Skip to main content
The BMJ logoLink to The BMJ
. 2002 Jan 5;324(7328):47.

Private health care in developing countries

Access cannot be equated simply with supply

Ian Mather 1, Sam Ramaiah 1
PMCID: PMC1121949  PMID: 11797637

Editor—Zwi et al in their editorial suggest means by which governments in developing countries should try to harness private providers to improve the health of their citizens.1 A recent article by Whitehead et al, however, points to a medical poverty trap, created by the introduction of user fees for public services and the growth of out of pocket expenses for private services.2 The authors conclude that the main challenge in developing countries is to improve public health services and enable the poorest sections of society to obtain the health care they need.

India has experienced a massive growth in private health provision despite high public investment in health services. Several studies have shown that there is a marked reluctance to use free facilities even among the poorest sections in Indian society. For example, a study of health and health care among scheduled castes showed that 38% sought private medical help when their children became ill, compared with 28% for government health facilities.3 Another study, which focused on the urban poor in Calcutta, concluded that public health facilities were used for emergency purposes but there was a preference for private practitioners for all other types of care.3 The implication of these studies is that access cannot be equated simply with supply but is dependent on locational, economic, and social access, as well as the quality of the services themselves.

At the same time as trying to make public services more responsive it is vital that resources are used efficiently in areas that maximise health improvement. At present, in India, over half of the health budget is spent on secondary and tertiary curative services, whereas better health outcomes could be achieved by investing in preventive measures. The emphasis on private healthcare provision may serve to distort these priorities even further.

References

  • 1.Zwi AB, Brugha R, Smith E. Private health care in developing countries. BMJ. 2001;323:463–464. doi: 10.1136/bmj.323.7311.463. . (1 September.) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Whitehead M, Dahlgren G, Evans T. Equity and health sector reforms: can low-income countries escape the medical poverty trap? Lancet. 2001;358:833–836. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(01)05975-X. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Das Gupta M, Chen L, Krishnan TN, editors. Health, poverty and development in India. Delhi: Oxford University Press; 1996. [Google Scholar]
BMJ. 2002 Jan 5;324(7328):47.

Strong public provision is only hope for health care in developing countries

Philip Crowley 1

Editor—The editorial by Zwi et al, in which principles are described for the participation of private providers in delivering health care in developing countries, is important.1-1

I worked for five years in northern Nicaragua between 1989 and 1994. During that time I witnessed the strengths of the primary healthcare system developed by the Sandinista government in partnership with powerful community and social organisations. I also witnessed the entry of the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund into Nicaragua and the impact that this had on health and health care. One of the central beliefs imposed by these agencies was that local people must pay user fees for health and education. Funding from the public sector was drastically reduced, and the result was the effective conversion of free state health care into private, pay as you go, health care provided by the state. Local people, for example, had to sell their only cow, the sole source of milk for the family, to pay for necessary drugs, which led to further malnutrition. In parallel to this doctors provided private health care in clinics.

The effect of all of this was to deprive the poor majority of local people of access to health care. The cutbacks in public sector funding resulted in major reductions in malaria control and other public health measures. The result of this was a significant increase in cases of malaria and dengue fever.

Thus it is hard to imagine how the private sector can have anything but an inequitable effect on healthcare delivery in developing countries. Poor people will not be able to pay. This is particularly true when their livelihood is so vulnerable to international markets. So many people in Nicaragua have been devastated by the collapse in the international market value of coffee (resulting from a coffee glut as a result of the International Monetary Fund and World Bank recommending too many new countries to get into coffee production).

The hope for health care in countries such as Nicaragua is the phenomenal voluntary contribution made by the teams of health brigadistas up and down the country in combating common diseases such a diarrhoea and malaria. The international community can help by promoting fair trade, encouraging debt cancellation swapped for public health sector investment, and ensuring that vital drugs are not denied to poorer countries because of excessive costs and patent periods.

References

  • 1-1.Zwi AB, Brugha R, Smith E. Private health care in developing countries. BMJ. 2001;323:463–464. doi: 10.1136/bmj.323.7311.463. . (1 September.) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Articles from BMJ : British Medical Journal are provided here courtesy of BMJ Publishing Group

RESOURCES