Skip to main content
Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health logoLink to Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health
. 2006 Nov;60(11):917–922. doi: 10.1136/jech.2005.044628

Deprivation and quality of primary care services: evidence for persistence of the inverse care law from the UK Quality and Outcomes Framework

G McLean 1,2,3, M Sutton 1,2,3, B Guthrie 1,2,3
PMCID: PMC2465488  PMID: 17053278

Abstract

Objective

To examine whether the quality of primary care measured by the 2004 contract varies with socioeconomic deprivation.

Design

Retrospective analysis of publicly available data, comparing quality indicators used for payment that allow exclusion of patients (payment quality) and indicators based on the care delivered to all patients (delivered quality).

Setting and participants

1024 general practices in Scotland.

Main outcome measures

Regression coefficients summarising the relationships between deprivation and payment and delivered quality.

Results

Little systematic association is found between payment quality and deprivation but, for 17 of the 33 indicators examined, delivered quality falls with increasing deprivation. Absolute differences in delivered quality are small for most simpler process measures, such as recording of smoking status or blood pressure. Greater inequalities are seen for more complex process measures such as diagnostic procedures, some intermediate outcome measures such as glycaemic control in diabetes and measures of treatment such as influenza immunisation.

Conclusions

The exclusions system succeeds in not penalising practices financially for the characteristics of the population they serve, but does not reward the additional work required in deprived areas and contributes to a continuation of the inverse care law. The contract data collected prevent examination of most complex process or treatment measures and this analysis is likely to underestimate the extent of continuing inequalities in care. Broader lessons cannot be drawn on the effect on inequalities of this new set of incentives until changes are made to the way contract data are collected and analysed.


A major part of the new General Medical Services contract implemented across the UK from April 2004 is the Quality and Outcomes Framework (QOF), under which up to a quarter of the general practitioners' income depends on practice performance measured against 146 clinical and organisational indicators.1 Indicators are assigned a fixed number of points, which weight them according to perceived workload and importance, each point being worth £75 to an average practice in 2004–5. A total of 76 indicators and 550 of the 1050 points relate to the management of 10 chronic diseases. The indicators capture the maintenance of a disease register, recording of risk factors, recording and achievement of intermediate outcomes, and delivery of recommended treatments. Payment is triggered once performance on each clinical indicator exceeds 25% and increases linearly until performance exceeds 90% for most process measures and 50–70% for most intermediate outcome measures.

Much of the early coverage of the QOF has been on the high average number of points achieved, with widespread coverage at both national and regional levels, indicating that quality of care is generally high, with relatively little variation between practices.2 However, two caveats apply to this conclusion. Firstly, maximum points can be achieved for percentages of the target population ranging from 50% to 90% depending on the indicator. Examining quality in terms of the actual percentages of patients achieving particular targets may therefore show variations that are not apparent in the distribution of points. Secondly, practices are allowed to exclude from the measurement of achievement those patients who are unsuitable for any chronic disease management or for particular indicators. Box 1 lists the acceptable reasons for exclusion.3,4 The intention is to avoid financially penalising practices for the characteristics of the population they serve. However, these reasons to exclude patients are likely to be more common in deprived populations (eg, through less response to invitations to attend clinics on chronic disease management). Measuring quality using payment percentages that account for exclusions may therefore conceal continuing inequalities in service provision5,6,7,8 and perpetuate them by failing to reward practices for the additional work required to bring deprived populations into systematic care.

Surprisingly, there has been little focus on the possible effect of allowing practices to exclude patients. This paper therefore examines how the quality of primary care varies by levels of deprivation, comparing two measures of the quality of care. “Payment quality” is the percentage of non‐excluded patients who achieve a particular target (eg, have their blood pressure measured, have their cholesterol controlled or have an influenza vaccination). This is the measure that determines payment under the QOF. “Delivered quality” is the percentage of all patients with the disease who achieve a particular target (box 2). This informs consideration of whether the QOF has helped exclude longstanding inequalities in care.5,6

Box 1 Acceptable reasons for exclusion of patients4

Exception reporting can be applied for the following:

  • Patients who have been recorded as refusing to attend a review or who have been invited on at least three occasions during the preceding 12 months;

  • patients for whom it is not appropriate to review the specific chronic disease parameters due to particular circumstances—for example, terminal illness and extreme frailty;

  • patients newly diagnosed within the practice or who have recently registered with the practice, who should have measurements made within 3 months and delivery of clinical standards within 9 months—for example, blood pressure or cholesterol measurements within target levels;

  • patients who are on maximum tolerated doses of a drug and whose levels of outcome remain suboptimal;

  • patients for whom prescribing a drug is not clinically appropriate—for example, those who have an allergy, another contraindication or have experienced an adverse reaction;

  • where a patient has not tolerated a drug;

  • where a patient does not agree to investigation or treatment (and after a reasonable discussion or written advice they have given their informed dissent) and this dissent has been recorded in their medical records;

  • where the patient has a supervening condition that makes treatment of their condition inappropriate—for example, cholesterol reduction where the patient has liver disease;

  • where an investigative service or secondary care service is unavailable.

An exception code may apply to an entire clinical domain or to specific indicators. In either case, patients are added back into both the numerator and denominator if they achieve the indicator.

Methods

Using publicly available data on QOF achievement for each practice,9 we calculated payment quality and delivered quality for clinical indicators, where the true denominator was all patients with the disease (box 2). Table 1 shows the indicators used for calculating payment quality and delivered quality.

Table 1 Mean payment quality and delivered quality for 33 clinical indicators.

Disease area Indicator definition Payment range (%) No of practices Mean payment quality (%) Mean delivered quality (%) Difference between means p<t
 CHD Record of smoking status in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 95.0 95.0 0.96
 Stroke Record of smoking status in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 93.3 93.0 <0.001
 Hypertension Record of smoking status since diagnosis 25–90 1021 95.0 94.6 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of smoking status in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 97.1 97.0 <0.001
 COPD Record of smoking status in the previous 15 months 25–90 1019 94.4 94.7 0.01
 CHD Record of blood pressure in previous 15 months 25–90 1020 95.0 94.7 0.39
 Stroke Record of blood pressure in previous 15 months 25–90 1020 94.0 93.5 <0.001
 Hypertension Record of blood pressure in previous 9 months 25–90 1021 88.7 88.4 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of blood pressure in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 97.6 97.3 <0.001
 CHD Record of total cholesterol in previous 15 months 25–90 1020 88.0 86.0 <0.001
 Stroke Record of total cholesterol in previous 15 months 25–90 1020 83.8 80.3 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of total cholesterol in previous 15 months 25–90 1020 94.4 92.9 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of retinal screening in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 86.4 78.6 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of peripheral pulse test in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 84.8 80.0 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of neuropathy testing in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 83.1 78.2 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of serum creatinine testing in the previous 15 months 25–90 1020 94.5 92.9 <0.001
 COPD Diagnosis confirmed by spirometry 25–90 1019 74.8 63.6 <0.001
 COPD Record of FEV1 in previous 27 months 25–70 1019 69.7 57.2 <0.001
Outcome
 CHD Blood pressure recorded in previous 15 months ⩽150/90 25–70 1020 84.9 82.8 <0.001
 Stroke Blood pressure recorded in previous 15 months ⩽150/90 25–70 1020 82.7 79.3 <0.001
 Hypertension Blood pressure recorded in previous 15 months ⩽150/90 25–70 1021 72.3 69.3 <0.001
 Diabetes Blood pressure recorded in previous 15 months ⩽145/85 25–55 1020 75.0 70.0 <0.001
 CHD Total cholesterol recorded in previous 15 months ⩽5 mmol/l 25–60 1020 69.3 63.7 <0.001
 Stroke Total cholesterol recorded in previous 15 months ⩽5 mmol/l 25–60 1020 63.3 55.8 <0.001
 Diabetes Total cholesterol recorded in previous 15 months ⩽5 mmol/l 25–60 1020 74.2 67.1 <0.001
 Diabetes HbA1c recorded in previous 15 months ⩽7.4% 25–55 1020 56.9 49.9 <0.001
 Diabetes HbA1c recorded in previous 15 months ⩽10% 25–85 1020 89.9 85.6 <0.001
Treatment
 CHD Aspirin, alternative antiplatelet or anticoagulant being taken 25–90 1020 89.5 87.6 <0.001
 CHD Treated with β‐blocker 25–50 1020 70.0 52.9 <0.001
 CHD Record of influenza immunisation in previous flu season 25–85 1020 86.6 75.8 <0.001
 Stroke Record of influenza immunisation in previous flu season 25–85 1020 83.7 71.6 <0.001
 Diabetes Record of influenza immunisation in previous flu season 25–85 1020 86.7 73.4 <0.001

CHD, coronary heart disease; COPD, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease; HbA1c, glycosylated haemoglobin; FEV1, forced expiratory volume in 1 s.

Numerators and denominators for payment were measured on 31 March 2005. As prevalence determines payment level (pounds per point), the number of patients on the disease register was recorded by the Quality Management and Assessment System (QMAS).10 For most practices, these prevalence levels were extracted on 14 February 2005, “National Prevalence Day”. Initial analysis indicated that in some practices, the reported register size on 14 February was smaller than the denominators for each indicator on 31 March, indicating that it is unreliable. The two may differ because

  • individuals with a diagnosis leave the practice or die;

  • new individuals with a diagnosis arrive at the practice;

  • new cases are diagnosed between 14 February and 31 March; and

  • cases diagnosed on 14 February are found inaccurate and deleted by 31 March.

Box 2 Definitions of payment quality and delivered quality

For each indicator, payment quality is defined as: Payment

quality=n/(d−e+ea)

where n is the number of patients for which the indicator was achieved; d is the number on the disease register (all patients eligible before exclusions); e is the total number with an exclusion code for that indicator; and ea is the number of excluded patients for which the indicator was achieved anyway.

We define delivered quality as the proportion of all patients who receive the care defined by each indicator:

Delivered quality=n/d

For each clinical area, the Quality Management and Assessment System (QMAS) reports the number of patients on the disease register on 14 February. For each indicator within a domain, QMAS reports n and (d−e+ea) on 31 March. However, for many indicators d is the number of patients on the disease register and for these indicators delivered quality can be estimated by the maximum value of the denominator within the disease area.

We therefore estimated the register size on 31 March using the maximum value of any denominator in the relevant clinical domain. This assumes that each practice has not excluded anyone from at least one of its indicators. It will therefore underestimate the true register size on 31 March and overestimate delivered quality. For the purpose of this analysis, the key issue is whether the estimate is systematically related to deprivation. No systematic relationship was found between deprivation and differences between the reported register size on 14 February and our estimate of register size on 31 March, which indicates that our results are unlikely to be due to bias in this method for estimating the total register size.

Our measure of practice deprivation is derived from the income domain of the Scottish Index of Multiple Deprivation, 2004.11 We chose the income domain rather than the overall score or other domains, because it receives the highest weight in the calculation of the overall index and is highly correlated with it, is available for small geographical areas representing between 500 and 1000 people and does not undergo transformations, making it easily interpretable. Average values for practices were calculated on the basis of the geographical distribution of registered populations.

QOF data were available for 1024 practices, although not all practices participated in each of the clinical domains examined, and one practice was excluded because no deprivation data were available. We provide results for payment quality (based on payment denominators) and delivered quality (based on total register size) for indicators where the true denominator is for all patients with the disease, for five clinical areas—coronary heart disease (CHD), stroke and transient ischaemic attack, diabetes mellitus, hypertension and chronic obstructive pulmonary disease (COPD; table 1). The chosen indicators represent 294 (53%) of the 550 points available for clinical quality.

We estimated the size and statistical significance of the trend across deprivation using regression analysis. We used linear regression throughout, estimated using Stata V.8 with robust standard errors. The calculation of mean values and the regression coefficients were weighted by population size.

The regression coefficients represented the change in quality associated with a one‐point increase in the percentage of the practice population receiving state benefits on the grounds of low income. We compared the regression coefficients when quality was measured by payment quality and delivered quality. Where the coefficient on delivered quality minus the coefficient on payment quality is negative, the implied exclusion rates are higher in more deprived practices. Exclusion rates are lower in deprived practices if the coefficient on delivered quality minus the coefficient on payment quality is positive.

Results

Table 1 gives the definitions, payment stages and national mean values for both payment quality and delivered quality. Absolute differences between payment quality and delivered quality for simpler process measures such as recording of smoking status, blood pressure, cholesterol and creatinine are generally small. Larger differences are found for indicators for more complex processes such as foot and eye screening in diabetes, and spirometry in COPD, and for intermediate outcomes. The largest differences are found for treatment indicators with β‐blockers falling 17.1% and the three immunisation indicators for CHD, stroke and diabetes falling 10.8%, 12.1% and 13.3%, respectively.

On the process indicators (table 2), payment quality is significantly (p<0.05) higher in more affluent practices for two of the 18 indicators, significantly (p<0.05) higher in more deprived practices for seven indicators and not significantly different for the remaining nine indicators. By contrast, delivered quality of care is better in more affluent practices on eight indicators, better in more deprived practices on one indicator and not significantly different on the remaining nine indicators. The most dramatic differences are for the two diagnostic indicators for COPD. For the monitoring of patients with COPD using forced expiratory volume in 1 s (FEV1), the regression coefficient changes from 0.35 for payment quality to −0.45 for delivered quality. The range in deprivation is 40.89 points, so this equates to a maximum change in measured quality of 32.7% (payment quality being 14.3% higher in the most deprived practices, whereas delivered quality is 18.4% lower). Three complex process diabetes measures (vascular and neuropathic foot screening, and eye screening) show similar reversals.

Table 2 Regression coefficients for process indicators.

Indicators Payment quality (%) Delivered quality (%)
Regression coefficient* p Value Regression coefficient* p Value
CHD—smoking status recorded −0.01 0.61 −0.01 0.56
Stroke—smoking status recorded 0.01 0.53 0.01 0.53
Hypertension—smoking status recorded 0.03 0.11 0.03 0.11
Diabetes—smoking status recorded 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.21
COPD—smoking status recorded 0.07 <0.001 0.07 <0.001
CHD—blood pressure recorded −0.07 <0.001 −0.09 <0.001
Stroke—blood pressure recorded −0.03 0.18 −0.03 0.03
Hypertension—blood pressure recorded 0.04 0.27 0.02 0.61
Diabetes—blood pressure recorded 0.01 0.24 0.00 0.78
CHD—cholesterol recorded −0.10 0.01 −0.11 <0.001
Stroke—cholesterol recorded 0.05 0.33 0.05 0.76
Diabetes—cholesterol recorded 0.07 <0.001 0.01 0.64
Diabetes—retinal screening recorded 0.07 0.17 −0.52 <0.001
Diabetes—peripheral pulses recorded 0.13 0.02 −0.17 0.01
Diabetes—neuropathy testing recorded 0.13 0.03 −0.18 0.01
Diabetes—creatinine recorded 0.04 0.20 −0.03 0.40
COPD—diagnosis by spirometry 0.32 <0.001 −0.35 <0.001
COPD—record of recent FEV1 0.35 <0.001 −0.45 <0.001

CHD, coronary heart disease; COPD, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease; FEV1, forced expiratory volume in 1 s.

*Reflects the effect of a one‐point increase in the percentage of patients receiving state benefits on the grounds of low income on the percentage of patients achieving the indicator. There is a 40.9‐point range in the deprivation measure, and 90% of practices lie in a 30‐point range.

On the intermediate outcome indicators (table 3), payment quality is significantly higher in more affluent practices for one of the nine indicators and higher in more deprived practices on four indicators. Delivered quality is higher in more affluent practices on four indicators, and higher in more deprived practices on three indicators (although for two of these, the relationship is weakened). Only cholesterol control in patients with CHD shows a stronger negative relationship with deprivation on payment quality than with delivered quality. Three indicators have a positive relationship with deprivation on both payment and delivered quality. The indicators reflecting blood pressure control for patients with hypertension and HbA1c levels <10% for patients with diabetes both become more negatively and significantly related to deprivation under delivered quality. The indicator reflecting HbA1c levels <7.4% for patients with diabetes is the only outcome indicator that moves from having a significant positive relationship with deprivation on payment quality to a significant and negative relationship with deprivation on delivered quality.

Table 3 Regression coefficients for outcome indicators.

Indicator Payment quality (%) Delivered quality (%)
Outcome Regression coefficient* p Value Regression coefficient* p Value
CHD—blood pressure controlled −0.02 0.53 −0.04 0.28
Stroke—blood pressure controlled 0.05 0.2 0.05 0.64
Hypertension—blood pressure controlled −0.05 0.14 −0.08 0.01
Diabetes—blood pressure controlled 0.31 <0.001 0.16 <0.001
CHD—cholesterol controlled −0.13 0.01 −0.12 0.01
Stroke—cholesterol controlled 0.13 0.03 0.13 0.04
Diabetes—cholesterol controlled 0.31 <0.001 0.10 0.01
Diabetes—HBA1c ⩽7.4% 0.21 <0.001 −0.15 <0.001
Diabetes—HBA1c ⩽10% −0.02 0.57 −0.20 <0.001

CHD, coronary heart disease; FEV1, forced expiratory volume in 1 s; HbA1c, glycosylated haemoglobin.

*Reflects the effect of a one‐point increase in the percentage of patients receiving state benefits on the grounds of low income on the percentage of patients achieving the indicator. There is a 40.9‐point range in the deprivation measure, and 90% of practices lie in a 30‐point range.

On the treatment indicators (table 4), payment quality is significantly higher in more affluent practices for two of the six indicators and higher in more deprived practices for just one indicator. Delivered quality is higher in more affluent practices for five indicators. None of the indicators show a significant positive relationship between deprivation and delivered quality. Only the taking of aspirin or equivalent drugs for patients with CHD shows a significant negative relationship between deprivation and delivered quality. Both influenza vaccination indicators for diabetes and COPD move from having a significant positive relationship with payment quality to a significant and negative relationship with delivered quality. The taking of β‐blockers for patients with CHD becomes more negatively and significantly related to deprivation on delivered quality and influenza immunisation of patients with CHD becomes more negatively related to deprivation and remains significant.

Table 4 Regression coefficients for treatment indicators.

Indicators Payment quality (%) Delivered quality (%)
Regression coefficient* p Value Regression coefficient* p Value
CHD—on aspirin or equivalent 0.01 0.78 0.03 0.2
CHD—on β‐blocker −0.06 0.21 −0.14 <0.001
CHD—had influenza vaccination −0.17 <0.001 −0.31 <0.001
Stroke—had influenza vaccination −0.09 0.05 −0.09 <0.001
Diabetes—had influenza vaccination 0.09 0.03 −0.14 <0.001
COPD—had influenza vaccination 0.02 0.59 −0.31 <0.001

CHD, coronary heart disease; COPD, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease.

*Reflects the effect of a one‐point increase in the percentage of patients receiving state benefits on the grounds of low income on the percentage of patients achieving the indicator. There is a 40.9‐point range in the deprivation measure, and 90% of practices lie in a 30‐point range.

Discussion

The introduction of the new General Medical Services reflects international interest in using financial incentives as a method of improving primary care. As such, the results of the new UK contract will attract much interest.12

This is the first study to compare quality using the measures that drive payment with quality measured in terms of the actual care delivered. Its major limitation reflects the way that data are held in the payment system. Delivered quality can only be estimated for a limited number of indicators because QMAS does not record either the true denominators for every indicator or the register size on the same date that the indicator data are extracted. The method we have used overestimates delivered quality but is not biased in terms of estimating the effect of deprivation.

At face value, new contract data for Scotland indicate that there is little systematic difference between practices serving populations with different levels of deprivation. It is consistent with financial incentives for quality such as the QOF mitigating previous inequalities in care.5,6,7,8,13,14 However, such conclusions based on payment quality are misleading. For 17 of the 33 indicators, delivered quality is systematically lower in practices serving more deprived populations. It is higher for only four indicators. This indicates that the exclusions system of the QOF conceals continuing inequalities in service provision. The absolute differences are relatively small for simpler process measures that can be delivered opportunistically (measurement of blood pressure and cholesterol and recording of smoking status), but are considerably larger for many diagnostic, intermediate outcome and treatment indicators.

There are two main explanations for these patterns. Firstly, more deprived populations may have more legitimate reasons for exclusion, such as not attending routine care, having greater comorbidity, and moving and therefore changing practice more often. Secondly, practices serving more deprived populations may be of lower quality generally and use exclusions to maximise payment. This is facilitated by the relative lack of definition of exclusions compared with the clarity of the indicators themselves.

Policy implications

  • The exclusions system in the contract offers little incentive for the extra work required to deliver care to deprived populations and contributes to a continuation of the inverse care law.

  • Changes in the way contract data are collected and analysed are required before inequalities in care can be identified accurately and acted on appropriately.

Identifying which of these explanations is true will require more detailed examination than is possible in this study. The first explanation is plausible, but many reasons for exclusion that are legitimate under the contract (such as poor attendance at routine clinics) are potentially amenable to health service intervention.15,16 Moreover, if the problem was a result of greater “no show” rates among the disadvantaged, it is hard to see why the implied exclusion rates differ across the same indicator for different diseases.

The payment system can be considered to have been successful in not penalising practices financially for the populations that they serve. However, it highlights that the contract does not reward for the extra work involved in delivering equal outcomes and treatments to disadvantaged populations. Furthermore, the indicators focus on levels of outcome, rather than changes in outcome. As some patients may achieve the outcome indicators without intervention, particularly in more affluent areas, practices may be rewarded for levels of outcome that are not attributable to their services.

What is already known

  • The inverse care law predicts that good‐quality health services will be less available to those populations that need them most.

  • The new contract for primary medical services introduced across the UK in 2004 included financial incentives directly linked to the quality of care provided.

  • For payment purposes, general practices are allowed to exclude patients from the indicators used to calculate the quality of their care.

What this paper adds

  • We compare performance for quality indicators used for payment that allow for the exclusion of patients (“payment quality”) and indicators based on the care delivered to all patients (“delivered quality”).

  • Under payment quality, there is little evidence that more deprived populations receive worse care.

  • However, based on delivered quality 17 of the 33 measures examined show markedly worse care for more deprived populations.

This study also highlights the limitations of QMAS data in examining the distribution of quality of care using different assumptions about exclusions. Notably, many of the diagnostic and treatment indicators do not have a recoverable true denominator (eg, most of the diagnostic indicators and some treatment indicators are limited to new diagnoses and the smoking advice indicator is based on the denominator of current smokers). As inequalities are greatest for similar indicators where we can recover a true denominator, the results presented here are likely to underestimate the extent of inequalities in delivered care.

In conclusion, this paper has shown that despite payment data indicating a relatively equitable distribution of quality under the 2004 general practice contract, the inverse care law still applies with persistent inequalities in the care actually delivered.5,6 Analysis of this inequality is hampered by the lack of information about exclusions in QMAS in 2004–5. The inclusion of data on exclusions in QMAS for the 2005–6 contract year will allow a more accurate analysis of inequalities in care across socioeconomic groups. Only then will the full effect of these financial incentives on equity be understood, and practices and primary care organisations be informed to make an appropriate response. Meanwhile, the lack of information on the reasons for exclusion limits the lessons that can be learned in other countries about the effect of this innovative set of incentives in improving the equity and quality of care.

Abbreviations

CHD - congestive heart disease

COPD - chronic obstructive pulmonary disease

QOF - Quality and Outcomes Framework

QMAS - Quality Management and Analysis System

Footnotes

GM is sponsored by the Platform Project, jointly funded by the Chief Scientist Office and the Scottish Higher Education Funding Council. MS and BG are funded by the Chief Scientist Office.

Competing interests: None declared.

References

  • 1.National Health Service Confederation and British Medical Association The new GMS contract. London: NHS Confederation and BMA, 2003, http: // www.dh.gov.uk/PolicyAndGuidance/OrganisationPolicy/PrimaryCare/PrimaryCareContracting/GMS/fs/en
  • 2.Timmins N. Do GPs deserve their recent pay rise? BMJ 2005331800. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.NHS Confederation and the BMA Quality and outcomes framework: guidance. Updated August 2004. http://www.dh.gov.uk/assetRoot/04/08/86/93/04088693.pdf (accessed 26 Aug 2006)
  • 4.BMA General Practitioners Committee The new GMS contract explained: focus on exception reporting. London: British Medical Association, 2004, http://www.bma.org.uk/ap.nsf/Content/focusexcept0304/$file/Focusexceptreport.pdf (accessed 26 Aug 2006)
  • 5.Hart J T. The inverse care law. Lancet 19711405–412. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Watt G. The inverse care law today. Lancet 2002360252–254. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Mantangi P, Breeze E, Kovats S.et al Inequalities in influenza vaccine uptake among people aged over 74 years in Britain. Prev Med 200541545–553. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Hippisley‐Cox J, O'Hanlon S, Coupland C. Association with deprivation, ethnicity, and sex with quality indicators for diabetes: population based survey of 53,000 patients in primary care. BMJ 20043291267–1269. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.ISD Scotland Quality and Outcomes Framework. http://www.isdscotland.org/isd/QOF (accessed 26 Aug 2006)
  • 10.British Medical Association Focus on Quality and Outcomes Framework Management and Analysis System, October 2004. http://www.bma.org.uk/ap.nsf/Content/FocusQMAS1004 (accessed 26 Aug 2006)
  • 11.Scottish Executive Scottish Index of Multiple Deprivation, 2004. http://www.scotland.gov.uk/stats/simd2004/ (accessed 26 Aug 2006)
  • 12.Roland M. Linking physicians pay to quality of care—a major experiment in the UK. N Engl J Med 20043511448–1454. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Kyaw M H, Wayne B, Chamlers J.et al Influenza and pneumococcal vaccine distribution and use in primary care and hospital settings in Scotland: coverage, practice and polices. Epidemiol Infect 2002128445–455. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Baker D, Middleton E. Cervical screening and health inequality in England in the 1990s. J Epidemiol Community Health 200357417–423. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Marsh G N, Cashman H A, Russell I T. Deprivation and health in one general practice. BMJ 19862921173–1176. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Marsh G N, Channing D M. Comparison in use of health services between a deprived and an endowed community. Arch Dis Child 198762392–396. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Articles from Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health are provided here courtesy of BMJ Publishing Group

RESOURCES