Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2009 Apr 15;4(4):e5192. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0005192

From Traditional Medicine to Witchcraft: Why Medical Treatments Are Not Always Efficacious

Mark M Tanaka 1,*, Jeremy R Kendal 2, Kevin N Laland 3
Editor: James Holland Jones4
PMCID: PMC2664922  PMID: 19367333

Abstract

Complementary medicines, traditional remedies and home cures for medical ailments are used extensively world-wide, representing more than US$60 billion sales in the global market. With serious doubts about the efficacy and safety of many treatments, the industry remains steeped in controversy. Little is known about factors affecting the prevalence of efficacious and non-efficacious self-medicative treatments. Here we develop mathematical models which reveal that the most efficacious treatments are not necessarily those most likely to spread. Indeed, purely superstitious remedies, or even maladaptive practices, spread more readily than efficacious treatments under specified circumstances. Low-efficacy practices sometimes spread because their very ineffectiveness results in longer, more salient demonstration and a larger number of converts, which more than compensates for greater rates of abandonment. These models also illuminate a broader range of phenomena, including the spread of innovations, medical treatment of animals, foraging behaviour, and self-medication in non-human primates.

Introduction

Traditional remedies, utilising medicinal plant and animal products, have been used as treatments for human diseases and medical conditions for millennia [1]. In recent years, 60–80% of the world's population, mainly from developing countries, depended primarily on traditional medicines, folk remedies and home cures, as well as treatment from witchdoctors and other ‘supernatural practices’, for their health-care needs [1]. In western societies, complementary and alternative medicine is garnering increasing interest and acceptance. At current growth rates, two-thirds of Americans are projected to be using alternative medicine by 2010 [2]. Asian governments are pouring billions of dollars into screening Traditional Chinese medicines in the hope that clinical trials will spawn lucrative drugs [3]. Traditional medicine has become big business.

While scientific studies have validated some traditional remedies, for instance, by confirming the biological activity of plant extracts [4], [5], the use of complementary and traditional medicines remains contentious, and doubts about the efficacy and safety of many treatments remain [1], [6], [7], [8]. Reservations over safety and efficacy underpin controversy over USA and UK universities' attempts to bring alternative medicines into medical school curricula [9]. The active ingredients used in many traditional medicines are potentially toxic, often containing dangerous elements, including heavy metals [5], [10]. Even the use of ineffective non-toxic remedies can be harmful if it delays effective treatment. For instance, fears have been expressed that, in Nigeria, witchcraft and traditional remedies of unknown efficacy are widely employed as treatments for malaria, instead of, or delaying access to, modern medicines of proven effectiveness [11]. In sub-Sarahan Africa there is a concern that the use of traditional remedies for mastitis, a condition often attributed to sorcery, may inadvertently be contributing to the spread of HIV [12].

In 2002 the WHO [1] launched a global plan to make the use of traditional medicine safer by encouraging evidence-based research on the safety, efficacy and quality of traditional practices. Accordingly, traditional medicines are currently undergoing scrutiny to evaluate their effectiveness and monitor adverse events [3], [13]. Such analyses have often failed to confirm the efficacy of traditional remedies: for instance, of nearly 25,000 applications for registration of traditional medicines received by Malaysian authorities, 37.3% were rejected, either on grounds of safety or ineffectiveness [14]. However, there is currently no compelling explanation for the prevalence of low-efficacy treatments.

Here we develop mathematical models of the spread of self-medicative treatments for medical conditions to explore the factors that lead to treatments becoming widespread, and how a treatment's efficacy affects its rate of spread. A treatment is acquired through social learning, but its spread depends on a variety of factors, including its efficacy, and the rates of conversion, death, recovery from illness and abandonment of the treatment. The approach is to derive expressions for the cultural fitness (mean number of converts to the treatment resulting directly from observation of a given demonstrator), Inline graphic, and the probability of spread of new treatments. We show that the treatments that spread are not necessarily those that are most efficacious at curing the ailment, and explain how ‘superstitious treatments’ with little efficacy and even maladaptive practices can spread under broad conditions. The models draw from two bodies of theory, cultural evolution modeling [15], [16], [17], [18] and stochastic (branching) processes [19], to develop theory applicable to investigating the spread of treatments of disease. Our analyses can also be viewed as contributing to the developing field of Darwinian medicine [20]. Although branching process models were developed to address the extinction of surnames [15], they have been more widely employed within biological evolution [21], and have yet to make further impact on the study of cultural evolution, despite extensive theory borrowing by the latter from the former [15], [16], [17], [18].

Methods

Basic assumptions

The general structure of the model is illustrated in Figure 1 and the symbols used are summarised in Table 1. We assume that individuals are either in a diseased state or in a healthy state. We model the spread of a behavioural trait expressed in treatment of disease. The behavioural trait in question is any innovation, practice or treatment that could potentially affect the outcome of this disease. To model the spread of a behavioural trait, we make the following assumptions. A new behavioural trait arises in (or is invented by) an ill individual who may then demonstrate this practice; others who are ill may adopt the practice upon being exposed to it, and then become demonstrators themselves. In other words, demonstrators convert observers. There is empirical support for the assumption that self-medicative treatments spread through social learning [22]. Observers adopt the trait at a constant rate per demonstrator per unit time. This rate is Inline graphic when the demonstrator is ill and Inline graphic when the demonstrator is healthy. Allowing for different rates of cultural transmission from sick and well individuals is important, since treatments for many ailments, ranging from snake bites to the common cold, are primarily applied when sick, and discontinued, or practiced at a less frequent rate, when the sufferer has recovered. As our models are concerned with the initial spread of a treatment, we assume a constant supply of observers. As the dynamics of the spread of the trait are much faster than demographic changes, there are no explicit births in this model. Death, however, occurs at rate Inline graphic per individual per unit time; there is an additional death rate Inline graphic for individuals with the disease.

Figure 1. General structure of the model.

Figure 1

This figure illustrates the processes through which demonstrators of a treatment can change health state. The parameters are defined in Methods.

Table 1. Summary of symbols used in the model.

Symbol Meaning
Inline graphic Rate of conversion of observers to the treatment practice when demonstrator is ill.
Inline graphic Rate of conversion of observers to the treatment practice when demonstrator is well.
Inline graphic Efficacy of treatment; Inline graphic when treatment is ineffective.
Inline graphic Rate of natural recovery from disease.
Inline graphic Rate of abandoning the treatment. We set Inline graphic.
Inline graphic Maximum rate of treatment abandonment.
Inline graphic Decay in abandonment rate as efficacy increases.
Inline graphic Rate of relapse to disease. We set Inline graphic.
Inline graphic Maximum relapse rate.
Inline graphic Decay in relapse rate as efficacy increases.
Inline graphic Background death rate.
Inline graphic Death rate due to the disease.
Inline graphic Cultural fitness of the practice (function of the parameters).
Inline graphic Number of observers converted by a demonstrator.
Inline graphic Time spent by a demonstrator being ill.
Inline graphic Time spent by a demonstrator being well.

Our assumption that observers adopt the trait in an unbiased fashion, and at a constant rate per demonstrator per unit time, may need further explanation. We do not assume that observers adopt self-medicative practices according to their efficacy in treating others, since we regard this to be difficult for an individual reliably to gauge. For instance, observers would be required to make a series of judgments: Has the demonstrator the same condition as me? Is the demonstrator's judgment of its effectiveness reliable? Will the treatment work as well for me? Would the demonstrator have recovered anyway? Etc. Rather, we leave judgments about the efficacy of treatments to self (i.e. the demonstrator), by allowing individuals to abandon the treatment, or revert to an alternative, based on their own evaluation of the treatment's effectiveness in curing themselves. Note, it does not follow from our assumption of unbiased copying that observers would be equally likely to adopt otherwise equivalent efficacious and ineffective practices, since demonstrators would be more likely to abandon the latter, as discussed below.

We are interested in both efficacious traits – those that hasten the recovery of the diseased individual – as well as those that are ineffective or even maladaptive (in that they retard or prevent recovery). The background rate of recovery is Inline graphic per individual per unit time, with an additional rate Inline graphic describing the efficacy of the treatment or practice (Inline graphic). When Inline graphic the treatment/practice is ineffective and the trait can be regarded as a superstition. When Inline graphic the trait is completely maladaptive because it prevents recovery, while if Inline graphic the treatment is beneficial.

Further assume that an individual who adopts the trait may abandon it or revert to a previous practice. The rate of abandonment is a decreasing function of the rate of recovery from the disease. This response is based on the assumption that sick individuals will become increasingly dissatisfied with their treatment as the time to recovery increases, and will abandon treatments that are perceived to be ineffective. Let this function be

graphic file with name pone.0005192.e031.jpg (1)

where Inline graphic is the maximum rate of abandonment, occurring when the trait is completely maladaptive (Inline graphic), and Inline graphic determines how strongly recovery influences abandonment (see Figure 2). While Inline graphic is a function of four parameters, we will write it simply as Inline graphic for convenience. Although we set this function to be an exponential decay, exploration of alternative forms of the relationship between abandonment and efficacy (e.g. hyperbolic function) showed they do not influence the qualitative outcomes of the analysis.

Figure 2. The relationship between rate of abandonment and efficacy.

Figure 2

Here we show several curves by varying the parameter Inline graphic and setting Inline graphic and Inline graphic (see Methods for interpretation of parameter values).

By letting recovered individuals relapse into the diseased state at rate Inline graphic per unit time we allow for multiple episodes of illness. This dynamic is suitable for describing recurring conditions. When Inline graphic there is only a single bout of illness, a scenario we consider first in developing the models below. The rate Inline graphic itself can be set as a function of Inline graphic, where the treatment practiced in a well state has a prophylactic effect. For example, the rate of relapse to disease might decrease exponentially at rate Inline graphic with respect to efficacy Inline graphic. In other words, the probability that sick individuals will relapse to the diseased state decreases with increasing effectiveness of the treatment they utilise (Inline graphic).

Constructing the model

We consider a set of special cases of the general model. In the simplest case, recovery is permanent so that there is only a single episode of illness (Inline graphic), and demonstration of the treatment is restricted to the period of illness – that is, demonstration ceases upon recovery (Inline graphic). The second model generalises this situation by allowing demonstration to continue after recovery (Inline graphic), but there is still only a single episode of illness (Inline graphic). We also consider a model in which there can be multiple episodes of illness (Inline graphic) and where demonstration is restricted to sick individuals (Inline graphic). In the general case Inline graphic and Inline graphic.

In each model, we focus on a single demonstrator and track the total number of individuals he or she converts. This is achieved by accounting for the conversion rates Inline graphic and the length of each period spent by the demonstrator being ill and well (Inline graphic and Inline graphic respectively). The time spent being an ill demonstrator within a given episode of illness is distributed exponentially with parameter

graphic file with name pone.0005192.e058.jpg

When the demonstrator is well, the time until death, abandonment or becoming ill again is distributed exponentially with parameter

graphic file with name pone.0005192.e059.jpg

The cultural fitness of the treatment Inline graphic is given by the mean number of converts produced by the demonstrator. We report below the formulas for cultural fitness and provide derivations in Appendix S1. The appendix also considers the probability of spread of the treatment from the innovator, which can be derived analytically for the first model (Section A.1.1) and otherwise studied through computer simulation (Section A.2.3).

In the first model, where there is a single episode of illness and demonstration only occurs during illness, the cultural fitness is given by

graphic file with name pone.0005192.e061.jpg (2)

Under the second model, where there is a single episode of illness and demonstration is continued after recovery,

graphic file with name pone.0005192.e062.jpg (3)

Under the most general model, where there can be multiple episodes of illness and continuous demonstration of the treatment,

graphic file with name pone.0005192.e063.jpg (4)

where Inline graphic is the mean number of episodes before abandonment of treatment or death and Inline graphic. The case where there are multiple episodes but restricted demonstration is specified by setting Inline graphic in Equation 4, giving Inline graphic.

Parameter values

Unless otherwise specified, parameters in the numerical analysis take the following values. We assume Inline graphic and Inline graphic per individual per year, corresponding to a 62.5 year lifespan without disease and an illness-related death rate which is half that of natural causes. We set Inline graphic, corresponding to an average episode of illness lasting 2 months. The number of converts per year per sick individual Inline graphic was set to 12, and that per healthy individual to Inline graphic. Other parameter values are: Inline graphic, corresponding to an average time of around 0.3 months before abandonment when Inline graphic and gives a maximum cultural fitness Inline graphic when the treatment efficacy Inline graphic; Inline graphic, corresponding to an average time of 6 months before abandonment when Inline graphic and Inline graphic; and Inline graphic, corresponding to an average time of 6 months of being healthy before relapse to disease when Inline graphic.

Results

We study our general model through subclasses, considering cases in which individuals experience either a single or multiple episodes of illness, and demonstration of the practice is either restricted to sick individuals, or continues after recovery.

First consider cases with a single bout of illness and treatment demonstration restricted to sick individuals (Equation (2), Figure 3). Across a broad range of conditions, the most efficacious treatments are not necessarily those most likely to spread, and superstitious treatments with no efficacy (Inline graphic), or even maladaptive practices (Inline graphic), frequently have the highest cultural fitness (Inline graphic). Superstitious treatments and maladaptive practices can spread because their very ineffectiveness results in sick individuals demonstrating the practice for longer than efficacious treatments, leading to more salient demonstration and more converts. This outcome occurs in spite of the fact that we assume that the less effective the treatment, the more likely a sick individual will abandon it, resulting in n-shaped functions for cultural fitness (Figure 3a–c) and probability of spread of the treatment (Figure 3d–f) The observed relationships represent a trade-off between duration of illness which is associated with demonstration of the treatment on one hand and retention of the treatment due to its efficacy on the other hand. That is, persistent illness leads to prolongued demonstration of the practice, yet an increased rate of abandonment of an ineffective treatment. In contrast, increased retention of an effective treatment is also associated with reduced demonstration of the practice.

Figure 3. A single episode of illness and demonstration only during illness.

Figure 3

The cultural fitness (a–c) and probability of spread (d–f) of self-medicative treatments, plotted as a function of treatment efficacy, Inline graphic, when there is a single episode of illness and demonstration occurs only during illness. Left (a and d), effect of varying maximum rate of abandonment, Inline graphic. Middle (b and e), effect of varying rate of recovery, Inline graphic. Right (c and f), effect of varying rate of decay in treatment abandonment. Unless otherwise stated Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (see also Methods and Table 1).

The quality of treatments that successfully spread depends critically on the rates of recovery from illness and abandonment of the treatment, with high-recovery/low-abandonment favouring superstitious/maladaptive treatments, and low-recovery/high-abandonment favouring efficacious treatments (Figure 3). From an evolutionary perspective, suppose the treatment or practice evolves through competition between alternative forms, each with its specific efficacy. Assuming treatments of higher cultural fitness always displace those of lower cultural fitness, the evolutionarily stable strategy in this system may well be a maladaptive treatment that hinders recovery. This scenario occurs when the abandonment parameter Inline graphic is sufficiently low relative to the recovery rate Inline graphic. Intuitively, this case describes a situation where individuals are very persistent in using a treatment, resulting in the spread of poor practices in the long term. Factors that precipitate low abandonment, such as social norms favouring traditional remedies, or treatments that are costly to learn, potentially facilitate the spread of superstitions/maladaptive traits, particularly in chronic cases. This analysis can explain the ineffectiveness of many prominent complementary and traditional medicines.

Continued demonstration after recovery (Inline graphic positive) typically increases the probability that efficacious treatments will spread, by weakening the aforementioned trade-off between retention of treatment and duration of illness, because a fast recovery does not prevent subsequent recruitment of others to the practice (Figure 4). If the conversion rate after recovery is sufficiently high relative to that in sickness, efficacious treatments are more likely to spread than maladaptive/superstitious treatments. Numerical analysis leads to the general prediction that, other factors being equal, treatments solely demonstrated in sickness are typically less effective than treatments also demonstrated in wellness.

Figure 4. A single episode of illness and continued demonstration.

Figure 4

The cultural fitness of self-medicative treatments (Inline graphic) plotted as a function of treatment efficacy, Inline graphic, when there is a single episode of illness (Inline graphic) and demonstration continues after recovery (Inline graphic). Parameter values are Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (see Methods for interpretation of parameter values).

Multiple episodes of sickness typically favour efficacious treatments, and make it more likely in general that treatments will spread compared to single episodes (Equation (4), Figure 5a). Multiple episodes allow demonstrators of efficacious treatments repeated opportunities to convert others to the practice. High efficacy, by enhancing recovery, increases the number of cycles of demonstration, weakening the trade-off between retention of treatment and duration of illness. Even with demonstration restricted to sick individuals, the efficacy of the treatment with the highest cultural fitness (or probability of spread) is typically high in cases where there is a high rate of relapse into sickness (i.e. large Inline graphic).

Figure 5. Multiple episodes of illness and demonstration restricted to sick individuals.

Figure 5

The cultural fitness of self-medicative treatments Inline graphic, (left and middle), and probability of spread of treatments (right) plotted as a function of treatment efficacy, Inline graphic. Left (a): cultural fitness Inline graphic; we set Inline graphic so that Inline graphic. Middle (b): cultural fitness Inline graphic; when treatment is prophylactic (Inline graphic). Right (c): The ultimate probability of spread (rugged lines) and the probability of spread from an innovator (smooth lines) for various rates of relapse Inline graphic (indicated by colour). Unless stated otherwise, parameter values are Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (see Methods for interpretation of parameter values).

Prophylactic treatments (Inline graphic) disproportionately reduce the relapse rate of efficacious traits over maladaptive treatments, thereby decreasing their opportunity to acquire new converts (for Inline graphic). It follows that prophylactic self-medicative treatments should spread less readily than non-prophylactic treatments (Figure 5b). Figure 5c shows that the ultimate probability of spread across Inline graphic exhibits a similar pattern to that of the cultural fitness (Figure 5a,b) and that naturally, the probability of initially spreading from the inventor is always higher than the ultimate probability of spread.

Generally, highly efficacious treatments have higher cultural fitness than superstitious/maladaptive traits in multiple-episode cases, but nonetheless superstitious treatments (Inline graphic close to 0) can spread. Superstitious and maladaptive practices are most likely to spread where treatments are primarily demonstrated in sickness (i.e. a low ratio of Inline graphic) and low abandonment (Inline graphic), particularly where relapse is unlikely (Inline graphic small). Figure 6 illustrates this principle through a density plot of the Inline graphic with highest probability of spread as a function of Inline graphic and the relative rate of conversion during healthy and sick periods (Inline graphic).

Figure 6. The effect of abandonment and conversion rates on the probability of spread.

Figure 6

A density plot showing the treatment with the highest probability of spreading Inline graphic as a function of Inline graphic and the relative rate of conversion during healthy and sick periods (Inline graphic), colour boundary range {−5,17.5;±2.5} (low values, dark). Unless otherwise stated Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (see Methods for interpretation of parameter values).

Discussion

This study offers a simple, novel and counter-intuitive hypothesis for the prevalence of ineffective medical treatments: unbiased copying of new treatments can frequently lead to the prevalence of ineffective practices because such treatments are demonstrated more persistently than efficacious alternatives, even when there is enhanced abandonment of ineffective cures. By unbiased copying, we mean copying in direct proportion to the rate at which the alternative variants are demonstrated. Here, in simple terms, treatment frequency dynamics are typically dominated by two processes, representing the rates of acquisition and loss of remedies. Maladaptive and superstitious treatments can become prevalent because their ineffectiveness prolongs illness, enhancing their rate of demonstration relative to efficacious cures, and leading to elevated rates of acquisition that may compensate for greater loss.

Our finding that superstitious treatments can easily spread is supported by reports of extraordinary treatments for conditions such as leprosy (treated with a drink made of rotting snakes) and syphilis (treated by eating a vulture), and by similar myths for poisonous snake bites (apply ‘guaco’ leaves, poisonous lizard skin or snake's bile), dog bites (drink tea made from the dog's tail) and scorpion stings (tie a scorpion against the stung finger) [23]. The analysis also helps explain the persistence of medical treatments of animals, such as ‘firing’ (cautery) of working horses, employed for millennia as treatment for lameness, where recovery is rare, and still widely practiced in many countries in spite of trials establishing its ineffectiveness [24]. In such cases, of course, the treatment belief is acquired by the owner, rather than by the diseased individual.

Even when highly effective treatments have higher cultural fitness values than ineffective treatments, our analysis shows that such highly functional innovations can easily be lost due to stochasticity. This has not been apparent to researchers studying the diffusion of foraging innovations in animals, for whom the failure of most innovations to spread, particularly those beneficial to the inventor, has been regarded as a mystery [25]. In fact, the observation that the majority of beneficial innovations are frequently lost is exactly what our model predicts.

The analyses presented here could usefully be extended to model disease frequencies explicitly, and to incorporate the costs of treatment. It is well-established that human life-history decision making is affected by costs [26], and this is also likely to be true of medical-treatment decisions. Nonetheless, our models make sense of a surprisingly broad set of phenomena.

Applications of the model

The primary application of our models is to the spread of self-medicative treatments in humans. The models are potentially relevant to any socially learned practice that is thought by the user to affect (that is, treat) their medical condition, through aiding recovery, reducing suffering, or reducing the probability of relapse, irrespective of whether or not the treatment actually does bring about the improvements in condition assumed by the user. The treatments include modern/established medical practices, complementary medicines, traditional medicines and alternative medicines. The models also potentially apply to instances of witchcraft, shamanism and magic in which the ‘treatment’ is believed to combat perceived underlying ‘supernatural’ causes of disease (e.g. the curse of a jealous neighbour, or a haunting by the ghost of an ancestor), so long as there exists a physical ailment in the user, and the treatment propagates through cultural transmission. While the use of modern medicines and well-documented and established complementary treatments is ontologically distinct from witchcraft and shamanism (they are not substitutes for each other, and their effectiveness is likely to be gauged by different criteria), nonetheless, all of these treatments share the fact that their use spreads through social learning and transmission, and uptake therefore is potentially a function of the rate of practice demonstration. Relevant medical conditions include physical and psychological disease, injuries and accidents. While the model can be applied to treatment of some infectious disease, we note that a satisfactory analysis of medical conditions that propagate rapidly relative to the rate of spread of treatments would require an extension of these models to track disease spread explicitly.

While the models assume treatments spread through social learning, the precise nature of the psychological mechanism is unspecified, and any of a range of established processes could be operating [27], [28]. Nor do the models require the conscious imitation or observational learning of a practice. Accordingly, while the models are developed with humans in mind, they potentially are relevant to the spread of self-medicative treatments in other animals, particularly nonhuman primates. There is now good evidence for self-medicating behaviour in nonhuman primates, particularly African apes [29], [30]. Chimpanzees, bonobos and gorillas are known to swallow whole and defecate intact leaves, traditional behaviour thought to be a means of purging intestinal parasites [29], [30]. Experimental evidence reveals that this can spread through social transmission, leading to the suggestion that self-medicative practices in apes are maintained as behavioural traditions [29], [30], [31]. As intestinal parasites are likely to inflict multiple episodes (Inline graphic), circumstances that should favour the spread of efficacious treatments, our analysis supports claims of effective self-medication in apes.

The models are also potentially applicable to veterinary practices, although here the sick/treated animal is a different individual to the individual practicing the treatment (its owner). The models are not applicable to the activities of a veterinarian, but rather to animal owners who apply socially transmitted knowledge to treat their animal's condition.

The models apply broadly to any case where there are two states associated with higher and lower mortality, with the behavioural practice affecting the transition from the former to the latter. For instance, the model could be used to investigate the diffusion of foraging innovations, where hunger equates to sickness and satiation to wellness. With ‘multiple episodes’ of hunger (Inline graphic), a high rate of abandonment of poor foraging techniques or low profitability foods (Inline graphic), and no ‘recovery’ without feeding (Inline graphic), our model predicts that efficacious traits are most likely to spread, and that the frequency of maladaptive or superstitious foraging innovations should be low. This conclusion holds even if alternative foraging strategies were available (Inline graphic), as would be the case where animals can feed without requiring social information. This may help to explain why there is not the same controversy over the spread of alternative foods and food-processing techniques as there is for treatments of disease: the latter are significantly more likely to be ineffective.

Remarks on unbiased copying

Our choice to set copying to be unbiased is a simple and parsimonious assumption. We also believe it is close to reality. Indeed, in recent years, considerable evidence has accumulated for such unbiased copying in the transmission of a broad range of cultural traits, from pottery designs, to baby names, to the popularity of dog breeds [32], [33], [34], but our analysis extends these findings to cultural traits that potentially affect Darwinian fitness. While individuals may seek to acquire effective remedies, they typically fail to do so in practice. In many circumstances, making judgments about the effectiveness of treatments deployed by others is challenging. For most ailments and practices, the decision to adopt a treatment is based on weak circumstantial evidence, cultural preconceptions and perceived efficacy, which may not reflect actual efficacy. Cultural mileux that frame natural phenomena in terms of supernatural causes would further weaken the connection between efficacy and the rate of adoption. Moreover, it is likely that people frequently recover irrespective of treatment (i.e. Inline graphic), are poor at making judgments about what led to recovery, and different people offer conflicting advice. Our model therefore makes the simple assumption that sick people are willing to try new remedies – through unbiased copying – and drop them if they do not appear to work, and this suffices to explain superstitious and maladaptive treatments. We note that if copying were strongly biased so that individuals adopt effective treatments preferentially over ineffective ones, both acquisition and loss processes would favour effective remedies, leading to the spread of only efficacious treatments. At best, such a scenario could account for the presence of adaptive remedies, and could not by itself explain the existence of maladaptive or superstitious treatments. Yet, as described above, there is strong evidence that ineffective treatments are commonplace [1], [6], [7], [8], [11], [12], [13], [14].

Unbiased copying should be distinguished from another notion – that sick people, in desperation, are willing to try any available treatment. Such a practice would not bring about unbiased copying (acquisition in proportion to observed frequency), but rather frequency independent copying, since all treatments would be equally likely to be adopted, irrespective of their frequency or efficacy. With no acquisition bias, treatment frequency dynamics would be dominated by the loss-process, which favours effective cures due to the abandonment of ineffective treatments. While the ‘desperate flailing’ process would preserve variation in treatments at low level, it could not explain how maladaptive or superstitious treatments could reach high frequencies. Moreover, this hypothesis runs counter to the strong empirical evidence that social learning increases with the frequency of demonstration [35], [36], [37], [38], [39]

Conceivably, in humans, the trade-off between trait efficacy and probability of spread predicted by our models will sometimes be negated through language. Individuals can simply sample others' evaluations, for instance, through conversation. However there is theoretical and empirical support for the hypothesis that individuals preferentially evaluate appropriate behaviour based on direct cues (e.g. self-evaluation), rather than observed behavioural decisions of others (e.g. evaluating others' treatments) [40], [41], [42]. Here, the contrast between technological/foraging innovations and medical treatments may be instructive. For technological/foraging innovations, the productivity of the innovation when employed by others is likely, in many situations, to be relatively straightforward to gauge, since observers can directly see the returns (higher yield, a better product etc) and make reliable judgments. This will mitigate against the spread of arbitrary of maladaptive practices, since observers would no longer be copying at random, but according to the efficacy of the trait. Individuals could equally inform others of effective self-medicative treatments, but with lower reliability, since the aforementioned factors (the difficulties of determining similarity of condition, demonstrator reliability, equivalence of treatment and the fact that individuals may have recovered independent of treatment), together with cultural norms about how medical conditions should be treated (e.g. the local convention in sub-Saharan Africa is to treat mastitis with witchcraft [12]) and placebo effects that accelerate recovery even when biologically inactive treatments have been adopted, render impartial evaluation of efficacy difficult.

Alternative hypotheses

While several established cultural evolution models explain the persistence of maladaptive traits, none are credible alternative explanations for the existence of ineffective or maladaptive self-medicative treatments on the scale observed. Selfish cultural variants, or memes [43], can lead to maladaptive traits spreading if the rate of imitation exceeds that of competing adaptive variants and overwhelms opposing selection [15], [16]. To explain maladaptive treatments, however, this hypothesis would require people to prefer treatments that do not work over treatments that do, which is implausible. Conformist biases are known sometimes to lead to maladaptive outcomes, where environmental change renders a once adaptive solution no longer adaptive, or if conformity favours group-beneficial traits [16], [38]. Yet for many complementary medicines (e.g. the ‘healing’ power of crystals) there is no evidence that these treatments ever worked, nor any suggestion that they are group beneficial. Sexual selection, operating at genetic, cultural, or gene-cultural levels, is also known to be capable of propagating maladaptive variants [44], [16], [45] but people typically do not adopt medical treatments to render themselves attractive to the opposite sex. Prestige biases [16], [46] are more credible, particularly in small scale pre-industrial societies, but in modern western societies where there is considerable prestige associated with doctors and the medical establishment, these institutions have typically lobbied against the use of complementary medicines and traditional treatments. These treatments appear to have spread in spite of a counteracting prestige bias, rather than because of one. In contrast to the above, the unbiased copying explanation that we favour is both simple and plausible.

Supporting Information

Appendix S1

(0.10 MB PDF)

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Alex Bentley, Gillian Brown, Lewis Dean, Anne Kandler, Rachel Kendal, Luke Rendell and Jamie Tehrani for valuable comments on earlier drafts of this article, to Christine Broster, Charlotte Burn and Richard Byrne for drawing our attention to further potential applications of the models, and to Andrew Whiten for helpful discussion of self-medication in nonhuman primates.

Footnotes

Competing Interests: The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.

Funding: The work was supported by the Australian Academy of Sciences, the Research Councils UK, Biotechnology and Biological Sciences Research Council UK and the European Union. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1.WHO. WHO Traditional Medicine Strategy 2002–2005. World Health Organization Geneva; 2002. [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Patwardhan B, Warude D, Pushpangadan P, Bhatt N. Ayurveda and traditional Chinese medicine: a comparative overview. eCAM. 2005;2:465–473. doi: 10.1093/ecam/neh140. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Normile D. The new face of traditional Chinese medicine. Science. 2003;299:188–190. doi: 10.1126/science.299.5604.188. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Fiot J, Sanon S, Azas N, Mahiou V, Jansen O, et al. Phytochemical and pharmacological study of roots and leaves of Guiera senegalensis JF Gmel (combretaceae). Ethnopharmacol. 2006;106:173–178. doi: 10.1016/j.jep.2005.12.030. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Palombo EA. Phytochemicals from traditional medicinal plants used in the treatment of diarrhoea: Modes of action and effects on intestinal function. Phytother Res. 2006;20:717–724. doi: 10.1002/ptr.1907. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Abbott A. Survey questions safety of alternative medicine. Nature. 2005;436:898–898. doi: 10.1038/436898b. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Abbott NC, White AR, Ernst E. Complementary medicine. Nature. 1996;381:361. doi: 10.1038/381361a0. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Shang A, Huwiler-Müntener K, Nartey L, Jüni P, Dörig S, et al. Are the clinical effects of homoeopathy placebo effects? Comparative study of placebo-controlled trials of homoeopathy and allopathy. Lancet. 2005;366:726–732. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(05)67177-2. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Giles J. Degrees in homeopathy slated as unscientific. Nature. 2007;446:352–353. doi: 10.1038/446352a. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Garnier R, Poupon J. Lead poisoning from traditional Indian medicines. Presse Med. 2006;35:1177–1180. doi: 10.1016/s0755-4982(06)74776-5. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Okeke TA, Okafor HU, Uzochukwu BSC. Traditional healers in Nigeria: Perception of cause, treatment and referral practices for severe malaria. J Biosoc Sci. 2006;38:491–500. doi: 10.1017/S002193200502660X. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.De Allegri M, Sarker M, Hofmann J, Sanon M, Bohler T. A qualitative investigation into knowledge, beliefs, and practices surrounding mastitis in sub-saharan Africa: what implications for vertical transmission of HIV? BMC Public Health. 2007;7:22. doi: 10.1186/1471-2458-7-22. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Hsieh SC, Lai JN, Chen PC, Chen HJ, Wang JD. Development of activesafety surveillance system for traditional Chinese medicine: an empirical study in treating climacteric women. Pharmacoepid and Drug Safety. 2006;15:889–899. doi: 10.1002/pds.1340. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Ang HH, Lee KL. Contamination of mercury in tongkat Ali hitam herbal preparations. Food Chem Toxicol. 2006;44:1245–1259. doi: 10.1016/j.fct.2006.01.014. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Cavalli-Sforza LL, Feldman MW. Cultural transmission and evolution: a quantitative approach. Princeton University Press; 1981. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Boyd R, Richerson PJ. Culture and the evolutionary process. Chicago University Press; 1985. [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Tanaka MM, Kumm J, Feldman MW. Coevolution of pathogens and cultural practices: a new look at behavioral heterogeneity in epidemics. Theor Popul Biol. 2002;62:111–119. doi: 10.1006/tpbi.2002.1585. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Pagel M, Mace R. The cultural wealth of nations. Nature. 2004;428:275–278. doi: 10.1038/428275a. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Karlin S, Taylor H. A first course in stochastic processes. New York: Academic Press; 1975. [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Nesse RM, Williams GC. Why we get sick: The new science of Darwinian Medicine. New York: Vintage; 1994. [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Ewens WJ. Mathematical population genetics, volume 9 of Biomathematics. New York: Springer-Verlag; 1979. [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Losada M, Ladio A, Weigant M. Cultural transmission of ethnobotanical knowledge in a rural community of northwestern Patagonia, Argentina. Econ Bot. 2006;60:374–385. [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Werner D. Where there is no doctor. London: Macmillan Press; 1983. [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Silver IA, Brown PN, Goodship AE, Lanyon LE, McCullagh KG, et al. A clinical and experimental study of tendon injury, healing and treatment in the horse. Equine Vet J Suppl. 1983;1:1–42. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Reader SM, Laland KN, editors. Animal Innovation. Oxford University Press; 2003. [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Mace R. Evolutionary ecology of human life history. Anim Behav. 2000;59:1–10. doi: 10.1006/anbe.1999.1287. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Whiten A, Ham R. On the nature and evolution of imitation in the animal kingdom: reappraisal of a century of research. Adv Study Beh. 1992;21:239–283. [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Heyes CM. Social learning in animals: categories and mechanisms. Biol Rev. 1994;69:207–131. doi: 10.1111/j.1469-185x.1994.tb01506.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Huffman MA. Animal self-medication and ethno-medicine: exploration and exploitation of the medicinal properties of plants. Proc Nut Soc. 2003;62:113–118. doi: 10.1079/pns2003257. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Huffman MA, Hirata S. An experimental study of leaf swallowing in captive chimpanzees: insights into the origin of a self-medicative behavior and the role of social learning. Primates. 2004;45:113–118. doi: 10.1007/s10329-003-0065-5. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Whiten A, Goodall J, McGrew W, Nishida T, Reynolds V, et al. Cultures in chimpanzees. Nature. 1999;399:682–685. doi: 10.1038/21415. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Bentley RA, Hahn MW, Shennan SJ. Random drift and culture change. Proc Roy Soc Lond B. 2004;271:1443–1450. doi: 10.1098/rspb.2004.2746. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Bentley RA, Hahn MW. Drift as a mechanism for cultural change: An example from baby names. Proc Roy Soc Lond B. 2003;270:S120–S123. doi: 10.1098/rsbl.2003.0045. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Bentley RA, Lipo C, Herzog M, Hahn MW. Regular rates of popular culture change reect random copying. Evol Hum Behav. 2006;28:151–158. [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Laland KN, Williams K. Shoaling generates social learning of foraging information in guppies. Anim Behav. 1997;53:1161–1169. doi: 10.1006/anbe.1996.0318. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Beck M, Galef BG., Jr Social inuences on the selection of a protein-sufficient diet by Norway rats (Rattus norvegicus). J Comp Psychol. 1989;103:132–139. [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Lefebvre L, Giraldeau LA. Cultural transmission in pigeons is affected by the number of tutors and bystanders present. Anim Behav. 1994;47:331–337. [Google Scholar]
  • 38.Henrich J, Boyd R. The evolution of conformist transmission and the emergence of between-group differences. Evol Hum Behav. 1998;19:215–241. [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Coultas JC. When in Rome… An evolutionary perspective on conformity. Group Proc and Intergroup Relat. 2004;7:317. [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Giraldeau LA, Valone TJ, Templeton JJ. Potential disadvantages of using socially acquired information. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci. 2002;357:1559–1566. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2002.1065. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 41.Bikhchandani S, Hirshleifer D, Welsh I. A theory of fads, fashion, custom and cultural changes as informational cascades. J Polit Econ. 1992;100:992–1026. [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Bikhchandani S, Hirshleifer D, Welsh I. Learning from the behavior of others: Conformity, fads and informational cascades. J Econ Perspect. 1998;12:151–170. [Google Scholar]
  • 43.Dawkins R. The Selfish Gene. Oxford University Press; 1976. [Google Scholar]
  • 44.Kirkpatrick M. Sexual selection and the evolution of female choice. Evolution. 1982;36:1–12. doi: 10.1111/j.1558-5646.1982.tb05003.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 45.Laland KN. Sexual selection with a culturally transmitted mating preference. Theor Popul Biol. 1994;45:1–15. doi: 10.1006/tpbi.1994.1001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Henrich J, Gil-White FJ. The evolution of prestige: freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav. 2001;22:165–196. doi: 10.1016/s1090-5138(00)00071-4. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Appendix S1

(0.10 MB PDF)


Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES