Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2010 Mar 29;5(3):e9882. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0009882

Cooperation and Stability through Periodic Impulses

Bo-Yu Zhang 1,2, Ross Cressman 3,*, Yi Tao 1,*
Editor: Wayne M Getz4
PMCID: PMC2848027  PMID: 20369003

Abstract

Basic games, where each individual chooses between two strategies, illustrate several issues that immediately emerge from the standard approach that applies strategic reasoning, based on rational decisions, to predict population behavior where no rationality is assumed. These include how mutual cooperation (which corresponds to the best outcome from the population perspective) can evolve when the only individually rational choice is to defect, illustrated by the Prisoner's Dilemma (PD) game, and how individuals can randomize between two strategies when neither is individually rational, illustrated by the Battle of the Sexes (BS) game that models male-female conflict over parental investment in offspring. We examine these questions from an evolutionary perspective where the evolutionary dynamics includes an impulsive effect that models sudden changes in collective population behavior. For the PD game, we show analytically that cooperation can either coexist with defection or completely take over the population, depending on the strength of the impulse. By extending these results for the PD game, we also show that males and females each evolve to a single strategy in the BS game when the impulsive effect is strong and that weak impulses stabilize the randomized strategies of this game.

Introduction

A great deal of game-theoretic research has been devoted to explain the prevalence of cooperation in biological systems as well as in human society. One reason for the vast literature from members of the game theory community on this topic is that their methods do not work for the underlying stage game, the symmetric Prisoner's Dilemma, which pits cooperative behavior against its nemesis of defection. In particular, the only rational option in this PD stage game is to Defect since this strategy strictly dominates Cooperate (i.e. a player is better off defecting than cooperating no matter what the opponent does).

On the other hand, cooperation can be rational when the payoffs of the PD game are modified by assuming some relatedness between the players [1], [2], by them playing the game an uncertain number of times [3], or by extending the model to a multi-player (i.e. more than two) public goods game [4]. These predictions are often based on applying either static (e.g. evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS)) or dynamic (e.g. the replicator equation) methods from evolutionary game theory [5] that assumes a large population of agents paired at random to play the game. Population interactions that are structured either spatially (e.g. through nearest neighbors on a lattice) or socially (e.g. through adjacent nodes in a graph) also enhance the evolution of cooperation [6][11] as do the stochastic effects of finite populations [12].

To a lesser extent, the question of stability of mixed strategy equilibrium solutions (and their interpretation) has also created controversy in the game theory community [13], [14]. This is especially true of two-player non symmetric games due to the result that, at any evolutionarily stable state of such games, players must use pure strategies [15]. The controversy here is clearly demonstrated through typical payoffs used in the Battle of the Sexes game [5], [16], [17] introduced into biology by Dawkins [18] to model the conflict between males and females concerning their respective contributions to parental investment (see also the Buyer-Seller game [19] that has the same qualitative payoff structure). In the BS stage game, each player has two pure strategies and the only equilibrium solution is for both players to use a mixture of their strategies. Furthermore, the replicator equation applied to this game yields periodic solutions around this mixed strategy equilibrium pair even though Maynard Smith [17] (Chapter 11C) states that “I am unable to offer illustrative examples, or evidence that such cycles occur.”

In this article, we re-examine the PD and BS stage games from the dynamic perspective where, in addition to the continuous trajectories of evolutionary game theory, there are periodic jumps in the population size. In biological systems, these latter impulsive perturbations may be due to sudden changes in the physical environment (e.g. the effects of climate change or natural disaster) or to intrinsic diurnal/nocturnal and seasonal life history effects in the physiological and reproductive mechanisms of individuals in the population. Impulsive perturbations have also been used to model the effect on human behavior of sudden market corrections or of sudden shifts in the business cycle [20]. We assume that the impulsive “coefficient” for an individual depends only on its strategy and analyze the resultant dynamics. In particular, we give analytic conditions for the coefficients in the PD game for the successful initial invasion of Cooperators into a population of Defectors as well as conditions based on stronger impulsive effects for Cooperators to completely take over the system. We also show that these latter conditions applied to the BS game imply global convergence to a monomorphic system where all males use one pure strategy as well as all females. Moreover, when impulsive effects are weak in the BS game, a globally attracting polymorphic state emerges near the mixed equilibrium pair.

Analysis

Prisoner's Dilemma

The PD stage game is ubiquitous in the game theory literature and so needs no introduction. We follow the standard notation by taking its payoff matrix as

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e001.jpg (1)

where Inline graphic. The entries in this matrix give the payoff to the row player in a two-player interaction with the column player (e.g. if a player Defects against an opponent who Cooperates, his payoff is Inline graphic). Since Inline graphic and Inline graphic, Defect strictly dominates Cooperate and so it is the only rational outcome of this one shot game.

To illustrate how periodic impulses can be combined with an evolutionary dynamics, suppose that the replicator equation (see Eq.4a below) models behavioral evolution. From a biological perspective, these dynamics result from a direct correspondence between expected payoff and reproductive success [21]. Specifically, if Inline graphic and Inline graphic are the numbers of Defectors and Cooperators respectively in the population at time Inline graphic, then

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e009.jpg (2)

where Inline graphic is the total population size. Here Inline graphic is the expected payoff to a Defector in a single interaction with a randomly chosen opponent assuming that population size is large. From Taylor and Jonker [21], the population dynamics (Eq.2) implies the frequency Inline graphic of Defectors in the population (i.e. Inline graphic) evolves according to the replicator equation (Eq.4a).

Now suppose that individuals die at periodic intervals Inline graphic for Inline graphic. That is, reproductive success (i.e. fitness) in Eq.2 refers only to births. Deaths cause a jump in the solution trajectories of Eq.2 of the form Inline graphic where Inline graphic (respectively, Inline graphic) is the number of Defectors immediately after (respectively before) the jump. If the death rate of each strategy type is independent of population size, then

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e019.jpg (3)

for some Inline graphic. The parameter Inline graphic is called the “impulsive coefficient” for the i-th strategy. The dynamical system with periodic impulsive effects combines Eq.2 when Inline graphic with Eq.3 when Inline graphic. In particular, for every nonnegative initial condition Inline graphic, this impulsive dynamical system has a unique nonnegative solution for all Inline graphic.

Evolutionary game theory is more concerned with the evolution of strategy frequencies than with how the absolute numbers of strategy users evolve over time. It is shown in File S1 (see also [22]) that

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e026.jpg (4a)
graphic file with name pone.0009882.e027.jpg (4b)

where Inline graphic denotes the jump in Inline graphic at moment Inline graphic. That is, Inline graphic (respectively, Inline graphic) is the frequency of Defector immediately after (respectively before) the jump. For the analysis of this dynamical system, it is important to notice that the frequency dynamics Eq.4 is independent of population size Inline graphic. When there are no impulsive effects, we have the standard replicator equation Eq.4a [21]. For this reason, we call Eq.4 the replicator equation with periodic impulses.

Remark

The replicator equation with periodic impulses developed above is based on continuous births throughout the season and deaths only at the end. One consequence of our assumptions is that birth and death rates are independent of population size. It can be shown [22] that dynamics Eq.4 also emerges when birth rates are altered by any strategy-independent background fitness (which is usually assumed to decrease as population size increases). This background fitness can be used to investigate the dynamics of total population size and not only the frequency dynamics as in the standard approach to evolutionary game theory [21]. The dynamics Eq.4 also models other periodic impulses in biological systems such as regular perturbations in the physical environment. It is well-documented [23][25] that humans (and other biological species) exhibit more cooperation in the face of natural disasters (also called the disaster syndrome). Such shifting of aggregate population behavior through individuals changing their strategy becomes a positive jump in the proportion of Cooperators. In fact, any impulsive coefficients in Eq.3 satisfying Inline graphic are suitable since Inline graphic for all Inline graphic in this case. The interpretation of Inline graphic is that the impulse is then beneficial to the i-th strategy.

From Eq.4a, Inline graphic strictly increases during the season (i.e. Inline graphic) if Inline graphic since Inline graphic and Inline graphic. Thus, if the Defector death rate is no higher than the Cooperator (i.e. Inline graphic), the population must evolve to all Defect since Inline graphic also increases at the end of each season. However, if the death rates benefit Cooperators (i.e. if Inline graphic), the effect of Defector deaths may offset their higher birth rates and so it is unclear which effect dominates (see Figure 1). In the extreme case where Inline graphic, all Defectors die at the end of the first season and the population is all Cooperate thereafter.

Figure 1. Trajectories for the replicator equation with periodic impulses (4) when payoffs Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic of the PD game are fixed at Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic respectively and the initial frequency of Defect is Inline graphic.

Figure 1

Here Inline graphic and the values taken for Inline graphic are (a) Inline graphic; (b) Inline graphic; (c) Inline graphic; and (d) Inline graphic.

For these reasons, we will assume that Inline graphic for the remainder of this section. The key to understanding the outcome in this scenario is to determine the stability of the boundary equilibria Inline graphic and Inline graphic of Eq.4. Heuristically, when Inline graphic is near 0, the trajectory Inline graphic during the first season is approximated by Inline graphic since, from Eq.4a, Inline graphic. Also, from Eq.4b, the jump at the end of this season is Inline graphic. For (asymptotic) stability of all Cooperate (i.e. for Inline graphic to converge to 0 if it is initially close to 0), we expect that Inline graphic. This is true if and only if

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e072.jpg (5)

Notice that Inline graphic when Inline graphic and so there are payoff matrices with Inline graphic for which all Cooperate is stable.

It is proved analytically in File S1 (see also [22]) that Inline graphic is stable if inequality Eq.5 is true and unstable (i.e. Inline graphic diverges from 0 if it is initially close) if this inequality is reversed (i.e. Inline graphic). It is also shown there that all Defect is stable if

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e079.jpg (6)

and unstable if the inequality is reversed. In fact, the dynamic stability of the boundary equilibria for threshold parameters when Eq.5 or Eq.6 is an equality is also characterized there. Besides one exceptional case discussed in the final paragraph of this section when both Eq.5 and Eq.6 are equalities, there is a unique interior Inline graphic-periodic trajectory (i.e. a Inline graphic with Inline graphic for all Inline graphic and Inline graphic for all Inline graphic) if and only if either both boundary equilibria are unstable or both are stable. In the first (respectively, second) case, Inline graphic is globally stable (respectively, unstable). Finally, if exactly one boundary equilibrium is stable, then it is globally stable in that it attracts all interior trajectories.

These analytic results from File S1, that are summarized in the preceding paragraph, are illustrated in Figures 1 and 2 for non threshold cases. In Figure 1, trajectories of Eq.4 are given for fixed payoff parameters and four different values of

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e087.jpg (7)

In Figure 2, Inline graphic is fixed and the stability of boundary equilibria and interior Inline graphic-periodic trajectories is characterized in different regions of the space with parameters Inline graphic and Inline graphic.

Figure 2. Regions of payoff parameter space determined by a fixed positive value of Inline graphic in Eq.7.

Figure 2

In region I, Inline graphic and Inline graphic, and all Defect is globally stable; in region II, Inline graphic and Inline graphic, both all Cooperate and all Defect are (locally) stable, and there exists an unstable Inline graphic-periodic solution; in region III, Inline graphic and Inline graphic, and all Cooperate is globally stable; and in region IV, Inline graphic and Inline graphic, both all Cooperate and all Defect are unstable, and there exists a globally stable Inline graphic-periodic solution corresponding to a mixture of Cooperators and Defectors.

For small values of Inline graphic, the population evolves to all Defect (Figs. 1a and 1b). An initial small population of Cooperators can successfully invade a population of Defectors once Inline graphic. Cooperators then completely take over the population if inequality Inline graphic also holds (Fig. 1d and quadrant III in Fig. 2); otherwise the system approaches a globally stable Inline graphic-periodic state consisting of a mixture of Cooperators and Defectors (Fig. 1c and quadrant IV in Fig. 2). If Inline graphic as in quadrants I and II of Figure 2, either all Defect completely takes over or we have a bistable situation where all Cooperate can persist if their initial frequency is sufficiently high.

It is instructive to consider the case of small impulsive effects (i.e. when the impulsive coefficients Inline graphic are both close to Inline graphic). By Taylor's expansion, Inline graphic is approximately equal to Inline graphic. Then Eq.7 becomes

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e112.jpg

which represents the average impulsive effect over one season in favor of Cooperate. By inequalities Eq.5 and Eq.6, if the positive payoff advantage during the season to Defect over Cooperate is always less than this average impulsive effect (i.e. if Inline graphic and Inline graphic are both less than Inline graphic), Cooperators invade and take over the population. This intuitive result can be generalized to all situations where impulsive effects are nearly equal (i.e. Inline graphic is close to Inline graphic but they are not necessarily close to 0) (see also File S1). The central message here is that a small difference in the death rates of Cooperators and Defectors can have a major impact on the evolution of cooperation.

In fact, if we call Inline graphic defined in Eq.7 the average impulsive effect over one season in favor of Cooperate for any choice of Inline graphic, the intuitive result of the previous paragraph remains true.

In the exceptional case where Inline graphic, the boundary equilibria are neutrally stable and every trajectory Inline graphic for any initial condition Inline graphic is Inline graphic-periodic. Interestingly, the special payoffs for the PD game that satisfy Inline graphic have attained prominence recently since this class includes the simplified PD games [1], [26] with payoff matrix

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e125.jpg (8)

Here Inline graphic is the payoff benefit a player interacting with a Cooperator gains and Inline graphic is the cost paid by Cooperators. Under the usual assumption that Inline graphic, the entries in this simplified payoff matrix have the same ordering as in Eq.1. From Eq.5 and Eq.6, if Inline graphic (respectively, Inline graphic), then all Cooperate (respectively, all Defect) is the final outcome. Unlike other studies on the simplified PD game [26] where the emergence of Cooperative behavior often depends on the cost-benefit ratio Inline graphic, here it depends only on the cost of Cooperation. The size of the payoff benefit has no impact on our results since neither the replicator equation Eq.4a nor the impulse Eq.4b depends on Inline graphic. In our model, it is the impulsive benefit Inline graphic that replaces the payoff benefit Inline graphic. In particular, Cooperation emerges if and only if the impulsive benefit to Cooperators is greater than the cost paid by Cooperators. That is, periodic impulses that favor cooperation provide a mechanism that promotes the evolution of cooperation.

Battle of the Sexes

In the BS stage game, male strategies are either “faithful” or “philandering” and females are “coy” or “fast” [18]. In the following two paragraphs, we briefly summarize well-known facts about this game [5], [16], [17].

If parental investment costs Inline graphic, the benefit gained from an offspring is Inline graphic and the cost of a long engagement is Inline graphic, then the payoffs to males and females are given in the following bimatrix (e.g. a philanderer receives the benefit Inline graphic against a fast female whose net payoff is then Inline graphic).

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e140.jpg (9)

With the usual assumptions that these payoffs satisfy Inline graphic, the characteristic feature of the BS game is the cyclical character of male and female best responses. If females are coy, it pays males to be faithful; if males are faithful, it pays females to be fast; if females are fast, it pays males to philander; and if males philander, it pays females to be coy. This characteristic also leads to cycling in the standard evolutionary dynamics that is concerned with the evolution of strategy frequencies.

Let Inline graphic be the frequency of philanders in the male population and Inline graphic be the frequency of coy females in their population. The bimatrix replicator equation is then

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e144.jpg (10a)
graphic file with name pone.0009882.e145.jpg (10b)

This two-dimensional dynamics on the unit square has the unique interior equilibrium Inline graphic and all trajectories are periodic orbits surrounding Inline graphic [5], [16], [17]. Figure 3a-b illustrates a typical trajectory of Eq.10 for the payoffs.

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e148.jpg

considered by Dawkins [18] that has Inline graphic.

Figure 3. Trajectories for the bimatrix replicator equation with periodic impulses for the BS game in the Inline graphic-Inline graphic phase plane, where Inline graphic and Inline graphic are represented by blue and red curves, respectively.

Figure 3

The parameters are taken as Inline graphic and Inline graphic, i.e., the payoff matrix is
graphic file with name pone.0009882.e156.jpg
and the neutral interior equilibrium is Inline graphic. The minimum period Inline graphic is about Inline graphic. In Figure 3a–b, Inline graphic (no impulses) and the time step is from 1 to 15. All the interior trajectories are periodic orbits surrounding Inline graphic. In Figure 3c, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (strong impulses) and the time step is from 1 to 3. Since Inline graphic and Inline graphic, from Table 1, boundary equilibrium Inline graphic is stable and all the interior trajectories converge to Inline graphic. In Figure 3d, Inline graphic (weak impulses) and the time steps are respectively 1 to 10, Inline graphic to Inline graphic and Inline graphic to Inline graphic. All the interior trajectories converge to an attracting set within 0.015 of the interior equilibrium Inline graphic. In Figure 3e–f, Inline graphic (intermediate impulses) and the time step is from 1 to 15. Clearly, interior trajectories do not always evolve to either a boundary equilibrium or to a set close to Inline graphic.

We again assume that trajectories of the replicator equation are based on male and female births throughout the season and that there are jumps at Inline graphic for Inline graphic due to deaths at the end of the season. If the male (respectively, female) death rate is Inline graphic (respectively, Inline graphic) for their Inline graphic-th strategy, these latter periodic impulses are

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e181.jpg (11a)
graphic file with name pone.0009882.e182.jpg (11b)

at Inline graphic where Inline graphic and Inline graphic. The bimatrix replicator equation with periodic impulses combines Eq.10 at Inline graphic with Eq.11 at Inline graphic.

The analysis of this impulsive dynamical system is more difficult than the replicator equation with periodic impulses for the PD game. We will assume that Inline graphic and Inline graphic for Inline graphic. Each edge of the unit square is then invariant (as is the interior of the square). For example, on the edge where Inline graphic, we have

graphic file with name pone.0009882.e192.jpg

This impulsive dynamics is the same as that for the PD game with simplified payoffs Eq.8 given by Inline graphic.

That is, on the edge where all females are fast, the game is one where males are playing a simplified PD game among themselves. Thus, all males will eventually be faithful if they have a lower death rate than philanderers (i.e., Inline graphic) that satisfies Inline graphic where Inline graphic is the impulsive benefit for faithful males (cf. the discussion in the PD section about Eq.7). If Inline graphic, it is an impulsive benefit for philandering males. On the other hand, philanderers will take over if their death rate is lower or if Inline graphic. In this section, we will not consider threshold parameter values where all trajectories on an edge are Inline graphic-periodic. Similarly, on the edge where all males are faithful, there is a simplified PD game among females (where Inline graphic is now identified with Inline graphic). Let Inline graphic be the impulsive benefit for fast females (i.e., Inline graphic). Thus, all females will eventually be fast (respectively, coy) if the cost of a long engagement is greater than (respectively, less than) the impulsive benefit for coy females, i.e. Inline graphic) (respectively, Inline graphic).

In fact, Inline graphic will be stable for the bimatrix replicator equation with periodic impulses (Eq.10 and Eq.11) on the unit square if males are eventually faithful on the first edge and females are eventually fast on the second edge. This result is indicated in the first row of Table 1 that summaries the stability of all four vertices of the unit square. The proof is in File S1 where it is also shown that, if one vertex is stable, then it is globally stable (i.e. all trajectories in the interior of the unit square converge to it). In particular, at most one vertex can be stable.

Table 1. Stability of Boundary Equilibria Inline graphic (Inline graphic is the frequency of males who philander and Inline graphic is the frequency of coy females).

Boundary Equilibrium Inline graphic Conditions for Stability of Boundary Equilibrium
Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic
Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic
Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic
Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic

From Table 1, if impulsive effects are strong enough on any edge to reverse the flow of the replicator equation Eq.10 there (i.e., if any of the inequalities Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic, or Inline graphic are true), then there is a globally stable pure strategy pair for males and females. In particular, these periodic impulses have removed the characteristic interior cycles of the BS game and replaced them with global stability at a vertex. Figure 3c illustrates a typical trajectory of Eq.10, Eq.11 when one of the stability conditions for the vertex (1,0) in Table 1 are satisfied.

When impulses are not strong (i.e. when Inline graphic and Inline graphic), the limiting behavior of each trajectory on the boundary of the unit square is the same whether or not periodic impulses Eq.11 are combined with the bimatrix replicator dynamics; namely, all these trajectories evolve to the first vertex encountered in a counterclockwise direction. On the other hand, no interior trajectory evolves to a point on the boundary. Figure 3e–f illustrates a typical trajectory when impulses are of intermediate strength. Notice that this trajectory does not surround Inline graphic since the impulses occur before it has enough time to do so. In fact, through simulations (see File S1), it is apparent that the properties of such trajectories are quite complex with multiple Inline graphic-periodic solutions possible. The number Inline graphic of these solutions appears to depend linearly on the ratio of Inline graphic to the minimum period Inline graphic of interior periodic cycles of the bimatrix replicator dynamics Eq.10 in that it is approximated by Inline graphic where [ ] is the integer part of a positive real number. Proofs of these conjectures suggested by simulations are beyond the current techniques available to analyze these impulsive systems. We are hopeful that game-theoretic intuition will extend these techniques in future research and, in the process, improve our understanding of how arbitrary periodic impulses affect the evolutionary dynamics, especially for non symmetric two-player games (such as the BS game) with a unique equilibrium in the interior of the strategy space.

Finally, for weak impulses (i.e. for Inline graphic and Inline graphic both close to 0 and at least one nonzero) with Inline graphic, simulations show that all interior trajectories evolve to a small neighborhood of Inline graphic (see Figure 3d). Specifically, although the limiting behavior is not exactly the interior equilibrium, the large periodic cycles of the bimatrix replicator dynamics are replaced by orbits that become arbitrarily close to this equilibrium as the impulsive effect weakens. In fact, except for the one Inline graphic-periodic solution, it appears that all trajectories approach the single orbit in Figure 3d (which is not Inline graphic-periodic).

In summary, both strong and weak impulsive effects promote stability in BS games. Strong impulses imply the system has a globally stable outcome where all males adopt the same strategy as do all females (i.e. both sexes exhibit monomorphic behavior). On the other hand, weak impulses eliminate the wild fluctuations typical of the periodic cycles of the bimatrix replicator dynamics Eq.10 and replace them with an attracting set near its interior equilibrium that consists of a stable polymorphic population of males and females.

Results and Discussion

Our model combining periodic impulses with an evolutionary dynamics is based on several simplifying assumptions. First, population sizes are assumed to be sufficiently large that stochastic effects due to finite populations are ignored in the deterministic dynamics and fitness is given by expected payoff as in the original development of the replicator equation [21]. Our assumption that death rates depend only on strategy type then implies total population size does not influence the evolution of strategy frequencies given by our replicator equation with periodic impulses. Moreover, in the BS game, we have adopted the unstated common assumption of evolutionary game theory applied to asymmetric games with a bimatrix payoff matrix [5] that individual fitness is based on one random interaction per unit time between different types of individuals.

The analysis of the effects of periodic impulses becomes more complex when finite populations and/or unequal population sizes of different types in asymmetric games are included. In particular, the dynamics of total population size must then be taken into account. From this perspective, our analysis of the frequency effects of periodic impulses can be viewed as a base model against which these more complex systems can be compared, in much the same way that the replicator equation of evolutionary game theory has served as a means to gain an intuitive understanding of behavioral evolution. Our analytic results, that characterize when periodic impulses favoring cooperation in the PD game can overcome the selective advantage of defection and when both strong and weak impulses have a stabilizing effect in the BS game, can then be tested (perhaps numerically) to see if they continue to hold in more complicated models that do not satisfy our simplifying assumptions.

Supporting Information

File S1

Supporting information for “Stability and Cooperation through Periodic Impulses”.

(1.03 MB DOC)

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the anonymous referee for helpful suggestions on the original paper.

Footnotes

Competing Interests: The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.

Funding: This research was supported by The National Basic Research Program (973) (No. 2007CB109107) of the People's Republic of China and by an Individual Discovery Grant from the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1.Hamilton WD. The genetical evolution of social behavior. J Theor Biol. 1964;7:1–16. doi: 10.1016/0022-5193(64)90038-4. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Taylor PD, Wild G, Gardner A. Direct fitness or inclusive fitness: how should we model kin selection. J Evol Biol. 2007;20:296–304. doi: 10.1111/j.1420-9101.2006.01196.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Axelrod R. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books; 1984. [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Sigmund K, Hauert C, Nowak MA. Reward and punishment. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2001;98:10757–10762. doi: 10.1073/pnas.161155698. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Hofbauer J, Sigmund K. Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1998. [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Nowak MA, May RM. Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature. 1992;359:826–829. [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Nowak MA, May RM. The spatial dilemmas of evolution. Int J Bifur Chaos Appl Sci Eng. 1993;3:35–78. [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Hauert C, Doebeli M. Spatial structure often inhibits the evolution of cooperation in the Snowdrift game. Nature. 2004;428:643–646. doi: 10.1038/nature02360. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Nowak MA. Evolutionary Dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press; 2006. [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Nowak MA. Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science. 2006;314:1560–1563. doi: 10.1126/science.1133755. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Ohtsuki H, Hauert C, Lieberman E, Nowak MA. A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks. Nature. 2006;441:502–505. doi: 10.1038/nature04605. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Nowak MA, Sasaki A, Taylor C, Fudenberg D. Emergence of cooperation and evolutionary stability in finite populations. Nature. 2004;428:646–650. doi: 10.1038/nature02414. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Maynard Smith J. Can a mixed strategy be stable in a finite population? J Theor Biol. 1988;130:247–251. [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Echenique F, Edlin A. Mixed equilibria are unstable in games of strategic complements. J Econ Theory. 2004;118:61–79. [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Selten R. A note on evolutionarily stable strategies in asymmetric conflicts. J Theor Biol. 1980;84:93–101. doi: 10.1016/s0022-5193(80)81038-1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Schuster P, Sigmund K. Coyness, philandering and stable strategies. Anim Behav. 1981;29:186–192. [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Maynard Smith J. Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1982. [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Dawkins R. The Selfish Gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1976. [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Cressman R. Evolutionary Dynamics and Extensive Form Games. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; 2003. [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Korn R. Some applications of impulse control in mathematical finance. Math. Meth Oper Res. 1999;50:493–518. [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Taylor PD, Jonker L. Evolutionarily stable strategies and game dynamics. Math Biosciences. 1978;40:145–156. [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Wang SC, Zhang BY, Li ZQ, Cressman R, Tao Y. Evolutionary game dynamics with impulsive effects. J Theor Biol. 2008;254:384–389. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2008.05.016. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Douty CM. Disasters and Charity: Some Aspects of Cooperative Economic Behavior. Am Econ Review. 1972;62:580–590. [Google Scholar]
  • 24.De Alessi L. Toward an analysis of postdisaster cooperation. Am Econ Review. 1975;65:127–138. [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Frey BS, Savage DA, Torgler B. Surviving the Titanic Disaster: Economic, Natural and Social Determinants. 2009. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 2551. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1347962.
  • 26.Nowak MA, Sigmund K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature. 2005;437:1291–1298. doi: 10.1038/nature04131. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

File S1

Supporting information for “Stability and Cooperation through Periodic Impulses”.

(1.03 MB DOC)


Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES