜2E=δπ˜2H+π˜2L

Proposition 3: Under the double discount pricing strategy for e-commerce platforms and retailers, the equilibrium prices in Period 2 are p˜2H*=c2(2β)c1+2(1β)v˜T(1(1f)λ)(4β) and p2L=c1+c2β2c2λ+β(1β)v˜T(1(1f)λ)(4β), respectively. The equilibrium expected profits of the two retailers and the e-commerce platform are π˜2H*=4112βc112c2λv˜T(1β)2(1(1f)λ)(4β)2(1β), π˜2L*=β2v˜Tβc1+c2λ+v˜T+2c2λ2β(1(1f)λ)(4β)2(1β) and π˜2E*=δπ˜2H*+π˜2L*, respectively.

Let U˜1H=U˜1L, the indifference point of in utility between the two retailers in Period 1 is v˜1H=c2c1λAHp˜1Lβ2+3AHp˜1L+BHβ+2p˜1L(22f)p˜1L+2γc12c2λ(1β)(4γ)ββ22γ. To simplify the presentation, we define AH=(1f)λ1, BH=c1+c2γ+2c14c2λ. Similarly, v˜2H is the indifference utility point of the two retailers in Period 2, and v˜3L is the indifference point of a consumer purchasing at retailer L or not in Period 2. The indifference point valuation between two periods is v˜T*, that is, v˜T*=c2(1f)p˜1Lβ+(44f)p˜1L+2c1+c2γ4c2λ(4β)p˜1Lβ2(4γ)β+2γ. Consumers purchase at retailer H in Period 1 if λv˜fp˜1Hc1+(1λ)v˜p˜1Hλβv˜fp˜1Lc2+(1λ)βv˜p˜1L, λ(v˜fp˜1Hc1+(1λ)v˜p˜1Hγλv˜fp˜1Hc1+(1λ)v˜p˜2H, λv˜fp˜1Hc1+(1λ)v˜p˜1Hγλβv˜fp˜2Lc2+(1λ)βv˜p˜2L. Consumers purchase at retailer L in Period 1 if λβv˜fp˜1Lc2+(1λ)βv˜p˜1Lλv˜fp˜1Hc1+(1λ)(v˜p˜1H, λβv˜tp˜1Lc2+(1λ)βv˜p˜1Lγλβv˜fp˜2L*c2+(1λ)βv˜p˜2L*, λβv˜fp˜1Lc2+(1λ)βv˜p˜1Lγλv˜fp˜2H*c1+(1λ)v˜p˜2H**.

Let v˜1H be the valuation of customers who are indifferent to purchasing at retailers H and L in Period 1, satisfying λv˜1Hfp˜1Hc1+(1λ)v˜1Hp˜1H=λβv˜1Hfp˜1Lc2+(1λ)βv˜1Hp˜1L. The payoff functions of H and L are:

π˜H=p˜1H1v˜1H+π˜2Hv˜T* (9)
π˜L=p˜1Lv˜1Hv˜T*+π˜2Lv˜T* (10)

The proof of Proposition 3 is provided in the S1 Appendix. The following proposition characterizes the equilibrium in Period 1.

Proposition 4: Under the double discount pricing strategy for e-commerce platforms and retailers, the equilibrium prices in Period 1 are:

p˜1H*=c1λ2γβ4+DHβ3+DLβ2+EHβ8γc114c2λ1γ+2+34c22c1λβ4+2β3γ+3β2γ2+8β3+12βγ240β224βγ+12γ2+60β32γ(1γ+fγ) and p˜1L*=β5+c1+c1λ2γ+9β4+ELβ3+FHβ2+FLβ4γc1+2c2γ5c2λγ3(1(1f)λ)13β4+23γ+83β3+γ2403β2+4γ28γ+20β+4γ2323γ, respectively.

Where DH=2γ2+4+2c1+2c2λγ+1210c1+c2λ, DL=c1+2c2λ6γ2+1810c1+6c2λγ42+30c12c2λ, EH=2λc152c2γ2+10c18c2λ4γ+3030c112c2λ, EL=6c1+2c2γ12c110c2λγ2+6γ24, FH=5c1+c2γ220c1+12c2γ+20c1+36c2λ3γ2+12γ+16, and FL=8c12c2γ24c18c2γ36c2λ16γ.

The proof of Proposition 4 is provided in the S1 Appendix. It can be seen that the pricing and expected profit of the retailer under the double discount sales strategy are significantly different from the e-commerce platform’s strategy of not providing rebates. The analysis of the equilibrium results is potentially very complex because each parameter can take any value in [0,1], and complex parameter results are difficult to compare. Therefore, the following section numerically simulates the effects of product variation factor β, rebate rate f, and rebate redemption rate λ on the equilibrium price and profit, we analyzes the property of the equilibrium decision of the retailer and e-commerce platform under the two pricing strategies. These results are established in the Numerical Study and Managerial Insights section.

5. Numerical study and managerial insights

In this section, we conduct exhaustive numerical experiments and discuss the managerial implications of our models and results. Our experimental design centers around four main contributing factors in the model, the vertical product differentiation β, the rebate rate f, the redemption rate λ, the level of strategic behavior γ. We consider different values of β while fixing γ = 0.4, f = 0.7, λ = 0.4, c1 = 0.05, and c2 = 0.03, and we consider different values of f, λ and γ while fixing β = 0.5. According to the industry practice of online sales platforms, the commission percentage factor is δ = 0.2, and similar values are used in the paper by Zhou [15]. After comparing multiple sets of values, we select the value with the most significant trend for display. Other numerical values may change the specific value of corresponding price, demand and income, but have no impact on the changes in factor relationships.

Optimal pricing strategy analysis

The comparative analysis of the influence of product quality difference coefficient β, rebate rate f, rebate redemption rate λ and the level of strategic behavior γ on the equilibrium on the two-stage optimal pricing in the sales period under two different scenarios, namely, retailer discount pricing strategy and e-commerce platform double discount pricing strategy, is shown in S2 and S3 Figs.

From the above figure, we can see that the smaller the difference is between the product quality offered by the two retailers (with the increase in β), the equilibrium price of retailer H in the two periods and the equilibrium price of retailer L in Period 2 decrease. The optimal pricing of retailer L in Period 1 increases and then decreases. Due to our assumption that the production and sales costs of retailers are 0, the prices in the above figure gradually tend towards cost. In essence, the reason is that retailers face homogeneous competition, and have to carry out “price wars” to attract consumers to buy products due to the increasing degree of product quality differences. This means that retailers should not narrow product quality differences to capture the market when using discount sales, but maintain a certain degree of product differentiation to focus on market segments, which is conducive to alleviate price competition among retailers. Then the optimal pricing for the retailer in both periods under the double discount pricing strategy is higher than the retailer discount pricing, which indicates that the essence of the platform rebate under the double discount pricing strategy is to give consumers an “illusion” of discounts. The internet shopping festival business “increase before decrease” routine has been frequently exposed in recent years. For example, the price of some brands of mobile phones had fallen to the low 2000 CNY on the eve of the shopping festival, but the price rose instead of falling after the Double 11, over 2000 CNY by several hundred. With such inflated prices and disorderly discounts, consumers are also less willing to buy, which affects retailers’ sales.

The prices of the two retailers fall as the rebate rate increases and rise as the rebate redemption rate increases. An increase in the rebate rate f means that the discount (1-f) enjoyed by consumers on the platform will be reduced. In order to make up for the weakened discount enjoyed by consumers on the platform, retailers will choose higher discount and price reduction to attract consumers, while when the rebate redemption rate increases and consumers receive higher discounts from the platform, the retailer will take the opportunity to increase prices to gain higher revenue. The two retailers increase their prices with the increase of γ in Period 2 because as consumers become more willing to wait for the lower price of the second period, the retailers who cannot afford too many discounts will choose to increase their prices to ensure return.

The impact of product quality differences on demand

The comparative analysis of the influence of the product quality difference coefficient β on the two-stage demand and total demand in the sales period under two different scenarios, namely, strategy E and strategy F, is shown in S4S6 Figs.

We observe that for a fixed f value, both retailers’ demand in Period 1 is increasing in β and the demand in Period 2 is decreasing in β. When the degree of product quality differences is small, the demand of both retailers under the strategy E is higher than that under the strategy F; when the degree of product quality differences is moderate, retailer H has higher demand for implementing the strategy F, and retailer L has higher demand for implementing strategy E; when the degree of product differences is small, the strategy F can drive higher demand from both retailers. For a larger β, the two retailers can obtain similar performance incentives under the double discount strategy. When the degree of product differences is moderate, consumers face the same discount activities and think that it is more cost-effective to buy high-quality products at that time, because they feel that they are “taking advantage” when comparing the product with the previous price, so high-quality retailer H can achieve consumer penetration under the platform subsidy, while low-quality retailers L can only carry out break-even promotions and cannot obtain considerable sales under the double discount strategy. For a smaller β, low-quality retailers are more reluctant to participate in double discount pricing in the discount sales season, while the two retailers have greater demand under the retailer discount pricing strategy and have differentiated market segment advantages.

The impact of product quality differences on profits

The comparative analysis of the product quality difference coefficient β on the profit of two retailers and e-commerce platforms under two strategies, is shown in S7S10 Figs.

These figures illustrate the equilibrium outcomes between retailers and e-commerce platform. For both of them, the expected profit of the double discount pricing strategy outperforms that of the retailer discount pricing strategy for different degrees of product quality differences. We show that under the double discount pricing strategy, retailers will increase the price before the discount sales season, but with the e-commerce platform rebate subsidy and retailer discount pricing, this change can erroneously give the consumer a sense of increased utility, thereby increasing profits for both the platform and retailers. We believe that retailers and e-commerce platforms should adopt a double discount pricing strategy. However, as the degree of difference in product quality increases, the degree of profit growth between retailers and platforms decreases, which shows that homogeneous competition weakens the profit advantage obtained from the rebates of e-commerce platforms.

Moreover, we can also see from the above figure that the smaller the degree of product quality differences is, the more intense the competition between the two retailers will be. Offering two products with little difference and the same platform rebates will lead to a convergence of pricing between the two retailers, leading to the accumulation of homogeneous competition for retailers and lower profit. Therefore, retailers should maintain certain product quality differentiation. Because we are in an era of product excess, products tend to be homogeneous, but consumer needs have become more diverse and personalized, consumers only buy products they like and truly want. Therefore, maintaining a certain degree of product quality differentiation plays a key role in the competition to attract and retain consumers.

To further verify the effectiveness of the double discount pricing strategy, we denote the profit margin between the two pricing strategies by Δπi=π˜iπi(i=H,L,E). We numerically verified the impact of the rebate rate f and rebate redemption rate λ on the profit of retailers and e-commerce platforms under the two pricing strategies. It can be obtained by the magnitude of Δπi; see S11 Fig for illustration.

Our numerical studies indicate that ΔπH,ΔπL,andΔπE are always greater than zero for different degrees of rebate rates f and rebate redemption rates λ, which indicates that the double discount pricing strategy is always effective for the retailer as well as for the e-commerce platform. We found that the profit margin between the retailers and the platform decreases with the increase in the rebate rate, and the impact of rebate redemption rates on the profit is the same. The greater rebate rate f means a smaller discount (1-f) for consumers on the platform, so the positive impact of rebates on demand growth diminishes and the advantage of a double discount pricing strategy weakens accordingly. Rising redemption rates indicate that the e-commerce platform needs to pay a larger rebate value and that the role of the rebate efficiency advantage is gradually decreasing. The increase in profits from an increase in market share cannot compensate for the loss caused by paying a higher rebate value. This also suggests that the profit advantage of the retailers and the e-commerce platform through double discount pricing diminishes, and the profit of the e-commerce platform and the two retailers decreases with the increase in the consumer rebate rate and rebate redemption rate.

Based on the results of the above analysis, we found that the importance of the e-commerce platform rebate rate and the rebate redemption rate for the double discount sales strategy. Our results suggest that e-commerce platforms and retailers should set reasonable rebate rates in conjunction with the actual situation of goods during important discount sales seasons (e.g., internet shopping festivals). Excessive redemption rates can lead to lower profits, in which case if the complexity of consumer access to platform rebates is appropriately set to achieve Pareto improvements in the market.

6. Summary

How to effectively determine discount sales strategies and maximize profits for retailers and e-commerce platforms during discount sales and normal sales periods is the key to the sustainable development of e-commerce platforms and retailers during discount sales seasons such as internet shopping festivals. This paper consider the dynamic pricing competition between two vertically differentiated retailers in the retailer discount pricing strategy and the double discount pricing strategy when customers are strategic. We establishes the game models of two pricing strategies and explore the market equilibrium of two retailers and the e-commerce platform, and analyze the effects of the product quality difference coefficient, e-commerce platform rebate rate, consumer rebate redemption rate and level of strategic behavior on retailers’ equilibrium pricing and revenue. Our results yield the following insights. Our research show that the optimal pricing of the two periods decreases as the product quality difference increases, and the optimal pricing of the two periods under the double discount pricing strategy is higher than that under the retailer discount pricing strategy, which reveals the retailer’s “increase before decrease” routine in the discount sales season. The pricing of the two retailers will decrease with the rebate rate, increase with the rebate cash rate, and increase with the rise in the strategic behavior level in discount sales period. Under the double discount pricing strategy, the demand of high-quality retailers is greater only when the degree of product difference is large, and the demand of low-quality retailers is greater only when the degree of product difference is small. Compared with the retailer discount pricing strategy, double discount pricing strategy can be used to effectively obtain increased profits for both the platform and the retailers and to achieve Pareto improvement of the market. The double discount pricing strategy is often reasonable when consumers have strategic waiting behavior, but the degree of product quality differences, rebate rates, rebate redemption rates and the level of strategic behavior will affect the expected profits of the e-commerce platform and retailers. One of the consequences of excessive rebate activities on the platform is the price increase of retailers in discount sales period, but retailers are pursuing price advantages or at least avoiding price disadvantages. The contradiction between price increases and price advantages has almost entered an endless loop. Overly complex rebate rules for the discount sales season can sap consumers’ enthusiasm and affect their interest in shopping. Therefore, retailers should maintain a reasonable degree of product quality differences, and at the same time, e-commerce platforms should optimize their rebate strategies to develop a reasonable rebate ratio according to their own circumstances to achieve a win‒win situation with retailers.

In view of the current situation of research in this field and the limitations of this paper, the following areas can be further explored in the future: Consumers have heterogeneous preferences, some consumers may only prefer to purchase from high- or low-quality retailers for various reasons such as preferences for product quality or for channel, online or offline, direct sales or distribution. In the future, the impact of the supply chain power structure on the decision-making of e-commerce platforms and retailers can also be considered. Furthermore, we believe that relaxing some of our assumptions, such as not just two retailers, asymmetric discount information, etc., has general significance and can deepen our insights, thus therefore constitutes interesting directions for future research.

Supporting information

S1 Fig. Diagram of the double discount pricing decision for e-commerce platforms and retailers.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s001.tif (61.3KB, tif)
S2 Fig. Equilibrium pricing analysis of retailer H under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s002.tif (377.3KB, tif)
S3 Fig. Equilibrium pricing analysis of retailer L under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s003.tif (388.3KB, tif)
S4 Fig. Retailer H demand analysis under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s004.tif (105.4KB, tif)
S5 Fig. Retailer L demand analysis under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s005.tif (107.7KB, tif)
S6 Fig. Comparative analysis of the demand of two retailers under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s006.tif (147.8KB, tif)
S7 Fig. Retailer H profit analysis under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s007.tif (109.3KB, tif)
S8 Fig. Retailer L profit analysis under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s008.tif (111.4KB, tif)
S9 Fig. Comparative analysis of the profit of two retailers under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s009.tif (120.8KB, tif)
S10 Fig. Comparative analysis of the profit of e-commerce platforms under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s010.tif (144.3KB, tif)
S11 Fig. Profit margins between retailers and e-commerce platforms under two pricing strategies.

(TIF)

pone.0296654.s011.tif (207.6KB, tif)
S1 Appendix

(DOCX)

pone.0296654.s012.docx (16.1KB, docx)

Acknowledgments

Thank you to my supervisor for their help in writing this article, and to my family and friends for their continuous support.

Data Availability

All relevant data are within the manuscript and its Supporting Information files.

Funding Statement

This study was supported by the Chongqing Transportation Bureau's Science and Technology Project: Estimation of the Effect of Chongqing Transportation on Promoting Industrial Development, No. 2021-1. And the National Social Science Foundation project: Research on the Multi party Linkage Mechanism of the Governance of the Online Ride hailing Market under the Background of Co construction, Co governance, and Sharing, with the number of 19XGL016. The sponsor has no role in research design, analysis, publication decisions, or manuscript preparation.

References

  • 1.China Business Intelligence[Internet]. Double Eleven major platform sales data overview [cited 2022 Jue 10]. Available from: https://www.askci.com/news/chanye/2021112/ 1044411280518.shtml.
  • 2.Chinese people’s Finance Review[Internet]. Double Eleven! It takes more than numbers to make history [cited 2022 Jue 10]. Available from: http://js.people.com.cn/n2/2019/1113/ c36029833535905.html.
  • 3.Muth JF. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Journal of the Econometric Society. 1961; 29(3): 315–335. [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Coase RH. Durability and Monopoly. The Journal of Law and Economics. 1972; 15(1): 143–149. [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Aviv Y, Pazgal A. Optimal pricing of seasonal products in the presence of forward-looking consumers. Manufacturing and Service Operations management. 2008; 1(2): 1–21. [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Otero DF, Escallon M, Lopez C, Tabatabaei AR. Optimal timing of airline promotions under dilution. European Journal of Operational Research. 2019; 277 (3): 981–995. [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Li H, Yang X. Research on the Pricing Strategy of the Perishable Products under the Consumer’s Price Comparison Behavior of Intertemporal Switching. Journal of Management Science. 2020; 33(1): 126–136. [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Aflaki A, Feldman P, Swinney R. Becoming strategic: The endogenous determination of time preferences and its implications for multiperiod pricing. Operational Research. 2020; 68(4): 1116–1131. [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Zhang Q, Chen H, Wan L. Reselling or agency model under markdown pricing policy in the presence of strategic customers. Managerial and Decision Economics. 2022; 43(7): 2911–2923. [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Elmaghrab W, Gulcu A, Keskinocak P. Designing optimal preannounced markdowns in the presence of rational customers with multiunit demands. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management. 2008; 10(1): 126–148. [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Levin Y, McGill J, Nediak M. Optimal dynamic pricing of perishable items by a monopolist facing strategic consumers. Production and Operations Management. 2010; 19(1): 40–60. [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Su X, Zhang F. On the value of commitment and availability guarantees when selling to strategic consumers. Management Science.2009; 55(5): 713–726. [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Liu Q, Zhang D. Dynamic pricing competition with strategic customers under vertical product differentiate on. Management Science. 2013; 59(1): 84–101. [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Ozgun CD, Pinar K, Swann J. Customer rebates and retailer incentives in the presence of competition and price discrimination. European Journal of Operational Research. 2011; 215(1): 268–280. [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Zhou YW, Cao B, Tang Q. Pricing and rebate strategies for an e-shop with a cash back website. European Journal of Operational Research. 2017; 262(1): 108–122. [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Rhee K, Thomadsen R. Behavior-based pricing in vertically differentiated industries. Management Science. 2017; 63(8): 2729–2740. [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Jeong Y, Maruyama M. Positioning and Pricing Strategies in a Market with Switching Costs and Staying Costs. Information Economics and Policy. 2018; 44(1): 47–57. [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Mantin B, Veldman J. Managing strategic inventories under investment in process improvement. European Journal of Operational Research. 2019; 279(3): 782–794. [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Feng Y, Niu QJ, Jun JK. The impacts of advance-order discounts on a three-echelon supply chain. Computers & Industrial Engineering. 2020; 145(1): 106498. [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Lu Q, Moorthy S. Coupons Versus Rebates. Marketing Science.2007; 26(1): 67–82. [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Mu LF, Wang FY. Research on Pricing Strategy of E-commerce Platform Based on Strategic Consumers. Operations Research and Management Science. 2020; 29(10): 225–232. [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Liang ZW, Yuan H, Du HW. Two-stage pricing strategy with price discount in online social networks. Theoretical Computer Science. 2021; 29(1): 115–126. [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Mu LF, Tang X, Sugumaran V. Optimal rebate strategy for an online retailer with a cashback platform: commission-driven or marketing-based? Electronic Commerce Research. 2021; 13(3): 551–575. [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Nie JJ, Wang QJ, Ding L. Rebate Research of Company Considering the Existence of Social Influence. Operations Research and Management Science. 2020; 29(9): 224–231. [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Zhao J, Qiu J, Hu X. Vertically differential product introduction and pricing in the presence of strategic consumers. System Engineering Theory and Practice. 2017; 37(12): 3098–3108. [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Heese HS, Kemahlioglu ZE. “Enabling opportunism: Revenues haring when sales revenues are unobservable. Production & Operations Management. 2015; 23(9): 1634–1645. [Google Scholar]

Decision Letter 0

Vincenzo Basile

31 Jul 2023

PONE-D-23-21142How Do E-commerce Platforms and Retailers Implement Discount Pricing Policies under Consumers are Strategic?PLOS ONE

Dear Dr. chen,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

==============================

ACADEMIC EDITOR: Please provide a final paper with all revisions made and I recommend an additional check on plagiarism and/or compliance with the Journal's guidelines.

==============================

Please submit your revised manuscript by Sep 14 2023 11:59PM. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at plosone@plos.org. When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols. Additionally, PLOS ONE offers an option for publishing peer-reviewed Lab Protocol articles, which describe protocols hosted on protocols.io. Read more information on sharing protocols at https://plos.org/protocols?utm_medium=editorial-email&utm_source=authorletters&utm_campaign=protocols.

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Vincenzo Basile, PhD

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal requirements:

When submitting your revision, we need you to address these additional requirements.

1. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=wjVg/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=ba62/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf

2. Thank you for stating the following financial disclosure:

“National Social Science Foundation Project (Research on Multi-Party Linkage Mechanism of Car-hailing Market Governance under the Background of Co-construction, Co-Governance and Sharing, 19XGL016, Li Hao).”

At this time, please address the following queries:

a) Please clarify the sources of funding (financial or material support) for your study. List the grants or organizations that supported your study, including funding received from your institution.

b) State what role the funders took in the study. If the funders had no role in your study, please state: “The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.”

c) If any authors received a salary from any of your funders, please state which authors and which funders.

d) If you did not receive any funding for this study, please state: “The authors received no specific funding for this work.”

Please include your amended statements within your cover letter; we will change the online submission form on your behalf.

3. Please respond by return e-mail with an updated version of your manuscript to include your abstract after the title page.

4. Please include captions for your Supporting Information files at the end of your manuscript, and update any in-text citations to match accordingly. Please see our Supporting Information guidelines for more information: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/supporting-information.

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Partly

Reviewer #3: Yes

**********

2. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: No

Reviewer #3: Yes

**********

3. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

Reviewer #3: Yes

**********

4. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: No

Reviewer #3: Yes

**********

5. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: This paper constructs a dynamic game model for an e-commerce platform and two retailers when they implement discount pricing, investigate the market equilibrium of the two retailers and e-commerce platform under multiple situations considering consumers’ strategic waiting behavior and competition between the two retailers, and further discuss the effectiveness of retailer discount pricing and the double discount pricing of the platform and retailers. The main results show that the optimal pricing decreases as the difference in product quality narrows under both pricing strategies.

This paper has contributed to the research field of e-commerce supply chain. However, this paper has serious drawbacks, stated as following. Detailed comments are provided below:

The model description of retailer discount pricing strategy (strategy E) is not very clear. I do not understand the retailer discount pricing. Can you demonstrate which parameter denote the discount pricing? Parameter β is the difference quality between the high and low products. So, what’s difference between the period 1 and period 2?

What’s meaning of ν_T in Eq. (1)?

In page 20, why do you assume the parameter settings, i.e., γ=0.4, f=0.7,λ=0.4,c_1=0.05,c_2=0.03,β=0.5,δ=0.2? If you change the values of them, whether the main results will be changed?

The references should follow the format of the Journal.

For S2 Fig (b) and (c), why the p_2^H is near 0? Please give some reasons.

The English level should be improved.

Reviewer #2: In the era of e-commerce evolution, devising sensible discount strategies for e-commerce platforms and retailers is crucial for maintaining a sustainable business. Drawing on the literature related to consumer strategic behavior and discount pricing strategies, this paper constructs a dynamic game model for the e-commerce platform and two retailers. The model investigates market equilibrium under various scenarios, factoring in consumers’ strategic waiting behavior and the impact of retailer discount pricing and dual discounts from the platform and retailers. This is an urgent challenge faced by retailers and e-commerce platforms. Although the author has made substantial efforts, from a professional standpoint, I believe this paper does not yet meet the publication standards of the PLOS ONE journal. Therefore, I recommend a "Reject" decision and provide specific review comments as follows:

1. The paper lacks sufficient innovation and some of the theoretical contributions put forth by the authors do not hold up. To elaborate:

(1) Mu et al. (2020) already investigated the optimal pricing strategy for merchants and e-commerce platforms, taking into account consumer rebates and the dual discount phenomenon. Liu and Zhang (2013) analyzed a market with two firms, H and L, both offering quality-differentiated products with q_H and q_L respectively.

(2) Furthermore, in your discussion of Strategy E, it's unclear how the retailer's offer of a discount is factored in. What is the precise relationship between p_1^i and p_2^i? Is it correct to infer that your paper strictly contemplates whether or not the platform provides rebates?

[1] Mu L, Wang F, Chen L. Research on pricing strategy of E-commerce platform based on strategic consumers[J]. Operations Research and Management Science, 2020, 29(10): 225.

[2] Liu Q, Zhang D. Dynamic pricing competition with strategic customers under vertical product differentiation[J]. Management Science, 2013, 59(1): 84-101.

2. There seem to be issues with your model, with certain expressions appearing ambiguous and confusing.

(1) The range of some parameters needs additional scrutiny. Specifically, "(q_H, q_L) to (1, β) with β∈[0,1]", where β cannot reach the value of 1 as q_H>q_L, and cannot be 0 either, since β might serve as the denominator.

(2) In Strategy E, could you provide further proof to validate that v_2^L fulfills the condition v_2^L=(p_2^L)/β?

(3) The statement "defining the rebate rate of the e-commerce platform as f, consumers can enjoy a discount of (1-f)" is perplexing. The definition of the rebate rate and discount seem rather similar. For instance, if a product is priced at ¥100 and has a rebate rate of "10%", it implies you pay ¥100 and receive ¥10 back, which means you effectively enjoy a discount of 10% and only need to pay ¥90. Consequently, consumers can enjoy a discount of "f", resulting in the actual price paid, (1-f)(p_2^i ) ~, under both platform and retailer discounts. Moreover, typically a discount is deducted directly at the time of purchase, while a rebate is returned to the consumer after purchase at a certain rate, a characteristic that this paper's model fails to represent effectively.

3. The use and citation of references and supporting content in the manuscript is incorrect. The citation marked as [27] in the manuscript states, "We can interpret γ as the level of strategic behavior (Prasad et al. [27]), and a higher γ means……". However, the actual reference is not [27] but [13], which states "Hence, γ can be interpreted as the level of customer’s strategicity/rationality; a higher γ implies that customers are more strategic" (Liu and Zhang 2013). In the manuscript, the authors mention that gamma represents the valuation discount factor for strategic waiting by the parameter, and thus, gamma should only affect value 'v', not '(v-p)'? In addition, strategic customer behavior (i.e., γ) does not play any role in the last period game because there are no future purchase opportunities (Liu and Zhang 2013).

4. The parameter values in the numerical examples lack practical case support, and there should be additional clarification regarding the data sources. The statement that "the optimal pricing of retailer L in the first period decreases before it increases" does not align with Fig. 3(a). The conclusions drawn from the research are quite intuitive, lacking in intriguing findings and valuable managerial insights.

5. Several issues related to English phrasing, grammar, and input errors require a comprehensive review and rectification throughout the text to prevent inaccuracies and increase readability. Therefore, it is recommended that the article undergo a thorough proofreading process. Illustrations of the points that need attention are as follows:

(1) The precision of the language needs to be enhanced. In the "Abstract" section, there are grammatical errors, for example, " In this paper, we constructs a dynamic game……,investigate the……,and further discuss the……" Also, in the "Numerical Study and Managerial Insights" section, the sentence, "The second factor is (the) rebate (rate), which is summarized by the parameter f," needs correction.

(2) Furthermore, some English expressions are challenging to understand. The phrase "Apply for refunding the deposit for presale product after receiving the goods" may not be a suitable example to illustrate the concept of rebate redemption in today's context, as the deposit is typically part of the final payment in reality. Sentences such as "An increase in the rebate rate means that consumers receive fewer discounts from the platform and the retailer will choose to reduce prices to attract consumers " and " The greater the rebate rate is, the smaller the discount on the platform." require refinement.

Reviewer #3: This paper constructs a dynamic game model to investigate the market equilibrium. The research problem is interesting, the model is solid, and the results seems right. I appreciate the authors’ hard work. I propose the following issues, which need the authors’ concerns.

1. The mathematical symbols are ugly. The authors should modify them.

2. I would like to ask why the authors submit this paper to Plos One? It seems that the paper is more suitable to a business journal.

**********

6. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article (what does this mean?). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: No

Reviewer #3: No

**********

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

Attachment

Submitted filename: renamed_b9f66.docx

pone.0296654.s013.docx (19.2KB, docx)
Attachment

Submitted filename: Review comments on PONE-D-23-21142.docx

pone.0296654.s014.docx (20.1KB, docx)
PLoS One. 2024 May 10;19(5):e0296654. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0296654.r002

Author response to Decision Letter 0


25 Oct 2023

For the reviewer's comments, we have attached a document description.

Attachment

Submitted filename: Response to reviewers.docx

pone.0296654.s015.docx (243KB, docx)

Decision Letter 1

Vincenzo Basile

26 Oct 2023

PONE-D-23-21142R1How Do E-commerce Platforms and Retailers Implement Discount Pricing Policies under Consumers are Strategic?PLOS ONE

Dear Dr. zhe chen,     Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

==============================

Please provide a final paper with all revisions made and I recommend an additional check on plagiarism and/or compliance with the Journal's guidelines.

==============================

Please submit your revised manuscript by 30 december 2023. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at plosone@plos.org. When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols. Additionally, PLOS ONE offers an option for publishing peer-reviewed Lab Protocol articles, which describe protocols hosted on protocols.io. Read more information on sharing protocols at https://plos.org/protocols?utm_medium=editorial-email&utm_source=authorletters&utm_campaign=protocols.

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Vincenzo Basile, PhD

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal Requirements:

Please review your reference list to ensure that it is complete and correct. If you have cited papers that have been retracted, please include the rationale for doing so in the manuscript text, or remove these references and replace them with relevant current references. Any changes to the reference list should be mentioned in the rebuttal letter that accompanies your revised manuscript. If you need to cite a retracted article, indicate the article’s retracted status in the References list and also include a citation and full reference for the retraction notice.

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

PLoS One. 2024 May 10;19(5):e0296654. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0296654.r004

Author response to Decision Letter 1


31 Oct 2023

Original Manuscript ID: PONE-D-23-21142

Original Article Title: How Do E-commerce Platforms and Retailers Implement Discount Pricing Policies under Consumers are Strategic?

Dear editor,

Thanks to the editors and reviewers for their comments, which are very helpful in improving the quality of the manuscript. We carefully revised our manuscript, further clarified the logic of writing for improving the quality of the manuscript. The red words on yellow are changes I have made in the original manuscript. Now I response the reviewer's comments with a point by point and highlight the changes in the revised manuscript. Full details of these files are listed below. We sincerely hope that you find our responses and modifications satisfactory and that the manuscript is now acceptable for publication. We are uploading (a) our point-by-point response to the comments (below) (response to reviewers), (b) an updated manuscript(Revised Manuscript with Track Changes), and (c) a clean updated manuscript without highlights.

Thank you and best regards,

Yours sincerely,

Corresponding author:Zhe Chen

E-mail:chenzhe029@163.com

The main corrections in the paper and the responds to the reviewers’ comments are as following:

Reviewer #1:

Comment 1:“The model description of retailer discount pricing strategy (strategy E) is not very clear. I do not understand the retailer discount pricing. Can you demonstrate which parameter denote the discount pricing? Parameter β is the difference quality between the high and low products. So, what’s difference between the period 1 and period 2?”

Response 1:The retail discount pricing strategy in our paper refers to: after a period of sales, retailers will reduce the price of their products, and there will be a price reduction time node. Before the node, we define it as Period 1, which is the normal sales period. At this time, the normal sales price is , after the node, we define it as Period 2, which is the price reduction sales period, where the discount price is . We have demonstrated through numerical simulation that the sales price of Period 1 is higher than that of Period 2, that is, , which means that consumers can enjoy discounts . For example, the Chinese shopping festival "Double Eleven" refers to a price reduction sale starting on November 11th. Before November 11th, the price of the Arthur ASICS brand sports shoe Flux 4 was 559 RMB. When the product starts to be reduced to 332 RMB at 00:00 on November 11th, consumers can enjoy a 41% discount. In the last paragraph of “The Model”, we analyzed in detail the meaning of discount pricing.

Comment 2:“What’s meaning of ν_T in Eq. (1)?”

Response 2:In equation 1, refers to the undifferentiated point estimation of the utility of a product purchased by a consumer in two periods, where the utility of a product purchased by a consumer in a normal sales period and a discounted sales period is equal, that is, , simplified to: . We have explained this in detail in the second paragraph after “Proposition 1”.

Fig.1

Comment 3: “In page 20, why do you assume the parameter settings, i.e., γ=0.4, f=0.7,λ=0.4,c_1=0.05,c_2=0.03,β=0.5,δ=0.2? If you change the values of them, whether the main results will be changed? ”

Response 3:Regarding parameter assumption: We assume that , , , , , is randomly selected to examine the relationship between factors. In fact, the size of the parameter does not change the equilibrium result. We change the value of to , and keep the other parameter values fixed , , , , . This will correspondingly change the specific values such as the main price, but the main trend remains unchanged. Similarly, we only change the value of one parameter and keep the other values unchanged to find the same trend. In addition, we also analyzed the impact of other random parameters on the equilibrium results in the article. In order to better present the results, only one set of values was selected in this article. Fig. 2 is the original graph, and Fig. 3 is the graph after parameter changes. It can be seen that although the values have changed, the overall trend has not changed. Based on this, we have come to a more universal conclusion. We point out this point in the first paragraph of “Numerical Study and Managerial Insights”.

Fig. 2 Fig.3

Comment 4:“The references should follow the format of the Journal.”

Response 4:Thank you very much for pointing out this issue. We are very sorry about the reference format and strictly follow the relevant format for modification. We have made every effort to meet the required editorial correction standards.

Comment 5: “For S2 Fig (b) and (c), why the p_2^H is near 0? Please give some reasons.”

Response 5:Regarding this issue, this is because the research conclusion of this article is similar to the Bertrand Nash game, which means that due to price competition between oligarchs, the final result is the same as in a completely free competition market, that is, the price drops to equal the cost. The price approaching 0 in the figure is obtained through numerical examples. The reason for this result is that under discounted pricing, the price competition between duopolies is carried out to attract more consumers. In order to attract more consumers, retailers engage in oligopolistic price competition without providing discounts on the platform. Additionally, due to the assumption of very low costs, the price in the second phase of the numerical simulation tends to be very low and seems to be zero. We point out this point in the second paragraph of the “Optimal Pricing Strategy Analysis” in the article.

Comment 6:“The English level should be improved. ”

Response 6:We are very sorry for the issue with our English proficiency. We have read through the entire text and have further revised any areas we consider unreasonable. Thank you for your sincere suggestions.

Dear reviewers,

Thank you for your careful review and constructive suggestions regarding our manuscript. We have revised the manuscript in accordance with the comments and marked all the amends on our revised manuscript. We hope that the modifications can be approved. Thank you again for your comment. We are happy to answer any further questions and comments you may have.

Thank you again and best regards.

Sincerely,

Hao Li, Zhe Chen

Reviewer #2:

Comment 1:1.“The paper lacks sufficient innovation and some of the theoretical contributions put forth by the authors do not hold up. To elaborate:

(1) Mu et al. (2020) already investigated the optimal pricing strategy for merchants and e-commerce platforms, taking into account consumer rebates and the dual discount phenomenon. Liu and Zhang (2013) analyzed a market with two firms, H and L, both offering quality-differentiated products with q_H and q_L respectively.

(2) Furthermore, in your discussion of Strategy E, it's unclear how the retailer's offer of a discount is factored in. What is the precise relationship between p_1^i and p_2^i? Is it correct to infer that your paper strictly contemplates whether or not the platform provides rebates?

[1] Mu L, Wang F, Chen L. Research on pricing strategy of E-commerce platform based on strategic consumers[J]. Operations Research and Management Science, 2020, 29(10): 225.

[2] Liu Q, Zhang D. Dynamic pricing competition with strategic customers under vertical product differentiation[J]. Management Science, 2013, 59(1): 84-101.”

Response 1:(1) We are very sorry that we may not have made a clear comparative analysis with existing literature. We pointed out this point in the “Literature Review”. In fact, our article is very different from the two papers you mentioned. Mu et al. (2020) did study the optimal pricing strategies of merchants and e-commerce platforms considering consumer rebates and double discounts. However, this article assumes that a market system consisting of an online retailer and an e-commerce platform does not consider the competitive relationship between high and low quality retailers. Moreover, this article studies whether e-commerce platforms provide rebates. This study is more in line with the reality of competition in the platform, and delves into the comparison of two strategies of discount pricing for retailers and dual discount pricing for retailers and e-commerce platforms, further expanded the research of Mu et al.

Liu and Zhang (2013) studied the dynamic pricing strategies of two companies, H and L, that provide differentiated quality qH and qL products. They compared static and dynamic pricing strategies between retailers, but did not consider the impact of e-commerce platforms on retailers; This article not only considers two retailers with vertical differentiation in the same competitive platform, but also considers the different discount pricing strategies of retailers and e-commerce platforms. The competition between retailers and platform rebates have a significant impact on the optimal strategy selection.

(2) We are very sorry that due to our unclear statement, the retailer discount we are considering is displayed through a two cycle price reduction. After normal sales, retailers will lower the product price. We define the time point before the price reduction as cycle 1, which is the normal sales cycle. At this time, the sales price is ; We define the price reduction node as cycle 2, which is the price reduction sales cycle. At this time, the discount price is . We have demonstrated through numerical simulation that the sales price for period 1 is higher than that for period 2, ,which is a discount pricing strategy with a decrease in price. As shown in the figure below, it can be seen that ( ) is true. We pointed out this in the last paragraph of “The Model”.

This article considers the rebate strategy of e-commerce platforms, which make decisions by providing the profit margin before and after the rebate. For example, platforms such as JD.com and Taobao do not offer rebate discounts on a daily basis, but offer certain rebates during holidays or shopping festivals. From a practical perspective, platforms offer rebates or different types of rebates. Therefore, this article considers the platform's decision on whether to offer rebates based on actual situations.

Fig.1

Comment 2:2. There seem to be issues with your model, with certain expressions appearing ambiguous and confusing.

(1) The range of some parameters needs additional scrutiny. Specifically, "(q_H, q_L) to (1, β) with β∈[0,1]", where β cannot reach the value of 1 as q_H>q_L, and cannot be 0 either, since β might serve as the denominator.

(2) In Strategy E, could you provide further proof to validate that v_2^L fulfills the condition v_2^L=(p_2^L)/β?

(3) The statement "defining the rebate rate of the e-commerce platform as f, consumers can enjoy a discount of (1-f)" is perplexing. The definition of the rebate rate and discount seem rather similar. For instance, if a product is priced at ¥100 and has a rebate rate of "10%", it implies you pay ¥100 and receive ¥10 back, which means you effectively enjoy a discount of 10% and only need to pay ¥90. Consequently, consumers can enjoy a discount of "f", resulting in the actual price paid, (1-f)(p_2^i ) ~, under both platform and retailer discounts. Moreover, typically a discount is deducted directly at the time of purchase, while a rebate is returned to the consumer after purchase at a certain rate, a characteristic that this paper's model fails to represent effectively.

Response 2:(1) Thank you very much for pointing out this issue. We have indeed overlooked this issue before, and your suggestion has made our model more rigorous. We have also made modifications to it, and we explained this in “The Model”.

(2) Let , at this point, the consumer valuation that retailer L can sell as far as possible in Period 2 is satisfied , therefore is determined by the value of and . At this time, only retailer L's products have demand in the market.

(3) We are very sorry that our statement may have caused ambiguity. In China, offering a few discounts is equivalent to enjoying a few discounts. In fact, what you said is quite correct. It should be that when the actual payment price is , consumers enjoy a discount . Secondly, after comprehensive consideration, we have decided to directly reflect the rebates paid by e-commerce platforms on consumer payment prices to more intuitively demonstrate the changes in consumer spending. We explained this in “Analysis of the double discount pricing strategy for retailers and e-commerce platforms”.

Comment3:3. The use and citation of references and supporting content in the manuscript is incorrect. The citation marked as [27] in the manuscript states, "We can interpret γ as the level of strategic behavior (Prasad et al. [27]), and a higher γ means……". However, the actual reference is not [27] but [13], which states "Hence, γ can be interpreted as the level of customer’s strategicity/rationality; a higher γ implies that customers are more strategic" (Liu and Zhang 2013). In the manuscript, the authors mention that gamma represents the valuation discount factor for strategic waiting by the parameter, and thus, gamma should only affect value 'v', not '(v-p)'? In addition, strategic customer behavior (i.e., γ) does not play any role in the last period game because there are no future purchase opportunities (Liu and Zhang 2013).

Response 3:Thank you very much for your correction of the literature citation. The essence of it should be as you said, and we have made modifications to it. But unlike Liu, what we define as the utility discount factor, like Levin Y, McGill J, and Nediak M, represents the degree of consumer strategy. A larger value indicates that consumers have greater utility in cross period purchases, and a higher willingness to wait until period 2 (discounted sales period) to make purchases. We are studying the relationship between period 1 and period 2. And we explained this in “The Model”.

[1] Levin Y , Mcgill J , Nediak M .Optimal dynamic pricing of perishable items by a monopolist facing strategic consumers[J].Operations Research, 2010.

[2] Levin Y , Mcgill J , Nediak M .Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of Strategic Consumers and Oligopolistic Competition[J]. 2017.DOI:10.1287/mnsc.1080.0936.

Comment4:4. The parameter values in the numerical examples lack practical case support, and there should be additional clarification regarding the data sources. The statement that "the optimal pricing of retailer L in the first period decreases before it increases" does not align with Fig. 3(a). The conclusions drawn from the research are quite intuitive, lacking in intriguing findings and valuable managerial insights.

Response 4:Regarding parameter assumption: We assume that , , , , is randomly selected to examine the relationship between factors. In fact, the size of the parameter does not change the equilibrium result.

We change the value to , we keep the other parameter values fixed , 。 , , This will correspondingly change the specific values such as the main price, but the main trend remains unchanged. Similarly, we only change the value of any other parameter and keep the other values unchanged. In multiple experiments, we found that changing the numerical simulation values will not affect the trend direction. Therefore, we chose a set of data that can most intuitively display the changing trend. Fig. 2 is the original graph, and Fig. 3 is the graph after parameter changes. Although the parameter values have changed, the overall trend in Fig. 2 and 3 has not changed. We point out this point in the first paragraph of “Numerical Study and Managerial Insights”.

Fig.2 Fig.3

Thank you for your correction. Due to our mistake, we did not accurately describe the price changes of retailers in Cycle 1. We have now checked and corrected several issues related to English wording, grammar, and input errors throughout the text, and have proposed some more thought-provoking discoveries and valuable management insights.

Comment 5:5. Several issues related to English phrasing, grammar, and input errors require a comprehensive review and rectification throughout the text to prevent inaccuracies and increase readability. Therefore, it is recommended that the article undergo a thorough proofreading process. Illustrations of the points that need attention are as follows:

(1) The precision of the language needs to be enhanced. In the "Abstract" section, there are grammatical errors, for example, " In this paper, we constructs a dynamic game……,investigate the……,and further discuss the……" Also, in the "Numerical Study and Managerial Insights" section, the sentence, "The second factor is (the) rebate (rate), which is summarized by the parameter f," needs correction.

(2) Furthermore, some English expressions are challenging to understand. The phrase "Apply for refunding the deposit for presale product after receiving the goods" may not be a suitable example to illustrate the concept of rebate redemption in today's context, as the deposit is typically part of the final payment in reality. Sentences such as "An increase in the rebate rate means that consumers receive fewer discounts from the platform and the retailer will choose to reduce prices to attract consumers " and " The greater the rebate rate is, the smaller the discount on the platform." require refinement.

Response 5:Thank you for your suggestion. We have thoroughly proofread the article. Corrected grammar and sentence errors, and rewrote sentences that were not clearly expressed, refining them based on actual situations. The reason why we say "Apply for refunding the deposit for presale product after receiving the goods" is because the promotion methods on the platform are more diverse nowadays. For example, during the Tmall Double 11 shopping festival, we launched a deposit first reservation product. After the final payment is settled, consumers can directly apply for a refund deposit on the shopping details page to complete the rebate.

Dear reviewer,

Thank you very much for taking the time to review this manuscript. We really appreciate your feedback and suggestions. We have revised the manuscript based on your comments and marked all modifications on the revised manuscript. We look forward to receiving your letter. If you have any questions, please do not hesitate to contact me.

Thank you again and best regards.

Sincerely,

Hao Li, Zhe Chen

Reviewer #3:

Comment 1: 1. The mathematical symbols are ugly. The authors should modify them.

Response 2:Thanks for your interest in our research. We tried our best to modified study for making article meet the requirement. We have optimized the entire article and made adjustments according to the requirements of “PLOS ONE” journal.

Comment 2:2. I would like to ask why the authors submit this paper to Plos One? It seems that the paper is more suitable to a business journal.

Response 2:Thank you for your sincere suggestion. PLOS ONE accepts articles in the fields of humanities and social sciences. Our article elaborates on discount sales seasons such as the Internet Shopping Festival, which essentially belongs to the field of humanities and social sciences. This article involves solving complex models with multiple cycles in derivation, exploring the economic laws under price discounts, revealing the social phenomenon of "increasing prices first and then decreasing prices", and providing certain guidance for the pricing of e-commerce platform retailers and consumer purchasing decisions. Based on this consideration, we believe that this article is suitable for submission to PLOS ONE.

Dear reviewer,

We are grateful for your effort reviewing our paper and your positive feedback. We have read through the entire text and revised the manuscript according to the journal's requirements based on your feedback, and have marked all modifications on the revised manuscript.

Thank you and best regards.

Sincerely,

Hao Li, Zhe Chen

Attachment

Submitted filename: Response to reviewers.docx

pone.0296654.s016.docx (243KB, docx)

Decision Letter 2

Vincenzo Basile

18 Dec 2023

How Do E-commerce Platforms and Retailers Implement Discount Pricing Policies under Consumers are Strategic?

PONE-D-23-21142R2

Dear Dr. zhe chen,

We’re pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been judged scientifically suitable for publication and will be formally accepted for publication once it meets all outstanding technical requirements.

Within one week, you’ll receive an e-mail detailing the required amendments. When these have been addressed, you’ll receive a formal acceptance letter and your manuscript will be scheduled for publication.

An invoice for payment will follow shortly after the formal acceptance. To ensure an efficient process, please log into Editorial Manager at http://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/, click the 'Update My Information' link at the top of the page, and double check that your user information is up-to-date. If you have any billing related questions, please contact our Author Billing department directly at authorbilling@plos.org.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper to help maximize its impact. If they’ll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team as soon as possible -- no later than 48 hours after receiving the formal acceptance. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

Kind regards,

Vincenzo Basile, PhD

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Additional Editor Comments:

Please provide a final paper with all revisions made and I recommend an additional check on plagiarism and/or compliance with the Journal's guidelines.

Acceptance letter

Vincenzo Basile

1 Mar 2024

PONE-D-23-21142R2

PLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Chen,

I'm pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been deemed suitable for publication in PLOS ONE. Congratulations! Your manuscript is now being handed over to our production team.

At this stage, our production department will prepare your paper for publication. This includes ensuring the following:

* All references, tables, and figures are properly cited

* All relevant supporting information is included in the manuscript submission,

* There are no issues that prevent the paper from being properly typeset

If revisions are needed, the production department will contact you directly to resolve them. If no revisions are needed, you will receive an email when the publication date has been set. At this time, we do not offer pre-publication proofs to authors during production of the accepted work. Please keep in mind that we are working through a large volume of accepted articles, so please give us a few weeks to review your paper and let you know the next and final steps.

Lastly, if your institution or institutions have a press office, please let them know about your upcoming paper now to help maximize its impact. If they'll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team within the next 48 hours. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

If we can help with anything else, please email us at customercare@plos.org.

Thank you for submitting your work to PLOS ONE and supporting open access.

Kind regards,

PLOS ONE Editorial Office Staff

on behalf of

Dr. Vincenzo Basile

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Associated Data

    This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

    Supplementary Materials

    S1 Fig. Diagram of the double discount pricing decision for e-commerce platforms and retailers.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s001.tif (61.3KB, tif)
    S2 Fig. Equilibrium pricing analysis of retailer H under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s002.tif (377.3KB, tif)
    S3 Fig. Equilibrium pricing analysis of retailer L under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s003.tif (388.3KB, tif)
    S4 Fig. Retailer H demand analysis under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s004.tif (105.4KB, tif)
    S5 Fig. Retailer L demand analysis under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s005.tif (107.7KB, tif)
    S6 Fig. Comparative analysis of the demand of two retailers under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s006.tif (147.8KB, tif)
    S7 Fig. Retailer H profit analysis under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s007.tif (109.3KB, tif)
    S8 Fig. Retailer L profit analysis under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s008.tif (111.4KB, tif)
    S9 Fig. Comparative analysis of the profit of two retailers under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s009.tif (120.8KB, tif)
    S10 Fig. Comparative analysis of the profit of e-commerce platforms under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s010.tif (144.3KB, tif)
    S11 Fig. Profit margins between retailers and e-commerce platforms under two pricing strategies.

    (TIF)

    pone.0296654.s011.tif (207.6KB, tif)
    S1 Appendix

    (DOCX)

    pone.0296654.s012.docx (16.1KB, docx)
    Attachment

    Submitted filename: renamed_b9f66.docx

    pone.0296654.s013.docx (19.2KB, docx)
    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Review comments on PONE-D-23-21142.docx

    pone.0296654.s014.docx (20.1KB, docx)
    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Response to reviewers.docx

    pone.0296654.s015.docx (243KB, docx)
    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Response to reviewers.docx

    pone.0296654.s016.docx (243KB, docx)

    Data Availability Statement

    All relevant data are within the manuscript and its Supporting Information files.


    Articles from PLOS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

    RESOURCES