Abstract
Prior research has debated the relative importance of such factors as human capital, political capital and region in determining workers’ earnings in reform-era urban China. This article argues that a main agent of social stratification in contemporary China continues to be the danwei, the work unit. Using data from a 1999 survey we conducted in three large Chinese cities, Wuhan, Shanghai and Xi’an, we assess the extent to which workers’ earnings (including regular wages, bonuses and subsidies) depend on the profitability of their danwei. Results show that the financial situation of the danwei is one of the most important determinants of earnings in today’s urban China. Furthermore, the importance of danwei profitability does not vary by city or by employment sector.
Accompanying the rapid economic growth in China since 1978 has been a sharp rise in economic inequality.1 One study estimates that the Gini index, a standard measure of income inequality, jumped steadily from 0.310 in 1985 to 0.415 in 2001.2 Responding to this rapid social change, sociological research on contemporary China has focused on social inequality in the past 15 years.3 With a few exceptions which explored reasons for the sharp rise in inequality,4 much of the research has attempted to address the distributional question of “who wins and who loses” during the transition.5
Two main themes have emerged in the literature. In a series of papers, Nee6 has advanced a thesis called “market transition theory,” the conjecture that income determination will depend more on market credentials (such as education) and less on political factors as economic reform advances. However, a large group of sociologists have challenged Nee’s thesis, citing both theoretical reasons pertaining to institutional, historical and cultural features unique to the reform-era Chinese economy, and empirical findings that defy predictions of market transition theory.7 For example, Xie and Hannum find that returns to education are higher in slow-developing cities than in fast-developing cities.8 Further, returns to education were lower for bonuses set by work units than for base salaries set by the government.9
While much sociological research has been devoted to the market transition debate, no consensus has been achieved. One problem is the difficulty operationalizing market transition.10 Despite the challenge of definitively testing Nee’s market transition theory, it has proved useful in generating new empirical research on social inequality in contemporary China. We now recognize the following empirical patterns, although their implications for market transition theory are still debatable. First, returns to education have significantly increased over time.11 Second, political capital has not only remained important but become more so.12 Third, regional variation has been very large and continues to dominate other determinants of earnings.13
At the core of the widespread scepticism concerning the applicability of market transition theory is the observation that the government, especially local government, continues to play a very strong role in the Chinese economy. At least at the local level, business interests are allied with government interests. In the words of Oi,14 “local governments in China [are] fully fledged economic actors, not just administrative-service providers as they are in other countries.” Oi has termed the merger of state and economy at the local level “local state corporatism.”15 One important reason for this merger is that the local government has a vested interest in promoting local economic interests so that it can provide welfare and public services to its population. While Oi’s work has been focused on rural China, her characterization can also be readily extended to urban China, where the work unit, known as danwei (), still serves as a well-being provider for its employees, continuing the long tradition of “paternalism” as discussed by Walder16 in pre-reform China. More concretely, an employer in contemporary China may not wish to maximize profits by reducing labour costs as low as the market would allow. Rather, it may be interested in protecting current employees by paying them at levels substantially higher than may be justified by the labour market competition.
If the labour market in China is not truly competitive, individuals who happen to be in favourable positions (for whatever reason) have structural advantages over those in less favourable positions.17 This situation is analogous to that described by Walder’s pioneering work on pre-reform China,18 in which the danwei played an all-encompassing role for urban citizens: one’s danwei defined one’s work life, political life, economic well-being and, ultimately, membership in society, so that individuals depended on their danwei for almost everything (“organized dependency”). Further, cadres in a danwei used their power to cater to the needs of their subordinates (“paternalism”) and favour some of them (“particularism”). Since the reform, the role of the danwei has changed but not disappeared. Some of their functions (such as housing provision, food rationing, entertainment provision and political rights conferment) have been displaced or at least substantially weakened. Non-state economic entities such as private firms and joint ventures with foreign firms have appeared and gained more prominence in the economy. Even state-owned or state-transformed employers, including large public-traded firms, universities and hospitals, have now lost their previous role as all-encompassing danwei. Technically, they are no longer part of the state’s command economy and thus are subject to “hard-budget” constraints emphasized by Kornai19 for economic efficiency. This leads to our question of whether and how the danwei continues to play an important role in determining earnings in reform-era urban China.
This article argues, and demonstrates with survey data, that danwei, the work unit, continues to be a main agent of social stratification in contemporary urban China. Using data from a 1999 survey we conducted in three large Chinese cities, Shanghai (), Wuhan () and Xi’an (), we assess the extent to which workers’ earnings (including regular wages, bonuses, and subsidies) depend on their danwei’s profitability. We find such profitability to be one of the most important determinants of earnings in urban China in the late 1990s. These results reveal the persisting role of the danwei in the social stratification regime of post-reform China.
Danwei, Then and Now
Danwei in pre-reform China
The central role of the danwei in contemporary China has long been studied by sociologists.20 Prior to economic reform, almost all urban workers were organized as part of a danwei, be it a factory, a store, a school or a government office. The danwei organizations had multiple social, political and economic functions, a permanent “membership” of life employment.21 Workers and their families were totally dependent upon their affiliated work units for material resources and career chances.22 Chinese urban society was organized as a hierarchy, in which each work organization functioned as a social “unit” in the system dominated by the state. Indeed, membership in a danwei was an important sign of social status and an important vehicle for status attainment and social mobility.23
Not all work units were equal. Resources at a work unit’s disposal were contingent upon its sector, ownership and bureaucratic rank in the redistributive hierarchy.24 First, government and Party agencies were de facto redistributors, and enterprises were required to submit most profits to central planners. Second, ownership type was an important criterion in resource distribution. The redistributive system favoured state-owned work units because they were considered the base of the communist regime. State-owned work units had priority in acquiring resources from the government to provide housing and subsidized coupons for their employees. Finally, each work unit had a rank which could strengthen its ability to gain resources from the state. The higher the work unit’s rank, the closer it was to the central planner, and thereby the more power it had in bargaining with government offices.25
Material compensations to employees provided by work units included both salaries and in-kind goods and services. After the 1956 wage reform, workers’ salaries were rigidly regulated by the government.26 Each person was given a rank in the wage ladder based on his or her occupational status, seniority and administrative position. The unified and centralized wage policies applied to all workers (called the eight-grade payment system), with some adjustments governed by clear rules.27 There was not much leeway for a work unit to pay its employees higher cash salaries than another work unit. Most inequalities under socialism were caused by the unequal distribution of in-kind goods and services such as housing, retirement insurance, medical care, social services and other welfare programmes among different types of work units at various ranks.28 In an economy of scarcity, access to these goods and services was more important than cash income and could be made available only through work units on the basis of their sector, ownership type and bureaucratic rank.
Economic reform and the transformation of danwei
The market-oriented reform that began in 1984 in urban areas has fundamentally transformed the redistributive system described above. One of the objectives of the Chinese economic reform was to restructure state-owned enterprises and improve their economic competitiveness.29 As a part of the decentralization process, enterprises had secured some discretionary decision-making power from the state and gradually evolved into economic entities with relative autonomy, especially with respect to rights pertaining to profit-retaining and distribution. Firms could decide their own forms of bonus distribution.30 Accordingly, a significant part of workers’ income was freed from the rigid salary system mandated by the state and subject to flexible adjustment supposedly reflecting workers’ productivity.
The reformers’ initial goal was to link workers’ material rewards closely to productivity, which would in turn improve a firm’s business performance. However, the loosened control over firms had both expected and unexpected consequences. First, it quickly became clear that firms’ profitability depended on many external factors other than workers’ productivity. Such external factors included technology, competition (that is, whether a firm had a monopoly) and regional advantages (access to natural resources or foreign technology). Second, the patron–client relationship between managers and workers31 motivated firms to increase bonus payments to employees, often out of proportion to increases in productivity and profitability.32 This practice was curtailed by policy measures such as setting a ceiling on bonuses in the late 1970s and levying bonus taxes on state firms in the 1980s.33 Third, while initially intended as a supplementary payment, bonuses gradually became a main source of income, indeed constituting more than half of total income on average in the late 1980s and early 1990s.34 While base salaries remained largely regulated by the government, the ability to generate bonus funds and to reward employees varied considerably from one firm to another.35 Therefore, variation in bonuses had become a main source of inter-firm income inequality in reform-era China.36 Finally, the incentive system that originated in the industrial sector began to be emulated by work units in all other sectors, even those where profitability either cannot be measured or is simply not meaningful, such as government branch offices, schools, hospitals and research institutions.
When the state-mandated salaries became only a small proportion of workers’ total compensation in the industrial sectors, workers in other sectors lagging behind pressured their danwei to generate extra revenue and upgrade their living standards. This institutional competition forced all Chinese danwei to generate extra revenue (chuangshou ) via a subsidiary business (sanchan ) so that they could pay bonuses and living stipends to their employees. The payouts were dependent more on membership in a danwei than on direct participation in revenue generation. For example, a high school might open a restaurant and hire migrant workers as contract-employees. Income from the business would provide financial resources for the welfare of teachers at the school.
As a result, under economic reform Chinese work organizations became less dependent on the state. Paradoxically, however, at the same time Chinese workers became more dependent on their danwei for their financial well-being, as an increasingly large share of a worker’s income became discretionary and dependent on funds generated by the danwei. Thus, as in pre-reform China, cadres and employees at the same danwei shared a common interest in confronting the state to protect the extraction of resources from the danwei by the state. Work units had two avenues through which to expand their disposable resources: improve their efficiency and/or hide their discretionary revenues. A typical strategy was to establish new subsidiary firms (essentially with the state-owned assets) under legitimate excuses.37 Factories could lease empty offices for rent and could run shops, restaurants and even hotels. The revenues from these sources were often unaccountable to supervising agencies and largely retained at the work units’ discretion.38
This practice of generating extra revenues for the financial benefit of employees extended to all types of danwei (including government agencies and non-profit institutions), in the form of collective moonlighting that diverted them from their designated organizational functions. Many government bureaus abused their regulatory powers to benefit their own staff by imposing unauthorized surcharges and fines.39 Primary and middle schools began to charge students miscellaneous fees under different covers to generate extra funds to pay teachers. Even academic departments in universities had to run businesses and training programmes completely unrelated to their teaching and research missions. In short, all work units tried to take advantage of their own structural positions and generate revenue for their employees, transformed from “rank-seeking” under the old redistributive system to “rent-seeking” in the socialist mixed economy.40
Some of the economic activities mentioned above were legal and some were illegal, but most simply lacked transparency, accountability and regulation. The involvement of state-owned factories in service industries was seen as part of their diversification strategy when facing increasing environmental uncertainties, 41 whereas government agencies’ arbitrary fines and fees were termed as “organizational corruption.”42 All in all, the widespread danwei revenue-generating activities should be understood in the context of the need and opportunity during economic reform for work units to provide financial benefits to their own employees. This change tightened the relationship between the worker and the danwei. As a result Chinese work units developed distinctive organizational interests and become welfare entities with great autonomy. Hence within-danwei inequality is held at a low level relative to between-danwei inequality, which has substantially increased in the reform era. Work units’ financial situation, or “profitability,” has become a key factor in social stratification in contemporary China.
During the economic reform period, a newly expanding private sector became an alternative provider of resources and life chances outside the redistributive sector. While this change means the declining importance of state-regulated bureaucratic co-ordination, it does not mean the end of the danwei as a persistent agent of stratification in Chinese society. Given the historical importance and the cultural expectation of work units as a unique link between the state and society, the danwei as an institution could be reproduced even in the market economy. For instance, danwei-like institutional features could be observed even in newly emerging sectors such as privately owned high-tech firms in urban areas43 or industrialized villages in rural China.44 One important difference between danwei-like private firms and state-owned or state-controlled danwei is that income redistribution in the former is directly reflected in salaries and wages rather than hidden in bonuses and other forms of welfare benefits as in the latter.
Danwei profitability and income distribution
Early studies of the social consequences of market transition in China largely focused on the changing effects of human and political capital on income distribution among individual workers.45 Controversial findings on those effects have been used to support different theoretical arguments on whether redistribution as the mechanism of social stratification has been changed in China.46 Recent research demonstrates that the transition to a market economy has no intrinsic implications for returns to either human or political capital.47 The effect of individual characteristics is mediated by concrete institutions, among which the Chinese urban work unit is important.48 In this context, the transformation of the danwei and its role in affecting economic outcomes need to be brought back into the centre of social stratification research on contemporary urban China. Without a proper understanding of this institution, we cannot fully understand urban social inequalities in reform-era China.
To understand the role of the danwei, most of which are owned by the state, it is important to realize that maximization of profits is not their only objective. Otherwise, highly profitable danwei would be interested in keeping labour costs low by not redistributing the profit among employees, as they could easily replace their workers at lower remuneration at the market level. In fact, workers’ remuneration has been heavily shaped by the internal structure and management–labour relationship within work units. Despite policies in the early years of economic reform targeted at breaking the “big pot rice” (da guo fan), distributions of bonuses and other welfare benefits became a major part of the internal politics within work units.49
Structurally, danwei managers serve as intermediaries between the state and workers in contemporary China. In the pre-reform era, a dependency relationship developed between managers and workers50: managers needed co-operation from their workers, whereas workers depended on their shop-floor leaders and managers for evaluation and promotion. This patron–client relationship enabled workers to put pressure on their managers for wage reforms. After the decentralization during the economic reform there were contradictory demands on danwei managers, as they were expected to make workers more productive while at the same time take responsibility for their well-being. More often than not, managers chose to side with workers, at least in the early years of reform. Bonuses were often allocated relatively equally within work units to avoid disputes and to keep everyone happy, and extra fringe benefits were used as a means to enhance danwei identity and harmony.51 Moreover, it became the common expectation that managers would secure the retained funds and use them to upgrade workers’ living standards. The better they fulfilled the expectation, the more legitimacy and popularity they would gain as danwei leaders. This is reminiscent of the “father and mother” image of an ideal local official in imperial China.52
Indeed, to escape from state regulation it has been a popular practice among Chinese work units to establish a secret account for extra revenues from the collective moonlighting activities (small golden coffer, or xiao jinku ).53 The retained revenues were used to pay workers (including managers) directly in bonuses and indirectly in fringe benefits and other welfare. After economic reform, workers and staff became increasingly dependent upon extra income distributed openly or secretly by their work units. It has been estimated that such irregular earnings accounted for about one-third to 40 per cent of workers’ total income in the 1980s, and overtook normal salaries in the mid-1990s.54 To overcome limits set by the state on bonus payouts, work units were also creative in providing substantial fringe benefits to employees, ranging from daily necessities, such as meals, children’s education fees and home electronics, to apartments. Prior to economic reform, collective consumption had been a key characteristic of Chinese work units.55 In an economy of scarcity, such in-kind goods and services were unavailable outside the work unit system. Although in the reform era these goods also became available from the market, work units continued their practices to circumvent restrictions imposed by the state on the distribution of cash incomes.
Because of differences in work units’ abilities to generate bonuses, income inequality across work units became more pronounced.56 Consequently, earnings determination became more dependent on the organizational attributes of the employer than on the characteristics of individual employees. Earnings might vary significantly among people with the same level of education working at the same occupations solely because of their affiliations with organizations with different revenue-generating ability.57 In other words, there was a substantial premium for workers in a good work unit, and this premium was not market-driven or productivity-based but rather an entitlement. As a result, the economic relationship between workers and danwei has been strengthened since the late 1980s.58
The Research Question
The fundamental changes brought by economic reform in China raise important questions about the continuing relevance of work units in determining earnings among urban Chinese workers. After over two decades of reform, as the labour market has gradually matured, and voluntary and involuntary labour mobility increased, does the danwei continue to serve as a major agent of social stratification in urban China?
We attempt to answer this question in the following analysis of survey data collected in three Chinese cities – Shanghai, Wuhan and Xi’an – in 1999. Most previous studies of work units are based on evidence from the late 1980s and early 1990s. Our data from 1999 provide a better opportunity to examine the continuing relevance of danwei in determining earnings among urban Chinese workers at a time when fundamental changes in employment policy and labour relationships began to take place and the country was moving towards a more marketized economy. Without longitudinal data, we approximate the three intentionally-picked cities into a sequence based on degree of reform – from the most reformed Shanghai to the moderately reformed Wuhan to the least reformed Xi’an – and examine cross-city variations to address the impact of reform on the work unit in urban China. Appendix A presents three demographic and economic indicators for the three cities in 1999. By both the per-capita gross industrial output and the average wage level, intended to measure overall economic development and/or marketization, we observe the expected order of Shanghai–Wuhan–Xi’an. Capitalizing on these large geographic differences, we study the variation in the importance of work units across employment sectors to test the idea that the danwei less important for workers in the more marketized sectors (such as the private sector) than for those in less marketized sectors (such as the government administrative/service sector).
Data and Methods
This study uses data from a survey, “Study of family life in urban China,” which we conducted in the summer of 1999 in Shanghai, Wuhan and Xi’an. We also refer to the study as the “three-city survey.” In the survey we designed a few items that allowed us to address our specific research question.
At each of the research sites, the survey initially targeted a probability sample of 1,000 households, with a two-stage probability sampling method. At the first stage, 50 neighbourhood communities were randomly chosen in proportion to size. Within each community, 20 households were randomly chosen. A Kish table was used to select an adult respondent (18 years or older) within each selected household. If the person being interviewed was younger than 60, we first interviewed the person with Questionnaire A. We then interviewed one of their parents with Questionnaire A+, which was specifically tailored to the elderly. If the person initially selected was 60 years or older, we interviewed them with Questionnaire B, which is similar to Questionnaire A+ for elderly respondents. We then randomly selected one of their children for an interview with Questionnaire B+, which is very similar in content to Questionnaire A for adult respondents.
We pooled all respondents between the ages of 20 and 60 across the forms. We then further restricted the analysis to respondents who earned at least 1,000 yuan regular salary in 1998 and had valid responses to other variables (discussed below), regardless of whether they worked in the public or private sector. A focus on earnings as the outcome variable is appropriate, given its increasing prominence in the social stratification system in today’s China.59 After the restriction, we had a total of 1,771 cases.
The dependent variable in our statistical analysis is the natural logarithm of total annual earnings in 1998. The earnings are composed of three parts: monthly salary from regular job, monthly bonus and year-end bonus. The monthly salary and monthly bonus were multiplied by 12 to convert to annual salary and annual bonus. The independent variables in this study include the following: city in which the respondent resided and was interviewed, the highest education level attended, years of work experience, gender, cadre status for the job worked at the survey time in 1999, sector of the job worked at the survey time, and danwei’s financial situation for the job worked at the survey time. We present the descriptive statistics of the variables used in the study in Appendix B.
The cities are Shanghai (reference category), Wuhan and Xi’an. There were six categories of the highest education level attended: no schooling, primary school, junior high school, senior high school or technical senior high school, junior college, and four-year college or graduate school. This variable was obtained from a sequence of questions of respondents’ education history. Work experience was measured in years and was calculated by subtracting the year beginning the first job from the year ending the last job or from the survey year, 1999, for those who were still working. If the year ending the last job was missing, the year of retirement was used. For those who had never worked before, work experience was coded 0. Gender is a dichotomous variable, with male as the reference group. Cadre status is a dichotomous variable and was coded 1 if a person’s job at the survey time was a cadre at the rank of department level (ke ji ) or above, and 0 if it was below ke ji or not a cadre. Sector is a categorical variable with four groups: government or public sector (reference category), state-owned enterprise, collectively owned enterprise, and privately owned enterprise. There were a few cases (three) of peasant work or doing odd jobs without a unit, and these were excluded from the study. The information about work experience, cadre status and sector was obtained from questions about the respondent’s job history.
The key explanatory variable in this study pertains to a measure of danwei profitability. Respondents were asked the question: “Is the economic situation of your work unit much better, better, about the same, worse or much worse than that of other work units of this city?” Respondents were instructed to interpret danwei broadly, as the work unit that issued a “worker’s card” (gongzuo zheng ). It thus covers all types of work organizations, including government agencies, institutions, state firms, collective firms, and private firms for which there is no single objective measure of extra revenue generated. Obviously, the measure employed here is a very crude way to assess a danwei’s financial situation, as it is no more than a subjective assessment on the part of the respondent. To make things worse, it is possible that respondents’ assessment of their danwei’s financial situation could be influenced by the amount of earnings they receive, our dependent variable in this study. We refer to this variable as “danwei profitability,” which was really concerned with the financial condition of work units, because a government/Party agency is not supposed to generate profits. We reverse coded the variable so that a higher number/category represents more profitability. We used the measures in two specifications, as a set of dummy variables (with “much worse” as the reference category) and as an interval variable from 1 to 5.
We hasten to admit that respondents’ subjective assessment of their danwei’s financial situation is very crude. Two methodological issues are at stake. First, our subjective measure is prone to error. Second, the measurement error may not be innocuous, as it could be influenced by the amount of earnings received. While we realize the limitations of the measure, we believe that it provides useful information that will shed light on our research question. We comment on the two methodological issues as follows. First, while social scientists are often sceptical about subjective measures, empirical research has shown their validity. One good example is subjectively rated health, which is usually implemented with a question similar to our danwei profitability: “Would you say that your health in general is excellent, very good, good, fair or poor?” A recent study60 shows that this subjective measure is a very strong predictor of cause-specific mortality resulting from poor health. Second, while we cannot pin down the potential endogeneity problem of this measure, we think that it is the best measure currently available, and this article is, as far as we know, the first empirical study that examines how a danwei’s financial situation affects workers’ earnings. We believe that the endogeneity could not be so large as to account for all the observed association, and thus our analysis will provide some new information about the importance of a danwei’s financial situation to its workers’ earnings. Future research can confirm or refine the results if better data become available.
The statistical analyses proceed in three stages. In the first stage, we examine the amount of variance in earnings that can be explained by the danwei profitability measure, relative to amounts of variance explained by other variables. We do this both separately (variable by variable) and jointly in a regression analysis. Second, we examine the impact of danwei profitability on earnings, relative to those of other variables, in a regression framework. Third, we test the interaction effects of danwei profitability with city and sector of employment. The tests will reveal whether danwei profitability matters more in a more marketized region or sector than in a less marketized one. However, we caution that, if the measurement bias of our danwei profitability measure varies by city or sector, the results from this exercise are subject to alternative interpretations.
Results
We first present results that compare the explanatory power of different determinants of earnings. Table 1 contains entries for each of the main determinants of earnings considered in our study, in four separate columns. The first column, “DF,” is the degrees of freedom for a particular parameterization of an earnings determinant. A higher number represents a conservative parameterization and is expected to be associated with greater explanatory power. For example, we use danwei profitability both as a linear function (1 DF) and as a set of dummies (4 DF). The second column, “R2,” is the proportion of the variance in logged earnings that is explained by a determinant, without control of any other variables. In the third column, “ΔR2(1),” we give the net proportion of the variance explained by a determinant after the inclusion of danwei profitability in its linear form. Finally, the fourth column, “ΔR2(2),” represents the net proportion of the variance explained by a determinant after the inclusion of danwei profitability in its linear form and all the other predictors considered in the study.
Table 1.
Variables | DF | R2 | ΔR2(1) | ΔR2(2) |
---|---|---|---|---|
City | 2 | 17.47*** | 18.11*** | 19.12*** |
Education level | 5 | 7.82*** | 5.49*** | 4.46*** |
Experience+experience2 | 2 | 0. 23 | 0.17 | 0.05 |
Gender | 1 | 4.78*** | 4.84*** | 3.05*** |
Cadre status | 1 | 3.08*** | 2.27*** | 0.63*** |
Sector | 3 | 3.54*** | 2.18*** | 1.80*** |
Danwei profitability (linear) | 1 | 12.52*** | 9.30*** | |
Danwei profitability (dummies) |
4 | 12.89*** | ||
N = 1771 |
Notes: DF refers to degrees of freedom. ΔR2(1) refers to the incremental R2 after the inclusion of Danwei’s financial situation (linear). ΔR2(2) refers to the incremental R2 after the inclusion of all the other variables.
p< 0.001
p<0.01
p<0.05, based on F-tests.
Source: 1999 Three-City Survey.
The first line of Table 1 confirms the earlier finding of Xie and Hannum61 and Hauser and Xie62 that there is a large regional variation in earnings. In our three-city study, the average differences across the three cities (represented by two dummy variables) explain the largest amount of variance. They alone account for 17.47 per cent of the variance. Furthermore, the large explanatory power of city is not attributable to any other variables, as both ΔR2(1) and ΔR2(2) are larger, rather than smaller, than the bivariate R2 reported in the second column.
The second most powerful explanatory determinant is danwei profitability. With the dummy variable specification, it alone accounts for 12.89 per cent of the variance. With the (1 DF) linear specification, it alone accounts for 12.52 per cent of the variance. Part of the explanatory power is attributable to other variables considered here. In the last column, where we control for all the other predictors, the incremental explanatory power, ΔR2(2), is 9.30 per cent. This is expected, as workers with higher human capital endowments are likely to be employed by more profitable danwei. However, even in the last column, which controls for all the other covariates, danwei profitability remains the second most important determinant after city.
The very large portions of the variance in logged earnings explained by city and danwei profitability are particularly striking when compared to those determinants of earnings in a conventional Mincer-type63 human capital model discussed extensively for the Chinese context by Xie and Hannum.64 Education level, gender, cadre status and sector all hold explanatory power, with that of education most significant. The five dummy variables representing different levels of education explain 7.82 per cent of the variance alone, and 4.46 per cent of the variance net of the other variables. Surprisingly, work experience does not contribute to the explanation of earnings. Gender, cadre status and sector all have modest explanatory power, ranging between 2 and 5 per cent.
To ascertain the magnitudes of the various determinants of earnings, we present linear regression results with logged earnings as the dependent variable, in two sets of columns in Table 2. In the first set, “observed effects,” we give the estimated coefficients and standard errors for separate regressions in which a determinant is the only predictor. In the second set, “adjusted effects,” we give the estimated regression coefficients and standard errors for different determinants in a single, multivariate regression. The comparison between the two sets tells us whether some of the observed effects in the bivariate models may work through other determinants. Given that the dependent variable is logged earnings, the exponential transformation of a coefficient indicates the change in earnings in ratio associated with one unit change in the predictor. For a dummy variable predictor, the exponential transformation of the coefficient indicates the ratio in earnings of the included category relative to the excluded category.
Table 2.
Variables | Observed effects | Adjusted effects | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
β | SE(β) | β | SE(β) | |
City (Shanghai=excluded) | ||||
Wuhan | −0.465*** | 0.033 | −0.539*** | 0.028 |
Xi’an | −0.628*** | 0.034 | −0.658*** | 0.028 |
Constant | 9.402*** | 0.024 | ||
Education level (no schooling=excluded) | ||||
Primary | 0.536* | 0.216 | 0.414* | 0.170 |
Junior high | 0.737*** | 0.202 | 0.447** | 0.161 |
Senior high | 0.770*** | 0.201 | 0.592*** | 0.161 |
Junior college | 1.049*** | 0.203 | 0.778*** | 0.162 |
College | 1.253*** | 0.207 | 0.923*** | 0.166 |
Constant | 8.120*** | 0.210 | ||
Experience+experience2 | ||||
Experience (×1000) | −11.235 | 6.029 | 2.421 | 4.775 |
Experience2 (×1000) | 0.288* | 0.144 | −0.017 | 0.114 |
Constant | 9.113*** | 0.059 | ||
Gender (male=excluded) | ||||
Female | −0.276*** | 0.029 | −0.225*** | 0.023 |
Constant | 9.144*** | 0.019 | ||
Cadre status (non-cadre=excluded) | ||||
Cadre | 0.375*** | 0.050 | 0.185*** | 0.042 |
Constant | 8.992*** | 0.015 | ||
Sector (government+public=excluded) | ||||
State-owned | −0.133*** | 0.037 | −0.043 | 0.030 |
Collectively owned | −0.397*** | 0.057 | −0.224*** | 0.045 |
Privately owned | 0.027 | 0.047 | 0.114** | 0.037 |
Constant | 9.129*** | 0.031 | ||
Danwei profitability (linear) | 0.256*** | 0.016 | 0.227*** | 0.013 |
Constant | 8.270*** | 0.050 | ||
Danwei profitability (dummies) (very poor=excluded) | ||||
Relatively poor | 0.100 | 0.062 | ||
Average | 0.405*** | 0.054 | ||
Fairly good | 0.702*** | 0.059 | ||
Very good | 0.918*** | 0.108 | ||
Constant | 8.624*** | 0.050 | ||
Constant | 8.237*** | 0.171 | ||
R2 (N = 1771) | 43.92% |
Notes: Observed effects on logged earnings are derived from bivariate models. Adjusted effects are derived from a multivariate model including all variables.
p<0.001
p<0.01
p<0.05, based on two-sided t-tests.
Let us interpret the results from the bivariate models first. As expected, workers earn much less in Wuhan and Xi’an than in Shanghai. The earnings ratio between Wuhan and Shanghai is 0.628 (exp(−0.465)), and that between Xi’an and Shanghai is 0.534 (exp(−0.628)). This pattern confirms our prior expectation that Shanghai is more developed than Wuhan, and Wuhan is more developed than Xi’an. The estimated education coefficients also confirm the expectation, as higher earnings are associated with higher levels of education. Relative to workers without formal education, those with a senior high school education earn 2.16 times as much, and those with a college education earn 3.5 times as much. Women workers face a disadvantage of about 24 per cent, whereas cadres enjoy an advantage of 45 per cent. The sector differences favour workers in the government and public sectors, as well as those in the private sector, with workers in collectively owned firms at a severe disadvantage (33 per cent), and those in state-owned firms at a smaller disadvantage (12 per cent).
Of particular interest in Table 2 are the coefficients of danwei profitability. We use two specifications, a dummy variable specification (which is conservative) and a linear specification (which is parsimonious). The F-test between the two specifications is 2.56 (for 3, 1,766 degrees of freedom), which is statistically insignificant. The results of the linear specification show that a one-unit increase in the danwei profitability scale (which varies from 1 to 5) is associated with a 30 per cent increase in earnings. This number is close to the separate increments associated with the dummy variable coefficients for the danwei profitability measure. In the multivariate model of Table 2 and interactive models of Table 3, we use the linear specification for simplicity.
Table 3.
Variables |
Danwei profitability*city |
Danwei profitability*sector |
||
---|---|---|---|---|
β | SE(β) | β | SE(β) | |
Constant | 8.180*** | 0.179 | 8.368*** | 0.196 |
City (Shanghai=excluded) | ||||
Wuhan | −0.498*** | 0.099 | −0.538*** | 0.028 |
Xi’an | −0.495*** | 0.100 | −.659*** | 0.028 |
Education level (no schooling=excluded) | ||||
Primary | 0.401* | 0.171 | 0.418* | 0.171 |
Junior high | 0.438** | 0.161 | 0.449** | 0.161 |
Senior high | 0.580*** | 0.161 | 0.594*** | 0.161 |
Junior college | 0.768*** | 0.162 | 0.781*** | 0.163 |
College | 0.911*** | 0.166 | 0.926*** | 0.166 |
Experience+experience2 | ||||
Experience (×1000) | 2.186 | 4.776 | 2.506 | 4.789 |
Experience2 (×1000) | −0.015 | 0.114 | −0.018 | 0.114 |
Gender (male=excluded) | ||||
Female | −0.225*** | 0.023 | −0.226*** | 0.023 |
Cadre status (non-cadre=excluded) | ||||
Cadre | 0.186*** | 0.042 | 0.186*** | 0.042 |
Sector (government+public=excluded) | ||||
State-owned | −0.042 | 0.030 | −0.202 | 0.122 |
Collectively owned | −0.223*** | 0.045 | −0.402* | 0.161 |
Privately owned | 0.112** | 0.024 | −0.024 | 0.142 |
Danwei profitability (linear) | 0.251*** | 0.024 | 0.184*** | 0.034 |
Danwei profitability (linear)*city | ||||
*Wuhan | −0.014 | 0.032 | ||
*Xi’an | −0.055 | 0.033 | ||
Danwei profitability (linear)*sector | ||||
*State-owned | 0.052 | 0.038 | ||
*Collectively owned | 0.059 | 0.053 | ||
*Privately owned | 0.044 | 0.045 | ||
R2 (N = 1771) | 44.02% | 43.98% |
Notes: Coefficients are estimated from a multivariate model including all variables.
p< 0.001
p<0.01
p<0.05, based on two-sided t-tests.
Because the various predictors of earnings are correlated, they do not exert independent effects. Thus, we include all the predictors in a multivariate model. We call the coefficients of the model “adjusted effects” and present them in the second set of columns in Table 2. There are differences between observed effects and adjusted effects. One surprise is that the estimated differences between Shanghai and the other two cities are enhanced rather than diminished in the multivariate case. The pattern associated with education levels remains strong but becomes less pronounced. The gender difference is also narrowed. So are disadvantages associated with working in collectively owned and state-owned firms. One notable change is the sharp decline in the estimated advantage of cadre status, more than halved from 45 to 20 per cent. This shows that most of the observed advantage of cadres in the bivariate model is due to their possession of attributes associated with higher earnings, such as higher levels of education. Net of other factors, we now observe an advantage of working in the private sector (at 12 per cent). Finally, the advantage associated with working in a more profitable danwei declines only slightly from 29 per cent (exp(0.256)) to 25 per cent (exp(0.227)). This means that most of the earnings premium associated with working in a profitable danwei cannot be accounted for by workers’ observed attributes commonly associated with productivity (such as education and work experience). If we change the danwei profitability scale from 1 to 5, earnings increase by 2.5 times. Thus, the danwei profitability effect is very large.
As a final step of the data analysis, we go on to test the interaction effects between danwei profitability and two structural measures that approximate marketization: city and sector. We hypothesize that Shanghai is more marketized than Wuhan, and Wuhan is more marketized than Xi’an (see Appendix A). If marketization weakens the importance of the danwei in earnings determination, we would expect a significant difference in the effect of danwei profitability across the three cities. Similarly, we expect the following order from more marketization to less marketization among the sectors: privately owned, collectively owned, state-owned and government/public. Again, if marketization weakens the role of danwei, we would expect the significant interaction terms between danwei profitability and sector. We enter the two sets of interaction effects separately to the last multivariate model in Table 2. The coefficients of the interactive models are presented in Table 3. We observe that neither of the hypothesized interactions is significant. F-tests reveal that the interactions do not significantly improve the previous additive model. Taken together, the results show that the danwei continues to play a strong role in determining earnings among Chinese workers, irrespective of city and sector. In particular, they negate the hypothesis that the danwei is much less important in a more developed city than in a less developed city, or less important in a more marketized sector than in a less marketized sector.
Discussion: The Declining Significance of Danwei?
As discussed earlier, the danwei premium can only be sustained when labour mobility is limited,65 as was the case until recently. It was only in the late 1990s that the Chinese government began to change social conditions so as to facilitate labour mobility. One major impediment to labour mobility in the redistributive economy was housing, as housing allocation in pre-reform urban China was mainly tied to work units.66 The differentiation in resources across work units was also reflected in their employees’ housing conditions.67 In the 1980s, the government tried to reform the public housing system by raising rents and encouraging workers to purchase their apartments with subsidized payments. Changes were slow, and privatization of housing was limited.68 Most employees in the state sector continued to count on work units for apartments or improvements in their living conditions.69 Another impediment to labour mobility was the provision of social security through work units under the old redistributive system. Without a socialized security system, work units could not effectively fire employees, and employees were reluctant to risk leaving work units.70
In the late 1990s, economic reform began to change these conditions by weakening workers’ organizational dependence on their work units. First, in 1998 housing allocation began rapid marketization and privatization. A nationwide policy to commercialize the urban housing sector was implemented, and most public housing units were sold to their current occupants at discounted prices. Direct allocation of new housing units by danwei ceased. Workers had to use their own savings and bank mortgages to purchase apartments. The four largest banks in China provided at least 75 million home loans in 1998. Work units’ housing benefits, if provided, were incorporated into wages, from a few hundred to a few thousand yuan per month.71 Meanwhile, the delivery of other in-kind benefits and services increasingly took the form of lump-sum cash payments, as the state further lifted its salary control on work units.72
Social security (pension and medical care) has now been detached from the danwei and unified at the provincial level, and its coverage has been further extended to the private sector. Both employers and employees are required to make contributions to pension and medical care funds, with individuals maintaining separate accounts. When workers change jobs, their accounts remain the same. This reform has removed a hurdle for labour mobility, particularly into the private sector. Furthermore, social security reform has also made it possible for state work units to lay off workers. Since the mid-1990s, the rapid growth of the private sector and foreign investment has meant that state-owned enterprises, as the work units that shouldered “social responsibilities” on behalf of the state, have barely been able to sustain themselves in the market competition. As the Chinese government has increased its tolerance for unemployment, enterprises and managers are now granted more power to lay off workers or cut payments and benefits.73 The resulting massive layoff of state workers indicates that work units no longer serve as patrons to protect workers’ interests. Management–labour relationships have worsened, and the patron–client relationship that once characterized the unique Chinese work-unit institution has been turned into what some scholars have called “managerial despotism” in the late reform era.74
Nevertheless, scholars continued to observe the prominent role played by work units in urban China’s stratification during the reform era.75 Indeed, it has been argued that the importance of work units has increased, and the relationship between workers and their work units has ironically been strengthened since the late 1980s.76 Two explanations compete for the continuing importance of danwei in contemporary China. First, the continuing and perhaps increasing importance of work units was a result of the “partial” status of economic reform: while the decentralization policy has allowed work units to retain more resources, and the labour market and the social security systems are not yet fully functional, workers naturally rely more on their work units to upgrade their living standards.77 According to this view, as the reform proceeds and labour mobility increases, the significance of the danwei is expected to decline in the long term. Alternatively, it has been argued that the danwei system may be deeply rooted in Chinese history and culture, as well as the broader structure of socialist political economy.78
Earlier studies of urban China in the 1980s revealed that employees’ danwei mattered a great deal in earnings stratification in terms of organizational ownership, type and rank, which together determine the level of resources a danwei receives from the state.79 As the economic relationship between the state and the danwei is further restructured, the way a danwei affects earnings distribution is no longer necessarily tied to its position in the socialist redistributive hierarchy; instead, its financial performance plays a direct role in determining earnings. Our survey data do not contain measures of danwei bureaucratic rank. However, we did measure work units’ ownership and type by the variable “employment sector,” and our results show that these are much less important than danwei profitability in explaining earnings inequality in urban China (see Table 1). Hence, we show that the danwei still plays an important role in social stratification in contemporary China, but via a modified mechanism in the era of further economic reform.
Work units’ continued importance in determining income has been well known to policy makers in China. For example, an article calling for “Establishing an income distribution system in a society that is scientifically fair and just” was published in the Chinese government’s official news outlet, Xinhua Net.80 In its opening paragraph, it states: “‘Too large income disparity outside the system’ leads to income imbalances as well as psychological imbalances across regions, across industries, and across danwei, triggering certain unstable and insecure factors and interfering with the construction of a harmonious society.”
Viewed comparatively, the existing effect of work organization on income inequality may not be unique to transitional urban China. The relationship between work organizations and social stratification in market economies has been well documented in previous literature.81 Economic rewards and career opportunities are found to be associated with specific organizational attributes, typically size and sector.82 What is perhaps distinctive in the Chinese case is our observation that the danwei’s financial situation has an unusually large effect, second only to region/city. The extremely important roles of both danwei and region suggest that earnings in urban China are not determined exclusively by a labour market, but that unique structural factors external to the market serve to shape the social stratification of Chinese workers.
Conclusion
In this article, we argue that the danwei, the work unit, is still a main agent of social stratification in contemporary China. Specifically, using data from a 1999 survey we conducted in three large Chinese cities, Wuhan, Shanghai and Xi’an, we find that workers’ earnings depend heavily on their danwei’s profitability. Workers who are employed in a highly profitable danwei earn as much as 2.5 times those who are otherwise comparable but employed in a relatively unprofitable danwei. Further, we do not find that the importance of danwei profitability differs by city or by sector of employment, suggesting that this is a widespread phenomenon in contemporary urban China.
Why does the danwei, a legacy of the Chinese socialist economy, still remain an important agent of stratification in post-reform China? We do not have a satisfactory answer but are willing to offer a conjecture. We think that the key is that the Chinese economy is not necessarily moving to a true capitalist-market economy, which indeed does not exist even in the West. Economic reform in China has been heavily shaped by the pre-existing institutions prior to reform. For one thing, there are millions of cadres – professional, life-time bureaucrats who are part of an enormous state apparatus – who constitute the upper, or middle-upper, class.83 For another, many firms, regardless of ownership, as well as many individuals, make use of certain structural advantages for financial returns. There are no transparent ways to compete for such structural advantages.84 One way to mitigate and to justify the perceived unfairness resulting from structural advantages is to stratify income on the basis of danwei, a unit of economic entity.
The danwei’s continued importance has both a social and an economic basis. The social basis is that workers can rationally accept the danwei as a stratifying agent that affects their lives. When a danwei has economic resources, workers expect it to provide welfare. When a danwei does not have economic resources, workers seem to accept their ill fate in being paid poorly; otherwise they would change jobs to a more profitable danwei if they could. Because the link between danwei profitability and one’s economic welfare is commonly accepted, potential for public protest is mitigated if a particular danwei fails and causes its workers to become economically poor. The economic basis for danwei-based stratification is the continuing growth of the Chinese economy. The unequal redistribution generated by work units in the past was mostly a result of differential growth rather than of the unequal distribution of existing resources. Given the growth trajectory, it seems fair to workers to derive benefits from wealth generation that occurs at the local level by means of their danwei.
In sum, the danwei continues to play a very important role in determining the economic well-being of workers in urban China. It is used effectively by the Chinese government as a buffer, on the one hand against money loss from unprofitable state-owned firms and on the other hand against national-level redistribution of wealth and resources generated by business and administrative organizations. The widespread mass layoffs in state-owned enterprises in the 2000s may have weakened the traditional life-time dependency of employees on their danwei. However, this may only have changed the boundaries of who should be sheltered by a danwei rather than making the danwei irrelevant altogether. For those who remain in state-owned enterprises, the patron–client relationship may well persist into the future. As Chinese observers have commented,85 the danwei serves an important function of bridging the gap between individuals and the very large society of China as a whole. One possible scenario in the future is that a combination of social institutions, including work units and local governments as key components, will serve the needed function of intermediaries between the state on the one hand and individuals on the other. In this sense, the continuing importance of the danwei in contemporary China has a political dimension to characterize the Chinese economic transition. Thus, one cannot truly understand social stratification in China without properly understanding the important role played by the danwei.
Appendix
Appendix A.
1999 population (million) |
1999 per capita gross industrial output (yuan) |
1999 average wage (yuan) | |
---|---|---|---|
Shanghai | 13.13 | 30,728 | 16,641 |
Wuhan | 7.40 | 14,667 | 8,812 |
Xi’ans | 6.75 | 9,099 | 7,764 |
Source: China Data Online (2007).
Appendix
Appendix B.
Variable | Mean | Std. Dev. |
---|---|---|
Logged earnings | 9.027 | 0.624 |
City | ||
Shanghai | 0.312 | 0.463 |
Wuhan | 0.353 | 0.478 |
Xi’an | 0.335 | 0.472 |
Education level | ||
No schooling | 0.005 | 0.071 |
Primary school | 0.030 | 0.170 |
Junior high | 0.298 | 0.457 |
Senior high | 0.439 | 0.496 |
Junior college | 0.158 | 0.365 |
College | 0.071 | 0.256 |
Experience+experience2 | ||
Experience | 20.107 | 8.973 |
Experience squared | 484.752 | 375.857 |
Gender | ||
Male | 0.577 | 0.494 |
Female | 0.423 | 0.494 |
Cadre status | ||
Cadre | 0.094 | 0.292 |
Sector | ||
Government and public | 0.219 | 0.414 |
State-owned | 0.516 | 0.500 |
Collectively owned | 0.094 | 0.292 |
Privately owned | 0.172 | 0.377 |
Danwei profitability (linear) | 2.954 | 0.862 |
Danwei profitability (dummies) | ||
Very poor | 0.076 | 0.265 |
Relatively poor | 0.147 | 0.355 |
Average | 0.545 | 0.498 |
Fairly good | 0.211 | 0.408 |
Very good | 0.021 | 0.143 |
Footnotes
Paper presented at the International Conference on Chinese Society and China Studies, 26–27 May 2007, Nanjing, China. The research is supported by a research grant from the National Science Foundation, a Guggenheim Fellowship from the John Simon Guggenheim Memorial Foundation, and a Fogarty grant for international research from the National Institute of Child Health and Development. We thank Meichu Chen for her research assistance and Miranda Brown, Cindy Glovinsky, James Lee and Xi Song for their comments and suggestions on earlier drafts.
References
- 1.Hauser Seth, Xie Yu. Temporal and regional variation in earnings inequality: urban China in transition between 1988 and 1995. Social Science Research. 2005;Vol. 34:44–79. [Google Scholar]; Khan AzizurR, Riskin Carl. Income and inequality in China: composition, distribution and growth of household income, 1988 to 1995. The China Quarterly. 1998;(No.154):221–253. [Google Scholar]
- 2.Wu Ximing, Perloff Jeffrey. China’s income distribution, 1985–2001. Berkeley: University of California; CUDARE Working Papers. 2005 http://www.uoguelph.ca/~xiwu/china_wu&perloff.pdf.
- 3.For a review, see Bian Yanjie. Work and Authority in Urban China. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press; 2002.
- 4.For example, see Hauser, Xie Temporal and regional variation. :44–79.
- 5.Wu Xiaogang, Xie Yu. Does the market pay off? Earnings returns to education in urban China. American Sociological Review. 2003;Vol. 68:427. [Google Scholar]
- 6.Nee Victor. A theory of market transition: from redistribution to markets in state socialism. American Sociological Review. 1989;Vol. 54:663–681. [Google Scholar]; Nee Victor. Social inequalities in reforming state socialism; between redistribution to markets in China. American Sociological Review. 1991;Vol. 56:267–282. [Google Scholar]; Nee Victor. The emergence of a market society: changing mechanisms of stratification in China. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;Vol. 101:908–949. [Google Scholar]
- 7.Bian See Yanjie, Logan John. Market transition and persistence of power: the changing stratification system in urban China. American Sociological Review. 1996;Vol. 61:739–758. [Google Scholar]; Zhou Xueguang. Economic transformation and income inequality in urban China. American Journal of Sociology. 2000;Vol. 105:1135–1174. [Google Scholar]; Andrew G Walder. Markets and inequality in transitional economies: towards testable theories. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;Vol. 101:106–173. [Google Scholar]; Wu Xiaogang. Work units and income inequality: the effect of market transition in urban China. Social Forces. 2002;Vol. 80(No. 3):1069–1099. [Google Scholar]; Wu, Xie Does the market pay off? :425–442. [Google Scholar]; Xie Yu, Hannum Emily. Regional variation in earnings’ inequality in reform-era urban China. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;Vol. 102:950–992. [Google Scholar]
- 8.Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992. [Google Scholar]
- 9.Wu Xiaogang. Work units [Google Scholar]
- 10.Nee The emergence of a market society. :908–949. [Google Scholar]; Nee Victor, Mathews Rebecca. Market transition and societal transformation in reforming state socialism. Annual Review of Sociology. 1996;Vol. 22:401–436. [Google Scholar]; Andrew G Walder. Markets and inequality in rural China. American Journal of Sociology. 2002;Vol. 67:231–253. [Google Scholar]
- 11.Hauser, Xie Temporal and regional variation. :44–79. [Google Scholar]
- 12.Ibid.
- 13.Ibid. Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992.
- 14.Jean C Oi. The role of the local state in China’s Transitional Economy. The China Quarterly. 1995;(No. 144):1137. [Google Scholar]
- 15.Jean C Oi. Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of local state corporatism in China. World Politics. 1992;Vol 45(No. 1):99–126. [Google Scholar]
- 16.Walder Andrew G. Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese Industry. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1986. [Google Scholar]
- 17.Zhao Renwei. Three features of the distribution of inequality in social distribution. In: Griffin K, Zhao Renwei, editors. The Distribution of Income In China. New York: St Martin’s Press; 1993. pp. 74–94. [Google Scholar]
- 18.Walder Communist Neo-Traditionalism [Google Scholar]
- 19.Kornai Janos. Contradictions and Dilemmas: Studies on the Socialist Economy and Society. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press; 1986. [Google Scholar]
- 20.Bian . Urban Life in Contemporary China. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1984. Work and Authority; Walder, Communist Neo-Traditionalism; Martin K. Whyte and William Parish. [Google Scholar]
- 21.Naughton Barry. Danwei: the economic foundations of a unique institution. In: Lü Xiaobo, Perry Elizabeth., editors. Danwei: The Changing Chinese Workplace in Historical and Comparative Perspective. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe; 1997. pp. 169–194. [Google Scholar]; Hussain Athar. The social role of the Chinese state enterprises. In: Warner Malcolm., editor. Changing Workplace Relations in the Chinese Economy. London: Macmillan Press; 2000. [Google Scholar]
- 22.Walder Communist Neo-Traditionalism; Walder, “Property rights and stratification in socialist redistributive economies,”. American Sociological Review. 1992;Vol. 57:524–539. [Google Scholar]
- 23.Lin Nan, Bian Yanjie. Getting ahead in urban China. American Journal of Sociology. 1991;Vol. 97:657–688. [Google Scholar]
- 24.Bian Yanjie. Danwei Zhongguo (Danwei China) Tianjin: Tianjin renmin chubanshe; 2000. Work and Authority; Jianjun Liu. [Google Scholar]
- 25.Bian Yanjie. In: Work and Authority. Li Lulu, Li Hanlin, danwei zuzhi Zhongguode., editors. Hangzhou: Zhejian renmin chubanshe; 2000. (China’s Work Unit Organization) [Google Scholar]; Walder Communist Neo-Traditionalism; Walder, “Property rights and stratification in socialist redistributive economies,”. American Sociological Review. 1992;Vol. 57:524–539. [Google Scholar]
- 26.Walder Andrew G. Wage reform and the web of factory interests. The China Quarterly. 1987;(No. 109):22–41. [Google Scholar]; Yuan Zhigang, Fang Ying. Zhongguo jiuye zhidu de bianqian (The Change of Employment System in China 1978–1998) Taiyuan: Shanxi jingji chubanshe; 1998. [Google Scholar]
- 27.You Ji. China’s Enterprise Reform: Changing State/Society Relationship after Mao. London & New York: Routledge; 1998. [Google Scholar]; Korzec Michel, Whyte MartinKing. Reading notes: the Chinese wage system. The China Quarterly. 1981;(No. 86):248–273. [Google Scholar]
- 28.Walder Property Rights. :524–539. [Google Scholar]
- 29.You Ji. China’s Enterprise Reform [Google Scholar]
- 30.Ibid.
- 31.Walder Communist Neo-Traditionalism [Google Scholar]
- 32.Walder Wage reform. :22–41. [Google Scholar]
- 33.You Ji. China’s Enterprise Reform [Google Scholar]
- 34. Bian See, Logan Market transition. :739–758. Khan Azizur Rahman, Griffin Keith, Riskin Carl, Zhao Renwei. Household income and its distribution in China. The China Quarterly. 1992;(No. 132):1029–1061. Khan Azizur R, Riskin Carl. Inequality and Poverty in China in the Age of Globalization. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001. Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992. Indeed the survey data collected in China since the 1990s have rarely made a distinction between base salaries and bonuses as the latter constitute an even greater proportion of earnings.
- 35.Walder Andrew G. Economic reform and income distribution in Tianjin, 1976–1986. In: Davis D, Vogel EF, editors. Chinese Society on the Eve of Tiananmen: the Impact of Reform. Cambridge, MA: East Asian Council, Harvard University; [Google Scholar]; Wu Xiaogang. Work units. :1069–1099. [Google Scholar]
- 36.Zhao Renwei. Three features. :74–94. [Google Scholar]
- 37.Guthrie Douglas. Dragon in a Three-Piece Suit. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; 1999. [Google Scholar]
- 38.You Ji. China’s Enterprise Reform. :129–130. [Google Scholar]
- 39.Lü Xiaobo. From rank-seeking to rent-seeking: changing administrative ethos and corruption in reform China. Crime, Law and Social Change. 1999;Vol. 32(No. 4):347–370. [Google Scholar]
- 40.Ibid.
- 41.Guthrie See Douglas. Between market and politics: organizational responses to reform in China. American Journal of Sociology. Vol. 102:1258–1304. Guthrie, Dragon in a Three-Piece Suit. [Google Scholar]
- 42.Lü Xiaobo. From rank-seeking. :347–370. [Google Scholar]
- 43.Francis Corinna-Barbara. Reproduction of danwei institutional features in the context of China’s market economy: the case of Haidian district’s high-tech sector. The China Quarterly. 1996;(No. 147):839–859. [Google Scholar]
- 44.Lin Nan. Local market socialism: local corporatism in action in rural China. Theory and Society. 1995;Vol. 24:301–354. [Google Scholar]
- 45.Bian, Logan Market transition. :739–758. [Google Scholar]; Hauser, Xie Temporal and regional variation. :44–79. [Google Scholar]; Nee A theory of market transition. :663–681. [Google Scholar]; Nee Social inequalities. :267–282. [Google Scholar]; Nee The emergence of a market society. :908–949. [Google Scholar]; Parish William L, Michelson Ethan. Politics and markets: dual transformations. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;Vol. 101:1042–1059. [Google Scholar]; Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992. [Google Scholar]
- 46.Szelényi Ivan, Kostello Eric. The market transition debate: toward a synthesis. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;Vol. 101:1082–1096. [Google Scholar]
- 47.Gerber Theodore. Structural change and post-socialist stratification: labor market transitions in contemporary Russia. American Journal of Sociology. 1997;Vol. 102:1258–1304. [Google Scholar]; Walder Markets and inequality in transitional economies. :106–173. [Google Scholar]; Wu, Xie Does the market pay off? :425–442. [Google Scholar]
- 48.Wu Xiaogang. Work units. :1069–1099. [Google Scholar]
- 49.Dittmer Lowell, Lü Xiaobo. Personal politics in the Chinese danwei under reform. Asian Survey. 1996;Vol. 36:246–267. [Google Scholar]
- 50.Walder Communist Neo-Traditionalism [Google Scholar]
- 51.Walder Wage reform. :22–41. [Google Scholar]; Economic reform and income distribution. :135–156. [Google Scholar]
- 52.Liu Jianjun. Danwei China. :101. [Google Scholar]; Will Pierre-Étienne. In: Bureaucracy and Famine in Eighteenth-Century China. Forster Elborg., editor. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 1990. tr. [Google Scholar]
- 53.Yang Xiaomin, Zhou Yihu. Zhongguo danwei zhidu (China’s Danwei System) Beijing: China Economy Press; 1999. [Google Scholar]
- 54. Huang Weituan. Zhongguo yinxing jingji (China’s Hidden Economy) Beijing: Zhongguo shangye chubanshe; 1992. You Ji. China’s Enterprise Reform. :130. also see n. 34
- 55.Bian . Work and Authority; Athar Hussain, “The social role of the Chinese state enterprises,”. In: Warner Malcolm., editor. Changing Workplace Relations in the Chinese Economy. London: Macmillan Press; 2000. [Google Scholar]
- 56.Zhao Renwei. Three features. :74–94. [Google Scholar]
- 57.Ibid. Zhao Zhenyu. Guanyu shehui fenpei chaju de jige wenti (“On several issues of inequality in social distribution”) Shehui kexue zhanxian (Frontier of Social Science) 1994;Vol. 1:112–121.
- 58.Naughton Danwei. :169–194. [Google Scholar]
- 59.Also see Wu, Xie Does the market pay off? :425–442. Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992.
- 60.Benjamins Maureen Reindl, Hummer Robert A, Eberstein Isaac W, Nam Charles B. Self-reported health and adult mortality risk: an analysis of cause-specific mortality. Social Science Research. 2004;Vol. 59:1297–1306. doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2003.01.001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 61.Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992. [Google Scholar]
- 62.Hauser, Xie Temporal and regional variation. :44–79. [Google Scholar]
- 63.Mincer Jacob. Schooling, Experience and Earnings. New York: Columbia University Press; 1974. [Google Scholar]
- 64.Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992. [Google Scholar]
- 65.Naughton Danwei. :169–194. [Google Scholar]
- 66.Yang, Zhou China’s Danwei System [Google Scholar]
- 67.Bian Yanjie, Logan John R, Lu Hanlong, Wang Ying. Work units and housing reform in two Chinese cities. In: Lü, Perry, editors. Danwei. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe; 1997. pp. 223–250. [Google Scholar]
- 68.Zang Xiaowei. Urban housing reforms in China. In: Zang X, editor. China in the Reform Era. Commack, NY: Nova Science Publishers; 1999. pp. 49–79. [Google Scholar]
- 69.Yang, Zhou China’s Danwei System [Google Scholar]
- 70.Ibid.
- 71.Zang Xiaowei. Urban housing reforms. :49–79. [Google Scholar]
- 72.Yang, Zhou China’s Danwei System [Google Scholar]
- 73.Cook Sarah. Readjusting labor: enterprise restructuring, social consequences and policy response in urban China. In: Warner M, editor. Changing Workplace Relations in the Chinese Economy. London: McMillan; 2000. pp. 227–246. [Google Scholar]
- 74.Lee Ching Kwan. From organized dependence to disorganized despotism: changing labour relations in Chinese factories. The China Quarterly. 1999;(No. 157):44–71. [Google Scholar]
- 75.Wu Xiaogang. Work units. :1069–1099. [Google Scholar]; Xie, Hannum Regional variation. :950–992. [Google Scholar]; Zhou Xueguang. Economic transformation. :1135–1174. [Google Scholar]
- 76.Naughton Danwei. :169–194. [Google Scholar]
- 77.Ibid.
- 78.Liu Jianjun. Danwei China [Google Scholar]
- 79.Bian Work and Authority; Walder, Communist Neo-Traditionalism; Walder, “Property rights,”. :524–539. [Google Scholar]
- 80.Zeng Xiangquan, Ying Yue. Jianli kexue heli gongping gongzheng de shehui shouru fenpei tixi. [Accessed 24 November 2007];Establishing an income distribution system in a society that is scientifically fair and just. Xinhua Net 2006–07–14. http://news.xinhuanet.com/theory/2006-07/14/content_4831556.htm. [Google Scholar]
- 81.Baron James. Organizational perspectives on stratification. Annual Review of Sociology. 1984;Vol. 10:37–69. [Google Scholar]; Kalleberg Arne L. Comparative perspectives on work structure and inequality. Annual Review of Sociology. 1988;Vol. 14:203–225. [Google Scholar]; Kalleberg Arne, Sorensen Aage B. The sociology of labor markets. Annual Review of Sociology. 1979;Vol. 5:351–379. [Google Scholar]
- 82.For example Barn James N, Bielby William T. Bring the firms back in: stratification, segmentation, and the organization of work. American Sociological Review. 1980;Vol. 45:737–765. Kalleberg Arne L, Wallace Michael, Althauser Robert. Economic segmentation, worker power, and income inequality. American Journal of Sociology. 1981;Vol. 87:651–683. Kalleberg Comparative perspectives. :203–225.
- 83.Lu Xueyi., editor. Dangdai Zhongguo shehui jieceng yanjiu baogao (A Research Report on the Social Stratification in Contemporary China) Beijing: Social Science Documents Press; 2002. [Google Scholar]
- 84.Zhao Renwei. Three features. :74–94. [Google Scholar]; Zhao Zhenyu. On several issues. :112–121. [Google Scholar]
- 85.Liu Jianjun. Danwei China; Liping Sun, Zhuanxin yu duanlie (Transition and Breakup) Beijing: Qinghua University Press; 2004. [Google Scholar]