Skip to main content
PLOS Computational Biology logoLink to PLOS Computational Biology
. 2009 Feb 6;5(2):e1000280. doi: 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1000280

Social Contact Networks and Disease Eradicability under Voluntary Vaccination

Ana Perisic 1, Chris T Bauch 1,*
Editor: Lauren Ancel Meyers2
PMCID: PMC2625434  PMID: 19197342

Abstract

Certain theories suggest that it should be difficult or impossible to eradicate a vaccine-preventable disease under voluntary vaccination: Herd immunity implies that the individual incentive to vaccinate disappears at high coverage levels. Historically, there have been examples of declining coverage for vaccines, such as MMR vaccine and whole-cell pertussis vaccine, that are consistent with this theory. On the other hand, smallpox was globally eradicated by 1980 despite voluntary vaccination policies in many jurisdictions. Previous modeling studies of the interplay between disease dynamics and individual vaccinating behavior have assumed that infection is transmitted in a homogeneously mixing population. By comparison, here we simulate transmission of a vaccine-preventable SEIR infection through a random, static contact network. Individuals choose whether to vaccinate based on infection risks from neighbors, and based on vaccine risks. When neighborhood size is small, rational vaccinating behavior results in rapid containment of the infection through voluntary ring vaccination. As neighborhood size increases (while the average force of infection is held constant), a threshold is reached beyond which the infection can break through partially vaccinated rings, percolating through the whole population and resulting in considerable epidemic final sizes and a large number vaccinated. The former outcome represents convergence between individually and socially optimal outcomes, whereas the latter represents their divergence, as observed in most models of individual vaccinating behavior that assume homogeneous mixing. Similar effects are observed in an extended model using smallpox-specific natural history and transmissibility assumptions. This work illustrates the significant qualitative differences between behavior–infection dynamics in discrete contact-structured populations versus continuous unstructured populations. This work also shows how disease eradicability in populations where voluntary vaccination is the primary control mechanism may depend partly on whether the disease is transmissible only to a few close social contacts or to a larger subset of the population.

Author Summary

Interest in infectious disease models that incorporate the effects of human behavior has been growing in recent years. However, most of these models predict that it should never be possible to eradicate a disease under voluntary vaccination, due to nonvaccinating “free riders” that emerge when vaccine coverage is high. This prediction contradicts the fact that smallpox was eradicated under a voluntary vaccination policy in many jurisdictions, and that other diseases such as polio are likewise near eradication. These previous models assumed that populations mix homogeneously. However, for some diseases, such as HIV and smallpox, individuals are more likely to get the disease from certain social contacts. Here we show that using a network model that captures this social structure can reconcile the previous theories to the empirical fact that diseases can be eradicated under voluntary vaccination. When infection is transmitted only through close contacts in the network, then an outbreak can be quickly contained using only voluntary vaccination. However, when infection can potentially be transmitted to almost everyone in the network (such as for measles), a disease outbreak can never be contained using voluntary vaccination. This latter observation may have some relevance to the Measles–Mumps–Rubella autism “vaccine scare.”

Introduction

Model-based analyses of vaccination programmes have often concluded that it should be difficult or impossible to eradicate a vaccine-preventable disease under a voluntary vaccination policy without other incentives [1][10]. As vaccination coverage increases, the disease becomes increasingly rare due to herd immunity. Eventually, the infection risk to susceptible individuals decreases to zero, while the individual risk due to the vaccine remains constant. Hence, the individual motive to vaccinate is also reduced to zero as vaccine coverage increases. This should be true, in principle, even for a disease such as smallpox with very high case fatality rates, as long as the infection risk is deemed sufficiently small. This effect, similar to the “Prisoner's Dilemma” has also been explored in game theoretical analyses of infectious disease dynamics and vaccination [3][6],[8],[9]. In game theoretical treatments, it has been shown that vaccine coverage beyond the eradication threshold is not a Nash equilibrium if vaccine risk is nonzero, because a small group of individuals can achieve a higher payoff by switching to a nonvaccinator strategy [4]. Such strategic, self-interested behavior has been suggested as a possible contributor to vaccine scares in countries with a voluntary vaccination policy, such as England & Wales, which experienced declines in vaccine uptake for pertussis in the 1970s [4],[5],[11], and in measles–mumps–rubella (MMR) vaccine uptake more recently [12]. Recent work has explored exceptions to this rule, for instance finding cases of multiple equilibria when virulence varies with age [13] and when vaccines are sufficiently imperfect [14].

To date, smallpox is the only vaccine-preventable disease ever to have been globally eradicated [15], although polio is closer to eradication than ever before [16]. The last foothold of smallpox was in low-income countries, particularly in Africa and South Asia [17]. Jurisdictions in these countries often had widely varying vaccination policies. For instance, vaccination was compulsory in some Indian states, but voluntary in others [10]. Even in the final stages of eradication, when outbreaks were becoming less frequent, individuals often continued to voluntarily opt for vaccination, without the benefit of individual financial incentives to vaccinate. If the foregoing theories are correct that diseases cannot generally be eradicated under voluntary vaccination, how was smallpox globally eradicated despite voluntary vaccination in some jurisdictions?

Most, if not all, previous mathematical models that analyze discrepancies between individually and socially optimal vaccination strategies under voluntary vaccination have considered populations without spatial or social contact structure (e.g. social networks), and where populations are large enough for the continuum approximation to apply. This also appears to be true of behavior-infection models more generally [18], including those that study vaccine supply-demand dynamics at the international level, and non game-theoretical treatments of the problem. In these previous analyses, populations are generally considered to be homogeneously mixing, meaning that individuals are as likely to be infected by a member of their own household as they are by someone from the general public. However, the inadequacy of homogenous mixing models for certain situations has been widely documented, as have the differences between the predictions of homogeneous-mixing models and models where transmission is constrained to take place on a contact network [19][23]. In the present context, the homogeneous mixing assumption is arguably a good approximation for highly transmissible diseases spread primarily through aerosol droplets, such as measles. However, the assumption seems less valid for diseases that are transmitted through close contact, such as sexually-transmitted infections. Despite a few spectacular and widely reported cases of aerosol transmission [24], smallpox is also spread primarily through close contact, and typically requires prolonged face-to-face contact [25].

Here, we show that disease dynamics under a voluntary vaccination policy are substantially and qualitatively altered by the introduction of individual-level social contact structure. We analyze a social contact network model, where each node represents an individual, and each link represents a close contact through which infection may spread. Individuals decide whether or not to vaccinate based upon their expected payoffs for vaccinating versus not vaccinating. We assume the vaccine is free to individuals, which describes the situation for many major pediatric vaccines in advanced countries, as well as the situation under the WHO smallpox eradication program in the 1970s. We first study epidemics on this contact network for a general vaccine-preventable infection with simplified SEIR-type (Susceptible-Exposed-Infectious-Recovered) disease history. At baseline parameter values, for small neighborhood sizes, outbreaks are quickly contained using only voluntary ring vaccination. As the neighborhood size increases while infection risk (force of infection) is held constant, a threshold neighborhood size is reached. Above this threshold, voluntary vaccination fails and the population experiences both a considerable final epidemic size and a large number vaccinated. Hence, the limit of large neighborhood size in this model recovers dynamics similar to those of homogeneous mixing models. Because the force of infection is held constant as neighborhood size increases, the failure of voluntary vaccination is attributable solely to a decrease in how localized disease transmission is on the network. We associate smaller neighborhood sizes with close contact infections such as smallpox, and larger neighborhood sizes with diseases that do not require close contact for transmission, such as measles. We carry out a similar investigation for smallpox-specific disease history and vaccine properties, with similar results. This analysis illustrates the importance of considering discrete, contact-structured populations for modeling vaccinating behavior for close contact infections, and provides a framework for reconciling previous theoretical predictions concerning the ineradicability of infectious diseases under voluntary vaccination to the empirical fact of the global eradication of smallpox and local elimination of many other infectious diseases through voluntary vaccination.

Methods

Here we describe the social contact network, infection transmission, and assumptions regarding individual vaccinating behavior. Definitions of parameters and corresponding parameter values appear in Table 1. We consider the case of a single epidemic outbreak. Because demographic processes are relatively slow on this timescale, we use a static network that does not include birth or death (other than due to the disease). An outbreak scenario was chosen, rather than an endemic situation, because the epidemiology of an infectious disease close to being eradicated is more aptly described in terms of stochastic outbreaks rather than sustained endemic transmission. The neighborhood size (node degree) of the network is Poisson-distributed with mean Inline graphic. The network is formed by adding links to randomly selected nodes until the desired value of Inline graphic has been reached. After this, no further links are added, and the infection is introduced by inoculating Inline graphic randomly chosen nodes out of a population of size Inline graphic composed of susceptible individuals. We chose Inline graphic to ensure that outbreaks did not fail simply due to stochastic effects. Additionally, we ensured Inline graphic so that successful outbreaks could go through at least two generations before depleting the pool of susceptible individuals. Hence, we expect results to be similar on larger networks. There is a probability Inline graphic per day at which an infectious node infects a neighboring susceptible node. Hence, if a susceptible node has Inline graphic infectious neighbors on a given day, the total probability Inline graphic that the node becomes infected on that day is

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e010.jpg (1)

The timestep of the simulation is one day, and each node's status is updated at the end of each day.

Table 1. Baseline parameter values for SEIR-type infection.

Parameter Meaning Value Reference
Inline graphic Population size 5,000
Inline graphic Initial number of individuals inoculated with smallpox 10
Inline graphic Mean neighborhood size 10
Inline graphic Probability of node-to-node transmission 0.02 day−1 [50]
Inline graphic Perceived probability of node-to-node transmission 0.02 day−1 [50]
Inline graphic Mean duration of latent period 12 days [51]
Inline graphic Variance of latent period 4 days2 [51]
Inline graphic Mean duration of infectious period 19 days [51]
Inline graphic Variance of infectious period 4 days2 [51]
Inline graphic Probability of death due to infection 0.3 [52],[53]
Inline graphic Probability of death due to vaccine-related complications 0.001 [36]
Inline graphic Vaccine efficacy 0.95 [50]
Inline graphic Payoff for individuals with continued susceptibility 40 life-years [30]
Inline graphic Payoff for individuals with lifelong immunity 40 life-years [30]

On any given day, each individual who has not already vaccinated decides whether or not to vaccinate depending upon their perceived risk of infection from neighbors versus the perceived risks of vaccination. We assume that infectiousness coincides with the onset of symptoms, and that individuals base vaccination decisions upon the presence of symptoms in a neighbor. If an individual has Inline graphic infected neighbors, we assume that the perceived probability Inline graphic per day of being infected today is given by

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e027.jpg (2)

where Inline graphic is the perceived probability per day that the individual is infected by a single given infectious neighbor. If the payoff Inline graphic for vaccinating exceeds the payoff Inline graphic for not vaccinating, then the individual seeks and acquires vaccination on that day. If the individual does not vaccinate today, the individual can still vaccinate on following days.

SEIR Infection

For the vaccine-preventable SEIR infectious disease, we assume that a newly-infected person remains in the latent stage for a duration of time drawn from a gamma probability density function (PDF) with a mean of Inline graphic days and a variance of Inline graphic days2. After this time, the individual becomes infectious and remains so for a duration of time drawn from a gamma PDF with a mean of Inline graphic and a variance of Inline graphic days2. Subsequently, the individual either dies with perceived probability Inline graphic due to fatal disease complications, or recovers to lifelong immunity with perceived probability Inline graphic. A gamma PDF was used for its convenience and realism [26]. The vaccine has efficacy Inline graphic and is assumed to confer lifelong immunity. The currency of the payoff functions is the number of life-years that the individual can expect to accrue as a result of their strategy choice. We do not consider non-fatal outcomes such as long-term health conditions and we assume that the start of infectiousness coincides with the appearance of symptoms. We also assume a relatively high baseline perceived probability of death due to vaccine, Inline graphic, to reflect the fact that individuals often have inflated perceptions of vaccine risks [27],[28].

We first consider the payoff Inline graphic for not vaccinating today. If the individual does not vaccinate, s/he is either infected today (with perceived probability of infection Inline graphic) or not (with probability Inline graphic). If the individual is infected today, then s/he experiences fatal disease complications with probability Inline graphic, accruing no additional life years. If the individual survives (probability Inline graphic), s/he can expect to accrue Inline graphic additional life years, where Inline graphic is the average remaining life expectancy for an individual who has lifelong immunity to the disease. Hence, the payoff if the nonvaccinating individual is infected is Inline graphic. On the other hand, if the nonvaccinating individual escapes infection today, then s/he receives a payoff of α. This payoff represents the individual's expected remaining life years, given that they remain susceptible today because they were neither vaccinated nor infected. The total payoff Inline graphic to an individual who does not vaccinate today is therefore

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e048.jpg (3)

The parameter Inline graphic is influenced by the likelihood of being infected or of being compelled to vaccinate later on during the current epidemic oubreak in the population, and the likelihood that these result in death. It is impractical to derive a closed form expression for the probabilities of all these events in order to generate an expression for Inline graphic. Also, in reality, individuals may resort to “rules of thumb” when weighing future outcomes. However, it is reasonable in any case to expect Inline graphic, since a person with immunity can expect to outlive a person without immunity, on average.

Over time horizons longer than the current epidemic, other factors may contribute to what assumptions must be made about Inline graphic. For instance, if vaccine-derived immunity wanes and the population is subject to another outbreak 20 years hence, then vaccination today may appear less favourable, even if Inline graphic is still valid. However, these distant future events would be heavily discounted [29] and so we will restrict our time horizon to the current outbreak only.

Due to uncertainties in exactly how much Inline graphic is less than Inline graphic, for our baseline analysis we assume Inline graphic (though we explore Inline graphic in sensitivity analysis). This makes nonvaccinating behavior more attractive and hence is a conservative assumption with respect to demonstrating the success of voluntary vaccination in containing outbreaks in a contact-structured population: if voluntary vaccination can control an oubreak for Inline graphic, it should also be absent when Inline graphic. In the baseline scenario, we assume Inline graphic years, representing the average remaining life expectancy in good health in a typical developed country [30]. We note that the baseline value of Inline graphic does not change the model dynamics qualitatively or quantitatively, since Inline graphic scales with Inline graphic (subject to above assumptions about future outbreaks).

We next compute the payoff Inline graphic to vaccinate today. If a person chooses to vaccinate, then either the vaccine is efficacious (probability Inline graphic), or not (probability Inline graphic). We suppose that the vaccine carries a perceived probability Inline graphic of death due to complications from the vaccine, where Inline graphic is generally small. (Under the assumption of perfect information, we note that Inline graphic could also be interpreted as the empirical probability of death.) If the vaccine is efficacious but results in fatal complications, then no additional life years are accrued. However, if the vaccine is efficacious and no complications ensue, then the individual receives a payoff

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e070.jpg (4)

By comparison, if the vaccine is not efficacious, then either the individual dies from vaccine complications, accruing zero additional life years (probability Inline graphic), or the individual does not die (probability Inline graphic). If the individual does not die from the vaccine, then either the individual is infected today, or the individual is not infected today. If the individual is not infected today (probability Inline graphic), then the individual has escaped both death due to the vaccine and infection and remain susceptible, so their payoff will be Inline graphic. However, if the person is infected (probability Inline graphic), then they suffer a perceived probability Inline graphic of dying due to the disease, but if they survive (probability Inline graphic), their payoff is lifelong immunity, or Inline graphic accrued life-years. Hence, in the case that the vaccine is not efficacious, the total payoff is

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e079.jpg (5)

and from Equations 4 and 5, we have

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e080.jpg (6)

On any given day, if

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e081.jpg (7)

then the individual decides to vaccinate. Otherwise they may still vaccinate in future according to the same decision rules, and with no influence from their previous decision history.

Smallpox Infection

To tailor the model to the case of smallpox, we incorporate a more realistic description of the natural history of smallpox and the effects of vaccination. We incorporate the fact that conventional smallpox vaccine can work in individuals who are already infected: those who receive the vaccine within 3 days of infection usually do not become infectious and subsequently recover with long-term immunity, those who receive the vaccine 4–7 days post-exposure experience less severe symptoms but will be as infectious as an unvaccinated person, and those who receive the vaccine more than 7 days post-exposure gain no benefit [31]. Assumptions about network structure were the same as for the SEIR-type infection. For the case of smallpox, we used an empirical value of Inline graphic [32], though we discuss the effect of using larger values of Inline graphic.

To compute payoffs for the case of smallpox, we accounted for both fatal and non-fatal outcomes, such as pockmarks or blindness due to vaccine or disease. In order to compare fatal and non-fatal health outcomes in the same payoff function, the payoffs were expressed in terms of quality-adjusted life years (QALYs), i.e., the number of life years accrued, multiplied by a utility score between 0 (death) and 1 (perfect health) to reflect quality of life during those years [33]. Utilities for each possible health state after vaccination or smallpox infection were obtained from the literature. The payoff functions for the generic vaccine-preventable infection (Equations 3 and 6) were thus adjusted to obtain the payoff functions for the case of smallpox:

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e084.jpg (8)
graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e085.jpg (9)

where Inline graphic is the payoff to a person who becomes infected today by smallpox, Inline graphic is the payoff to a person who vaccinates today and in whom the vaccine has been efficacious (but who may experience complications or death due to vaccine), and Inline graphic is the payoff to a person who vaccinates today and in whom the vaccine is not efficacious, but who avoids becoming infected today (and who may experience complications or death due to vaccine). Details of the derivation, as well as the full expressions for Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic in terms of model parameters and utilities appear in Text S1. We note that Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic at realistic parameter values. Again we assume Inline graphic for our baseline scenario. Parameter values appear in Text S1. An equation analogous to Equation 10 can also be derived, with a similar interpretation.

Results

It is possible to show from Equations 3 and 6 that an individual with at least one infectious neighbor will vaccinate (i.e., Inline graphic for the individual) if and only if

graphic file with name pcbi.1000280.e097.jpg (10)

The derivation of this expression appears in Text S1. We note that Inline graphic for many common vaccines. Also, Inline graphic in most cases except when individuals have unrealistically inflated assessment of vaccine risks, such as during a “vaccine scare.” Therefore, whether or not an individual with at least one infectious neighbor vaccinates hinges largely upon the value of Inline graphic. If Inline graphic is sufficiently high then self-interested (rational) vaccinating behavior will result in eradication in a contact-structured population. (We note that rational behavior is precisely what causes failure to eradicate in a homogeneously-mixing population under a voluntary vaccination policy [4].) On the other hand, if Inline graphic is sufficiently small, then an individual with at least one infectious neighbor may not judge the risk of infection great enough to vaccinate, and the infection may thereby spread through the entire population. We note that Equation 10 holds regardless of the assumed network structure.

Low values of Inline graphic may occur for an infectious diseases where the number of social contacts through which infection can potentially be transmitted is large, but the probability of becoming infected from any single given contact is small. For instance, the number of potential effective contacts for measles transmission is large: the virus can be transmitted through aerosolized droplets that remain airborne for long periods, therefore the list of individuals to whom measles infection can potentially be passed is very large. However, even in a fully susceptible population, only 10–20 of these individuals are actually infected [34]. By comparison, we note that Inline graphic may be high for a sexually transmitted or close contact infection, where the list of contacts to which infection can be transmitted may be small, but the probability of transmission to each contact is high.

In the present model, as the average neighborhood size increases and the node-to-node transmission rate declines correspondingly, we should therefore expect to find conditions where Equation 10 is violated and voluntary vaccination fails to contain the outbreak, as predicted by models that assume homogeneous mixing. To test for this, we simulated the spread of the SEIR-type and smallpox infections on the network under a wide range of possible values for the average neighborhood size Inline graphic. For each value of Inline graphic tested, the value of the node-to-node transmission rate Inline graphic was adjusted so that the average force of infection per susceptible node remained the same as for the baseline parameter values. Holding the average force of infection constant as neighborhood size increases is crucial, since any change in model dynamics is thereby attributable to a decline in how localized the contact network is, rather than an increase in the overall force of infection (see [35] for an analogous approach for the effects of concurrency). Method I for maintaining constant infection risk assigned Inline graphic day−1 for each value of Inline graphic tested (where Inline graphic day−1 = 0.2 day−1 for the baseline parameters). Hence, a doubling of the number of social contacts would reduce the node-to-node transmission rate by half, which should maintain approximately the same infection risk per susceptible node as in the baseline scenario. However, higher-order effects relating to network structure are not accounted for in this approach and could change the infection risk in subtle ways. Therefore, we also controlled for infection risk using Method II, which involved calibrating the value of Inline graphic to ensure the measured infection risk was the same across all neighborhood sizes. For each value of Inline graphic, simulations were run for a range of finely stratified Inline graphic values. The value of Inline graphic which yielded a final epidemic size within 0.2% of the average baseline final size of 10 realizations was selected. Hence, for each value of Inline graphic, we know a corresponding value of Inline graphic for which a given susceptible person has the same chance of becoming infected as for the baseline scenario. The simulations were run in a population without vaccination, since the goal was to obtain a range of infections with the same average risk to individuals but varying neighbourhood sizes, and including vaccination would thus bias this calibration. All other parameters were as in Table 1, except we maintained Inline graphic throughout.

For the SEIR-type infection, the simulation results under Method I indicate that voluntary vaccination contains the outbreak until the average neighborhood size Inline graphic (Figure 1A). Below this threshold, both the final size and total number vaccinated remain small, since the outbreak is easily controlled through voluntary ring vaccination. Above this threshold, each infected node infects more than one neighboring node on average (usually a nonvaccinator with insufficient infectious neighbors to compel him/her to vaccinate). As a result, the infection breaks through imperfect rings of vaccinated individuals, and percolates through the entire network until almost all individuals have been either vaccinated or infected. This outcome is qualitatively similar to the divergence between individually and socially optimal strategies observed in homogeneous mixing models–these exhibit regimes where a large number of individuals can choose to vaccinate, but never enough to eradicate the disease completely [4]. The simulation results under Method II are very similar, with failure of voluntary vaccination materializing once Inline graphic (Figure 1B). Hence, social contact structure can enable outbreak containment even when the neighborhood size is relatively large. We note that for Inline graphic, the threshold values of Inline graphic would be higher.

Figure 1. Final size and number vaccinated versus average neighborhood size for an SEIR-type infection, under Method I (A) and Method II (B), and for smallpox, Method I (C) and Method II (D).

Figure 1

Inline graphic. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per datum.

For smallpox infection, voluntary vaccination contains the outbreak for all Inline graphic (Figure 1C and 1D). This difference compared to the SEIR-type infection is attributable mainly to the difference in the perceived probability of death due to the vaccine, Inline graphic. In the case of the SEIR-type infection, the perceived probability was taken to be a relatively high Inline graphic, since individuals tend to inflate vaccine risks [36]. However, for smallpox, we used the empirical value Inline graphic. Therefore from Equation 10 we observe that value of Inline graphic must be very low (i.e., Inline graphic must be very large) before voluntary vaccination fails to contain the outbreak. This would require a simulated population size on the order of Inline graphic million, but our simulation became prohibitively slow beyond Inline graphic. We note that homogeneous mixing models assume the continuum approximation holds, such that Inline graphic is a real number, and therefore voluntary vaccination should fail to contain an outbreak even for arbitrarily small vaccine risks and arbitrarily high case fatality rates. Simulations for smallpox with an inflated Inline graphic are similar to those for the SEIR-type infection, with voluntary vaccination not failing until the neighborhood size is significant.

We also carried out a univariate sensitivity analysis with respect to the payoff Inline graphic to individuals who remain susceptible, the node-to-node transmission rate Inline graphic, and the vaccine efficacy Inline graphic. As each of these parameters was separately varied, the other parameters were kept at the baseline values. For the SEIR-type infection, in the case of varying Inline graphic, we observe that voluntary vaccination contains the outbreak for all Inline graphic (Figure 2A). For Inline graphic, vaccination appears attractive even in the absence of an infected neighbor, and all individuals vaccinate. For Inline graphic, vaccination is attractive when there is one or more infectious neighbors, and the outbreak is controlled through voluntary ring vaccination. When Inline graphic, vaccination only becomes attractive once the number of infectious neighbors is already quite large (i.e., too large to prevent further transmission), and hence the final size is very large. As Inline graphic grows, the final size continues to grow and the number who seek vaccination continuously decline, since vaccination becomes progressively less attractive for larger Inline graphic. However, as discussed in the Methods section, biologically realistic solutions are restricted to Inline graphic. The final size and number vaccinated is not strongly dependent on the transmission rate Inline graphic (Figure 2B). This is not surprising, since for small Inline graphic individuals rapidly vaccinate once it becomes known they have an infectious social contact, preventing further transmission. In the case of varying vaccine efficacy Inline graphic we observe that the final size increases monotonically as Inline graphic drop below 0.7 (Figure 2C). The number vaccinated is highest for Inline graphic. Below Inline graphic, the number vaccinated is small because the vaccine is not efficacious enough to justify the individual decision to vaccinate. Above Inline graphic, the number vaccinated is small because voluntary ring vaccination contains the outbreak relatively quickly. Results are similar for smallpox (Figure S1). We also tested the robustness of model predictions to several extensions, such as including delays in time required for the vaccine to confer immunity, probabilistic descriptions of the individual decision-making process, and the possibility that individuals may choose to vaccinate once their neighbor's neighbors become infected, but found no major qualitative differences in model dynamics at biologically realistic parameter values (results not shown).

Figure 2. Final size and number vaccinated versus vaccine efficacy Inline graphic (A), future payoff under continued susceptibility Inline graphic (B), and node-to-node transmission probability Inline graphic (C), for the SEIR-type infection.

Figure 2

Inline graphic. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per datum. Note difference in vertical scale for (C).

Figures S2 and S3 depict several representative time series for the SEIR-type and smallpox infections respectively, at the baseline parameters values. As expected, secondary and tertiary transmission is limited in the baseline scenario, and occur only because of vaccine failures in some individuals. After each instance of secondary transmission, neighbors of the new case vaccinate and the outbreak is quickly controlled.

Discussion

It is now a well-established principle in theoretical population biology that the dynamics of spatially structured populations can differ significantly from the dynamics of unstructured populations [37][39]. In spatially structured populations, coexistence, diversity and altruism develop more easily [40],[41], evolutionary velocities are slower [42], and epidemics have more realistic time series and critical community sizes [43]. Similar differences have been observed in the case of network models versus homogeneous mixing models [19][23]. The present model likewise illustrates dramatic changes in behavior-infection dynamics once social contact structure is introduced. When populations mix homogeneously, “rational” self-interested behavior leads to a divergence between individually and socially optimal strategies: vaccination coverage can be high, but never high enough to eradicate a vaccine-preventable infection. By comparison, the same kind of self-interested behavior in networks where contact structure is sufficiently local can rapidly and efficiently curtail outbreaks in discrete, contact-structured populations, through voluntary ring vaccination. This work also illustrates the importance of discrete effects in structured populations [37]. Events at the local, individual level (as played out in local neighborhoods on the network) can have significant implications for population-level outcomes such as final size and total number vaccinated. Finally, the present analysis recovers the homogeneous mixing case in the limit of large neighborhood size, thus capturing two qualitatively distinct regimes of behavior-infection dynamics. It thereby provides a framework for reconciling the predictions of behavior-infection models that assume homogeneously mixing populations to the empirical fact that many infectious diseases have been either globally eradicated or locally eliminated despite voluntary vaccination policies.

We expect that our results for SEIR infections should generally apply to vaccine-preventable infectious diseases where the SEIR disease history is a good approximation to the actual disease history, and where appearance of symptoms approximately coincides with the start of infectiousness. Examples of such diseases include smallpox (for the small neighbourhood limit), and measles, rubella, chickenpox, perhaps pertussis (for the large neighbourhood limit).

The basic reproductive number, Inline graphic (the average number of secondary infections produced by a single infectious person in an otherwise susceptible population), is a fundamental measure that indicates how easily an infectious disease outbreak can be controlled. However, recent theory points to other aspects of infectious diseases that may be equally important. For instance, one such aspect is the proportion of transmission occurring before the onset of clinical symptoms [44]. Likewise, the current analysis suggests that whether a disease requires close contact for transmission may be an important factor determining the feasibility of outbreak control under voluntary vaccination policies.

Some previous game theoretical models have suggested that eradication is less likely to occur under voluntary vaccination when Inline graphic is higher, such as for measles and pertussis [4],[5]. The results from the present analysis dovetail with these earlier predictions, since diseases with higher Inline graphic are also more likely to be spread through means other than close personal contact. For these more transmissible infections, the average neighborhood size is higher since the number of social contacts that could potentially result in transmission events is greater. Hence, the results of the present study also suggest that diseases with higher Inline graphic are more likely to be associated with failure to eradicate under voluntary vaccination. The present results also extend previous predictions by showing how the severity of the disease, as expressed through Inline graphic, can influence whether voluntary vaccination will work.

It has previously been observed that spatial structure can also encourage the persistence of cooperative behavior in classical games such as the Prisoner's Dilemma [45]. This is phenomenologically similar to what occurs in the present study: in a contact-structured population, what is optimal for the group becomes coincident with what is optimal for the individual, when neighborhood size is small enough. In the case of the Prisoner's Dilemma, small clusters of cooperating individuals can maintain “equal footing” with clusters of defectors, because of the high cooperate-cooperate payoffs that occur within cooperator clusters. In the present analysis the mechanism is quite different, having to do with the large difference in infection risk between those who neighbor infectious individuals and those who do not. This individual-level structure cannot be described in a homogeneously mixing population subject to the continuum approximation [37].

There were several limitations to the present analysis. First, we assumed that Inline graphic. For a more realistic assumption of Inline graphic, we would expect a higher threshold in neighborhood size for failure of voluntary vaccination. In the same vein, the payoff functions are static and do not reflect expected future disease dynamics. Static functions were used because we assumed that individuals do not weigh future outcomes heavily in the face of a current outbreak, especially if there are significant uncertainties about future disease dynamics. However, if individuals did make strategic choices according to expected future disease dynamics, the predictions may change. A second limitation is that we used a static, random network. Outcomes may differ for other types of networks. For instance, in a network with small characteristic path length [46], infection and vaccination should percolate through the network more quickly than was the case here, although we do not expect the final state of the network to change. Similarly, networks with scale-free neighborhood size distributions [47] may exhibit highly variable outcomes due to the large heterogeneity in neighborhood size: an infectious node with many neighbors could lead to a higher epidemic final size in the whole population, whereas a vaccinated node with few neighbors could significantly reduce final size. Finally, if network edges can form and be dissolved, then failure of voluntary vaccination should emerge for a sufficiently high rate of turnover of network edges, regardless of neighborhood size. Future work on behavior-infection dynamics in contact-structured populations should take into account more realistic networks such as those derived from household sizes, sexual behavior surveys, or contact-dairy studies. A third limitation is our assumption that becoming infective coincides with the appearance of recognizable symptoms. For diseases where individuals can transmit before exhibiting symptoms, voluntary ring vaccination would be less successful and we would expect the thresholds of Figure 1 to shift to the left. This is because individuals may still become infected if they wait to vaccinate until their neighbors exhibit symptoms. For smallpox in particular, some transmission may occur during the prodrome phase of infection, where individuals exhibit non-specific symptoms. However, because the contribution from this phase is relatively small [48] and smallpox has a low Inline graphic, we do not expect this to qualitatively change our results. A fourth limitation is that we assumed that the vaccine works immediately upon innoculation. This is plausible for smallpox, since vaccination can prevent both disease and viral shedding in individuals if they are vaccinated within three days after becoming infected [31]. However, if a vaccine requires a sufficiently long time to take effect, waiting to vaccinate until a neighbor exhibits symptoms again may not prevent infection (though it may encourage individuals to vaccinate pre-emptively once disease has entered their local population). Models that accommodate these alternative possibilities could yield different predictions, and it is possible to imagine scenarios of disease propagation through individual-based networks that are analogous to the “race to trace” that has been described for universal smallpox vaccination [49]. Finally, we made the standard game theoretic assumption of “rational” behavior, although humans do not always act in this way. In this context, one implication is that individuals may react differently to outbreaks of a disease that has caused significant mortality very recently, compared to one that has not caused significant mortality in a long time.

Subject to the above limitations, there are a priori reasons to think that the basic dynamics illustrated here may describe a wide range of vaccine-preventable diseases that are spread through close contact. At the initial stages of an outbreak, the average prevalence of the disease across the whole population is very low. In a homogeneously-mixing population where infected persons are equally likely to make contacts with anyone in the population, the infection risk to any given individual is therefore also initially small, and individuals do not immediately seek vaccination. The disease thus transmits freely until the average prevalence is high enough to justify vaccinating for the remaining susceptible individuals. On the other hand, in a socially or spatially structured population, the short-term infection risk is heterogeneous across the population: nonexistent for most individuals, but very high for the immediate neighbors of an infected person. Hence, the neighbors of an infected person vaccinate as soon as their neighbor's symptoms appear. Since these effects are likely to apply to a broad range of infections spread through close contact, behavior-infection models of such infections may need to weigh the potential effects of individual-level contact structure.

Supporting Information

Text S1

Additional details on mathematical derivations and smallpox parameter values.

(0.10 MB PDF)

Figure S1

Dependence of final epidemic size and final number vaccinated on vaccine efficacy epsilon (A), payoff alpha for continued susceptibility (B), and node-to-node transmission probability beta per day (C) for smallpox infection. N = 5000. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per data point.

(0.06 MB PDF)

Figure S2

Representative realizations from the simulation: time series of number infected and number vaccinated for the SEIR-type infection. N = 5000. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per data point.

(0.15 MB JPG)

Figure S3

Representative realizations from the simulation: time series of number infected and number vaccinated for smallpox infection. N = 5000. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per data point.

(0.15 MB JPG)

Acknowledgments

CTB and AP are grateful for comments from three anonymous reviewers.

Footnotes

The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.

This work was funded by the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada, who had no role whatsoever in the conception, design, analysis, or reporting of the work.

References

  • 1.Fine P, Clarkson J. Individual versus public priorities in the determination of optimal vaccination policies. Am J Epidemiol. 1986;124:1012–1020. doi: 10.1093/oxfordjournals.aje.a114471. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Geoffard P, Philipson T. Disease eradication: private versus public vaccination. American Economic Review. 1997;87:222–230. [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Bauch CT, Galvani AP, Earn DJD. Group interest versus self interest in smallpox vaccination policy. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2003;100:10564–10567. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1731324100. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Bauch C, Earn D. Vaccination and the theory of games. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2004;101:13391–13394. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0403823101. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Bauch C. Imitation dynamics predict vaccinating behaviour. Proc R Soc Lond B. 2005;272:1669–1675. doi: 10.1098/rspb.2005.3153. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Galvani A, Reluga T, Chapman G. Long-standing influenza vaccination policy is in accord with individual self-interest but not with the utilitarian optimum. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2007;104:5692–5697. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0606774104. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.d'Onofrio A, Manfredi P, Salinelli E. Vaccinating behaviour, information, and the dynamics of sir vaccine preventable diseases. Theor Pop Biol. 2007;71(3):301–317. doi: 10.1016/j.tpb.2007.01.001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Vardavas R, Breban R, Blower S. Can Influenza epidemics be prevented by voluntary vaccination? PLoS Computational Biology. 2007;3:e85. doi: 10.1371/journal.pcbi.0030085. doi:10.1371/journal.pcbi.0030085. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Breban R, Vardavas R, Blower S. Mean-field analysis of an inductive reasoning game: application to influenza vaccination. Physical Review Letters E. 2007;76:031127. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.76.031127. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Barrett S. The smallpox eradication game. Public Choice. 2007;130:179–207. [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Gangarosa EJ, Galazka AM, Wolfe CR, Phillips LM, Gangarosa RE, et al. Impact of anti-vaccine movements on pertussis control: the untold story. The Lancet. 1998;351:356–361. doi: 10.1016/s0140-6736(97)04334-1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Roberts RJ, Sandifer QD, Evans MR, Nolan-Farrell MZ, Davis PM. Reasons for non-uptake of measles, mumps and rubella catch up immunisation in a measles epidemic and side effects of the vaccine. British Medical Journal. 1995;310:1629–1639. doi: 10.1136/bmj.310.6995.1629. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Reluga T, Medlock J, Poolman E, Galvani A. Optimal timing of disease transmission in an age-structured population. Bull Math Biol. 2006;69:2711–2722. doi: 10.1007/s11538-007-9238-5. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Chen F. A susceptible-infected epidemic model with voluntary vaccination. J Math Biol. 2006;53:253–272. doi: 10.1007/s00285-006-0006-1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Fenner F, Henderson DA, Arita I, Jezek Z, Ladnyi ID. Smallpox and Its Eradication. Geneva: World Health Organization; 1988. [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Global Polio Eradication Initiative. 2008. Available: http://www.polioeradication.org. Accessed 5 January 2009.
  • 17.Brilliant L. The management of smallpox eradication in India. University of Michigan Press; 1985. [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Klein E, Laxminarayan R, Smith D, Gilligan C. Economic incentives and mathematical models of diseases. Environment and Development Economics. 2007;12:707–732. [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Keeling M, Grenfell B. Individual-based perspectives on r 0. J Theor Biol. 2000;203:51–61. doi: 10.1006/jtbi.1999.1064. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Keeling M. The implications of network structure for epidemic dynamics. Theor Pop Biol. 2005;67:1–8. doi: 10.1016/j.tpb.2004.08.002. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Meyers L, Pourbohloul B, Newman M, Skowronski D, Brunham R. Network theory and sars: predicting outbreak diversity. J Theor Biol. 2005;232:71–81. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2004.07.026. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Bansal S, Grenfell BT, Meyers LA. When individual behavior matters: homogeneous and network models in epidemiology. J Roy Soc Interface. 2007;4:879–891. doi: 10.1098/rsif.2007.1100. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Aparicio J, Pascual M. Building epidemiological models from r 0: an implicit treatment of transmission in networks. Proc R Soc Lond B. 2007;274:505–512. doi: 10.1098/rspb.2006.0057. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Gelfand H, Posch J. The recent outbreak of smallpox in Meschede, West Germany. Am J Epidemiol. 1971;93:234–237. doi: 10.1093/oxfordjournals.aje.a121251. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Centers for Disease Control. Smallpox disease overview. 2008. Available: http://www.bt.cdc.gov/agent/smallpox/overview/disease-facts.asp. Accessed 5 January 2008.
  • 26.Wearing H, Rohani P, Keeling M. Appropriate models for the management of infectious diseases. PLoS Medicine. 2005;2(7):e174. doi: 10.1371/journal.pmed.0020174. doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.0020174. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Asch DA, Baron J, Hershey JC, Kunreuther H, Meszaros J, et al. Omission bias and pertussis vaccination. Medical Decision Making. 1994;14:118–123. doi: 10.1177/0272989X9401400204. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Smailbegovic MS, Laing GJ, Bedford H. Why do parents decide against immunization? The effect of health beliefs and health professionals. Child: Care, Health and Development. 2003;29:303–311. doi: 10.1046/j.1365-2214.2003.00347.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Meltzer M. Introduction to health economics for physicians. The Lancet. 1992;358:993–998. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(01)06107-4. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.St-Arnaud J, Beaudet M, Tully P. Life expectancy. Statistics Canada, catalogue no. 82-003-xie. Health Reports. 2005;17:43–47. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.McKesson Provider Technologies, University of Michigan Health System Smallpox vaccine. Available: http://www.med.umich.edu/1libr/aha/aha_smallpox_crs.htm. Accessed 5 January 2009.
  • 32.Edmundson K, Schweer J, Wilkinson E. Should the federal government make smallpox vaccine available to the public on a voluntary basis? 2003. Available: http://www.pubpol.duke.edu/courses/pps255s/2003/t-team-b/frontmatter.pdf. Accessed 5 January 2009.
  • 33.Gold M, Stevenson D, Fryback D. HALYs and QALYs and DALYs, oh my: similarities and differences in summary measures of population health. Annual Review of Public Health. 2002;23:115–134. doi: 10.1146/annurev.publhealth.23.100901.140513. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Anderson RM, May RM. Infectious Diseases of Humans. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1991. [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Morris M, Kretzschmar M. Concurrent partnerships and the spread of HIV. AIDS. 1999;11:641–648. doi: 10.1097/00002030-199705000-00012. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Bellaby P. Communcation and miscommunication of risk: understanding UK parents' attitudes to combined MMR vaccination. British Medical Journal. 2003;327:725–728. doi: 10.1136/bmj.327.7417.725. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Durrett R, Levin S. The importance of being discrete (and spatial). Theor Pop Biol. 1994;46:363. [Google Scholar]
  • 38.Levin S, Grenfell B, Hastings A, Perelson A. Mathematical and computational challenges in population biology and ecosystems science. Science. 1997;275:334. doi: 10.1126/science.275.5298.334. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Rand D. Correlation equations and pair approximations for spatial ecologies. Blackwell Science 1999 [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Matsuda H, Ogita N, Sasaki A, Sato K. Statistical mechanics of population. Prog Theor Phys. 1992;88:1035. [Google Scholar]
  • 41.van Baalen M, Rand D. The unit of selection in viscous populations and the evolution of altruism. J Theor Biol. 1998;193:631. doi: 10.1006/jtbi.1998.0730. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Rand D, Keeling M, Wilson H. Invasion, stability, and evolution to criticality in spatially extended host-pathogen systems. Proc Roy Soc Lond B. 1995;259:55. [Google Scholar]
  • 43.Keeling M, Grenfell B. Disease extinction and community size: Modeling the persistence of measles. Science. 1997;275:65. doi: 10.1126/science.275.5296.65. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 44.Fraser C, Riley S, Anderson R, Ferguson N. Factors that make an infectious disease outbreak controllable. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A. 2004;101:6146–6151. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0307506101. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 45.Nowak M, May R. Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature. 1992;359:826–829. [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Watts D, Strogatz S. Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature. 1998;393:440–442. doi: 10.1038/30918. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 47.May R, Lloyd A. Infection dynamics on scale-free networks. Physical Review E. 2001;64:066122. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.64.066112. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 48.Chin J. Control of communicable diseases manual, 17th edition. Washington, D.C.: American Public Health Association; 2000. [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Kaplan EH, Craft DL, Wein LM. Emergency response to a smallpox attack: The case for mass vaccination. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2002;99:10935–10940. doi: 10.1073/pnas.162282799. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.Halloran M, Longini I, Nizam A, Yang Y. Containing bioterrorist smallpox. Science. 2002;298:1428–1432. doi: 10.1126/science.1074674. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 51.Nishiura H, Eichner M. Infectiousness of smallpox relative to disease age: estimates based on the transmission network and incubation period. Epidemiol Infect. 2007;135:1145–1150. doi: 10.1017/S0950268806007618. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 52.Henderson DA, Inglesby TV, Bartlett JG. Smallpox as a biological weapon: medical and public health management. JAMA. 1999;281:2127–2137. doi: 10.1001/jama.281.22.2127. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 53.Breman J, Henderson D. Diagnosis and management of smallpox. New Engl J Med. 2002;346:1300–1308. doi: 10.1056/NEJMra020025. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Text S1

Additional details on mathematical derivations and smallpox parameter values.

(0.10 MB PDF)

Figure S1

Dependence of final epidemic size and final number vaccinated on vaccine efficacy epsilon (A), payoff alpha for continued susceptibility (B), and node-to-node transmission probability beta per day (C) for smallpox infection. N = 5000. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per data point.

(0.06 MB PDF)

Figure S2

Representative realizations from the simulation: time series of number infected and number vaccinated for the SEIR-type infection. N = 5000. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per data point.

(0.15 MB JPG)

Figure S3

Representative realizations from the simulation: time series of number infected and number vaccinated for smallpox infection. N = 5000. Error bars represent two standard deviations from the mean across 20 simulations per data point.

(0.15 MB JPG)


Articles from PLoS Computational Biology are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES