Abstract
The global financial crisis of 2007–2009 exposed critical weaknesses in the financial system. Many proposals for financial reform address the need for systemic regulation—that is, regulation focused on the soundness of the whole financial system and not just that of individual institutions. In this paper, we study one particular problem faced by a systemic regulator: the tension between the distribution of assets that individual banks would like to hold and the distribution across banks that best supports system stability if greater weight is given to avoiding multiple bank failures. By diversifying its risks, a bank lowers its own probability of failure. However, if many banks diversify their risks in similar ways, then the probability of multiple failures can increase. As more banks fail simultaneously, the economic disruption tends to increase disproportionately. We show that, in model systems, the expected systemic cost of multiple failures can be largely explained by two global parameters of risk exposure and diversity, which can be assessed in terms of the risk exposures of individual actors. This observation hints at the possibility of regulatory intervention to promote systemic stability by incentivizing a more diverse diversification among banks. Such intervention offers the prospect of an additional lever in the armory of regulators, potentially allowing some combination of improved system stability and reduced need for additional capital.
Keywords: financial stability, global financial markets, financial regulation
The recent financial crises have led to worldwide efforts to analyze and reform banking regulation. Although debate continues as to the causes of the crises, a number of potentially relevant factors have been identified. Financial regulation was unable to keep pace with financial innovation (1, 2), was fragmented in its nature (2), and did not address important conflicts of interest (1, 3–7). More generally, an issue raised by the crises is that of individual vs. systemic risk: regulation was focused on the health of individual firms rather than the stability of the financial system as a whole (1, 2, 4, 8–10). In this paper, we investigate a particular issue that, although not necessarily at the heart of the recent crises, is of great relevance given the newly found interest in systemic regulation. Specifically, we explore the relationship between the risks taken by individual banks and the systemic risk of essentially simultaneous failure of multiple banks.
In this context, we use a deliberately oversimplified toy model to illuminate the tensions between what is best for individual banks and what is best for the system as a whole. Any bank can generally lower its probability of failure by diversifying its risks. However, when many banks diversify in similar ways, they are more likely to fail jointly. This joint failure creates a problem given the tendency for systemic costs of failure to grow disproportionately with the number of banks that fail. The financial system can tolerate isolated failures, but when many banks fail at one time, the economy struggles to absorb the impact, with serious consequences (11–13). Thus, the regulator faces a dilemma: should she allow banks to maximize individual stability, or should she require some specified degree of differentiation for the sake of greater system stability? In banking, as in many other settings, choices that may be optimal for the individual actors may be costly for the system as a whole (14), creating excessive systemic fragility.
Our work complements an existing theoretical literature on externalities (or spillovers) across financial institutions that impact systemic risk (15–32). Much of this literature has focused on exploring liability-side interconnections and how, although these facilitate risk-sharing, they can also create the conditions for contagion and fragility. For instance, some researchers have shown the potential for bankruptcy cascades to take hold, destabilizing the system by creating a contagion of failure (20, 26). When one firm fails, this failure has an adverse impact on those firms to whom it is connected in the network, potentially rendering some of these susceptible to failure. Most obviously affected are those firms to whom the failed institution owes money, but also, the firm's suppliers and even those companies that depend on it for supplies can be put in vulnerable positions. Another insightful strand of research has emphasized the potential for other forms of interdependence to undermine systemic stability, irrespective of financial interconnections: fire sales of assets by distressed institutions can lead to liquidity crises (28). In a very recent approach, the financial crisis is understood as a banking panic in the “sale and repurchase agreement” (repo) market (33). Other recent studies have drawn insights from areas such as ecology, epidemiology, and engineering (34–39).
The present paper builds on the early work by Shaffer (22) and Acharya (23) to explore the systemic costs that attend asset-side herding behavior. Other recent contributions in this direction have considered situations where assets seem uncorrelated in normal times but can suddenly become correlated as a result of margin requirements (refs. 29 and 32 have comprehensive reviews of relevant contributions). In the current work, we use the simplest possible model to investigate other systemic and regulatory implications of asset-side herding, thereby knowingly side-stepping these and many other potential features of real world financial networks. We do not claim that asset-side externalities were at the center of the recent crisis or were more important than other contributory factors. Also, we do not take any position on the extent to which the asset price fluctuations that we consider are because of external economic conditions altering the fair value of certain assets, fire sale effects temporarily depressing the value of assets, price bubbles leading to banks overpaying for assets whose prices subsequently collapse when the bubble bursts, general loss of confidence because of uncertainty, global economic imbalances, or other factors. Rather, we study asset-side herding, because it can have very important and not fully explored implications. Possible extensions of our work are discussed in SI Text.
We present a framework for understanding the tradeoffs between individual and systemic risk, quantifying the potential costs of herding and benefits of diverse diversification. We then show how systemic risk can be largely captured by two directly observable features of a set of bank allocations: the average distance between the banks in the allocation space and the balance of the allocations (i.e., distance from the average allocation to the individually optimal allocation). We hope that our work may offer insight to policy makers by providing a set of tools for exploring this particular facet of systemic risk.
Model
Consider a highly stylized world, with N banks and M assets. An asset here can be considered as something in which a bank can invest and that can inflict losses or gains proportional to the level of investment. At time t = 0, each bank chooses how to allocate its investments across the asset classes. At some later time, t = 1, the change in value of each asset is drawn randomly from some distribution. All assets are assumed to be independent and identically distributed. A bank has then failed if its total losses exceed a given threshold. We recognize that many other factors may cause bank failures, including fire sale effects, interconnections between banks, liquidity issues, and general loss of confidence, but these issues are not the focus of the present work.
For illustrative simplicity, we will take the asset price fluctuations to be drawn from a student t distribution with 1.5 degrees of freedom, a long-tailed distribution often used in financial models (40, 41). The distribution is additionally specified by a probability p that a bank will fail if all its investments are in a single asset class. As we will show, our main findings seem remarkably robust to changes in the detailed assumptions used, including the choice of distribution and the probability p.
We define Xij as the allocation of bank i to asset j. We also define Vj as the loss in value between time t = 0 and t = 1 of asset j (with negative losses representing profits) drawn from a student t distribution as described above. The total loss incurred by bank i at time t = 1 is, thus, . Bank i is then said to have failed if Yi > γi (that is, if its total losses exceed a given threshold γi set by its capital buffer). Additional model details are in SI Text.
Results
We now examine the outcomes of this system. Fig. 1A illustrates how the probability of individual bank failure depends on the allocation between two asset classes when p = 10%. The individually optimal allocation for any given bank, in the sense of minimizing risk for expected return, is to distribute equal amounts into each asset class. We call this individually optimal allocation O*, and we call the associated probability of individual failure p*. When all banks are at the individual optimum, we call the configuration uniform diversification, because all banks adopt a common diversification strategy. Uniform diversification, thus, represents a state of the banks maximally herding together in the sense of adopting the same set of exposures. Readers familiar with the standard finance literature will recognize these allocations as those allocations selected under modern portfolio theory (42).
Fig. 1B illustrates the probability of total system failure in this system of two banks, pSF (i.e., the probability that both banks fail simultaneously). Unlike individual failure, we find that the probability of joint failure is not minimized by uniform diversification. Instead, a reduction in the probability of joint failure can be achieved by moving the banks away from each other in the space of assets. Indeed, the minimal probability of joint failure is achieved by having each bank invest solely in its own unique asset, which we will call full specialization. Thus, we observe a tension between what is best for an individual bank and what is safest for the system as a whole. The regulator faces a dilemma: should she allow institutions to maximize their individual stability or regulate to safeguard stability of the system as a whole?
To explore this dilemma, we introduce a stylized systemic cost function c = ks, where k is the number of banks that fail and s ≥ 1 is a parameter describing the degree to which systemic costs escalate nonlinearly as the number of failed banks increases. When many banks fail simultaneously, private markets struggle to absorb the impact. Instead, society incurs real losses, and the economy's long-term potential may be affected (13). Our particular choice of cost function is, of course, an illustrative simplification, but as we show below, our results are robust to considering alternative nonlinear cost functions, and our model is easily extendable to consider any particular cost function of interest.
Fig. 1 C–E shows the expected systemic cost of failure C for two banks and two asset classes using various values of s. For a linear cost function (s = 1), expected cost is minimized under uniform diversification. In this special case, individual and systemic incentives are aligned. However, when we consider more realistic cases where the cost function is convex (so that the marginal systemic cost of bank failure is increasing), the configuration that minimizes C is no longer uniform diversification but rather, a configuration with diverse diversification. As s increases, an increasingly larger departure from uniform diversification is required to minimize C.
In Fig. 2, we illustrate a more general case of five banks investing in three assets, randomly sampling 105 asset allocations. For varying degrees of nonlinearity s, we show the configuration with the lowest expected cost C. When the cost function is linear, the lowest cost configuration is again uniform diversification O*, where each bank allocates one-third of its investments to each asset. As we increase s, we find that pushing the banks away from uniform diversification to diverse diversification reduces C.
To further explore the relationship between the positioning of banks in asset space and the expected systemic cost, we define D as the average distance between the asset allocations of each pair of banks, scaled so that the distance between banks exposed to nonoverlapping sets of assets is one. We also define a second parameter G to describe how unbalanced the allocations are on average, which is defined as the distance between the average allocation across banks and the individually optimum allocation O*. SI Text has more detailed specifications of D and G. Note that, if all banks adopt the individually optimum allocation, both D and G are zero. Thus, in this case, all banks either survive or fail together, and the system behaves as if there were only a single representative bank. This finding is true regardless of assumptions about how the asset values fluctuate, but of course, it may not extend to more complex models with features such as stochastic heterogeneity across banks.
In Fig. 3, we show expected cost C as a function of D and G across 105 random allocations of five banks on three assets. As we have already seen in Fig. 2, in the special case of s = 1, expected cost is minimized by uniform diversification at D = G = 0; thus, expected cost is increasing in both distance D and imbalance G. At larger values of s, expected cost remains consistently increasing in imbalance G, but the relationship between cost and distance D changes. At s = 1.2, cost is large for distances that are either too small or too large. The relationship between distance and cost is clearly nonlinear, and cost is lowest at an intermediate value of D. As s increases to s = 4, cost is now lowest when distance is large, and thus, cost is decreasing in D. Providing additional evidence for the ability of D and G to characterize systemic cost, regression analysis finds that D, D2, and G together explain over 90% of the variation in log(C).
All of this information suggests that it may be possible in principle, and it could provide a useful guide in practice, to regulate expected systemic cost. For a given level of capital, regulators might set a lower bound on distance D and an upper bound on imbalance G. As shown in Fig. 4, fixing G = 0 and requiring D to exceed some value of DMin results in a substantial reduction in the capital buffer needed to ensure that the worst-case expected cost remains below a given level. We particularly consider the worst-case expected cost to take into account potential strategic behavior on the part of the banks. This most pessimistic case shows that, even if the banks are colluding to purposely maximize the probability of systemic failure, regulating D and G creates substantial benefit for the system. Fig. 4 also illustrates the robustness of our results to model details. We observe similar results when varying model parameter values, including the number of banks and assets (Fig. 4A), the nonlinearity of the cost function (provided that s is not too low) (Fig. 4B), and the value of p (Fig. 4C). We also observe similar results when varying the distribution of the asset prices (provided that the tails of the distribution are heavy enough) (Fig. 4D) and when considering assets with a substantial degree of correlation (Fig. 4E and SI Text). Furthermore, Fig. 4F shows that our results continue to hold when considering alternate cost functions in which (i) the system can absorb the first i bank failures without incurring any cost, with systematic cost then increasing linearly for subsequent failure (i = 2 in our simulations), and (ii) each of the first i failures causes a systemic cost C1, whereas each additional failure above i causes a larger systemic cost C2 (i = 2, C1 = 5, and C2 = 30 in our simulations; SI Text has discussion of the various cost functions). This robustness is extremely important, because many of these features are difficult to determine precisely in reality. Because our results do not depend on the details of these assumptions, the importance of diverse diversification may extend beyond the simple model that we consider here.
Regulatory changes under discussion are estimated to require banks to increase their Core Tier One capital substantially in the major developed economies (43). In this context, the potential ability of diverse diversification to reduce capital buffers is of great economic significance. Estimates suggest that, for each 1% reduction that does not compromise system stability, sums in excess of $10 billion would be released for other productive purposes, with the economic benefits likely to be substantial (43, 44).
Discussion
There is a growing appreciation that prudent financial regulation must consider not only how a bank's activities affect its individual chances of failure but also how these individual-level choices impact the system at large. The analysis presented in this paper highlights a particular aspect of the problem that a systemic regulator will face: when the marginal social cost of bank failures is increasing in the numbers of banks that fail, systemic risk may be reduced by diverse diversification. This nonlinearity of the systemic cost is a natural assumption. The societal costs of dealing with bank failures grow disproportionately with the numbers that fail. Hence, the regulator may wish to give banks incentives to adopt differentiated strategies of diversification.
These results also have implications beyond the financial system. For example, the tension between individually optimal herding and systemically optimal diversification is a powerful theme in ecological systems (45, 46). Natural selection pressures organisms in a given species to adapt (in the same way) to their shared environment. However, maintenance of diversity is essential for protecting the species as a whole from extinction in the face of fluctuating environments and emergent threats such as new parasite species. Herding is also an issue for human societies in domains other than banking. In the context of innovation, for example, people often herd around popular ideas and fads, creating systemic costs by making it difficult for new ideas to be appreciated (47).
In our model, the expected systemic cost of bank failures is largely explained by two global parameters of risk exposure and diversity. Both these parameters can be derived by the regulator without the need for complicated calculations of systemic risk, and they can be decomposed into their contributions from individual actors. We also show that a given level of expected systemic cost can be achieved with a more efficient use of capital if the regulator is able to encourage a suitable level of diversity between banks in the system. Thus, this framework presents a potentially useful tool for systemic regulation; our analysis points to the possibility of regulation that combines knowledge of system aggregates and individual bank positions to identify and induce the desired degree of diverse diversification. The practical design of this aspect of regulatory strategy can only emerge from a fuller program of research.
In the meantime, it is our hope that the insights developed in this paper can weigh on the deliberations that are gathering pace surrounding the reform of financial regulation. Active discussion is under way regarding the design of capital surcharges based on an individual bank's contribution to systemic risk (4, 10, 48). Meanwhile, it is increasingly recognized that financial reporting must improve significantly to support the function of the systemic regulator, and discussion has turned to the practical details of data gathering and analysis (1, 4, 8–10). The basic notion that common diversification strategies can increase systemic risk is not entirely absent from current policy thinking (7), and it predates the recent crisis (49); however, it has received relatively little attention in the literature. A priority for future research is to convert theoretical insights into practical approaches for regulators.
Supplementary Material
Acknowledgments
We thank John Campbell, Chris Chaloner, Ren Cheng, Sally Davies, Andy Haldane, Sujit Kapadia, Jeremy Large, Edmund Phelps, Simon Potter, Roger Servison, Bernard Silverman, and Corina Tarnita for helpful discussions. We also thank the editor and four anonymous referees for helpful comments. D.G.R. is supported by a grant from the John Templeton Foundation. N.B. is grateful for support from the Man Group and Fidelity Management and Research. This work was completed while K.C. was based at New College, Oxford University, and the Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance. Financial support from both institutions is gratefully acknowledged.
Footnotes
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.
This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1105882108/-/DCSupplemental.
References
- 1.French KR, et al. The Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial System. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- 2.Hillman R. Financial Regulation: Recent Crisis Reaffirms the Need to Overhaul the U.S. Regulatory System. Washington, DC: United States Government Accountability Office; 2009. Testimony Before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs GAO-09-1049T. [Google Scholar]
- 3.Makin JH. Risk and Systemic Risk. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research; 2008. [Google Scholar]
- 4.Bank of England . The Role of Macroprudential Policy. London, UK: Bank of England; 2008. Bank of England Discussion Paper. [Google Scholar]
- 5.Bolton P, Freixas X, Shapiro J. The Credit Ratings Game. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2009. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 14712. [Google Scholar]
- 6.Thanassoulis J. This is the right time to regulate bankers’ pay. Economist's Voice. 2009;Vol 6(Issue 5):Article 2. [Google Scholar]
- 7.Haldane A. Banking on the state. BIS Rev. 2009;139:1–20. [Google Scholar]
- 8.Lo A. The Feasibility of Systemic Risk Measurements. Written Testimony for the House Financial Services Committee on Systemic Risk Regulation. 2009 Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1497682. [Google Scholar]
- 9.Sibert A. A systemic risk warning system. Vox. 2010 http://voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/4495. [Google Scholar]
- 10.International Monetary Fund . Global Financial Stability Report: Meeting New Challenges to Stability and Building a Safer System. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- 11.Brunnermeier M. Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007–2008. J Econ Perspect. 2009;23:77–100. [Google Scholar]
- 12.Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS. The aftermath of financial crises. Am Econ Rev. 2009;99:466–472. [Google Scholar]
- 13.Acharya VV, Richardson M. Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair a Failed System. New York: New York University Stern School of Business; 2009. [Google Scholar]
- 14.Nowak MA. Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science. 2006;314:1560–1563. doi: 10.1126/science.1133755. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Bhattacharya S, Gale D. Preference shocks, liquidity and central bank policy. In: Barnett WA, Singleton KJ, editors. New Approaches to Monetary Economics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press; 1987. [Google Scholar]
- 16.Rochet J-C, Tirole J. Interbank lending and systemic risk. J Money Credit Bank. 1996;28:733–762. [Google Scholar]
- 17.Kiyotaki N, Moore J. Credit cycles. J Polit Econ. 1997;105:211–248. [Google Scholar]
- 18.Friexas X, Parigi B. Contagion and efficiency in gross and net interbank payment systems. J Financ Intermed. 1998;7:3–31. [Google Scholar]
- 19.Freixas X, Parigi B, Rochet J-C. Systemic Risk, Interbank Relations and Liquidity Provision by the Central Bank. Barcelona: Universitat Pompeu Fabra; 1999. Working Paper of the Universitat Pompeu Fabra. [Google Scholar]
- 20.Allen F, Gale D. Financial contagion. J Polit Econ. 2000;108:1–33. [Google Scholar]
- 21.Gai P, Kapadia S. Contagion in financial networks. Proc R Soc Lond A Math Phys Sci. 2010;466:2401–2423. [Google Scholar]
- 22.Shaffer S. Pooling intensifies joint failure risk. Res Financ Serv. 1994;6:249–280. [Google Scholar]
- 23.Acharya VV. A theory of systemic risk and design of prudential bank regulation. J Financ Stab. 2009;5:224–255. [Google Scholar]
- 24.Stiglitz JE. Risk and global economic architecture: Why full financial integration may be undesirable. Am Econ Rev. 2010;100:388–392. [Google Scholar]
- 25.Battiston S, Delli Gatti D, Gallegati M. Liaisons Dangereuses: Increasing Connectivity, Risk Sharing, and Systemic Risk. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2009. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
- 26.Castiglionesi F, Navarro N. Optimal Fragile Financial Networks. Tilburg, The Netherlands: Tilburg University; 2007. Discussion Paper of the Tilburg University Center for Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- 27.Lorenz J, Battiston S. Systemic risk in a network fragility model analyzed with probability density evolution of persistent random walks. Networks Heterogeneous Media. 2008;3:185–200. [Google Scholar]
- 28.Diamond DW, Rajan R. Fear of Fire Sales and Credit Freeze. Vol. 86. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2007. pp. 479–512. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
- 29.Shin HY. Risk and Liquidity, Clarendon Lectures in Finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- 30.Allen F, Babus A, Carletti E. Financial Connections and Systemic Risk. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2010. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
- 31.Greenwald B, Stiglitz JE. Externalities in economies with imperfect information and incomplete markets. Q J Econ. 1986;101:229–264. [Google Scholar]
- 32.Allen F, Gale D. Understanding Financial Crises, Clarendon Lecture Series in Finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2007. [Google Scholar]
- 33.Gorton G, Metrick A. Haircuts. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2010. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
- 34.May RM. Network structure and the biology of populations. Trends Ecol Evol. 2006;21:394–399. doi: 10.1016/j.tree.2006.03.013. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 35.May RM, Levin SA, Sugihara G. Complex systems: Ecology for bankers. Nature. 2008;451:893–895. doi: 10.1038/451893a. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 36.May RM, Arinaminpathy N. Systemic risk: The dynamics of model banking systems. J R Soc Interface. 2010;7:823–838. doi: 10.1098/rsif.2009.0359. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 37.Haldane A. Rethinking the Financial Network. London, UK: Bank of England; 2009. Speech delivered at the Financial Student Association, Amsterdam, April 2009. [Google Scholar]
- 38.Haldane AG, May RM. Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Nature. 2011;469:351–355. doi: 10.1038/nature09659. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 39.Sheng A. Financial crisis and global governance: A network analysis. In: Spence M, Leipziger D, editors. Globalization and Growth Implications for a Post-Crisis World. Washington, DC: World Bank; 2010. pp. 69–93. [Google Scholar]
- 40.Owen J, Rabinovitch R. On the class of elliptical distributions and their applications to the theory of portfolio choice. J Finance. 1983;38:745–752. [Google Scholar]
- 41.Blattberg RC, Gonedes NJ. A comparison of the stable and student distributions as statistical models of stock prices. J Bus. 1974;47:244–280. [Google Scholar]
- 42.Elton EJ, Gruber MJ. Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. New York: Wiley; 1995. [Google Scholar]
- 43.Institute of International Finance . Interim Report on the Cumulative Impact on the Global Economy of Proposed Changes in the Banking Regulatory Framework, June 2010. Washington, DC: Institute of International Finance; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- 44.Basel Committee on Banking Supervision . An Assessment of the Long-Term Economic Impact of Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements, August 2010. Basel, Switzerland: Basel Committee on Banking Supervision; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- 45.Levin S. Ecosystems and the biosphere as complex adaptive systems. Ecosystems. 1998;5:431–436. [Google Scholar]
- 46.Elmqvist T, et al. Response diversity, ecosystem change, and resilience. Front Ecol Environ. 2003;9:488–494. [Google Scholar]
- 47.Pech R. Reflections: Termites, group behaviour, and the loss of innovation: Conformity rules! J Manag Psychol. 2001;7:559–574. [Google Scholar]
- 48.Adrian T, Brunnermeier M. CoVar. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; 2009. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 348. [Google Scholar]
- 49.Gieve J. Financial System Risks in the UK: Issues and Challenges. London, UK: Bank of England; 2006. Centre for the Study of Financial Innovation Roundtable, Tuesday 25 July 2006. [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.