Abstract
A dynamic optimization model of parents choosing investments in their children’s health motivates an empirical model of parents’ choices of health inputs for their children and the impacts of these decisions on their children’s subsequent health. Estimates of the child health input demand functions and the child health production functions from the Cebu Longitudinal Health and Nutrition Survey accord with the prediction that optimizing behavior results in higher levels of aggregate child health. Observable parental behaviors respond to the physical developmental status of their children. These parental responses appear to yield large and statistically significant improvements in children’s early physiological outcomes. However, because some health inputs choices are not observable, it is impossible to ascertain whether these measured effects are due solely to variations in the observed input choices.
Keywords: health production function, parental health inputs, unobserved heterogeneity
1. Introduction
This study explores the determinants of parents’ behaviors that can influence their children’s early childhood development and the impacts of these actions on their children. It traces how birth outcomes and children’s growth over the first two years of life influence parents’ decisions about breast-feeding, supplemental feeding, preventative health care, maternal work decisions, and timely vaccinations. We assess how these endogenous, compensatory behaviors appear to affect the growth of children throughout these formative years, and we include a detailed discussion of some key issues in interpreting these estimated effects that arise because one cannot observe all of the inputs that parents choose to influence their children’s physiological development.
From a biomedical perspective, the first two years of life is a critical period for cognitive development, during which nutritional deficits are hypothesized to directly limit the growth and development of the brain (Smart 1998, Lozoff 1998). Biomedical scientists conclude that anthropometric indicators of poor nutritional status are consistently associated with poor cognitive outcomes. In less developed countries, the inadequate living environment poses a great threat to the child’s growth and cognitive development, which in turn could affect learning ability and school achievement, and ultimately limit the performance in the labor market. There has been a great deal of emphasis on early child development programs in less developed countries, as witnessed recently by large investments in such programs by the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank.
Social scientists also have concluded that there are strong effects of mothers’ education and household income on child health outcomes (see Behrman and Taubman 1990; Blau 1999; Duncan, Brooks-Gunn, and Klebanov 1994). Nevertheless, we have little understanding about the underlying relationship between these socioeconomic factors and parents’ health-related behaviors. At the same time, given that parents might determine the health inputs in response to their and their child’s observed and unobserved health-related characteristics, child health production studies without adequate control for endogeneity and unobserved heterogeneity can lead to biased estimates about the effects of health inputs. The limited understanding of the determinants of health-related behavior has undermined our ability to evaluate the health impact of these potential programs. In this paper we model and estimate the relationships among child outcomes, subsequent endogenous health inputs, and health outcomes. The results provide empirical evidence on the determinants of these health-related behaviors, as well as an assessment of the health consequences from parents adjusting their health behaviors in response to the child’s physiological development.
Using the Cebu Longitudinal Health and Nutrition Survey (CLHNS), a comprehensive longitudinal data set collected in the Philippines, this study incorporates prenatal care information, birth outcomes, important subsequent parental inputs, and multiple measures of early childhood health outcomes. While many studies have examined the effects of prenatal care on pregnancy outcomes, little attention has been given to the decision and timing of prenatal care. We hypothesize that ceteris paribus initiating prenatal care earlier tends to be more beneficial. Using the CLHNS data, numerous studies have assessed the associative relationships between health inputs in early childhood and subsequent child outcomes. For instance, Adair (1999) uses a discrete time duration model to study the impacts of various factors on the probability of recovery from stunting among children who were stunted at age 2. She concludes that children with great growth potential at birth, indicated by high birth length and tall maternal stature, are more likely to recover from stunting at age 2. Mendez and Adair (1999) and Daniels and Adair (2004) investigate the association between a child’s nutritional status at age 2 and her predicted academic achievements through high school. They find a lingering effect of the early childhood nutrition status through high school. While remaining statistically significant, these estimated associations become smaller when additional socio-economic factors are controlled for. More importantly, considering the potential endogeneity of health inputs is not accounted for in these studies, the estimated effects may be biased.
Several previously studies attempt to investigate the casual relationship between health-related goods (behaviors) and health outcomes measured by growth or morbidity. The common econometric strategy to address the endogeneity problems is an instrumental variables approach, but the lack of good instruments and strong functional form assumptions may likely have contributed to the inconsistency in results across studies. Adair, Popkin, and Guilkey (1993) investigate the impact of a set of socioeconomic and biological factors on the duration of full and partial breast-feeding. They allow time-varying independent variables to enter the hazard rate equation with a one-period lag. Most of these studies focus on estimating the overall effects of one or more health related parental behaviors on children’s health outcomes in a reduced-form health production function. The Cebu Study Team (1992) presents a structural model similar to the models suggested by Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983). The authors rely on a two-stage regression framework to directly estimate the models with endogenous variables on the right hand side. The unobserved heterogeneity specific to a given child is accounted for using a random effects generalized least squares estimator. There are two main shortcomings with their empirical results. First, every health outcome is estimated separately. Second, the standard errors reported in the paper fail to take into account the fact that pre-estimated explanatory variables are used in place of the actual variables. Additionally, the study does not focus on the compensatory behaviors in their empirical analyses.
This paper addresses the following two important questions: how do parents change their behavior in response to their children’s health outcomes and how effective are these changes. Guided by a dynamic economic model of parental investments in a child’s health, we propose a tractable empirical model that includes a set of parents’ demand functions for health inputs in conjunction with a set of health production functions for how a child’s physiological development responds to these inputs. We specifically allow unobserved heterogeneity across mothers and children to enter the health production functions as well as the health input demand functions, and we use flexible parametric forms to help uncover the dependence of behaviors on prior outcomes and the dependence of subsequent outcomes on these behaviors. The joint estimation of these parental behaviors and child health outcomes achieves more statistical efficiency than estimating separate equations by techniques such as two stage least squares.
We find that parents adjust their behaviors in response to their children’s observed health. Most importantly, our estimates indicate that these adjustments are statistically significant and, subject to the proviso that the estimated effects might be tainted because one cannot observe all of the behaviors parents make to help their children, they appear to yield substantively important improvements in child growth and health. While there is evidence of lingering impacts of low birth weight on some child outcomes, the mothers adjust their behaviors in response to low birth weight and contemporaneous adverse outcomes during the early life course. For instance, we find that a mother of a low birth weight child is less likely to work during the first year of the child’s life, feeds the child more calories per kilogram, and breast-feeds the child longer. Moreover, empirical analyses that ignore the interactions and endogeneity of parental behaviors and childhood health-related events provide biased estimates of the effectiveness of parental behavior towards their children.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines a dynamic economic model and presents some testable implications of optimizing behavior. Section 3 describes the Cebu Longitudinal Health and Nutrition Survey data and the basic empirical specifications and goals. Section 4 describes the empirical models used in this analysis. Section 5 discusses key limitations in estimating health production functions like those examined here that arise because one cannot observed all of the choices parents make about the inputs to their children’s health. Section 6 presents the results of the estimation and policy simulations from the empirical model’s estimates. We provide a discussion and our conclusions in Section 7.
2. A Prototypical Economic Model of Parent’s Investments in Children’s Health
2.1 The Dynamic Optimization Problem
Suppose the parents of a single young child attempt to maximize the present discounted value of a time separable utility function subject to a per period budget constraint. Their utility flow depends on their current consumption and their perception of the well being or health of their child. Let U(ct, ht) be the per period utility function where ct is the parents’ consumption during period t and ht is the stock of child health at the start of this time period. We assume that this per period utility function is concave, that the marginal utility of child health is not increasing in the parents’ consumption, and that the price of consumption is normalized to one.
While parents cannot alter the health of their child within a period, they may make investments in their children that can lead to higher expected child health at the start of the subsequent time period. Let the deterministic component of the health production process be given by
where we allow next period’s child health to depend on today’s actual health as augmented by the health investment inputs ft purchased today by the parents at price pt. We assume
This latter restriction, on the cross derivative, captures the notion that equally sized increases in health investments would do more to improve the health of less healthy children. Realized child health at the start of the next time period is given by the product of the deterministic component and an independent mean 1 health shock st+1, i.e., . The parents’ information about the distributions of future prices, incomes and health shocks is contained in the information set Ωt.
2.2 Derivation of the Demands for Inputs to the Child Health Production Function
Using Bellman’s formulation under these conditions, the parents’ dynamic optimization problem at point of time t can be simplified to
subject to the above health production function and the per period budget constraint
The function Vt+1(ht+1) is the optimized value function as of the start of period t+1, and β is a discount factor. The solution to this optimization problem implies a demand equation for inputs to the child’s health production process of the form:
Even though this period t demand function is part of a dynamic optimization process, it only depends on variables observed by the parents as of time period t.1 One can express the demand for the input f at each point in time t solely as a function of the state variables observed at that point in time. If the only uncertainty about the future comes from uncertainty about future incomes, prices, and health shocks, the future joint distribution of yt and pt, follows a first order Markov process, and the health shocks st are independent over time, then it is unnecessary to further condition the demand function on the information set Ωt. Such simplifying assumptions are commonly made in many structural dynamic models (E.g. see Blundell et al, 1997). Mroz and Weir (2003) provides a more detailed discussion of the interpretation of dynamic formulations of this type.
While in general it will be impossible to solve for closed form solutions for the age specific demand functions, this economic framework provides important implications for an empirical analysis of parents’ choices of inputs to the child health production process and the estimation of the health production process. Most importantly, it implies that there is a well-defined demand function for health inputs that only depends on the state variables observed by the parents at time t. In our empirical analysis we exploit this fact and implement in the estimation a flexible functional form for the demand equations to approximate the actual solutions to the optimal investment in child’s health problem, if that is in fact how the parents make their choice about inputs to their children’s health. Additionally, provided one continues to condition the health demands on the relevant parts of the parent’s information set, the estimation approach could uncover arbitrary, or even irrelevant, rules of thumb. This framework does not require that parents solve an explicit maximization problem in order to solve for their demands for health inputs, but it can approximate the expected utility optimizing rules if that is how parents make their decisions.
2.3 Key Restrictions Implied by a Dynamic Optimization Model
The production process for expected child health in the next time period depends on two factors. The first is the child’s health state when entering the current time period, and the second is the amount of investment, ft, the parents use to help produce more health for the child. In this dynamic optimization model parents are willing to trade their own current consumption for child health inputs that can raise their utility from the flow of future child well-being. Since the parents’ period specific utility function is concave, parents will receive less additional expected future utility from a given increment to their child’s health when their child’s current health is high than they would from the same health increment if their child’s health were low. As a consequence of optimizing behavior, ceteris paribus, parents will spend less on child health investments when their child’s health is good (and more on their own current consumption) than when their child’s health is poor, or .
These differential investments by otherwise identical optimizing parents whose children have different health statuses at the start of period t will result in a population distribution of subsequent health of their children that is more concentrated than if they had treated all children equally regardless of the health status of the children when making investment and consumption decisions. Stated differently, optimizing behavior yields more equality in child outcomes. A somewhat stronger implication arises when one exploits the assumption that the production function for child well-being exhibits diminishing returns.
Suppose there is a non-degenerate distribution of child health at time t, and consider a population of parents of who are otherwise identical. If these parents were maximizing expected life cycle utility as in the above model, then the distribution of child health statuses ht would induce a distribution of optimal parental inputs ft in the population. Through the stochastic health production function, this distribution of parental actions would result in a distribution of child health in the subsequent time period. Let Gt(f) be the marginal distribution of these inputs in the population for children of age t. Now, suppose that instead of solving a dynamic optimization model to choose their investments ft (which would depend on each child’s observed health status), that parents randomly choose their inputs from the marginal distribution Gt(f) without conditioning on their child’s health. Since optimizing parents allocated more resources towards those children whose health production functions had the higher expected marginal returns, the random allocation of child investments would result in fewer children in bad health, and more children in good health, receiving large health investments. This implies that the subsequent distribution of child health would have a lower expected value when parents randomly choose their child investments. In Section 6 we use the estimates of the parents’ investment demand functions and for the child health production function to assess whether the types of behavior parents exhibit in the Cebu data are consistent with this implication of the stochastic dynamic optimization model.
3. Data, Basic Empirical Specifications, and Identification
3.1. The Cebu Longitudinal Health and Nutrition Survey Data
This paper focuses on the CLHNS data, which have been analyzed extensively by scholars from numerous disciplines. The CLHNS is an ongoing longitudinal study of a cohort of Filipino children (and their mothers) who were born in 1983–84. Through a stratified and single-stage sampling procedure, a random sample was selected of 33 communities or barangays from the Metropolitan Cebu area, Philippines. A baseline survey took place for 3,327 women at a median gestation week of 30 (range 14–44). Postnatal interviews took place immediately after birth. Starting at age 2 months, interviews took place every two months until the child reached age two. The birth information survey revealed a total of 3,080 single live births among sample women.2 Among these single live births, 2,873 infants had valid measurements of birth weight and length. The surveys collected information on anthropometric measures of the children (length and weight), infant breast-feeding and supplemental feeding practices, the incidence of diarrhea and respiratory illnesses, the labor supply and health care behaviors of the mother, and other important economic and demographic data. Concurrent with the sequence of household level interviews, the survey team collected community information on health facilities, health care personnel, food prices, and other community characteristics. There are too few infant deaths in this sample for one to carry out a meaningful analysis of the determinants of child mortality.
3.2 General Forms for the Dynamic Relationships
In our empirical strategy we utilize both health production functions and health input demand functions to characterize the health outcome trajectories of infants. Ideally, the production functions we estimate would describe the technical relationships between the health outcomes and health inputs, while the input demand functions would describe the parents’ possibly endogenous choices of health-related inputs. Let H(t) represent a set of child health outcomes, such as weight, length, and disease incidents at time t, and let M(t-1) be a health input vector, such as lagged choices of prenatal care, preventive health care, and breast-feeding practice. The health production process in time t is modeled as a function of a vector of exogenous child and family characteristics (X(t)), a vector of community characteristics relevant for the outcome under consideration (C(t)), lagged health (H(t−1)), lagged health inputs (M(t−1)), an unobserved heterogeneity term (μH ), and an independently distributed shock (εH(t)) according to the following formulation:
(1) |
The time index indicates the occurrence of interviews starting from the baseline, prenatal survey at t= −1. Following t = 0, which denotes the information collected about the day of birth, there were 12 bi-monthly longitudinal surveys (numbered 1 through 12). For each of these latter 12 survey dates we have information on the child’s health and growth and parental behaviors that could influence child outcomes.
We make two important assumptions about health production. First, the biological process involved in the production of health takes time and, therefore, the current health outcomes are determined typically by lagged inputs. Note that the only exception to this sequencing of events concerns the impacts of breast-feeding. For breast-feeding it is likely that a two month lag might conceal some of its key impacts. Further discussions about the identification of the effects of these health inputs are presented in Section 3.3. Second, we model all health outcomes as “value-added” functions, where we use lagged outcomes to substitute for all historical inputs.3 Given the relatively short window between interviews, we model each of the relevant parental behaviors (working away from home, breast-feeding, preventative health care for the child, and children’s caloric intakes) as a function only of lagged child outcomes. Mroz and Weir (2003) discuss how a sequential model of this type can be interpreted as an approximation to the solution of a stochastic dynamic optimization problem.
The permanent unobserved heterogeneity μH can be decomposed into two components, a mother-specific unobserved heterogeneity (μ1 ) and a child-specific unobserved heterogeneity (μ2 ). An “i” subscript that denotes the ith mother-child pair is dropped to simplify the notation. A common set of contemporaneously measured exogenous variables are used as determinants of all health outcomes in a given bi-monthly survey after birth. For instance, the vector of child and family exogenous characteristics, X (t), includes child and mother’s demographic information and household composition; C(t) contains information about population density, deflated prices of important food items, and climate. As we discuss in more detail in Section 5, we include these contemporaneous family and community characteristics to control for unobserved inputs and unobserved changes in inputs that take place in the two month window between observation time periods t−1 and t. As discussed in that section and in Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983), unmeasured inputs to the health production process can limit one’s ability to interpret derivatives of equation (1) with respect to the health inputs M(t−1) as marginal products.
The input demands are specified as functions of exogenous child and family characteristics, community characteristics, lagged health outcomes, a time-varying heterogeneity term (μM ), and an independently distributed shock (εM ) as follows.
(2) |
where μM can vary over t; in particular, its child-specific heterogeneity component is not effective until the child is born.4 We specify μM as:
(3) |
where 1(·) is an indicator function for the event in parentheses. As discussed in Section 5, these input demand functions do have standard interpretations as demand functions even when there are unmeasured healthy inputs, provided the prices of these inputs and other factors affecting their demands are controlled for in the vectors C(t) and X(t).
In order to facilitate the modeling of various outcomes and inputs, we have explicitly made assumptions about the timing of corresponding measurements. We assume that health outcomes are revealed at the end of period t (or the very start of t+1), while the decisions about health inputs are made at the beginning of t. In addition, i.i.d. random shocks εH and εM are assumed to be realized at the start of time t.5 Table 1 contains a description of the dependent variables modeled in this paper and Table 2 presents summary statistics for all variables used in the analysis of prenatal care and birth outcomes. Table 3 provides information on the endogenous and exogenous variables appearing in the empirical model of the dynamics of the child’s physiological development during the first two years of life.
Table 1.
Description | Survey Source | Timing (t) | Statistical Model | Freq | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
V(g, τ) | g measures the gestational age of first prenatal visit and τ represents the type of visit | Baseline survey | t = −1 | Discrete time hazard model | 1 |
bw | Birth weight | Birth date survey | t = 0 | “Hazard” model | 1 |
bl | Birth length | Birth date survey | t = 0 | “Hazard” model | 1 |
bf | Breast-feeding choices | Birth date, post-birth date, follow-up surveys | t =0,1,…,12 | logit | 13 |
wk | Mother working away home | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | logit | 12 |
phc | Preventive health care, including immunization shots and any doctor visits | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | logit | 12 |
cal | Calorie intake | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | “Hazard” model | 12 |
fri | Incident of severe respiratory disease | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | logit | 12 |
dia | Incident of diarrhea | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | logit | 12 |
cw | Child weight | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | “Hazard” model | 12 |
ch | Child length | Follow-up surveys | t = 1,…,12 | “Hazard” model | 12 |
Table 2.
Variable Name | Description | Mean | (S.D.) |
---|---|---|---|
Prenatal care information | |||
1st month of visit (g) | Timing of the first prenatal visit if it happens before than the end of 7th month; otherwise, individuals are treated as having no visits. | 4.300 | (1.362) |
Traditional visit | 1 = 1st prenatal visits occurs at a traditional care-giver; 0 = otherwise | 0.351 | (0.477) |
Hospital visit | 1 = 1st prenatal visits occurs at a hospital; 0 = otherwise | 0.085 | (0.278) |
Clinic visit | 1 = 1st prenatal visits occurs at a clinic; 0 = otherwise | 0.358 | (0.480) |
Mother’s characteristics | |||
Parity | Previous number of live births | 2.235 | (2.204) |
Previous baby | 1 = woman had live birth before current pregnancy; 0 = otherwise | 0.789 | (0.408) |
Mother’s age | Age of the mother in 10 years | 2.603 | (0.596) |
Mother’s height | Age of the mother in 10 centimeters | 15.059 | (0.500) |
Education | Years of formal schooling | 7.176 | (3.314) |
Family socioeconomic factors | |||
Household assets | Total deflated real value of assets household owned in 1000’s 1978 pesos | 12.275 | (48.124) |
Household size | Number of household members | 5.615 | (2.822) |
Other HH members income | Sum of deflated weekly income of household members other than the pregnant woman in 1000’s 1978 pesos | 0.221 | (0.301) |
Insurance coverage | 1 = women’s prenatal care is covered by insurance; 0 = otherwise | 0.104 | (0.305) |
Extended household | 1 = extended household, either vertically or horizontally; 0 = nuclear | 0.395 | (0.489) |
No. children 0–6 | Number of children in this age group | 1.515 | (1.133) |
Catholic | 1 = husband and wife are Catholic; 0 = otherwise | 0.947 | (0.225) |
Husband present | 1 = husband/partner was living with the pregnant woman; 0 = otherwise | 0.942 | (0.235) |
Ethnic origin (Cebuano) | 1 = Cebuano spoken by husband and wife; 0 = otherwise | 0.921 | (0.270) |
Community/health facility characteristics | |||
Urban | 1 = the barangay is classified as urban; 0 = rural | 0.767 | (0.423) |
Population density | The population density of the barangay (1000 persons per km2) | 14.020 | (18.665) |
Price of corn | Deflated price of corn (10 pesos per kg) | 0.233 | (0.036) |
Price of cereal | Deflated price of cereal (10 pesos per kg) | 0.307 | (0.023) |
Dry season | 1 = birth occurred in dry season; 0 = otherwise | 0.240 | (0.427) |
Wet season | 1 = birth occurred in wet season; 0 = otherwise | 0.517 | (0.500) |
Waiting time in hospital | Average waiting time in hospitals serving the barangay (min) | 16.127 | (6.556) |
Waiting time in clinic | Average waiting time in clinics serving the barangay (min) | 6.073 | (9.390) |
Cost in hospital | Average costs for a prenatal visit in hospitals serving the barangay in 1978 pesos | 7.432 | (3.015) |
Cost in clinic | Average costs for a prenatal visit in clinics serving the barangay in 1978 pesos | 2.697 | (3.665) |
Doctor/patient ratio in hospital | The doctor/patient ratio in hospitals serving the barangay | 0.008 | (0.013) |
Part-time traditional caregiver | Percentage of traditional prenatal care providers that are part-time practitioners. | 0.086 | (0.084) |
Health outcomes of pregnancy | |||
Birth weight (bw) | Weight obtained within one hour postpartum (kg) | 2.993 | (0.429) |
Birth length (bl) | Length obtained within one hour postpartum (cm) | 49.076 | (2.071) |
Table 3.
Age of Child
|
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
2 months Means (s.d.) |
4–12 months Means (s.d.) |
14–22 months Means (s.d.) |
24 months Means (s.d.) |
|
Endogenous health inputs | ||||
Mother working away | 0.150 (0.357) | 0.226 (0.418) | 0.318 (0.466) | 0.348 (0.476) |
Preventive health care | 0.125 (0.331) | 0.143 (0.351) | 0.035 (0.183) | 0.018 (0.132) |
Exclusive breast-feeding | 0.262 (0.440) | 0.036 (0.187) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) |
Any breast-feeding | 0.863 (0.343) | 0.742 (0.438) | 0.396 (0.489) | 0.181 (0.384) |
*Calorie intake (kcal/day) | 0.109 (0.196) | 0.319 (0.343) | 0.624 (0.411) | 0.735 (0.418) |
Health outcomes | ||||
Diarrhea | 0.067 (0.250) | 0.206 (0.404) | 0.205 (0.404) | 0.180 (0.384) |
FRI | 0.109 (0.311) | 0.168 (0.374) | 0.169 (0.374) | 0.153 (0.360) |
Weight (kg) | 4.881 (0.656) | 7.162 (1.155) | 8.818 (1.230) | 9.790 (1.235) |
Length (cm) | 56.286 (2.379) | 66.261 (4.374) | 75.093 (3.877) | 79.168 (3.674) |
Community Characteristics | ||||
Urban | 0.761 (0.427) | 0.756 (0.430) | 0.753 (0.431) | 0.752 (0.432) |
Population density(persons/km) | 14.900 (19.121) | 14.802 (19.125) | 14.755 (19.194) | 14.812 (19.245) |
Dry season | 0.222 (0.415) | 0.257 (0.437) | 0.266 (0.442) | 0.202 (0.402) |
Wet season | 0.416 (0.493) | 0.414 (0.493) | 0.409 (0.492) | 0.484 (0.500) |
Average price of corn cereal | 3.154 (0.319) | 3.265 (0.284) | 3.410 (0.465) | 3.112 (0.934) |
Minimum price of formula | 3.640 (0.724) | 3.621 (0.697) | 3.465 (0.517) | 3.107 (0.764) |
| ||||
N | 2711 | 12713 | 12235 | 2426 |
Note:
This measure only accounts for the calories contained in the supplemental food.
3.3 Statistical Identification in this Dynamic Empirical Model
Each of the child outcomes and post-natal parental decisions depends on possibly endogenous explanatory variables, and it is important to assess whether the statistical model proposed here can identify the impacts of these lagged outcomes on current behaviors and outcomes. First, note that the CLHNS collected bi-monthly data on food and infant formula prices and local labor market conditions for each household’s barangay of residence. We incorporate cereal and formula prices, local wages and seasonality indicators, as well as period specific descriptors of each household’s composition, as time varying determinants of child outcomes and parental responses. Cebu is comprised of hundreds of small islands and the whole region underwent dramatic yet uneven economic development during the period when the surveys were conducted. Consequently, there were sizable variations of food prices and wage rates among our sample barangays cross-sectionally and over time. These prices as well as changes in family composition and seasonality of interviews provide important exogenous time-variants to our empirical models. The spatial and time variations in these determinants provide numerous exclusion restrictions in a dynamic empirical model.
Second, as discussed in Bhargava (1991), panel data relationships like those studied here implicitly provide many more over-identification restrictions than one might infer by simply listing the number of exogenous variables excluded from a single structural equation of interest. Bhargava’s (1991) paper considered a linear, dynamic structural equations estimator, and his careful examination of the reduced form equations revealed that every lag of each exogenous variable (i.e., the C(t′)’s and X(t′)’s in equation (1)) could have a separate impact on the “contemporaneous” value of an endogenous explanatory variable. The dynamic setting provides a multiplicity of exclusion restrictions when exogenous variables vary through time. Cameron and Trivedi (2005) also discuss the possible surfeit of exclusion restrictions in dynamic models.
Third, in nonlinear dynamic models, Mroz and Surette (1998) demonstrate how the time ordering of the exogenous variables and their interactions can provide even higher degrees of over-identification. As an example, consider using whether a child was being breast fed as an endogenous explanatory variable. First, note that both a household’s wealth and the price of infant formula are determinants of breast-feeding behavior at each point in time (Stewart and Guilkey, 2000), and that breast-feeding is nearly impossible to recommence after a temporary cessation. Previous research suggests that on average it takes a larger fall in the price of infant formula to induce a less wealthy mother to stop breast-feeding than it does for a mother in a wealthier household (Stewart and Guilkey, 2000; Rous, 2001). Under these conditions, the interactions of the timing of formula price and wealth changes matter for the cessation of breast-feeding in addition to the average levels of these variables. With several additional time-varying exogenous explanatory variables influencing the breast-feeding decision over time, there would be even more identification arising from interactions among the time series patterns of all these variables. The maximum likelihood framework we use to estimate the dynamic model optimally exploits all such dynamic, interactive, over-identifying conditions.
As an illustration of some of these identification sources, we estimate a simplified version of one child outcome equation in our model. In particular, we examine a two-stage least-squares regression of child weight outcomes regressed on three endogenous regressors: a low birth weight dummy variable, the child’s weight in the previous time period, and the child’s caloric intake in the previous time period. We also condition on a full set of assumed exogenous contemporaneous prices and descriptors of the household at that point in time. As instruments for the three endogenous explanatory variables we use four lags of the price and household descriptor measures.
Each of the three F-statistics for the relevance of the lagged values as predictors of the three endogenous explanatory variables exceed 10, and an Anderson IV relevance test (Canonical Correlation Test) resoundingly rejects the null hypothesis of under-identification (p-value < 0.001). In addition, a test of the overidentification conditions fails to reject the null hypothesis (Hansen J statistic p-value=0.15). It appears that even the limited time series variation in instrumental variables provides sufficient predictive power allow one to identify the impacts of three endogenous explanatory variables. Only one of the three estimated effects of the endogenous explanatory variables in this simple linear model, however, is statistically significantly different from zero at a conventional testing level. This might reflect the inefficiency of two stage least squares in this dynamic setting. In the full maximum likelihood model the implicit number of lags is greater and the interactions among the lagged exogenous variables are implicitly more complicated than what we use in this simple illustrative two stage least squares model. In addition, the maximum likelihood model incorporates the identifying information into the model without requiring the estimation of entirely new sets of coefficients as two-stage least squares does. It is likely that the identification sources in the maximum likelihood model are much richer than we see here for the two stage least squares model.
4. The Econometric Model
Empirically, we are estimating a sizable longitudinal model where prenatal visits, birth outcomes, and early childhood events are linked by child- and mother-specific heterogeneities and estimated simultaneously. Our statistical model starts with the mother’s decision about whether to use any prenatal care from a hospital, clinic, or traditional provider and the timing of when to first seek care. We then follow the mothers and children bimonthly from birth through age two. We model the dynamics of the child’s growth in both length and weight and the processes governing the bi-monthly incidence of severe respiratory infections and diarrhea. We focus on how parental behaviors such as exclusive breast-feeding, partial breast-feeding, supplemental feeding, mother’s working, and preventive health care respond to previous health and growth outcomes after continuing to control for correlated unobserved mother heterogeneity and unobserved heterogeneity specific to each child.
4.1 Maternal Inputs to Child Health
A primary goal of this paper is to explore whether parents adjust their behaviors that could affect their children’s growth in response to the observed developmental progress of their children. We model five separate parental behaviors: the commencement and type of prenatal care, and at each of the bimonthly interviews, the mother’s working away from home, preventative health care visits for the children, breast-feeding, and the child’s non-breast milk caloric intake. The empirical models for the mother working away from home and for the use of preventative health care visits since the last survey are standard logit models conditional on heterogeneity. These are discussed further in Appendix A. The modeling of the prenatal care, breast-feeding, and the child’s caloric intake are not standard, and we discuss them briefly in the following subsections.
Prenatal visits (V)
The choice of prenatal visits is characterized by a two-element vector V(g, τ), where g measures the gestational age at the first prenatal visit and τ represents the visit type if it occurs prior to the end of the sixth month of pregnancy. We impose the assumption that if a woman had not initiated prenatal care by the end of the second trimester that it would be unlikely that commencing prenatal care during the last trimester would have important beneficial effects on birth outcomes. We divide all prenatal visits during the first two trimesters into three categories: traditional prenatal care, modern care in a hospital, and modern care in a clinic. Detailed descriptions of these different visit types can be found in Table 2. See Appendix A for a complete description of the empirical model used to describe the timing and type of the first prenatal care visit.
The design of the original CLHNS induced a key data limitation, namely that prenatal care information was only collected at the time of the single prenatal interview. Let Gi be the time, in gestation age, of the prenatal interview. Researchers can only observe the timing and type of a woman’s first prenatal visit if the first visit took place at or prior to Gi. Women who were interviewed prior to the 6th month of pregnancy and before a prenatal visit took place, for example, could have had their first prenatal care before the end of the 6th month, but we would have no way to know whether it took place. In particular, there are 185 women who had not completed their 6th month of pregnancy and who reported that they had not visited any prenatal care-giver, accounting for 6.4% of our estimation sample. In our empirical model we address this data truncation problem by integrating over all possible decisions about prenatal care, conditional on their not having had a first visit by the date of their prenatal interview. We describe this in our derivation of the likelihood function. Note that our solution to this truncation issue assumes that prenatal care visits are independent of the gestation age at which the prenatal survey took place after controlling for observed covariates and unobserved heterogeneity.
Breast-feeding (bf)
Breast-feeding behaviors have important effects on various infant health outcomes. In particular, exclusive and partial breast-feeding patterns are associated with enhanced child growth and reduced diarrhea morbidity. An array of factors may play a role in the decision to initiate or to continue breast-feeding. We model discrete choices of breast-feeding in a nested logit framework. A complete discussion of the empirical model of breast feeding choices is in Appendix A.
Caloric intake (cal)
Given that the CLHNS only collects data on the caloric contents of non-breast milk food for the infants, we only model the caloric intake for children who are not breast-fed exclusively6. The caloric intake measure we use is the number of calories per gram of the child’s weight at the prior interview. We adopt a flexible parameterization to specify the process that determines the quantity of caloric intake cal(t). More specifically, we follow the conditional density method proposed by Gilleskie and Mroz (2004). A key advantage of this approach is that it allows the empirical model of unobserved heterogeneity to more easily capture and control for the across equation error correlations that give rise to the endogenous explanatory variables. Additionally, this approach relaxes the restrictive assumptions about error distributions implied by other parametric specifications.
To do this we partition the normalized caloric intakes into ten discrete cells and model the conditional probability of an advance to a higher, discretized caloric level. Conditional on reaching at least a given level p, the probability of reaching at least the next highest level (i.e., 1 minus the hazard rate) is specified as:
(4) |
cal(t) is the observed caloric intake per gram of weight at t and Cell(•,•) is the age -specific function mapping calories consumed at age t into a discrete cell. Fcal,b(p) represents the “baseline hazard” at caloric intake level p and Fcal captures the effects of covariates. The baseline hazard rate is specified as a third-order polynomial in the current caloric level p as follows:
(5) |
where P is the highest caloric intake level, defined as 10 in this study. The covariate component is further specified as
(6) |
Because the caloric intake decision depends on the health status of the child and endogenous health inputs, we include the relevant lagged health inputs and outcomes, including mother’s working away, any breast-feeding, preventive health care, and incidents of diarrhea and febrile respiratory illness (FRI).
4.2 Child Health Outcomes
We focus on six measures of the child’s health. Birth weight and birth length are measured at t=0. Each of the other four is measured at the bimonthly interviews (t=1,…,12): the child’s length, its weight, any diarrhea during the past two months, and whether the child had febrile respiratory illness during the prior two months. Birth outcomes depend upon prenatal visits, and each of the latter four outcomes depends upon the child’s prior health status as well as on parental behaviors that could have been responding to prior observations on the child’s health. The bimonthly incidences of disease are simple logit models conditional on heterogeneity and we discuss them in Appendix A. The empirical models for the child size measures are not standard, and we discuss them in detail in this subsection.
To model the determinants of continuous measures in this maximum likelihood framework, we use flexible functional forms like those for caloric intakes. For the models of child weight and height, we group children of the same age (in months) into 10 equal-sized sets based on the age specific percentiles of their weights and lengths respectively (5:1–10, 15:11–20, …, 95:91–100), and model the determinants of how a child outcome measure “progresses” from one cell to the next highest cell through the logit hazard rate model described earlier in this section. The child’s weight depends on characteristics of the child such as his/her age and gender, characteristics of the mother such as her age, fertility history, presence of her spouse, schooling level, and community characteristics such as food prices and urbanization level. Additionally, child weight is also a function of lagged weight and length, prior health status, such as previous incidents of diarrhea and severe respiratory disease, breast-feeding practices, and their parents’ other health inputs, including previous maternal employment and preventive health care. The specification of the process of child length increase is modeled nearly identically to that of the child weight function.
We use a similar discretized empirical model for the two primary birth outcomes: birth weight and length. To test the hypothesis that the effect of the first prenatal visit on birth outcomes is a function of the timing of the visit during a woman’s pregnancy, we include as additional regressors interaction terms between visit type dummies and the gestational age when the first visit occurred.
4.3 The Likelihood Function
We use a quasi-maximum likelihood method with discrete factors to estimate this multi-equation system. All parameters in the dynamic statistical model are estimated jointly. Each individual’s contribution to the likelihood function comprises the joint probability of observing each of the aforementioned health inputs and outcomes. Instead of assuming a restricted multivariate parametric specification for the error terms that cause correlations across different equations, we use a semi-parametric formulation to approximate the distribution of the unobserved heterogeneity terms. Heckman and Singer (1981) as well as Mroz (1999) show that the discrete factor estimators often have a superior performance than tightly parameterized heterogeneity distributions like the normal and gamma distributions.
Given our specification of discrete distributions for mother-specific heterogeneity term μ1 and child-specific heterogeneity term μ2, where μ1 takes on J1 different values and μ2 takes on J2 different values, with corresponding probabilities Pr(μ1, j1) and Pr(μ2, j2), the likelihood contribution from woman i is then given by:
We use a binary variable si as an indicator for prenatal care information truncation: si =1 for a woman i who had her first prenatal care visit before the time of the baseline interview (Gi), and si=0 otherwise. The second line of the likelihood function is the contribution to the likelihood from the prenatal care visits and birth outcomes of for women whose prenatal information was not truncated (si =1). In the third line we integrate over all possible combinations of timing and types of their first prenatal visit, including no visit at all before the end of the 6th month of their pregnancy, and the birth outcomes associated with each of those possible timings and types of prenatal visits. This only takes place for those whose first visit timing was censored by the event of the prenatal interview (si =0). The last line of the likelihood contains the contribution of the maternal behaviors at birth and the child outcomes and parental behaviors at each of the 12 bimonthly surveys. There are J1 points of support for the mother/family specific heterogeneity and J2 points of support for the child specific heterogeneity. In the empirical model we set these to seven and four points of support, respectively. The heterogeneity terms μ1 and μ2 enter various equations as third order polynomial forms. These are quite flexible specifications of the unobserved heterogeneity.7 The coefficients on 1st, 2nd, and 3rd order polynomials in μ1 and μ2 are similar to factor loadings.
5. Limitations of this Matching of the Empirical Model to the Theoretical Model
5.1 Unobserved Inputs to the Health Production Function
Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983) discuss the empirical consequences of estimating a health production function when all of the relevant inputs are not observed. Their insights can be easily displayed in the following simple description of the household’s choices of inputs and their impacts on the child health outcomes. Throughout this example, we assume parents are attempting to maximize a well-defined expected utility function subject to a per period budget constraint as discussed in Section 2.
For simplicity, we assume that there are only two inputs to the health production process; only one of these can be observed by the researcher. The deterministic dynamic health production function depends only on these two inputs and the current health state of the child:
The expected utility maximizing choice of the two health inputs are
where the budget constraint is given by yt = ct + p1t f1t + p2t f2t and the price of the composite consumption good has been normalized to one. Suppose that the second input is not observed.
In general the optimal choice of the unobserved input can be obtained from a conditional demand function of the form
which is evaluated at the optimal choice of the first input. Note that the functional form of this conditional demand is in equivalent to the rationed demand when the household is forced to consume (and pay for) a particular level of the first input. It differs from a standard two stage budgeting formulation because we do not assume separability of the two inputs in the production function. Non-separability implies that “impact” of the first input on the conditional demand for the second input need not be captured entirely through its impact on the budget constraint.
Replacing the unobserved input with its conditional demand in the health production function yields:
This is a restatement of the hybrid production function developed by Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983). Taking the derivative of this hybrid production function with respect to a change in the level of the first input yields
(7) |
The expression in equation (7) corresponds to what one would estimate for the “partial effect” of f1t on health if information on the level of the second input was not controlled for in the empirical analysis. It could differ substantially from the true partial effect of the first input, f1t, on health, . Provided the second input has positive marginal effect and the income effect on the conditional demand is small (say due to its comprising at most a small budget share), then the empirical estimate of the effect of the first input will tend to be overstated when higher levels of the first input increase the marginal productivity of the second input (the two inputs are complements in production). In practice it will almost always be the case that the researcher cannot observe and control for some inputs to the health production process and therefore will be unable to obtain uncontaminated estimates of the impacts of the observed health inputs. Nevertheless, it may be possible to assess a priori the extent of possible biases from knowledge about the likely magnitudes of the three partial derivatives comprising the bias.
5.2 “Intermediate” Inputs
In the estimation of health production functions, researchers are frequently interested in the impacts of “intermediating” inputs such as doctor, hospital, and clinic visits on health outcomes. Consider, for example, the impact of prenatal care visits on birth weight. It is unlikely that the act of visiting a prenatal clinic by itself has any direct beneficial impact on the birth outcome. Rather, the impact of the prenatal visit would operate through the induced changes in more proximate inputs to the health production process such as better nutrition, more exercise, extended bed rest if necessary, tetanus shots, and lower levels of alcohol and cigarette consumptions8. If one were to estimate a health production function incorporating these more direct health inputs in addition to the input “any prenatal care visit,” it is likely that one would conclude that the ceteris paribus beneficial impact of a health care visit is at most trivial. Especially for the evaluation of potential policies aimed at increasing access to prenatal care, however, that ceteris paribus interpretation likely would not provide relevant information about the benefits of prenatal care that incorporate the several paths through which it might operate. Many pregnant women might have made different decisions about their choices of the other health inputs in the absence of a prenatal visit.
The most commonly used estimation strategy in such a situation is to substitute out for the more direct inputs (e.g., nutrition) and model the health production function as depending only on the occurrence of a prenatal visit. Typically one would also control for the prices and other determinants of the more direct inputs that would capture the levels of these inputs in the absence of the prenatal care visit intervention. This is the strategy used in this paper to model the impacts of prenatal care visits9. If the true ceteris paribus impact of the visit is indeed zero (i.e., the first term in equation (7) is zero), then in this instance one would presumably be estimating as the impact of prenatal care the entire second term in equation (7). The complementarity of the knowledge obtained from the prenatal visit with the other health inputs, acting through these more direct inputs’ marginal effects, would describe the relevant mechanism through which the prenatal care visits affect health outcomes. If the price of the observed input is low, or the conditional income effects for the unobserved inputs are small, then one should be able to obtain an informative estimate of the indirect physiological impact of the intermediating input on health outcomes.
5.3 Data Timing Issues
The ideal empirical economic analysis of a production relationship would entail one observing a complete set of production inputs and then observing the actual level of output associated with that particular set of instruments. It would provide, for the most part, a purely technical description of the mapping from the inputs to the outputs. Health production functions, however, do not fit neatly into that framework. Not only are there issues of unobserved and indirect inputs as discussed above, but there are also important timing issues as it typically takes a somewhat lengthy period for many health inputs to cumulate and have measurable impacts on health. Compounding these difficulties, it is typically the case that one only intermittently observes a set of inputs and the corresponding outputs. The issue of what types of effects one can estimate in the presence of such time-dated, intermediating inputs can be analyzed in the context of a model quite similar to that used above for the interpretation of effects estimated in the presence of unobserved inputs.
Suppose, in the context of a three period model, that preferences are intertemporally separable and there are no financial borrowings or savings across time periods. We assume that health stocks, ht, and health inputs, ft, can be observed at time periods 1 and 3, but are unobserved at time period 2. As above, health evolves over time as a function of the previous period’s health stock, the choices of inputs in the previous period, and a set of random health shocks as in
The input demand function at time period 2 is give by
where p2 is the price of the health input (the price of consumption is normalized to one) and y2 is the household’s income at that time period. Preferences need not be myopic in this model, but if families are maximizing the expected present discounted value of lifetime utility, then one needs to assume that contemporaneous prices and incomes do capture the expectations of future economic variables. The first order Markov assumption used in nearly all micro-empirical stochastic dynamic programming models is a simple example of this type of restriction on the information set used in the production process.
The health stock observed at time period 3 as a function of the observable inputs, prices, incomes, and health shocks and observable health stocks is given by
The derivative of this function with respect to the period 1 input is given by
(8) |
The first of these two terms defines the cumulative effect of increasing the period 1 input on observed health in period 3 holding constant the period 2 inputs. The second term describes how the additional inputs at period 1 affects the unobserved second period inputs (though their impact on health at period 2) and their subsequent impact on observed health in at time 3. The expectation of the derivative in equation (8) with respect to the distribution of ε2 defines the observable impact of period 1 inputs on period 3 health holding constant health at period 1 and prices and incomes10.
Equation (8) provides key information for assessing the impacts of beneficial health inputs on subsequent health. First, increases in inputs at the early time period can be undone during the unobserved second period whenever higher health stocks lead to lower levels of health inputs . Family behaviors that are responsive to health changes would imply that the estimated effect of period 1 inputs from equation (8) would tend to be smaller than the ceteris paribus effect. Second, the shorter the span of time between periods the more similar will be the input choices in the first two time periods . In this situation the estimated effect would correspond more closely to a “two period” change in the health input rather than to a change in the first period’s input that could be “undone” in the second time period. The “omitted variable bias” resulting from not being able to control for the unobserved time period 2 input could mean that one estimates a quantity more like the impact of a longer term change in the input f than the effect of just an instantaneous change in the input. The two month interview horizons for the CLHNS data used here, consequently, are more likely to provide estimates corresponding to relatively constant changes in health inputs than would be obtained if one instead used data with information on inputs and health status collected every six or twelve months.
The above behavioral models suggest that the empirical models and data used here, while clearly imperfect, might be able to capture much of what economists hope to estimate from demand and production functions. For example, the effects on birth outcomes from prenatal care visits that we estimate do confound the complementarities of other health inputs with the “prenatal care.” Unobserved, relevant inputs to the production processes present the most formidable barriers to clean, precise interpretations of marginal effects. However this “contaminated” effect likely captures a policy relevant interpretation of the impact of receiving prenatal care.
In our birth outcome models the only major “input” considered in previous studies that we do not specify is smoking behaviors, which were only observed during the baseline pregnancy survey of the CLHNS. Recent evidence presented in Walker, Tekin, and Wallace (2007), however, suggests a large component of what most researchers have estimated as the impact of smoking on birth outcomes could be due to unobserved heterogeneity rather than to direct physiological effects. In light of the above discussion of intermediating inputs in Section 5.2, one might obtain a more policy relevant estimate of prenatal care impacts by not directly conditioning on smoking behaviors. Regardless of whether smoking is an important birth outcome determinant or not, our empirical model provides a framework to assess the “total” impact of prenatal care. We cannot, however, disentangle the paths through which it operates.
The production functions for post birth outcomes that we estimate do include many of the most important inputs to early child physiological development. We include breastfeeding and post breastfeeding nutritional inputs, constraints on the mother’s time as captured by her working outside the home, and preventive care visits for the child. We allow the previous health outcomes to affect both health input choices and the health production functions, as implied by the models we specified above. The estimations also condition on family characteristics, such as the mother’s age and education, the number of other adults in the household, whether a spouse is present, and the number of young children in the household, which likely affect the marginal technological efficiency of the health inputs. Because of the two month lag between observation periods we do include intervening prices in the production functions, as discussed above. Equations (7) and (8) provide a framework for assessing the interpretations of the production function estimates from imperfectly observed sets of inputs like those used here. In general the above analysis suggests that unless both the marginal impacts of the unobserved inputs are large and the income effects in their conditional demands are large, the biases arising from estimating the production functions with only the observed inputs might be small enough for one to obtain useful (but imperfect) inferences from the input demands and health production functions estimated in models like those considered here. As seen from the empirical results we present below, we do find there are some significant price effects.
5.4 Which Estimated Effects Are Robust to Missing Inputs?
The preceding discussion highlights important difficulties in obtaining simply interpretable estimates of production function effects when one cannot observe all relevant input choices. In general, the interpretation of estimated “marginal effects” when all inputs are not observed will require one to make assumptions about the magnitudes of quantities like conditional income effects and complementarities between observable and unobserved inputs. As discussed above, however, the evaluation of some potential policies might better be evaluated without conditioning on many chosen inputs, as those policies may best be thought of as operating through their impacts on the set of inputs chosen by the family. In addition, there are two classes of effects that can be calculated where the interpretations of the estimated effects are not hampered by one’s ability to observe all of the inputs to the health production process. For estimates to make sense in both of these general cases, it is necessary for one to be able to control for all of the prices and other factors affecting the demands for all of the observed and unobserved inputs to the health production process.
First, one can readily obtain estimates of the demand functions for each of the observable inputs. This follows directly from the definition of a demand function and the assumption that one observes all relevant prices and other factors affecting the input demands. In particular, one can obtain interpretable estimates of own and cross price effects, as well as of the impacts on the input demands of the child’s prior health status, family composition measures, and other factors that are not determined by the family simultaneously with the health inputs. Any of these measures that depends on unobserved heterogeneity that also influences the demand equation, prior health status for example, will need to be treated as endogenous in order to interpret any of the estimated demand effects as causal.
Second, it is possible to obtain readily interpretable effects of all of the factors affecting the demands for the observable inputs on the subsequent health outcomes. These effects are those that allow the family to re-optimize all inputs in response to changes in the “economically exogenous” demand factors. They measure the total effect of a change in the “constraint” on the health outcome, not a partial effect. To calculate these effects one must allow the observable input choices to vary in response to the changing constraints and then trace out how the changes in the observed input choices and constraints affect the hybrid demand system11. That is precisely the approach used in several of the simulations presented below. The reason one can obtain interpretable estimates of such effects even with a hybrid production function is that the conditional demand functions for the unobserved inputs, after substituting in the functional forms of the optimal demands for the observed inputs, are functionally identical to the unconditional input demands for unobserved inputs.
6. Empirical Results
Given the nonlinear nature of this estimation framework, it is quite difficult to interpret directly the parameter estimates. Instead of discussing the actual point estimates, we use simulations from the estimated relationships to explore parental behaviors and the impacts on children. Appendix B, however, does contain point estimates and standard errors for all of the parameters estimated for our most general model12. In this section we present the impacts of the timing of the commencement of prenatal care on birth outcomes, the determinants of the parents’ input decisions, and the impacts of parents’ responses on children’s health. At the end of this section we assess the benefits of parents using compensatory behaviors instead of making child care decisions that are unrelated to their children’s development.
6.1 Impacts of prenatal care on birth outcomes
Prenatal care is a key health behavior investigated in this study. It is important to recall the definition of the prenatal care effects that we estimate. Given that there are no other behavioral choices modeled as affecting birth outcomes, these prenatal care effects measure those discussed in section 5.2 and described in equation (7). In particular, these prenatal care effects measure the sum of the effects from the changes in all of the more direct birth outcome determinants that take place because the mother had a prenatal care visit. As seen from the first term within brackets in equation (7), these changes in the more direct inputs reflect the financial cost of the prenatal visit in addition to the more technological effects of changes in the unmeasured parental behaviors.
In this section we examine two general types of prenatal care effects. The first corresponds to an exogenous assignment of prenatal care to all pregnant mothers; it corresponds to an average treatment effect (ATE). The second measures the impact of prenatal care on those mothers who would be induced to receive prenatal care because of a change in a price or availability of prenatal care; these correspond to local average treatment effects (LATEs). It is important to note that the LATEs, since they are the overall responses to exogenous changes in constraints for an identifiable subgroup, do provide uncontaminated measures of the overall effect of the constraint changes on child health for this subset of the population, regardless of the precise mechanism through which the prenatal care operates. The LATEs are likely to be more relevant for evaluating new health policies, as they do correspond to possible policy changes which could be instituted in the hope of increasing prenatal care visits. The ATEs, on the other hand, measure the overall importance of prenatal care, but one would be hard pressed to posit an implementable public policy where an ATE would measure well the new policy’s impact.
As a baseline, consider a simplified model without heterogeneity controls that estimates the average treatment effects (ATEs) of various types of prenatal visits. Figure 1 displays the estimated impacts of these prenatal visits on the child’s birth weight. According to these estimates, it appears that delaying the onset of prenatal visits, or never receiving prenatal care (as measured by the 6+ category) almost always results in better birth outcomes. Consider, for example, a woman who would only receive prenatal care from a traditional provider. These simple estimates imply that if she postponed her first traditional visit from the first month of pregnancy to the sixth month her child’s birth weight would increase by about 80 grams.
Unobserved heterogeneity, perhaps due to pregnancy complications, could be leading to the rather counter-intuitive implications from the simple prenatal care model as displayed in Figure 1. When we use unobserved heterogeneity approaches to help control for the possible endogeneity of the timing of the first prenatal care visit, the implications change dramatically. As shown in Figure 2, postponing the first clinic visit from the first gestation month until the sixth would result in about a 120 gram reduction in birth weight, and never having a first visit would lead to a further reduction of almost 140 grams. According to these estimates there are clear and important benefits from mothers receiving early prenatal care. Surprisingly, having one’s first prenatal care visit at a hospital visit appears to be less effective at increasing birth weight than either traditional or clinic first prenatal visits. Possibly this could be due to incomplete controls for heterogeneity in fetal health, or it might reflect that first going to a hospital does not encourage women, or enable them as much, to receive regular, subsequent prenatal care.
We examine the impacts of several potential policies for increasing a mother’s willingness to start prenatal care at an earlier date. We do this by varying the value taken on by the price, availability, and convenience of prenatal care measures that influence the choice of prenatal care. By doing so we focus on that group of individuals who would be impacted by such potential policy changes, and consequently these effects can be interpreted as local average treatment effects (LATE). Table 4 contains simulation results for these experiments.
Table 4.
(1) Half price hosp3 (36% with no prenatal care responded ) | (2) No wait in clinic4 (9% with no care responded) | (3) Full-time trad care5 (21% with no care responded) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Before | After | Before | After | Before | After | |
Mean 1st visit month2 | - | 4.4 | - | 4.8 | - | 4.7 |
Mean birth weight (kg) | 3.05 | 3.06 | 3.02 | 3.05 | 3.04 | 3.08 |
Mean birth length (cm) | 48.9 | 49.1 | 49.7 | 49.8 | 49.1 | 49.4 |
Note:
Using 2873 observations and full model parameter estimates to simulate a subsample of women who will not receive prenatal care at baseline but they will do so after environmental variables change.
First visits that occurred after the 6th month of gestation are re-coded into no visits;
This change represents an average price drop of 3.7 pesos;
This represents an average drop of 6 minutes in clinic for prenatal care;
This represents an increase in full-time percentage of traditional care-givers from 91.4% to 100%.
After reducing the average cost of hospital visits by half, 36% of women who did not seek any prenatal care before the price drop would alter their decisions. The average weight of their newborns, however, increases by only 10 grams. The magnitude of increase is significantly less than the treatment effects indicated in Figure 2. These somewhat conflicting implications reflect the difference between average treatment effects and local average treatment effects. According to our estimates, those women who altered their behavior in response to the price change had unobserved characteristics that are positively associated with good pregnancy outcomes. There is much less room for improvements in their children’s birth outcomes from early prenatal visits than for the general population. Increasing the number of traditional caregivers yields somewhat stronger results. After an approximate 10% increases in the number of full-time traditional practitioners, 21% of women who would not seek prenatal care otherwise receive some type of prenatal care. The changed behavior is associated with an increase in average birth weights of 40 grams. Eliminating the waiting time in clinics only induced 9% of women into participating in prenatal care. However, the average improvement in birth weights of their newborns is about 30 grams. These simulated LATE results are modest compared to marginal treatment effects already discussed, but they are not inconsequential.
6.2 Parents’ compensatory behaviors
Table 5 contains estimates of parental behaviors under two scenarios: one where the child had low birth weight (2,000 grams) and the other where the child had an average birth weight (3,300 grams). We impose these two birth “initial conditions” and simulate separately a parent’s behaviors regarding work, preventative health care, breast-feeding, and supplemental feeding using a representative woman who otherwise has individual and community characteristics corresponding to the medians of those observed in the sample. As discussed in Section 5.4, these effects on the input demands should measure the average effect on the observable behavioral choices for the representative woman, provided that the empirical model controls for the prices and other determinants of all the behavioral decisions made by the family.
Table 5.
Sample size: 30001 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
(1) Low birthweight2 (S.E.)4 | (2) Normal birthweight3 (S.E.)4 | Parental response (1)–(2) (S.E.)4 | ||
Expected working months | up to year 1 | 2.251 (0.081) | 2.641 (0.083) | −0.390 (0.034) |
up to year 2 | 5.901 (0.183) | 6.634 (0.172) | −0.733 (0.082) | |
#of month w/preventive care5 | up to year 1 | 1.507 (0.076) | 1.315 (0.062) | 0.192 (0.056) |
up to year 2 | 1.912 (0.096) | 1.651 (0.082) | 0.261 (0.072) | |
Duration of breast-feeding (months)6 | Exclusive | 0.684 (0.056) | 0.725 (0.044) | −0.041 (0.054) |
Any | 15.721 (0.252) | 15.116 (0.208) | 0.605 (0.173) | |
Caloric intake (calorie/kg)7 | At end of year 1 | 54.412 (3.361) | 53.128 (3.081) | 1.284 (0.456) |
At end of year 2 | 70.873 (3.342) | 69.642 (3.135) | 1.231 (0.488) |
Note:
The sample used in these simulation is comprised of 3000 replicates of a typical mother-child pair whose exogenous characteristics are median values of the estimation sample;
The birth weight is set to be 2.0 kg and birth length is set to be 34.0cm;
The birth weight is set to be 3.3 kg and birth length is set to be 51.0cm;
Standard errors are obtained after bootstrapping using 1000 draws of parameters using estimated parameter vector and covariance matrix;
Expected preventive visits within first year (6 bi-monthly surveys) and first two years (12 bimonthly surveys) respectively;
Conditional on having initiated breast-feeding at the first follow-up survey;
Caloric contents from breast milk are not included.
We simulate 3000 life courses for each child up to age two and construct summary measures from these simulations.13 To obtain standard errors of these summary statistics, we use a parametric bootstrap procedure. For each of 1000 sets of parameters drawn from the estimated asymptotic distribution of the parameter estimators, we recalculate these summary measures from the 3000 life course simulations. We report as standard errors the standard deviations of outcomes across these 1000 simulations.
The mother of the low birth weight child is less likely to work at all during the first year of the child’s life or during the first two years of the child’s life than the mother of the average birth weight child. While these effects are somewhat small, they are statistically significant. The mother of a low birth weight child had 16% more preventive care visits during the first two years of the child’s life than the mother whose child had an average birth weight, and this difference is statistically significant. On average, mothers of low birth weight children breast-feed (exclusively or non-exclusively) for about 0.6 month longer, conditional on having initiated breast-feeding at the first follow-up survey. The normal weight children are exclusively breast fed slightly longer than the low birth weight children, though this difference in exclusive breast-feeding practices is not statistically significant. At both the first and second birthdays, the low birth weight child receives about 1.2 more calories of food per kilogram in its weight than the child with an average birth weight. These estimates suggest that adverse birth outcomes have lingering impacts on parents in Cebu as they make work, health care, and infant and child feeding decisions during their children’s early childhood.
Table 6 contains estimates of how a representative parent responds to her child’s weight when making preventative care, nutrition, and work decisions. In this table we compare women whose child was at the 20th percentile of each age-adjusted weight distribution to one at the 80th percentile. Unlike the estimates just discussed, these do not incorporate the effect of having a birth weight below 2500 grams. If they are not breast-feeding, at age 12 months the parents of the smaller child provide about 7 more calories of nutritional intakes per kilogram of weight, and this difference is statistically significant. Parents of the smaller children are slightly more likely to take their children to preventative health care visits, and this difference is also statistically significant. Mothers of the smaller children are somewhat more likely to be working when the child is four months old, but the effect is not statistically significant. It is, however, difficult to put a clear interpretation on this result.
Table 6.
Sample size: 30001 | |||
---|---|---|---|
(1) 20th pctile2 (S.E.)4 | (2) 80th pctile3 (S.E.)4 | Parental response (1)–(2) (S.E.)4 | |
Expected calories/kg at year 15 | 84.713 (3.138) | 77.521 (3.080) | 7.192 (0.667) |
Prob(preventive care) at year 1 | 0.116 (0.012) | 0.109 (0.011) | 0.007 (0.003) |
Prob (working away) at month 4 | 0.172 (0.013) | 0.167 (0.014) | 0.005 (0.004) |
Note:
The sample used in these simulation is comprised of 3000 replicates of a typical mother-child pair whose exogenous characteristics are median values of the estimation sample;
Lagged weight and length are held at 20th percentile of population weights and lengths respectively. The values are equivalent to 5371.3 grams and 58.7cm in month 4 and 6953.1 grams and 67.8cm in year 1;
Lagged weight and length are held at 80th percentile of population weights and lengths respectively. The values are equivalent to 6669.0 grams and 62.8cm in month 4 and 8691.3 grams and 72.8cm in year 1 ;
Standard errors are obtained after bootstrapping using 1000 draws of parameters using estimated parameter vector and covariance matrix;
The simulation is carried out conditional on no breast-feeding.
6.3 Impacts of Parental Behaviors on Child Outcomes
Figure 3 presents the estimates of the impacts of breast-feeding on the child’s weight gain over the first year of life using a representative sample to simulate the trajectory of child weights after birth. As discussed in Section 5.1, if there are important, costly, and unmeasured inputs affecting the child’s health, then these effects obtained from a hybrid production function do not capture just the ceteris paribus impact of changes in the observed inputs. Instead, they also incorporate the effects of changes in the unobserved inputs brought about because they are complements or substitutes for the observed inputs, in conjunction with the changes in the unobserved inputs resulting from “loss” of income because one is forced to utilize more of the observed inputs.
The top curve in Figure 3 represents the average weight of children who exclusively breast fed during the first four months of life and thereafter continued to breast-feed with supplemental food through the remainder of the first year of life. Exclusively breast fed children at first gain weight more rapidly than those who only partially breast fed. At month four, these children are about 200 grams heavier. Additionally, these children at age four months are about 400 grams heavier than children who were never breast fed. These differences, however, start to diminish after age four months. By age six months or later there is almost no discernable difference in weight between the children who were exclusive breast fed for the first four months and those who were only partially breast fed. By age 12 months, the children who were never breast fed have nearly caught up with those children who had been breast fed; they are only about 180 grams lighter at that age.
Table 7 presents the estimated impacts of other parental behaviors on the children’s probability of contracting diseases and their weights and lengths when they are age four months. Holding month two child health outcomes and each of the other health inputs constant, we simulate the expected child outcomes at month four in response to parents’ different choices about breast-feeding, maternal working, preventive health care, and caloric intake respectively. Similar to the results shown in Figure 3, significant health benefits are associated with exclusive breast-feeding. The children who are exclusively breast fed up to month four will outgrow those who are not breast-fed after month two by about 240 grams and nearly 0.2 cm in length from month two to month four. The exclusively breast-fed children are also less likely to contract diarrhea and FRI. These latter improvements are somewhat less statistically significant. A mother staying at home at month two and seeking preventive health care at month two appears to have positive effects on children’s weights and lengths at month four, albeit with much smaller magnitudes in contrast to the impacts of exclusive breast-feeding. Preventive health care only reduces the probability of contracting diseases slightly, and the benefits are not statistically significant. However, by increasing caloric intake level at month two from the 20th percentile to the 80th percentile, average children gain an extra 147 grams in weight between months two and four.
Table 7.
Simulation sample size: 30001 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Prob(Diarrhea) (S.E.)2 | Prob(FRI) (S.E.)2 | Weight(kg) (S.E.)2 | Length(cm) (S.E.)2 | |
(1) Exclusive Breast-feeding | 0.218 (0.036) | 0.155 (0.024) | 6.502 (0.105) | 61.411 (0.113) |
(2) No Breast-feeding | 0.240 (0.036) | 0.167 (0.020) | 6.262 (0.105) | 61.220 (0.115) |
(3)Effect of Breast-feeding = (1) – (2) | −0.022 (0.013) | −0.012 (0.014) | 0.240 (0.015) | 0.191 (0.018) |
(4) Working Away from Home | 0.224 (0.036) | 0.165 (0.018) | 6.400 (0.104) | 61.250 (0.114) |
(5) Not working away | 0.232 (0.036) | 0.159 (0.017) | 6.418 (0.104) | 61.266 (0.013) |
(6) Effect of Working Away from Home = (4) – (5) | −0.008 (0.006) | 0.006 (0.007) | −0.018 (0.005) | −0.016 (0.008) |
(7) Preventive care | 0.228 (0.036) | 0.156 (0.018) | 6.417 (0.104) | 61.221 (0.113) |
(8) No preventive care | 0.232 (0.035) | 0.159 (0.016) | 6.415 (0.103) | 61.268 (0.114) |
(9) Effect of Preventative Care = (7) – (8) | −0.003 (0.007) | −0.003 (0.008) | 0.002 (0.006) | −0.047 (0.011) |
(10) 80th pctl supplemental calorie consumption | - | - | 6.451 (0.106) | 61.281 (0.112) |
(11) 20th pctl supplemental calorie consumption | - | - | 6.304 (0.105) | 61.222 (0.111) |
(12) Effect of Extra Calorie Supplementation = (10) – (11) | - | - | 0.147 (0.007) | 0.059 (0.019) |
Note:
The sample used in these simulation is comprised of 3000 replicates of a typical mother-child pair whose exogenous characteristics are median values of the estimation sample;
Standard errors are obtained after bootstrapping using 1000 draws of parameters using estimated parameter vector and covariance matrix.
As was the case for the analysis of the effects of breastfeeding, equation (7) implies that these measured effects of the parental behaviors are contaminated by the parents changing their use of the unmeasured inputs as one exogenously varies the observed health inputs. It is possible to use equation (7) to assess the extent of the possible bias. Suppose there is a single unobserved input with positive marginal product and that this input is a normal good in its conditional demand equation. Under these assumptions, the effects discussed above will underestimate the actual marginal impacts of these inputs unless the observed inputs are strong complements to the unobserved inputs (as measured in the conditional demand). With multiple unobserved inputs, one can derive somewhat similar though more complex, conditions under which the marginal effect from the hybrid demand function will yield underestimates of the true marginal effects. In general, it is likely that these estimates provide lower bound estimates of the true marginal effects, provided there are not large complementarities between the observed and unobserved inputs.
6.4 The Importance of Parental Compensatory Behaviors
The preceding two subsections suggest that parents in Cebu do alter their behaviors in response to their children’s early health outcomes and that these parental behaviors can have beneficial impacts on their children. In this subsection we compare simulations of parental behaviors and outcomes based on estimates from our full model to those from a set of simulations of child outcomes based on situations where parents randomly make their work, breast-feeding, preventative care, and caloric supplementation decisions. The economic model presented in Section 2 predicted more favorable child outcomes, on average, for parents who chose their behaviors “optimally” as opposed to those who picked their behaviors “randomly.” One could clearly pick alternative definitions of non-responsive, counterfactual behaviors, but this one seems to convey well the notion that parents may vary in their behaviors even when they are not motivated by the potential impacts of these behaviors on their children.
If parents do solve a dynamic optimization problem like that described in Section 2, then the estimates we obtain from the CLHNS data should reflect the implications of theoretical model. To assess whether the observed data are in accord with these theoretical predictions, we simulate the estimated dynamic relationships under two scenarios where children vary in initial (birth) status. The first simulates the parents’ behavioral responses as functions of their children’s health status over time and uses these responses as “inputs” to the estimated health production functions. This yields a distribution of child outcomes over time that should correspond to whatever types of decision rules parents actually use for deciding how take care of their children. The second simulated scenario assumes that parents do not takes their children’s observed health status into account when making their when making their health investment decisions. Instead, they “randomly” choose a set of health investments from the observed distribution of parental behaviors from the data set at each age. We use these as inputs to the estimated health production functions in the dynamic simulations.14
We compare the simulated distributions of health outcomes under these two scenarios to assess whether the estimated behavioral relationships appear to yield outcomes that are in accord with the predictions of the dynamic optimization model. A finding that the simulated health outcomes do not differ between the two scenarios in a way that is consistent with the predictions of the theoretical model could be considered a rejection of theory. However, a finding that the results appear to be in accord with the theoretical predictions should not be interpreted as conclusive evidence of optimizing behavior, as the implications we examine are only necessary conditions. Other behaviors, not necessarily ones following from stochastic dynamic optimizing decision rules, could also satisfy the necessary conditions.
Table 8 presents estimates of the consequences of compensatory behaviors for the incidence of diarrhea and respiratory illness. We carry out this analysis separately by whether the child was low birth weight as examined above. For both types of illnesses, we see that the incidence of disease is lower when parents make their behavioral decisions by taking into account the actual health status of their children, though the results are much more striking for the incidence of diarrhea. Nevertheless, all these differences are statistically significant. Additionally, we see that it is the low birth weight children who benefit the most from parents being able to adjust behaviors in response to each child’s progress.
Table 8.
Simulation sample size: 30001 | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Low birthweight2 |
(3) Compensation Effect (1)–(2) (S.E.)6 | Normal birthweight3 |
(6) Compensation Effect (4)–(5) (S.E.)6 | (7) Differential Compensation Effect (3)–(6) (S.E.)6 | ||||
(1) with compensation4 (S.E.)6 | (2) without comensationp5 (S.E.)6 | (4) with compensation4 (S.E.)6 | (5) without compensation5 (S.E.)6 | |||||
Expected months w/diarrhea | in yr 1 | 2.326 (0.076) | 2.412 (0.078) | −0.086 (0.026) | 2.151 (0.043) | 2.228 (0.056) | −0.077 (0.029) | −0.009 (0.001) |
in yr 1,2 | 4.824 (0.156) | 4.976 (0.162) | −0.152 (0.036) | 4.468 (0.204) | 4.580 (0.207) | −0.112 (0.036) | −0.040 (0.007) | |
Expected months w/FRI | in yr 1 | 1.972 (0.108) | 2.017 (0.115) | −0.045 (0.018) | 1.874 (0.082) | 1.901 (0.088) | −0.027 (0.012) | −0.018 (0.004) |
in yr 1,2 | 4.060 (0.152) | 4.136 (0.178) | −0.076 (0.024) | 3.946 (0.206) | 4.004 (0.214) | −0.035 (0.028) | −0.041 (0.013) |
Note:
The sample used in these simulation is comprised of 3000 replicates of a typical mother-child pair whose exogenous characteristics are median values of the estimation sample;
The birth weight is set to be 2.0 kg and birth length is set to be 34.0cm;
The birth weight is set to be 3.3 kg and birth length is set to be 51.0cm;
Both health outcomes and health inputs are simulated using the full model estimates;
Health inputs are randomly drawn from sample;
Standard errors are obtained after bootstrapping using 1000 draws of parameters using estimated parameter vector and covariance matrix.
Figures 4 and 5 examine the consequences of compensatory behavior for normal birth weight children on their weight gain and length increases over the first two years of life. Children whose parents alter their behaviors in response to their child’s development on average have a two-year weight gain 300 grams higher than that for children whose parents do not adjust their behaviors. Similarly, children whose parents’ behaviors respond to the child’s health grow an additional 0.6 centimeters on average over the first two years of life. The estimates we obtain indicate that parents adjust their behaviors in response to their children’s observed health. Most importantly, these adjustments appear to bring about key aggregate improvements in child growth and health. These are precisely the predictions of the dynamic optimization model presented in Section 2.
The analysis in Section 5 revealed, even when there are unmeasured health inputs, that the empirical model can provide uncontaminated estimates of the physiological outcomes resulting from changes in baseline constraints and conditions. Consequently, the columns and graphs labeled “with compensation” in Table 8 and Figures 4 and 5 should provide accurate estimates of the child outcomes when the parents follow their own behavioral rules. The simulations labeled “without compensation,” as implied by equation (7), do not necessarily yield health outcomes corresponding to random allocations of all health production function inputs. Consequently, these comparisons of outcomes with and without compensation likely provide biased estimators of the impacts of the parent’s targeted responses on health outcomes.
It is important to recognize that the empirical model implicitly allows parents to select optimally the unobserved health inputs for any constrained, specified levels of the observed inputs. If the parents are making utility optimizing health input decisions, then the simulations where only the observed inputs are randomly assigned implicitly allow the parents in these counter factual situations to choose purposefully new optimal levels of all the unobserved health inputs. We suspect, but have not proven, that in many cases the choices of the unobserved inputs subject to the randomly chosen constraints will result in health outcomes more closely related to optimally chosen ones without the random constraints, on average, than would be the case if it were possible to assign randomly all health inputs.
If this were indeed the case, then the simulations “without compensation” likely overstate the average health outcomes relative to the case where all inputs would be randomly assigned. In this case, the effects presented in Table 8 and Figures 4 and 5 would understate the true effects of compensating behaviors. Additionally, with diminishing marginal utility of child health and diminishing returns to health inputs, parents who were randomly assigned more observable health inputs than they would have chosen without the constraint would likely choose fewer of the unobserved health inputs than in an unconstrained optimal choice, unless there were quite high production complementarities between the observed and the unobserved inputs. Similarly, parents assigned fewer healthy inputs than they would have optimally chosen without a constraint would compensate by purchasing more of the unobserved health inputs than in the unconstrained case. If this were the case, then the differential compensation effects presented in Table 8 would likely be under-estimates of the true health differential compensation effects that would appear when all inputs were randomly assigned. Compensating behaviors might be even more important for improving health and reducing inequality than the estimates presented in this paper.
7. Discussion and Conclusions
Our simulation results indicate that parental behaviors importantly affect early child health outcomes in Cebu, Philippines. After including controls for unobserved heterogeneity across women, prenatal care results in better birth outcomes in terms of birth length and weight. Early initiation of prenatal care during pregnancy appears to be most beneficial. We find that the event of having been a low birth weight baby has lingering effects even after allowing adjustments in parental behaviors to compensate for this adverse early childhood outcome. Mothers of low birth weight children tend to breast-feed longer relative to mothers whose currently identically sized children had not been low birth weight. Mothers of low birth weight babies are less likely to work; they are more likely to seek preventive health care for their children; and their children consume more calories per kilogram in weight.
While there is evidence of lingering impacts of low birth weight on some child outcomes, the mother’s responses to low birth weight and contemporaneous adverse outcomes during the early life course suggest that there are important compensatory behaviors taking place. For instance, the parents will significantly increase the caloric intake and preventive care visits when their child’s growth appears slow. Analyses that ignore the interactions and endogeneity of parental behaviors and childhood health-related events provide biased estimates of the efficacy of parental behavior towards their children.
Ideally, the characteristics of other children within the family could help researchers understand better the allocation of resources among the family. The CLHNS, however, regularly collected detailed information only on one child for each woman. This limitation makes it difficult to study the family health production process. At the same time, it is also possible that the genetic endowments of low-birth weight children are associated with their parents’ unobserved heterogeneity, which partially determines household resources available to support child growth. Also important might be the fact that we imposed somewhat arbitrary exclusion restrictions and timing conventions on the sequencing of parental behaviors and child outcomes. We did, however, examine alternative conventions and found quantitatively similar results.
It is clear that we have not been able to include all of the relevant health inputs in our empirical analysis. As trenchantly observed by Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983), the resulting hybrid health production function relationships need not correspond well to what economists usually consider as health production functions. Our statistical models do not adjust for these possible factors, and therefore the interpretations placed on the estimated impacts of maternal decisions on child outcomes need to be interpreted with caution. We do, however, present a theoretical analysis of the consequences of missing health inputs and argue that our estimated relationships provide useful, though imperfect, measures of the health production functions.
According to our estimates, mothers in Cebu make work decisions, infant feeding decisions, and preventative child health care decisions based in part on their children’s growth and health. Their tailored behavioral responses appear to be quite effective in improving child outcomes, but it is impossible to disentangle completely the effects of their observable behavioral responses from those due to the hidden behavioral responses in the choices of unobserved health inputs. Overall, there appears to be substantial evidence that these parents are not passive receptors to their children’s progress as they adjust their child care actions in a way that enhances their children’s outcomes. In particular, mothers with the worst off children, as measured by low birth weight and low weight for age, appear to make extra efforts to help their children overcome these developmental deficiencies.
Appendix A—Included here only for Reviewers; this should appear on the web for readers. Additional Empirical Modeling Specifications
Prenatal Care Visits
We use a discrete-time hazard model to help describe the mother’s prenatal care decision and investigate how the probability of commencing professional prenatal care evolves over the course of the pregnancy and how that probability is affected by observed and unobserved characteristics of the mother, the family, and the community where they lived. Conditional on having a prenatal visit, we also model the probability of selecting each one of the three care types.
To facilitate the modeling of this hazard, we use an auxiliary time line, t′, which starts at the initiation of pregnancy and ends when the gestational age is 7 months. The hazard rate for starting prenatal care at time t′ is defined as the probability that she initiated prenatal care at t′ given that she had not done so before t′. This probability is given by:
where t′0 represents the starting time of pregnancy. We model this probability as:
where Logit[x] = exp(x)/[1+ exp(x)], and T′, here equaling 6, represents the assumed maximum gestational age (measured in months) for the first prenatal visit to have a meaningful impact on birth outcomes. To capture arbitrary forms of duration dependence in this hazard function we include a set of time dummies within the hazard rate specification where the omitted period is the first.
In each period t′, we use a nested logit model to characterize the choice of the prenatal care provider, where the first-level alternative is a binary choice of having any prenatal visit (v=0 if not) and the bottom-level alternatives conditional on having any visit are traditional (v=1), hospital (v=2) and clinic (v=3, omitted). For instance, given that a first visit of any type happens at time t′, the probability that this first visit is with a traditional health care provider is modeled by the function
Breast-feeding (bf)
Like the prenatal care visits, discrete choices of breast-feeding are modeled in a nested logit framework, where the first-level alternative is a binary choice of practicing any breast-feeding (bf=1) and the bottom-level alternatives conditional on any breast-feeding are exclusive breast-feeding (bf=2) and partial breast-feeding (bf=3, omitted).
The probabilities of observing breast-feeding practice type k, Pr(bft = k| μ1, μ2) are given by:
and for k =3,
where each of these binary events is modeled as
The choice of working away from home can impose great constraints on decisions about breast-feeding and, in addition, a recent preventive care can have an impact on the breast-feeding choices. To take into account these constraints, we include the lagged choices of working away and preventive care (M) as an explanatory variable in the breast-feeding equations.
Birth Outcomes
After we discretize the measures of birth weight and length, we use the conditional density/hazard rate approach to specify the probability of observing certain birth outcomes. For example, the probability for a newborn’s weight or length to reach a higher discrete level of value conditional on achieving a given level is given by
(16) |
where bo=bw or bl, and the baseline hazard is defined as
(17) |
The covariate component of the hazard rate specification for each birth outcome is given by
for bo=bw, bl.
Weight gain and length increases
We use a similar model for the discretized child outcomes length and weight measured at each of the 12 post-birth surveys. In particular, we model:
where co=cw(child weight) or ch (child length), and the baseline hazard is defined as
The covariate component of the hazard rate specification for each outcome is given respectively by
and
Maternal labor supply (wk)
We specify the probability of mother being working away from home,
Pr[wk (t) =1| μ1,μ2, Ωt] as:
(A.1) |
Here, Xwk (t) contains exogenous child and family characteristics, including child age, child gender, family members, and mother’s demographic variables. The low birth weight status, lagged weight, and lagged heights are included in vector Hk(t−1).
Preventive health care (phc)
We define the preventive health care as any preventive checkup or immunization shots, Pr( phc(t) =1| μ1, μ2, Ωt ),by
(A.2) |
Given that timely immunization shots and physical checkups are important to child’s health outcomes at various stages of their lives, we have included a measure of the time interval between last preventive care and the current month in Xphc(t). This term is also interacted with the current child age so that we can capture any age trend of the impacts of the missed preventive health care treatments. To account for the fact that working mothers can increase their children’s exposure to pathogens brought from outside, we also include a term that measures whether the mother worked away from home at t−1. For women whose work information is missing, we measure this work variable with a predicted probit probability.
Diarrhea (dia)
Diarrhea can have serious consequences for young children, including death. The statistical specification used in this study allows for the identification of a number of important susceptibility and exposure inputs significantly related to the incidence of diarrhea over the first two years of the child’s life. The probability of the child contracting diarrhea at t,
Pr[dia(t) = 1| H (t − 1), M (t − 1, t), μ1, μ2] is given by
(A.3) |
where Mdia(t−1,t) is a vector that comprises a set of endogenous health inputs, including current breast-feeding choice, and lagged values of preventive health care and maternal employment.15 We hypothesize that these health inputs are results of parents’ compensatory behaviors. In particular, parents respond to adverse birth outcomes or other health outcomes they have observed in past periods by modifying the time spent at home (proxied by the choice of working away from home), and preventive health measures. Note that we make an exception about the duration of breast-feeding as its contemporaneous value is used instead of lagged value per discussion presented in Section 2.
Febrile respiratory infection (FRI)
FRI is an important negative health outcome in developing countries. Like diarrhea, this illness is a major cause of infant mortality. However, not only FRI might be caused by different pathogens but also the two diseases have different effects on child development. The probability of any incidence of FRI at t, Pr[fri (t) = 1| H (t − 1), M (t − 1,t), μ1, μ2], is given by
(A.4) |
Similar to the specification for the incidence probability of diarrhea, Mfri includes contemporaneous breast-feeding choice, and the lagged values of preventive health care, and maternal employment and their interaction terms.
Appendix B—Included here only for Reviewers; this should appear on the web for readers
Point Estimates and Standard Errors
B.1.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −3.2038 | 0.5187 |
waiting time in hospital | 0.1159 | 0.1504 |
waiting time in clinic | −0.0743 | 0.0521 |
mean cost of hospital visit | −0.3217 | 0.3085 |
mean cost of clinic visit | −0.0529 | 0.1156 |
doctor/patient ratio hospital | 0.0083 | 0.0046 |
doctor/patient ratio clinic | 0.3672 | 0.5008 |
doctor/staff ratio hospital | 0.1449 | 0.1484 |
trad. caregiver part-time pct | −0.2352 | 0.1274 |
# male in HH age 13+ | −0.0178 | 0.0373 |
# female in HH age 13+ | 0.0229 | 0.0402 |
extended family | 0.0716 | 0.0772 |
# children b/n 0–6 in HH | −0.1531 | 0.0276 |
spouse present | 0.3359 | 0.1255 |
speaking cebu dialect | −0.1653 | 0.1007 |
catholic | −0.0281 | 0.1350 |
other HH members income | 0.1018 | 0.1783 |
HH wealth | 0.0010 | 0.0006 |
mother hlth insurance | 0.1171 | 0.0883 |
mother highest grade | 0.0586 | 0.0096 |
mother age | 0.0049 | 0.0509 |
cereal price | −1.6464 | 1.2632 |
corn price | 0.8583 | 0.8432 |
urban | −0.0083 | 0.0904 |
gestation month 2 | 0.4407 | 0.1508 |
gestation month 3 | 1.6294 | 0.1312 |
gestation month 4 | 1.8718 | 0.1321 |
gestation month 5 | 3.1890 | 0.1282 |
gestation month 6 | 3.2850 | 0.1393 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −0.8642 | 0.9988 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 2.0874 | 2.3189 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −1.6832 | 1.5026 |
B.2.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | 1.5241 | 0.9593 |
mean wait time in hospital | 0.1012 | 0.2831 |
mean waiting time in clinic | 0.0096 | 0.0883 |
mean cost of hospital visit | −0.1917 | 0.5766 |
mean cost of clinic visit | −0.2181 | 0.2092 |
doctor/patient ratio hospital | 0.0010 | 0.0082 |
doctor/patient ratio clinic | −1.4374 | 0.8820 |
doctor/staff ratio hospital | −0.1265 | 0.2697 |
trad. caregiver part-time pct. | 0.2024 | 0.2259 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.0170 | 0.0642 |
# females in HH age 13+ | −0.0472 | 0.0723 |
extended family | −0.1108 | 0.1350 |
# children b/n 0–6 in HH | 0.0744 | 0.0464 |
spouse present | 0.0470 | 0.2343 |
speaking cebu dialect | 0.1422 | 0.1895 |
catholic | 0.4980 | 0.2326 |
other HH members income | −0.0368 | 0.2858 |
HH wealth | 0.0001 | 0.0008 |
mother hlth insurance | −0.5856 | 0.1819 |
mother highest grade | −0.1697 | 0.0186 |
mother age | −0.2348 | 0.0939 |
cereal price | 0.8390 | 2.3244 |
corn price | −3.2306 | 1.4674 |
urban | −0.3164 | 0.1566 |
gestation month 2 | −0.2997 | 0.3183 |
gestation month 3 | 0.1276 | 0.2813 |
gestation month 4 | −0.1697 | 0.2802 |
gestation month 5 | 0.0873 | 0.2683 |
gestation month 6 | −0.1820 | 0.2772 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | 1.6184 | 1.7107 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | −2.7457 | 3.9830 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | 1.6407 | 2.5983 |
B.3.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −2.6137 | 1.8277 |
mean waiting time in hospital | 0.4814 | 0.7556 |
mean waiting time in clinic | −0.0678 | 0.1868 |
mean cost of hospital visit | −2.7443 | 1.4875 |
mean cost of clinic visit | 1.0955 | 0.3729 |
doctor/patient ratio hospital | −0.0002 | 0.0195 |
doctor/patient ratio clinic | −3.3542 | 2.6624 |
doctor/staff ratio hospital | −1.6629 | 0.4870 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.0618 | 0.1087 |
# females in HH age 13+ | −0.0443 | 0.1344 |
extended family | 0.3373 | 0.2460 |
# children b/n 0–6 in HH | −0.2349 | 0.0982 |
spouse present | −0.6769 | 0.3504 |
speaking cebu dialect | −0.2454 | 0.2844 |
catholic | 0.1484 | 0.3249 |
other HH members income | −0.3396 | 0.3890 |
HH wealth | 0.0009 | 0.0019 |
mother hlth insurance | −0.0520 | 0.2404 |
mother highest grade | 0.1836 | 0.0316 |
mother age | 0.1633 | 0.1782 |
cereal price | 6.9607 | 4.7710 |
corn price | −3.5714 | 2.9767 |
urban | 0.4319 | 0.5194 |
gestation month 2 | −0.5921 | 0.5252 |
gestation month 3 | 0.4789 | 0.3875 |
gestation month 4 | 0.2422 | 0.4011 |
gestation month 5 | 0.3985 | 0.3864 |
gestation month 6 | 0.4878 | 0.4143 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −4.1047 | 3.1056 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 8.4240 | 8.0826 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −5.6046 | 5.6789 |
B.4.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
Intercept | −7.6586 | 0.9175 |
cereal price | 2.3825 | 1.2905 |
corn price | −0.0363 | 0.7468 |
parity X previous baby | 0.0554 | 0.0188 |
previous baby | 0.3440 | 0.0766 |
mother age | 0.0524 | 0.0648 |
mother height | 0.0431 | 0.0053 |
dry season at interview | 0.0327 | 0.0794 |
wet season at interview | 0.0092 | 0.0581 |
sex of child | 0.0741 | 0.0511 |
urban | 0.2321 | 0.0630 |
clinic care | 0.2445 | 0.1639 |
traditional care | 0.4197 | 0.3165 |
hospital care | 0.1705 | 0.1455 |
clinic care X month of visit | −0.0424 | 0.0339 |
trad care X month of visit | −0.0496 | 0.0685 |
hosp care X month of visit | −0.0153 | 0.0297 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −3.6243 | 0.9288 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 6.1173 | 2.0610 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −4.3450 | 1.2893 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | −0.9869 | 0.6364 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 0.7428 | 0.8940 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 0.5330 | 0.4387 |
1st order baseline hazard | 0.1054 | 0.0703 |
2nd order baseline hazard | 2.4697 | 0.8052 |
3rd order baseline hazard | −5.0244 | 2.0832 |
4th order baseline hazard | 2.4647 | 1.3635 |
B.5.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −9.4864 | 0.9582 |
cereal price | 0.4248 | 1.2476 |
corn price | 2.8800 | 0.7852 |
parity X previous live baby | 0.0082 | 0.0184 |
previous live baby | 0.1328 | 0.0781 |
mother age | 0.1202 | 0.0657 |
mother height | 0.0534 | 0.0055 |
dry season at interview | −0.0974 | 0.0772 |
wet season at interview | −0.0137 | 0.0615 |
sex of child | 0.2148 | 0.0529 |
urban | 0.2604 | 0.0614 |
clinic care | 0.1060 | 0.1673 |
traditional care | 0.2479 | 0.1347 |
hospital care | 0.1007 | 0.3264 |
clinic care X month of visit | −0.0177 | 0.0337 |
trad care X month of visit | −0.0466 | 0.0274 |
hosp care X month of visit | −0.0156 | 0.0694 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −3.0574 | 0.9447 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 5.2561 | 2.1210 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −3.9619 | 1.3407 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 4.6884 | 0.8212 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | −9.7967 | 2.0925 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 4.8447 | 1.3621 |
1st order baseline hazard | −0.3764 | 06290 |
2nd order baseline hazard | 1.2144 | 0.8790 |
3rd order baseline hazard | 0.6042 | 04319 |
4th order baseline hazard | 0.0991 | 0.0693 |
B.6.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −5.2773 | 10.0890 |
child age | −0.2542 | 0.0444 |
child age squared | 0.0032 | 0.0012 |
# children 0–6 | 0.0009 | 0.0283 |
density of community | 0.0061 | 0.0021 |
# females in HH age13+ | −0.0490 | 0.0376 |
# males in HH age 13+ | 0.1026 | 0.0345 |
mother height | −2.0684 | 0.6461 |
mother highest grade | −0.0861 | 0.0098 |
mother age | 0.0160 | 0.0054 |
previous live baby | 0.3310 | 0.0891 |
sex of child | −0.1112 | 0.0594 |
urban | −0.2005 | 0.0893 |
cereal price | −0.1269 | 0.0691 |
lowest formula price | 0.1072 | 0.0539 |
other HH members inc | −0.0741 | 0.0947 |
extended family | −0.0832 | 0.0600 |
spouse present | 0.0901 | 0.0845 |
dry season at interview | 0.0437 | 0.0675 |
wet season at interview | 0.1827 | 0.0606 |
distance to City Hall | −0.1323 | 0.0984 |
prevailing unskilled wage rate | −0.0964 | 0.0895 |
prevailing female wage rate | −0.1016 | 0.2773 |
travel time to nearest health facilities | 0.0027 | 0.0027 |
average waiting time in clinics | 0.0395 | 0.0323 |
low birth weight | 0.1507 | 0.0919 |
log(lagged weight) | 0.3331 | 1.1571 |
log(lagged weight)2 | 0.6294 | 0.3370 |
log(lagged height) | 11.6603 | 11.4542 |
log(lagged height)2 | −3.5877 | 3.0840 |
birth day interview | −5.8677 | 0.2565 |
first followup interview | −0.6247 | 0.2455 |
lagged working away | −0.1347 | 0.0691 |
lagged preventive health care | −0.0743 | 0.1133 |
lagged diarrhea | −0.1672 | 0.0746 |
lagged FRI | −0.0929 | 0.0826 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | 3.2509 | 0.9781 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | −6.2673 | 2.2127 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | 4.2331 | 1.4235 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 0.1712 | 0.8704 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | 2.4846 | 2.2970 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | −2.4903 | 1.4973 |
B.7.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −3.8953 | 22.2504 |
child age | 1.9009 | 0.7065 |
child age squared | −0.3291 | 0.0754 |
# children 0–6 | 0.0396 | 0.0483 |
density of community | 0.0071 | 0.0035 |
# females in HH age 13+ | −0.0630 | 0.0694 |
# male in HH age 13+ | 0.0692 | 0.0617 |
mother height | 0.4628 | 0.9317 |
mother highest grade | −0.1671 | 0.0180 |
mother age | −0.0518 | 0.0090 |
previous live baby | 0.3424 | 0.1587 |
sex of child | −0.3095 | 0.0914 |
urban | −0.9695 | 0.1258 |
cereal price | 0.0076 | 0.1595 |
lowest formula price | 0.1377 | 0.0655 |
other HH members inc | 0.0799 | 0.2220 |
extended family | −0.0486 | 0.1070 |
spouse present | 0.4287 | 0.1748 |
dry season at interview | −0.0970 | 0.1201 |
wet season at interview | −0.0984 | 0.1063 |
distance to City Hall | −0.1094 | 0.1464 |
prevailing unskilled wage rate | 0.2747 | 0.1361 |
prevailing female wage rate | 0.2008 | 0.4299 |
travel time to nearest health facility | 0.0075 | 0.0033 |
average waiting time in clinics | 0.1320 | 0.0520 |
low birth weight | 0.1216 | 0.1546 |
log(lagged weight) | −0.0592 | 2.1120 |
log(lagged weight)2 | 0.3337 | 0.7892 |
log(lagged height) | −4.3825 | 27.5899 |
log(lagged height)2 | 1.5546 | 8.3203 |
first followup interview | 1.6172 | 0.6888 |
lagged working away | 0.1680 | 0.2515 |
lagged preventive health care | −0.1130 | 0.2409 |
lagged diarrhea | −0.1766 | 0.3163 |
lagged FRI | −0.1421 | 0.2331 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | 0.3075 | 1.6054 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 1.5179 | 3.5433 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −1.0359 | 2.2520 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 1.5960 | 1.9769 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | 17.6457 | 3.9170 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | −17.4876 | 2.2798 |
B.8.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −24.9318 | 8.5382 |
child age | −0.1065 | 0.0420 |
child age squared | −0.0019 | 0.0014 |
# children 0–6 | −0.0732 | 0.0255 |
density of community | −0.0048 | 0.0017 |
# females in HH age 13+ | 0.0538 | 0.0308 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.0047 | 0.0290 |
mother height | 0.5710 | 0.5245 |
mother highest grade | 0.0730 | 0.0080 |
mother age | 0.0007 | 0.0048 |
previous live baby | −0.0625 | 0.0748 |
sex of child | −0.1419 | 0.0504 |
urban | 0.5736 | 0.0909 |
cereal price | −0.0462 | 0.0811 |
lowest formula price | −0.0916 | 0.0487 |
other HH members inc | 0.0559 | 0.0772 |
extended family | −0.1032 | 0.0562 |
spouse present | −0.0956 | 0.0787 |
dry season at interview | 0.2232 | 0.0663 |
wet season at interview | 0.1846 | 0.0599 |
distance to City Hall | −0.0946 | 0.1002 |
prevailing unskilled wage rate | −0.0326 | 0.0858 |
prevailing female wage rate | 1.1876 | 0.2459 |
travel time to nearest health facility | −0.0040 | 0.0028 |
average waiting time in clinics | −0.3153 | 0.0351 |
low birth weight | 0.1294 | 0.0786 |
log(lagged weight) | 3.0252 | 1.0818 |
log(lagged weight)2 | −0.5781 | 0.3184 |
log(lagged height) | 21.1641 | 10.1088 |
log(lagged height)2 | −5.5282 | 2.7977 |
lagged working away | −0.1341 | 0.0735 |
lagged preventive health care | 0.4072 | 0.0908 |
lagged diarrhea | −0.1150 | 0.0737 |
lagged FRI | 0.0789 | 0.0730 |
duration since last care | −0.4308 | 0.0595 |
age X duration | 0.0304 | 0.0063 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −0.2065 | 0.8073 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 1.1896 | 1.9239 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −1.0378 | 1.2929 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | −0.4647 | 0.7757 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | 0.0222 | 1.9479 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 0.3845 | 1.2483 |
B.9.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −0.0518 | 7.9031 |
child age | 0.1356 | 0.0358 |
child age squared | −0.0024 | 0.0010 |
# children 0–6 | 0.0329 | 0.0193 |
density of community | −0.0016 | 0.0013 |
# females in HH age 13+ | 0.0350 | 0.0246 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.0140 | 0.0226 |
mother height | 0.3132 | 0.4147 |
mother highest grade | 0.0262 | 0.0058 |
mother age | 0.0342 | 0.0034 |
previous live baby | −0.1239 | 0.0614 |
sex of child | 0.0846 | 0.0394 |
urban | 0.1551 | 0.0605 |
cereal price | −0.0448 | 0.0538 |
lowest formula price | 0.0449 | 0.0381 |
other HH members inc | −0.1468 | 0.0400 |
extended family | 0.1286 | 0.0435 |
spouse present | −0.0194 | 0.0580 |
dry season at interview | −0.0231 | 0.0535 |
wet season at interview | −0.0339 | 0.0485 |
distance to City Hall | 0.0732 | 0.0608 |
prevailing unskilled wage rate | 0.0976 | 0.0534 |
prevailing female wage rate | −0.0527 | 0.1706 |
travel time to nearest health facilities | 0.0068 | 0.0017 |
average waiting time in clinics | −0.0203 | 0.0214 |
low birth weight | −0.1707 | 0.0603 |
log(lagged weight) | −0.5598 | 1.0817 |
log(lagged weight)2 | −0.1594 | 0.3078 |
log(lagged height) | −1.4161 | 9.2069 |
log(lagged height)2 | 0.0434 | 2.4674 |
lagged working away | 3.6719 | 0.0348 |
lagged preventive health care | 0.1142 | 0.0803 |
lagged diarrhea | 0.0720 | 0.0599 |
lagged FRI | 0.0173 | 0.0604 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −1.4538 | 0.5712 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 0.6137 | 1.3208 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | 0.1711 | 0.8705 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | −3.2073 | 0.5708 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | 3.7475 | 1.4826 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | −1.0438 | 0.9571 |
B.10.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −12.2108 | 7.1138 |
child age | 0.0033 | 0.0284 |
child age squared | −0.0019 | 0.0008 |
# children 0–6 | 0.0122 | 0.0145 |
density of community | 0.0054 | 0.0008 |
# females in HH age 13+ | −0.0762 | 0.0187 |
# males in HH age 13+ | 0.0298 | 0.0169 |
mother height | −1.8312 | 0.3298 |
mother highest grade | −0.0414 | 0.0052 |
mother age | −0.0071 | 0.0026 |
previous live baby | −0.0257 | 0.0446 |
sex of child | 0.0842 | 0.0311 |
urban | 0.0768 | 0.0363 |
cereal price | 0.1012 | 0.0426 |
lowest formula price | −0.1633 | 0.0320 |
other HH members inc | −0.0464 | 0.0538 |
extended family | 0.0072 | 0.0328 |
spouse present | −0.0343 | 0.0479 |
dry season at interview | −0.0898 | 0.0458 |
wet season at interview | 0.0948 | 0.0399 |
low birth weight | 0.0311 | 0.0445 |
log(lagged weight) | 1.0214 | 1.0721 |
log(lagged weight)2 | −0.0061 | 0.2839 |
log(lagged height) | 12.6017 | 8.3219 |
log(lagged height)2 | −3.2086 | 2.1758 |
age X any BF | 0.0171 | 0.0063 |
age X exclusive BF | 0.1214 | 0.1118 |
exclusive BF | −0.6005 | 0.3070 |
any BF | −0.4164 | 0.0865 |
lagged working away | −0.0255 | 0.0380 |
lagged preventive health care | −0.0052 | 0.0601 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | 0.0940 | 0.4875 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 0.6789 | 1.0911 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −0.2235 | 0.7162 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 1.8284 | 0.4428 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | −4.8991 | 1.1018 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 3.2175 | 0.7091 |
B.11.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −3.8651 | 6.7524 |
child age | −0.0018 | 0.0298 |
child age squared | −0.0007 | 0.0008 |
# children 0–6 | 0.0304 | 0.0171 |
density of community | 0.0001 | 0.0009 |
# females iin HH age 13+ | −0.0319 | 0.0219 |
# males in HH age 13+ | 0.0412 | 0.0197 |
mother height | −0.6480 | 0.3625 |
mother highest grade | −0.0379 | 0.0057 |
mother age | 0.0065 | 0.0030 |
previous live baby | 0.0290 | 0.0529 |
sex of child | 0.0739 | 0.0353 |
urban | 0.1427 | 0.0417 |
cereal price | 0.0998 | 0.0458 |
lowest formula price | 0.0244 | 0.0323 |
other HH members inc | 0.0305 | 0.0532 |
extended family | 0.0547 | 0.0373 |
spouse present | −0.0112 | 0.0539 |
dry season at interview | −0.0261 | 0.0476 |
wet season at interview | −0.0287 | 0.0422 |
low birth weight | 0.0038 | 0.0495 |
log(lagged weight) | −1.0488 | 0.9229 |
log(lagged weight)2 | 0.2583 | 0.2528 |
log(lagged height) | 2.7776 | 7.7935 |
log(lagged height)2 | −0.4150 | 2.0671 |
age X any BF | 0.0013 | 0.0070 |
age X exclusive BF | 0.1443 | 0.0475 |
exclusive BF | −0.4763 | 0.1878 |
any BF | −0.1474 | 0.1048 |
lagged working away | 0.0744 | 0.0411 |
lagged preventive health care | −0.0412 | 0.0651 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −0.3592 | 0.5837 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 1.7963 | 1.2871 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −1.1841 | 0.8234 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 2.0884 | 0.5013 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | −6.0085 | 1.2724 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 3.9608 | 0.8249 |
B.12.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −15.4131 | 1.6463 |
child age | 0.1074 | 0.0159 |
child age squared | −0.0035 | 0.0005 |
# children 0–6 | −0.0238 | 0.0125 |
density of community | 0.0037 | 0.0009 |
# females in HH age 13+ | 0.0244 | 0.0168 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.0389 | 0.0157 |
mother height | −0.2600 | 0.2748 |
mother highest grade | 0.0975 | 0.0044 |
mother age | 0.0242 | 0.0022 |
previous live baby | −0.3132 | 0.0421 |
sex of child | 0.2001 | 0.0244 |
urban | 0.3931 | 0.0335 |
cereal price | −0.0911 | 0.0318 |
lowest formula price | −0.0594 | 0.0189 |
other HH members inc | 0.0325 | 0.0431 |
extended family | 0.0084 | 0.0257 |
spouse present | −0.0703 | 0.0414 |
dry season at interview | −0.0546 | 0.0307 |
wet season at interview | −0.0290 | 0.0263 |
distance to City Hall | 0.1564 | 0.0415 |
prevailing unskilled wage rate | 0.0989 | 0.0425 |
prevailing female wage rate | 0.2985 | 0.1206 |
travel time to nearest health facility | −0.0085 | 0.0010 |
average waiting time in clinics | −0.0459 | 0.0139 |
low birth weight | 0.0113 | 0.0389 |
log(lagged weight) | 0.3642 | 0.4872 |
log(lagged weight)2 | −0.3029 | 0.1463 |
log(lagged height) | 30.4222 | 3.9453 |
log(lagged height)2 | −7.6010 | 1.0891 |
any bf | −15.4131 | 1.6463 |
lagged working away | −0.0050 | 0.0321 |
lagged preventive care | −0.0155 | 0.0410 |
lagged diarrhea | 0.1337 | 0.0347 |
lagged FRI | 0.0851 | 0.0354 |
1st order baseline hazard | 4.0612 | 0.5437 |
2nd order baseline hazard | −6.8270 | 0.9870 |
3rd order baseline hazard | 5.2690 | 0.6161 |
4th order baseline hazard | −1.2166 | 0.1257 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −0.9738 | 0.4005 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 0.4064 | 0.9167 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | 0.5128 | 0.5992 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | −3.3163 | 0.2960 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | −7.4179 | 0.6962 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 9.1297 | 0.4432 |
B.13.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | −11.3768 | 0.6572 |
child age | −0.6600 | 0.0187 |
child age squared | 0.0129 | 0.0005 |
# children 0–6 | −0.1073 | 0.0197 |
density of community | −0.0069 | 0.0011 |
# females in HH age 13+ | 0.0897 | 0.0240 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.1288 | 0.0231 |
mother height | 10.4594 | 0.3977 |
mother highest grade | 0.1315 | 0.0065 |
mother age | 0.0122 | 0.0035 |
previous live baby | −0.3713 | 0.0632 |
sex of child | 1.1325 | 0.0402 |
urban | 0.0729 | 0.0481 |
cereal price | −0.0770 | 0.0259 |
lowest formula price | 0.0143 | 0.0181 |
other HH members inc | −0.0638 | 0.0428 |
extended family | 0.0797 | 0.0242 |
spouse present | −0.0736 | 0.0366 |
dry season at interview | 0.0008 | 0.0286 |
wet season at interview | −0.1429 | 0.0239 |
low birth weight | −0.5494 | 0.0625 |
log(lagged weight) | −11.6773 | 0.2823 |
log(lagged weight)2 | 5.6933 | 0.0930 |
exclusive BF | 0.4855 | 0.0516 |
any BF | 1.2055 | 0.1203 |
log(lagged calorie/gram) | −0.1273 | 0.0277 |
log(lagged calorie/gram)^2 | 0.3110 | 0.0386 |
lagged working away | 0.0095 | 0.0302 |
lagged preventive care | −0.0329 | 0.0317 |
lagged diarrhea | −0.5507 | 0.7903 |
lagged FRI | 6.5557 | 4.0048 |
log(lagged calorie/g) X any BF | −2.6040 | 0.3630 |
age X any BF | −0.1227 | 0.0093 |
age X any BF X log(lagged cal/g) | 0.4290 | 0.0337 |
log(lagged cal/g) X 0–6 months | −2.6736 | 0.2643 |
log(lagged cal/g) X 7–12 months | −2.2087 | 0.1563 |
1st order baseline hazard | 0.6845 | 0.3005 |
2nd order baseline hazard | 5.5748 | 0.5943 |
3rd order baseline hazard | −4.4990 | 0.3919 |
4th order baseline hazard | 1.2283 | 0.0835 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −16.3379 | 0.5280 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 28.9373 | 1.2071 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −20.3668 | 0.7665 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 0.1113 | 0.48138 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | 2.9761 | 1.20737 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | −3.1704 | 0.78399 |
B.14.
Coeff. | S.E. | |
---|---|---|
intercept | 62.4437 | 2.3480 |
child age | −1.0259 | 0.0175 |
child age squared | 0.0168 | 0.0005 |
# children 0–6 | −0.1183 | 0.0129 |
density of community | −0.0020 | 0.0007 |
# females in HH age 13+ | 0.0600 | 0.0153 |
# males in HH age 13+ | −0.0645 | 0.0151 |
mother height | 8.8000 | 0.2695 |
mother highest grade | 0.0829 | 0.0043 |
mother age | 0.0097 | 0.0023 |
previous live baby | −0.2132 | 0.0416 |
sex of child | 0.5697 | 0.0255 |
urban | −0.0192 | 0.0309 |
cereal price | −0.0286 | 0.0240 |
lowest formula price | −0.0001 | 0.0150 |
other HH members inc | 0.0065 | 0.0385 |
extended family | 0.0935 | 0.0211 |
spouse present | 0.0112 | 0.0303 |
dry season at interview | 0.0306 | 0.0232 |
wet season at interview | −0.1335 | 0.0214 |
low birth weight | −0.2706 | 0.0382 |
log(lagged height) | −108.5019 | 2.6205 |
log(lagged height)2 | 37.8897 | 0.7503 |
lagged exclusive BF | 0.5764 | 0.0440 |
lagged any BF | 0.0711 | 0.0752 |
log(lagged calorie/g) | −0.0897 | 0.0256 |
log(lagged calorie/g)^2 | 0.1405 | 0.0309 |
lagged working away | −0.1064 | 0.0271 |
lagged preventive care | −0.0244 | 0.0273 |
lagged diarrhea | 2.1423 | 0.9651 |
lagged FRI | 2.2280 | 4.1186 |
log(lagged calorie/g) X lagged any BF | 0.0323 | 1.1646 |
age X any laggedd BF | 0.0102 | 0.0057 |
age X any BF X lagged(lagged cal/g) | 0.0421 | 0.0955 |
log(lagged cal/g) X age 0–6 months | −4.3009 | 0.7127 |
log(lagged cal/g) X age 7–12 months | −4.5082 | 0.5007 |
1st order baseline hazard | 1.1848 | 0.2918 |
2nd order baseline hazard | 3.0667 | 0.5802 |
3rd order baseline hazard | −2.5627 | 0.3817 |
4th order baseline hazard | 0.7342 | 0.0810 |
loading on 1st order μ1 | −7.7425 | 0.3829 |
loading on 2nd order μ1 | 14.2328 | 0.8648 |
loading on 3rd order μ1 | −10.3500 | 0.5542 |
loading on 1st order μ2 | 6.5951 | 0.3374 |
loading on 2nd order μ2 | −13.5458 | 0.8419 |
loading on 3rd order μ2 | 6.3459 | 0.5399 |
B.15.
Support Point | Coefficient | Standard Error | Implied Probability |
---|---|---|---|
0 | 0.5311 | 0.0302 | 0.1636 |
1/3 | −0.6775 | 0.0198 | 0.2610 |
2/3 | −0.6999 | 0.0197 | 0.2779 |
1 | - | - | 0.2975 |
B.16.
Support Point | Coefficient | Standard Error | Implied Probability |
---|---|---|---|
0 | −0.7674 | 0.0586 | 0.0706 |
1/6 | −1.0166 | 0.0781 | 0.1192 |
1/3 | 1.1364 | 0.1293 | 0.1463 |
1/2 | −1.4625 | 0.1047 | 0.2248 |
2/3 | 4.8695 | 0.1075 | 0.2126 |
5/6 | 1.1509 | 0.1117 | 0.1496 |
1 | - | - | 0.0769 |
Footnotes
We thank two referees and the editor for extensive and insightful comments on earlier versions of this paper. We also thank seminar participants at the 2006 Southern Economic Association meetings, University of Virginia, Ohio State University, and University of Regensburg for comments and discussions.
In some situations researchers estimate dynamic demand models which hold constant the marginal utility of wealth. The above formulation is consistent with such an approach as the marginal utility of wealth is necessarily only a function of the current observed state and the current, observed information set.
There were 37 stillbirths, 13 miscarriages, 27 twin births, and 170 women who either migrated before the childbirth or refused further interviews..
This approach directly corresponds to the economic models described in previous section. A variety of empirical specifications have been discussed and tested by researchers that study the health and education production processes. For example, Rosenzweig and Schultz (1983), Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1988), Hanushek (1992), and Todd and Wolpin(2003, 2007) provide extensive discussions on this issue. An alternative specification would relate current health outcomes to all historical health inputs. This “cumulative” approach is not practical in this paper. Note that we do not carry out an assessment of the importance of measurement errors in these lagged explanatory variables.
We conducted a sensitivity analysis about this assumption by specifying a single heterogeneity term, which is equivalent of modeling fixed composition of both sources of heterogeneity from mother and child. In general, the specification of time-varying heterogeneity terms yields an improved statistical fit.
Given the assumption that ε’s are serially uncorrelated, this specification implies that any serial correlations are captured by heterogeneity terms, μ. Further discussions about the restrictiveness of this specification are provided in the sections below.
We do model breast-feeding and its effects which can vary by breastfeeding intensity and across mothers. “Self-selection” is then modeled by allowing dependence among the person-specific unobservable factors affecting breast feeding, caloric consumption, and all the other modeled processes.
They would be completely nonparametric if we used four points of support for each discrete distribution
Presumably, the purpose of choosing a prenatal visit in this context would be for the mother to obtain more information about how to choose better prenatal inputs and use them more efficiently.
A more complete approach would be to model the decision about whether to have a prenatal care visit as a comparison of the expected utilities with and without the prenatal care visit, and then to estimate the impacts of this decision on all of the other prenatal care inputs and how those changed input levels impact the birth outcomes. In this paper we provide an empirical approximation model for the prenatal care decision, but we do not trace though the complete set of pathways through which the information obtained at the prenatal visit affects the other input choices.
Prices and incomes at period 2 will typically be unobserved. In our empirical analysis we impose the restriction that prices and income at time “period 3” proxy for the time “period 2” economic variables. In preliminary work we instead used period 1 variables to proxy for these exogenous factors for the intervening time period and obtained nearly identical results.
These total effects would be identical to those calculated by substituting the unconditional demands for all inputs into the production function. This would be, except for the presence of statistically endogenous health determinants like prior health status, a reduced form expression for health production.
To reduce the number of parameters in the model, we excluded from the health outcome equations the five community characteristics associated with labor market conditions and accessibility to health facilities. None of the main model implications are sensitive to this set of exclusions.
Specifically, we assign a representative woman with mean values of all exogenous characteristics over the sequence of observational periods from the estimation sample. We then draw 3000 sets of i.i.d. Extreme Value errors for each equation and period indicated in the likelihood function (Section 4.3). For each set of these errors, we also draw a heterogeneity type for each mother/child pair and the probability of each type is given by the estimates presented in Table B15 and B16. Following the time-line described in Section 4, we trace out the sequence of endogenous health inputs as well as health outcomes.
These random draws, in a sense, hold the aggregate health expenditures constant in the population. By sampling unconditionally from the distribution of observed actions, this approach also introduces possible variations in behaviors due to family background characteristics unrelated to each child’s health status. Note that this approach does not require these imposed inputs to satisfy the budget constraint for each household.
It also includes interaction terms between child age and breast-feeding choices, given that the age-specific effects of supplemental feeding on the incidence of child diseases are nonlinear.
Publisher's Disclaimer: This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final citable form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
Contributor Information
Haiyong Liu, Department of Economics, East Carolina University.
Thomas Mroz, Department of Economics, Clemson University.
Linda Adair, Department of Nutrition, Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.
References
- Adair LS. Filipino children exhibit catch-up growth from age 2 to 12 years. Journal of Nutrition. 1999;129:1140–1148. doi: 10.1093/jn/129.6.1140. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Behrman JR, Taubman P. The intergenerational correlation between children’s adult earnings and their parents’ income: results from the Michigan Panel Survey of Income Dynamics. Review of Income and Wealth. 1990;36(2):115–27. [Google Scholar]
- Bhargava A. Identification and panel data models with endogenous regressors. Review of Economic Studies. 1991;58:129–140. [Google Scholar]
- Blau DM. The effect of income on child development. Review of Economics and Statistics. 1999;91(2):261–276. [Google Scholar]
- Blundell R, Magnac T, Meghir C. Savings and labor market transitions. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. 1997;15(2):153–164. [Google Scholar]
- Cameron AC, Trivedi PK. Microeconometrics. Cambridge University Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Cebu Study Team. A child health production function estimated from longitudinal data. Journal of Development Economics. 1992;38:323–351. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Daniels Melissa C, Adair Linda S. Growth in young Filipino children predicts schooling trajectories through high school. Journal of Nutrition. 2004;134:1439–1446. doi: 10.1093/jn/134.6.1439. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Duncan GJ, Brooks-Gunn J, Klebanov PK. Economic deprivation and early childhood development. Child Development. 1994;65:296–318. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Gilleskie D, Mroz T. A flexible approach for estimating the effects of covariates on health expenditures. Journal of Health Economics. 2004;23:391–418. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2003.09.008. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Hanushek EA. The trade-off between child quantity and quality. Journal of Political Economy. 1992;100(1):84–117. [Google Scholar]
- Heckman J, Singer B. A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica. 1984;52(2):271–320. [Google Scholar]
- Kramer MS. Determinants of intrauterine growth and gestational duration: A methodologic assessment. Bulletin of the WHO. 1987;65:663–737. [Google Scholar]
- Lozoff B. Nutrition, Health and Child Development. Washington DC: Pan American Health Organization Scientific Publication No 556; 1998. Explanatory mechanisms for poorer development in iron deficient anemic children; pp. 162–178. [Google Scholar]
- Mendez Michelle A, Adair Linda S. Severity and timing of stunting in the first two years of life affect performance on cognitive tests in late childhood. Journal of Nutrition. 1999;129:1555–1562. doi: 10.1093/jn/129.8.1555. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Mroz TA. Discrete factor approximations in simultaneous equation models: estimating the impact of a dummy endogenous variable on a continuous outcome. Journal of Econometrics. 1999;92(2):233–74. doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(98)00091-8. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Mroz T, Surette B. Post-secondary schooling and training effects on wages and employment. UNC-Chapel Hill Department of Economics; mimeo: 1998. [Google Scholar]
- Mroz T, Weir D. Stochastic dynamic optimization models with random effects in parameters: An application to age at marriage and life-cycle fertility control in France under the old regime. In: Guinnane T, Sundstrom W, Whatley W, editors. History Matters: Essays in Honor of Paul A David. Stanford University Press; 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Rosenzweig MR, Wolpin KI. Heterogeneity, intrafamily distribution, and child health. Journal of Human Resources. 1988;23(4):437–461. [Google Scholar]
- Rosenzweig MR, Schultz TP. Estimating a household production function: Heterogeneity, the demand for health inputs, and their effects on birthweight. Journal of Political Economy. 1983;92:723–746. [Google Scholar]
- Rous JJ. Is breast-feeding a substitute for contraception in family planning? Demography. 2001;38(4):497–512. doi: 10.1353/dem.2001.0037. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Smart JL. Nutrition, Health and Child Development. Washington DC: Pan American Health Organization Scientific Publication No 556; 1998. Malnutrition, behavior and learning: Recent advances in laboratory animal research; pp. 1–13. [Google Scholar]
- Stewart JF, Guilkey DK. Estimating the health impact of industry infant food marketing practices in the Philippines. Journal of Development Studies. 2000;36(3):50–77. [Google Scholar]
- Todd PE, Wolpin KI. On the specification and estimation of the production function for cognitive achievement. Economic Journal. 2003;113:3–33. [Google Scholar]
- Todd PE, Wolpin KI. The production of cognitive achievement in children: Home, school, and racial test score gaps. Journal of Human Capital. 2007;1(1):91–136. [Google Scholar]
- Walker M, Tekin E, Wallace S. NBER working paper. 13386. 2007. Teen Smoking and Birth Outcomes. [Google Scholar]