Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2013 May 1.
Published in final edited form as: Econ J (London). 2012 Apr 12;122(560):418–448. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02499.x

The Effect of Education on Old Age Cognitive Abilities: Evidence from a Regression Discontinuity Design*

James Banks 1, Fabrizio Mazzonna 2
PMCID: PMC3351837  NIHMSID: NIHMS338875  PMID: 22611283

Abstract

In this paper we exploit the 1947 change to the minimum school-leaving age in England from 14 to 15, to evaluate the causal effect of a year of education on cognitive abilities at older ages. We use a regression discontinuity design analysis and find a large and significant effect of the reform on males’ memory and executive functioning at older ages, using simple cognitive tests from the English Longitudinal Survey on Ageing (ELSA) as our outcome measures. This result is particularly remarkable since the reform had a powerful and immediate effect on about half the population of 14-year-olds. We investigate and discuss the potential channels by which this reform may have had its effects, as well as carrying out a full set of sensitivity analyses and robustness checks.


The association between schooling and many positive economic, social and health outcomes is well documented. Although this association needs to be interpreted with caution because of reverse causality and the potential indirect effect of unobserved factors, the economic literature has recently been able to identify a causal effect of education on many of these outcomes, often through the use of an estimation strategy based on exploiting plausibly exogenous variations in schooling. One leading example is that of changes to compulsory schooling laws. These laws are ideal instruments not only because they allow the evaluation of the exogenous effect of one more year of education, but also because they allow the evaluation of the efficacy of such a policy change. A series of papers has systematically investigated the gains to various adult outcomes from compulsory schooling using reforms to schooling laws in both the US and the UK. The main outcomes studied have been earnings (e.g. Angrist and Krueger, 1991; Harmon and Walker, 1995; Acemoglu and Angrist, 2001; Oreopoulos, 2006), crime (Lochner and Moretti, 2004; Machin at al., 2011) and health (Lleras-Muney, 2005; Clark and Royer, 2010).

However, not all of the potential benefits from such policies have been explored. In particular, the effect of schooling on old age cognitive abilities is missing, though this effect should be of an increasing interest in an aging society. Cognitive abilities are fundamental for decision making and a crucial element for the appropriate formulation and subsequent execution of consumption and saving plans (Banks and Oldfield, 2007). And individual or household decision-making skills are arguably becoming more important for older individuals with the increasing importance of individual provision, and the declining importance of state provision, in social security and healthcare systems around the world. More generally, cognitive abilities may be regarded as one aspect of human capital, along with education, health, and non-cognitive abilities.

For this reason, in this paper we analyze the 1947 British compulsory school reform which increased the minimum school leaving age from 14 to 15 years old, presenting new evidence of the causal relationship between the resulting additional years of education and late life cognitive skills. We use this law change for two main reasons. First, it was targeted at the least educated groups and specifically aimed at affecting subsequent physical and mental trajectories as is clear from the government’s motivations, initially reported by Oreopoulos (2006): “…improve the future efficiency of the labor force, increase physical and mental adaptability, and prevent the mental and physical cramping caused by exposing children to monotonous occupations at an especially impressionable age.1”.

Second, the 1947 British school law affected a very large proportion of the 14 years old population – decreasing by around 50 percentage points in one year the proportion of people who left full-time education before age 15. We exploit this dramatic change in educational attainment using a fuzzy regression discontinuity (FRD) design to evaluate the causal effect of the additional year of schooling induced by the reform on old age cognitive ability. Although it is not a “sharp” design, because the increase in educational attainment did not affect the entire population involved by the reform, the large proportion affected is particularly important in comparison to similar US compulsory school changes that affected only about 5% of the relevant cohorts (Lleras-Muney, 2005). This difference is particularly important if the effect of interest is not homogeneous across the population since our estimation strategy allows us to recover only local effects (LATE) instead of averages across the population (ATE) (see Imbens and Angrist, 1994). As a consequence, a local parameter based on such a large proportion of the population should be more relevant then one based on a very small subgroup as in the US case.

We find that the compulsory school law change of 1947 had a quite large impact – around half of one standard deviation – on male memory and executive functioning at older ages measured using a set of cognitive tests from the English Longitudinal Survey on Aging (ELSA). Such a magnitude could be rationalized by diminishing marginal returns to schooling, coupled with the reform being incident only on those in the lower tail of the education distribution and the fact that our estimators focus only on the effects of the reform on those who were actually “affected”. Nevertheless, given this perhaps surprisingly large magnitude, we engage in a full battery of sensitivity and robustness tests. In order to test for confounding factors we look for potential effects of the reform on other variables – in our case childhood health prior to the reform and father’s occupation – that might be thought to be predetermined and operating independently of the reform. In addition we look for discontinuities at dates-of-birth other than the cut-off around which the reform was defined, we consider a broad range of linear and polynomial trend controls, and we consider subsamples defined by different sized windows on either side of the reform and by the exclusion of those with high education levels. None of these tests provide any basis on which to doubt the empirical findings.

Consequently, in our analysis we also discuss possible explanations for these results and the mechanisms and channels through which education may be thought to have affected old age cognitive abilities. The income channel is the more reasonable due to the estimated large impact of the 1947 reform on earnings (Oreopoulos, 2006). We also find some positive effects of the reform on males’ social and cultural participation and engagement, although we argue these may themselves only be an artefact of income or employment effects since such effects are only present for men. Finally, we are able to exclude the health channel. In addition to poor evidence found for the effect of the reform on many health outcomes in other analyses (Clark and Royer, 2010; Jürges at al., 2009), we do not find significant effect of the reform on late-life subjective wellbeing and quality of life using a measure (CASP 19) that is known to be highly correlated with many health outcomes (Wiggins et al., 2008).

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section we briefly review the literature on the relationship between schooling and cognitive abilities and discuss the main features of the 1947 compulsory school reform. Section 2 describes the data used for our analysis and Section 3 describes the empirical strategy along with the main identification issues. Section 4 presents our results and, finally, Section 5 offers some further discussion of issues arising from the results and presents our conclusions.

1 Background

1.1 Education and Cognitive Abilities

The relationship between schooling and cognitive abilities is one of the more studied issues in both psychology and economics. The controversial book “The Bell Curve” by Herrnestein and Murray (1994) claims that education does not affect cognitive skills. According to their view, intelligence, measured by IQ is fixed at a relatively early age – around age eight. This would imply that intelligence is mainly responsible for students staying in school and for subsequent economic and social achievements. Different evidence comes from Ceci and Williams (1997) who report some evidence of a bidirectional relationship between schooling and intelligence which affects variations in economic outcomes.

In the labor economics literature a large debate concerns whether schooling plays a role mainly as a market signal of innate ability or as way to improve skills. For this reason, many efforts have been concentrated on assessing the economic return to education controlling for endogeneity due to unobserved ability (e.g. Ashenfelter and Rouse, 1998; Card, 2001; Oreopoulos, 2006). This literature clearly identifies a causal effect of education on earnings but even this could not be considered an evidence of an effect of schooling on cognitive skills since such an effect would also be predicted by a signaling model (Spence, 1973) in which schooling emerges as a signal that an agent sends about her ability level to the employer. In that case, schooling may allow individuals to obtain those formal qualifications required to apply for higher earnings job.

Cunha and Heckman (2007) build an analysis that draws a distinction between innate ability and acquired skills. They argue that “abilities are created, not solely inherited, as interaction between genes and environment” to produce cognitive and non cognitive skills that have both a genetic and an acquired character. They show evidence of critical and sensitive periods in skill formation and dynamic complementarity in investments. The main consequence of their findings is the importance of early life intervention in particular for the subsequent evolution of cognitive abilities. They show that returns to late childhood investment in young adolescents from disadvantaged backgrounds are very low compared with the returns to early investment. Not less important is the role of non cognitive abilities that are responsible for performance in many economic, health and social achievements. Recently, Heckman et al. (2010) show that the Perry Preschool Program, which enhanced the subsequent economic and social performance of participants, did not boost participant adult IQ but only their non-cognitive abilities.

Even less clear is the relationship between schooling and old age cognitive abilities, which is the main target of our work. Many empirical studies (e.g. Le Carret et al., 2003; Mazzonna and Peracchi, 2010) underline the positive association between education and old age cognitive abilities, but only Glymour et al. (2006) find evidence of a causal relationship between education and memory. Exploring geographical variation in US compulsory school reforms they found a positive effect of an additional year of education on memory test scores at older ages using data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS). In that study, however, the estimated effects are based on an instrument (the compulsory school reforms in US) that only affects a very small fraction of the population (see below for more detail) and in addition assumes that the effect of different reforms applied in different states in different points in time is homogeneous. Additionally, they use a separate-sample instrumental variable (SSIV) estimator in which the first step is estimated using the 1980 US census 5% sample and as such, their estimates may be sensitive to differential response patterns in the HRS and Census samples.

The specific mechanism through which education might affect old age cognitive abilities is not clear. Mazzonna and Peracchi (2010) apply the Grossman model of health capital to cognitive outcomes in order to generate empirical predictions about the evolution of cognitive abilities at older ages. In that framework there are multiple channels that can be identified: productive effciency; employment, earnings and occupational choice; or preferences for social and cultural-stimulating activities. The direct effect of the reform in this case would be through productive efficiency, which means that more schooling allows individuals to obtain better health from a given amounts of inputs. However, this framework seems less directly applicable to cognitive outcomes than to health. In addition, a direct effect of the reform on cognitive abilities might seem inconsistent with the results from the previously cited literature on cognitive skill formation that shows poor effect of investment on young adolescents.

The occupation channel is perhaps more interesting. In a signaling model schooling could, through formal qualifications, allow individuals to apply for higher earning jobs and such jobs could positively affect cognitive abilities, particularly at older ages if they are more cognitively demanding. However, the changing nature of education signals over time when cohorts are affected by reform would need to be borne in mind in making any more formal statements along these lines. And, as we explain in the next section, the 1947 reform did not lead to additional formal qualification for the affected students so signals may not be particularly strong. On the other hand Oreopoulos (2006), exploiting the same reform, found a significant and large effect (around 15%) of the additional year of schooling on earnings. To the extent that these greater earnings are associated with either higher rates of employment, or more cognitively demanding jobs amongst those employed, then these two factors may protect against cognitive decline at older ages (Mazzonna and Peracchi, 2010; Willis and Rohwedder, 2010). Given the different labor market pattern of males and females from cohorts born in the 1930s, with low rates of female labor force participation in particular, differences in the effect of the reform across gender could be thought to indicate support for this channel. To this end, Devereux and Hart (2010), reviewing the findings in the Oreopolous’s paper, highlight evidence of positive returns to schooling reform only for males although they estimate the magnitude of the effect to be smaller – around 4-7% as opposed to the 10-15% estimated by Oreopolous (2006).2 In Section 4 it will be shown that this last evidence is consistent with our result of a positive effect of the reform only on males’s cognitive abilities at older ages.

A similar set of considerations applies to the third channel, namely social and cultural participation. The positive effects of such activities have been extensively described by Hertzog et al. (2008) in a comprehensive review of cognitive-enrichment effects at old ages. In this case, the general idea would be that education could affect the parameters of the utility function thus increasing the utility derived from more cognitive demanding activities and consumption (e.g. reading newspapers, using the internet or engagement in social and cultural organizations, club or societies).

The last channel we consider is health. If the reform improved health trajectories of the affected population this may also have an effect on cognitive abilities at older ages. However, using many waves of the Health Survey of England (HSE) Jürges et al., (2009) and Clark and Royer, (2010) do not find any significant effects of the same 1947 reform on many health outcomes, specifically - mortality, blood pressure, self-assessed health and selected biomarkers. Given this lack of evidence on physical health we will explore a more global measure of subjective wellbeing and quality of life, the so-called CASP19 index which captures Control, Self-Realisation, Autonomy and Pleasure (see Appendix A). This measure is particularly important in an aging society where living longer is no more enough, and quality of life during the old age it is recognized to be equally important (Hyde et al., 2003).

1.2 The 1947 British School Leaving Age Reform

Legislation from UK’s 1944 Education Act raised the minimum school-leaving age in England, Scotland and Wales on 1st April 1947 from 14 to 15 years old.3 This law and its implementation has been extensively discussed in papers which use the same exogenous variation in compulsory schooling as an instrument for identification of the effect of education on income and health (Oreopolous, 2006; Jürges et al., 2009; Clark and Royer, 2010). For this reason we will only briefly discuss the main points of this reform here.

Put simply, whilst children born before 1st April 1933 could leave school when they turned 14, the 1947 reform stated that those born after that date could not leave until they turned 15. As stressed by Oreopoulos (2006), this law change affects a large proportion of the population. Figure 1 shows the fraction of males and females that left full time education by the age of 14. Using the ELSA data described in more detail below, the Figure displays averages at quarter of birth level with the vertical black line marking the exact cutoff point at 1st of April 1333. It is evident that before the reform about 60% of the population left the school at age of 14, whilst after its implementation this proportion dramatically decreases to below 10%.

Fig. 1.

Fig. 1

Effect of 1947 Reform on Fraction Leaving Full-time Education at or before Age 14.

This successful implementation was a result of a “national operation that expanded the supply of teachers, buildings and furniture” (Oreopoulos, 2006). The proportion of children immediately affected by this reform is particularly important when compared with similar US compulsory school changes used in the literature (Lleras-Muney, 2005) that affected only 5-10% of the relevant cohorts.

Age of school entry remained unchanged: students had to have started school by the term in which they reached their fifth birthday.4 Finally, it is worth noting that this increase in compulsory schooling did not lead to identifiable formal qualifications for the cohort involved. At that time, students could not obtain formal high school qualifications before the age of 17. As a consequence, students affected by the increasing in compulsory schooling would still have had to stay for at least two further post-compulsory years of education in order to obtain a formal qualification.

A last important remark relates to the timing of the reform, in the context of the main identifying assumption that will allow us to identify the causal effect of education on cognitive abilities, namely the absence of any other unobserved changes at the time of the reform (or more precisely, to the cohorts treated by the reform at any point in their lifetimes) that might also have affected cognitive abilities. Naturally, many important events happened during that period that involve the cohorts of interest. They were born a few years after the Great Depression, and affected by rationing and bombing during WWII, but without being involved in fighting. However, exposure to these circumstances was very similar for cohorts born on either side of the 1 April 1933 cutoff (Clark and Royer, 2010) and we will be including flexible trend variables throughout our analysis to control for gradual changes across date of birth cohorts. Moreover, as in Jürges et al. (2009), we will also condition our estimates on adult height to control for both economic and disease environment in childhood (Case and Paxson, 2009). Finally, we take care to ground our estimation strategy on a narrow interval around the reform as not to potentially confound the effect of the reform with that of other unobservables.

2 Data and Summary Statistics

2.1 Data

Our data come from the first 3 waves (2002, 2004, 2006) of the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing (ELSA) a multidisciplinary survey of health, economic position and quality of life as people age. Its target population consists of people aged 50+ living in private households in England at baseline, plus their co-resident partners. The survey sample was drawn from respondents to the Health Survey for England (HSE). Around 12,000 respondents were recruited from three separate years (1998, 1999, 2001) of HSE.

The topic areas covered in the main questionnaire include individual and household characteristics; physical and mental health, cognitive abilities and functioning, subjective psychological health and wellbeing, social participation and social support; housing, work, pensions, income and assets; and expectations for the future. All data are collected by face-to-face, computer-aided personal interviews (CAPI), supplemented by a self-completion paper-and-pencil questionnaire that is left behind at the interview and subsequently returned by respondents.

This last element is used to collect information on factors such as quality of life, psychosocial wellbeing, social participation, mobility, life satisfaction, perceived social position, social networks and social capital. Due to the survey design, not all individual respond to the self-completion questionnaire – in our sample we have a non response rate of around 15%. From this questionnaire, we make use of a well recognized measure of quality of life, the CASP-19, and an index for social and cultural participation. CASP 19 is an acronym for Control, Autonomy, Self-Realization and Pleasure and it is a 19-item scale derived from questions about aspects of life that older adults reported as important in qualitative studies. The index for social and cultural participation is based on a selection of 8 questions about social and cultural activities. Appendix A gives more details on the construction of these two variables.

Our analysis uses different subsamples of the ELSA sample for our various empirical specifications although we exclude all immigrants from the sample throughout our analysis. Firstly we define subsamples according to birth cohort. We consider different cohorts ranges, selecting from one year on either side of the cutoff date of 1st April 1933 (i.e. those born from 1 April 1932 to 31 March 1934) to 10 years on either side. The exact cohort range also depends on the estimation method in use.

Our second sample selection criterion is based on educational attainment. One feature of our data is that education is recorded as the age at which the individual completed full-time education, with the data being truncated from above and all values of 19 or higher being grouped together as a single categorical value for 19 or more. Since we are mainly interested in the lower educated groups who will have been the ones affected by the reform, we construct 3 different sample selections for analysis. The first is simply the whole sample, regardless of their age left education. A second subsample is limited just to those that left full time education before the age of 19 (age left<19). In this case we exclude from the sample all individuals with at least some college attainment, but still include many respondents that would have left school after the age of 15 regardless of the reform (these are sometimes known as ”always-takers”).

The last and most restrictive education subsample excludes all individuals who left full time education after the age of 15 (age left<16). Since we can only estimate local average treatment effects and this sample should contain the biggest concentration of “compliers”, i.e. those that increase their educational attainment by one year only as a consequence of the reform, this last group is the most important sample from the point of view of our estimation strategy. The educational breakdown underlying these three subsamples is shown in Table 1 which shows the distribution of age left education in our sample for the cohorts born between 1930 and 1936, split by sex and whether the cohorts were born before or after the reforms cutoff date. It is clear that the big change in educational attainment following the reform is from 14 to 15. This is particularly true for males, where the fractions leaving school at older ages in the ’after’ cohorts are only increased very slightly. The distribution of educational outcomes across the reform dates for women is slightly different with the reduction in the proportion leaving at age 14 being accompanied by a large increase in the proportion leaving at age 15 but also a not insubstantial increase in the proportion of women leaving school between 16 and 18. We return to this fact later in our discussion.

Table 1.

Per cent Distribution of Age Left Full-time Education by Age and Date of Birth.

Males Females

Age left fte Before
1/4/1930 - 31/3/1933
After
1/4/1933 - 31/3/1936
Before
1/4/1930 - 31/3/1933
After
1/4/1933 - 31/3/1936
14 58.0 7.4 55.9 5.7
15 11.8 58.3 12.1 48.3
16-18 21.0 26.3 25.7 38.5
19+ 9.3 8.0 6.3 7.5
100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

Notes. Individuals born three years either side of the cut-off date for the 1947 reform.

Some concern may arise with the use of education-restricted subsamples since they are selected on the value of the endogenous variable. Such sample selection criterion has, however, already been applied in the literature on the effects of the 1947 British compulsory school reform (Lindeboom et al., 2009; Oreopolous, 2008) because, as already evident from Table 1, the reform mainly affected the educational choices of those individuals at the lower end of the educational distribution. Nevertheless, throughout the paper we will provide evidence to show that such a stringent sample selection criterion does not affect the validity of our estimation strategy. In particular, the robustness checks in Appendix B show that we cannot reject the hypothesis that the observed predetermined characteristics of the people born just before and after the cutoff date are the same.

2.2 Cognitive Measures and Descriptive Statistics

The ELSA cognitive function module contains measures of cognitive function based on simple tests of memory, word-finding ability, executive function, speed of processing and numerical ability. The memory assessment is subdivided into retrospective memory (recalling information that was learned previously) and prospective memory (remembering to carry out an intended action). The executive function tests refer to a number of cognitive control processes, which include attention, initiation, mental flexibility, organization, abstraction, planning and problem-solving. The test format adopted by ELSA is based on the Telephone Interview of Cognitive Status-Modified (TICS-M) test which utilizes a format for the assessment of cognitive functions that can be administered in person or by telephone and is highly correlated with the Mini-Mental State Exam (MMSE) (Folstein et al., 1975), a screening tool frequently used by health-care providers to assess overall brain function.

The tests are comparable to cognitive tests implemented in the HRS and in Survey of Health, Aging and Retirement in Europe (SHARE), and follow a protocol aimed at minimizing the potential influences of the interviewer and the interview process.5 We exclude from our analysis the tests of orientation in time and prospective memory because they exhibit very little variability across respondents. We also exclude the numeracy test as it was administered only in the first wave of the three waves of ELSA that we use here.

We will therefore evaluate the effect of the increase in compulsory school reform on two different cognitive domains: memory and executive functioning. The memory tests consist of verbal registration and recall of a list of 10 words. The respondent hears the list only once. The test is carried out immediately after the encoding phase (immediate recall), and then again after the other cognitive questions have taken place (delayed recall), usually a period of five or so minutes later. ELSA uses the same word lists as the Health and Retirement Study in the US. In both studies there are four different wordlists so that different lists can be given to different members of the same household and to the same individual over time. Repeated exposure to the same tests, in fact, may induce learning effects which are likely to if anything improve the cognitive scores of some respondents over time. From these two tests we calculate a Memory score as the sum of the number of target words recalled in the two recall phases (immediate and delayed). This score can, and does, range from 0 to 20.

Executive functioning is assessed using two different tests, namely verbal fluency and letter cancellation. The verbal fluency test is a test of how quickly participants can think of words from a particular category, in this case by counting how many distinct elements from the animal kingdom (real or mythical, excluding repetitions or proper nouns) the respondent can name within one minute. This test requires self-initiated activity, organization and abstraction and set-shifting (Steel et al., 2004). Letter cancellation is a test of attention, visual search and mental speed. The participant is handed a clipboard with a page of random letters of the alphabet set out in rows and columns, and is asked to cross out as many target letters (P and W) as possible within one minute. The page comprises 26 rows and 30 columns, and there are 65 target letters in all. Respondents are asked to work across and down the page as though they were reading and to perform the task both as quickly and as accurately as possible. After one minute they are asked to mark the point on the page where they stopped. The total number of letters searched provides a measure of speed of processing, whilst the number of target letters (P and W) missed by the respondent provides a measure of accuracy.

As in Steel et al. (2004), an executive function index has been derived from the verbal fluency and letter cancellation tests together. Our index is constructed by summing the two standardized scores (each constructed by subtracting off their mean and dividing for the standard deviation). One attractive feature of the scores obtained from both memory and executive function is the fact that they do not suffer from floor or ceiling effects that usually characterize other measures of cognitive functioning such as the Mini-Mental State Examination (MMSE, see de Jager et al., 2003). Table 2 presents means and standard deviations of our test scores by age of leaving full time education and sex, for people born five years before and after the cutoff date of 1st of April 1933. The first set of rows reports these statistics for the full sample, while the second and the third sets report the same statistics conditional on leaving school before 19 and 16 years old, respectively. Table 3 reports means comparison between treatment groups for our cognitive and non-cognitive outcomes and other predetermined individual characteristics. We report these statistics for respondents born 5 years before and 5 years after the cutoff date.

Table 2.

Mean and Standard Deviation of Test Scores by Sex and Age Left Full-time Education.

Males Females

Mean S.D. Mean S.D.
Full sample

Memory 8.82 3.35 9.60 3.29
Exec. func. −0.12 1.56 0.07 1.56
N 3441 4024

Age left fte < 19

Memory 8.66 3.30 9.44 3.24
Exec. func. −0.19 1.49 −0.01 1.53
N 3110 3638

Age left fte < 16

Memory 8.16 3.21 9.01 3.21
Exec. func. −.40 1.40 −0.18 1.52
N 2280 2528

Notes. We select all individuals born five years before and after the cut-off date of 1st April 1933.

Table 3.

Mean Test Scores Comparison for Those Born 5 Years Before and After the 1st April 1933, by Educational Attainment.

Age left<19 Males Females

Before After p-value Before After p-value
Memory 8.32 8.95 0.00 8.99 9.89 0.00
Exec. func. −0.40 −0.00 0.00 −0.22 0.21 0.00
Soc. part. 2.75 2.93 0.00 2.42 2.58 0.00
Casp19 42.25 42.30 0.88 41.76 42.66 0.00
Child health 2.19 2.12 0.16 2.35 2.39 0.42
Father job 2.64 2.64 0.93 2.62 2.57 0.14
N 1109 1171 1314 1214

Age left<16 Males Females

Before After p-value Before After p-value

Memory 7.87 8.43 0.00 8.65 9.41 0.00
exec3. func. −0.59 −0.23 0.00 −0.38 0.04 0.00
Soc. part. 2.57 2.66 0.15 2.20 2.31 0.06
Casp19 41.57 41.32 0.53 41.20 41.89 0.08
Child health 2.26 2.21 0.34 2.45 2.39 0.28
father job 2.79 2.79 0.92 2.74 2.71 0.41
N 1109 1171 1314 1214.00

Notes. The p-values derive from t tests on the equality of means.

Social participation and CASP19 are taken from the self-completion questionnaire that shows a lower response rate with respect the core sample of about 15%. Social participation ranges between 0 and 8; Casp19 ranges between 0 and 57; Child health values: 1 excellent, 2 very good, 3 good, 4 fair, 5 poor; father job values: 1 professional and managerial, 2 skilled non-manual, 3 skilled manual, 4 unskilled manual.

The first set of rows of Table 3 (age left<19) reports the comparison of means for those that left full time education before the age of 19, while the second set (age left<16) reports the same comparison for those that left before 16. The predetermined characteristics are childhood health (self-assessed by the responded) and father’s last job. The third column for each sex reports p-values from t tests on the equality of means. In both educational groups and for both sexes, these tests reject the null of equality of means (at the 1 percent level) for both our cognitive test scores. Similar results are apparent for our measure of social participation where, except for males in the lower educational subsample, we reject the null of equality of means at least at 5% level. The quality of life measure (CASP19), however, does not show significant differences between the two groups, except for females with higher educational attainment. Finally, the characteristics we consider to be predetermined – fathers occupation, and respondents childhood health – seem to be well balanced between the two groups. This last finding is important for our analysis as differences would have cast doubt about the “continuity” hypothesis, the main assumption of our estimation strategy, as discussed in Section 3.2. However, this kind of comparison is purely descriptive, because it does not take account of cohort trends in such variables so we will return to this test later when we estimate full models with control variables.

2.3 Graphical Analysis

To examine the effect of law change on educational attainment we present a set of descriptive figures that shows the relationship between birth cohort and different educational outcomes. Each point of each graph represents the sample mean for a particular quarter of birth cell, with the overall sample covering the period 5 years before and after the cuto date of 1st of April 1933.

Purely for descriptive purposes, the fitted lines are based on a local linear fit on 5 years before and after the reform. The vertical line denotes the cohort of birth cutoff for the law change (2nd quarter of 1933). As discussed previously, the discontinuity presented in Figures 1 on the fraction leaving full-time education by age 14 is clearly evident for both males and females. Before the reform about 60% of the individuals left full time education by age 14 whilst after the reform this fraction collapses to below 10%. At the same time, however, the reform generated a small positive spillover to higher levels of education. As discussed earlier, the Figure 2 shows that the reform had only a small effect on the female fraction leaving full-time education before age 16, but no effect on this fraction for males.

Fig. 2.

Fig. 2

Effect of 1947 Reform on Fraction Leaving before Age 16.

The fact that the reform did not affect people with higher educational attainment is even more clear in Figure 3 which shows no effect of the reform on the fraction leaving education before age 19 for both males and females. On the contrary, the discontinuity is amplified if we consider only people that left full time education before the age of 16 as in Figure 4. The jump at the discontinuity point is almost sharp, from about 80% to 10%. The effect of the reform on this subsample is particularly important because this subsample relates to the most affected people, i.e. those who, without the reform, would have been most likely to leave the school by age 14.

Fig. 3.

Fig. 3

Effect of 1947 Reform on Fraction Leaving before Age 19.

Fig. 4.

Fig. 4

Effect of 1947 Reform on Fraction Leaving before Age 14 (Conditional on Leaving Before 16).

The second set of descriptive figures show the discontinuity in the cognitive scores of interest. Figures 5 and 6 show the discontinuity in memory score conditional on leaving school before the age of 16 and in the full sample while Figure 7 and 8 show the same discontinuities for the executive function score. All figures show a very high variability in quarter of birth averages.

Fig. 5.

Fig. 5

Effect of 1947 Reform on Memory (Conditional on Leaving before 16).

Fig. 6.

Fig. 6

Effect of 1947 Reform on Memory (Full Sample).

Fig. 7.

Fig. 7

Effect of 1947 Reform on Executive Functioning (Conditional on Leaving before 16).

Fig. 8.

Fig. 8

Effect of 1947 Reform on Executive Functioning (Full Sample).

This high variability may be the results of different factors. First, it may be due to a small number of observations per cell (an average of 36 observation for each month of birth). Second, as explained in Section 1.2, ages at school entry and exit vary according to a set of rules depending on date of birth (Clark and Royer, 2010). These rules generate a lot of variability in the total months spent at school within each cohort but do not affect the validity of our estimation strategy, because the rules themselves did not change with the compulsory school reform of 1947. Finally, we could have a selection effect due to differential mortality rates, particularly for the older cohort. This issue is discussed in more detail in Section 3.2, but it is clear that this selection effect will become less important as our estimation strategy focuses on tighter and tighter intervals around the discontinuity.

The descriptive analysis presented in Figures 5 and 6 suggests that, even though less immediately evident, the discontinuity in memory, especially for males follows the same patterns that we have seen in the educational figures. The effect on memory for males is evident only conditional on leaving before the age of 16, while there are some positive spillover also for females with higher educational attainment. This consistency between the discontinuity in education and cognitive abilities is important because different evidence would have cast doubt on the unconfoundedness hypothesis. In the case of executive function, although the fitted lines in Figures 7 and 8 show discontinuities in this test very similar to those in memory, they are less convincing due to the high variability in quarter of birth averages. For this reason, in Figure 9 we show the same discontinuities in executive function as in Figure 7, but reporting annual year-of-birth averages on a 20 years interval. Although the variability across cohorts in executive function averages, the discontinuity for males conditional on leaving before 16 is now more apparent.

Fig. 9.

Fig. 9

Effect of 1947 reform on Executive functioning (Conditional on Leaving before 16).

Finally, we note that even using a higher order polynomial fitting or using a year-of-birth instead of quarter-of-birth level of aggregation does not change the message from the graphical evidence. In order to save space this analysis is not presented. Instead we move on to our full empirical models with a more complete set of control variables and specification tests.

3 Empirical Strategy

3.1 Regression Discontinuity Design

The nature of the reform clearly makes it a candidate for a Regression Discontinuity (RD) design providing us the opportunity of estimating the effect of one more year of schooling on old age cognitive abilities under relative weak conditions that we discuss in the next section. The general idea in RD design is that the probability of receiving a treatment (an additional year of schooling) is a discontinuous function of a continuous treatment determining variable (day of birth). However, the treatment in our case does not change from 0 to 1 at the cutoff point (1st April 1933). Following Angrist and Imbens (1994), we have people that, regardless of the reform, decide to stay at school also over the minimum compulsory school leaving age (“always-takers”). There are also a few people that, regardless of the reform, leave the school before the minimum compulsory age (“never-takers”). In such case the Fuzzy Regression Discontinuity (FRD) design is appropriate because it allows for a smaller jump in the probability of assignment to treatment at the cutoff. In the case of a binary treatment FRD design may be seen as a Wald estimator (around the discontinuity c):

τFRD=limxcE(YX=x)limxcE(YX=x)limxcE(WX=x)limxcE(WX=x),

where, in our case, c is the cutoff point; X is the date of birth; W is the treatment (one more year of education). Specifically, we estimate the following two equations:

Yics=α0+α1Eics+f(Ric)+Xicsα2+uics, (1)
Eics=γ0+γ1Zc+g(Ric)+Xicsγ2+νics, (2)

where Yics and Eics are the cognitive scores and the educational level of the individual i, of the cohort c, in the survey year s; Z is a dummy variable to capture whether the individual is born after the cutoff date i.e. equal to 1 if the individual is born after the 1st of April 1933 and 0 otherwise; the running variable R is an individual birth cohort (measured in months) relative to the cutoff; the vector X contains pre-determined characteristics such as survey year and adult height. Functions f(.) and g(.) capture the relationship between birth cohort and cognitive outcome and educational attainment respectively. Notice that substituting the treatment equation into the outcome equation yields the reduced form:

Yics=β0+β1Zc+h(Ric)+Xicsβ2+ics, (3)

where β1 = α1 * γ1. The parameter of interest is α1 and its estimate is the ratio of the reduced form coeffcients β1/γ1.

We estimate the parameter of interest α1 using two different methods as suggested by Lee and Lemieux (2009). The first is based on a local linear regression around the discontinuity choosing the optimal bandwidth in a cross-validation procedure that we report in Appendix C. The second method makes use of the full sample6 using a polynomial regression in which the equivalent of the bandwidth choice is the choice of the correct polynomial order (see Appendix D). In both cases, we estimate the treatment effect using 2SLS which is numerically equivalent to computing the ratio in the estimated jump (at the cutoff point) in the outcome variable over the jump in the treatment variable, provided that the same bandwidth or the same polynomial order is used for both equations. This allows us to obtain directly the correct standard errors that are robust and clustered at individual level.

Controlling for clustering is particularly important in this setting because we have two possible sources of serial correlation, within individual over time and across individuals in the same month of birth.7 The first best in this case would be clustering at the higher level of aggregation that corresponds to the month of birth level. But in this case the number of clusters would be too small, particularly when we focus our analysis on a very small bandwidth around the discontinuity. For this reason we control for the larger source of correlation that is across the same individual over time.8 Lastly, although no less important, we fully interact the polynomials f(.) and g(.). Otherwise, we are imposing the restriction that the slope coeffcients are the same on both sides of the discontinuity point.

One final estimation issue is the potential effect of panel attrition on our estimators. In an ageing survey like ELSA, panel attrition may be an important concern depending on the selection mechanism that determines ongoing participation in the panel. In our sample some individuals are observed three times (62%), other twice (19%) and other only once (19%). One way of dealing with potential attrition would be to use weights based on the inverse of the number of times people are observed. Although simple, this method should be highly ineffcient because gives the same weight to all individuals observed the same number of times. Alternatively, if one were to assume a Missing at Random (MAR) selection mechanism (Rubin, 1976), Inverse Probability Weights (IPW) could be calculated based on the estimated probability of participating in the second and then third waves conditional on observable baseline controls. Neither method is particularly satisfactory, nor are there, in the absence of further information or assumptions on the survey participation process, particular good criteria for choosing one over the other or for that matter over an unweighted strategy. Nevertheless, we experimented with both weighting methods (with the observable variables in the MAR case being defined as sex, cubic polynomial in age, education and height). In both cases, the results (available from the authors on request) revealed similar coeffcients (albeit with a loss of precision particularly, as expected, when we use the former weighting strategy). As a consequence we simply present estimates here that do not account for attrition, essentially assuming a missing completely at random selection mechanism (Rubin, 1976).

3.2 Identification Issues

The attractive feature of the RD estimation strategy is that it provide estimates that are “as credible as those from randomized experiment” (Lee and Card, 2008) under relative weak assumptions. The key assumption here is that the conditional expectations of the potential outcomes (age left full time education and cognitive scores) with respect to the treatment determining variable (birth cohort) are smooth (continuous) functions at the threshold (R = 0). This allows us to attribute any discontinuity in the outcomes of interest at the threshold only to the effect of the reform. As with any identification assumption this is directly untestable but, as common in the literature (Lee and Lemieux, 2009), we can employ some indirect tests. First, we can test whether there are discontinuities in pre-determined characteristics for which we have data, but which are known not to have been affected by the treatment. We have already seen in Table 3 that the comparison of means of pre-determined characteristics like childhood health and father’s last job does not reject the null hypothesis of equal means. We therefore tested the assumption of zero effects on these predetermined characteristics using the same estimation strategy used for estimating the treatment effect on cognitive test scores. As with the previous comparison of means the results, reported in Appendix B, do not reject the null of zero effects of the reform on these variables.

Perhaps more importantly, since our population is made up of older individuals whose cognitive abilities are assessed long long after the reform took place, the main concern about this assumption regards a possible selection effect due to subsequent mortality. This selection effect could have two different sources. The first is the differential in mortality rates between cohorts on the two sides of the discontinuity. In particular, older cohorts (i.e. on the left hand-side) could be more affected by mortality between the time of the reform and the time our outcome variables were observed (i.e. 2002-2006). However, focusing our estimation on a narrow interval around the discontinuity or conditioning for higher order polynomials of date of birth (when we increase the bandwidth) should allow us to control for the broad cohort pattern of age-specific mortality rates rather well, and discontinuities are unlikely to remain after these controls. Moreover, it is reasonable to assume that this selection mechanism is likely to affect mainly people with poor health and poor cognitive abilities (i.e. any selection would be a positive selection on survival). Since mortality is greater amongst the older cohorts on the left side of the discontinuity this implies that any estimated effect of education on cognitive abilities would, if anything, most likely be a downward biased estimate of the true effect.

The second concern about mortality is due to the possible existence of a causal effect of the reform itself (through education) on mortality. However, this second concern was tested directly in the analysis of Clark and Royer (2010) who looked at the effect of the 1947 reform on mortality in detail. They find that, in line with similar results for physical health, the compulsory school reform had little or no causal effect on mortality.

A final set of robustness tests for the validity of our RD design involves estimating jumps in outcomes at points where there should be not jumps in the treatment distribution. The results, also reported in Appendix B, do not show any evidence for the presence of jumps in the distribution of the treatment variable in the two subsamples on either side of the cutoff value.

4 Estimation Results

We begin this section by showing the estimated effect of the reform on schooling using local linear regression. In Appendix C we discuss the cross validation procedure suggested by Imbens and Lemieux (2008) for choosing the optimal bandwidth. This procedure results in an optimal bandwidth that is calculated to be one year (on both sides of the discontinuity) for our cognitive test scores and 3 years for education. For this reason, in the following table we explore the sensitivity of the results to a range of bandwidths that goes from 1 to 3 years around the discontinuity.

Table 4 shows the estimated effect of the compulsory school reform on school leaving age conditional on three different samples of educational attainment and 3 different bandwidths h.

Table 4.

Estimated Impact of 1947 Reform on School Leaving Age, by Sex (Local Linear Regression).

Males Females

Full sample h = 1 h = 2 h = 3 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3
1947 reform .340
(.598)
.446
(.419)
.136
(.355)
.186
(.463)
.592 *
(.335)
1.256 ***
(.307)
N 703 1385 2057 777 1559 2369
F-test .36 1.36 .12 .17 2.61 15.14

Age < 19

1947 reform .220
(.280)
.440 **
(.204)
.346 **
(.168)
.873 ***
(.232)
.668 ***
(.174)
.708 ***
(.146)
N 636 1258 1860 718 1424 2163
F-test .46 3.95 4.33 10.90 11.97 21.00

Age < 16

1947 reform .641 ***
(.110)
.694 ***
(.077)
.672 ***
(.062)
.595 ***
(.109)
.546 ***
(.077)
.636 ***
(.063)
N 431 928 1400 491 968 1435
F-test 31.02 76.59 111.75 21.00 49.63 100.03

Notes. Table reports estimated effects of compulsory school reform on schooling. Columns denote the bandwidth selection h from 1 to 3 years. Rows indicate three different sample selections: (a) full sample; (b) conditional on leaving before the age of 19; (c) conditional on leaving before the age of 16. All regressions include: a linear function of month of birth and its interaction with the reform dummy; controls for adult height and for survey year. The standard error in parenthesis are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at individual level. Significance levels:

(*)

p-values between 10 and 5 percent;

(**)

p-values between 5 and 1 percent;

(***)

p-values less than 1 percent.

The last row for each sample selection reports the F-test on the excluded instrument - the dummy variable indicating the effect of the reform. The first set of rows in this table show the estimated effects for the full sample, where dependent variable is the age of left full-time education as recorded in ELSA. Such estimates present two main problems. Firstly, this variable is truncated from above (at age 19). Second it yields the average effect of the reform across all responders including those with higher educational attainment. Consistent with the result in Lindeboom et al. (2009), the estimated effect of the reform is very poor in this sample. Except for females in the larger bandwidth specification, in fact, the coeffcients are not significantly different from zero.

The second set of rows of Table 4 uses the same model specification, but the estimation sample excludes people that left full time education at or after the age of 19. That is, it excludes all individuals with at least some college attainment, but it still includes many respondents that, regardless of the reform, would leave the school after the age of 15 (the ”always-takers”). In this case, if we look at the smallest bandwidth h = 1, the estimated effect of the reform is significant only for females. This result is consistent with Table 1 and Figure 2. Finally, the third set of rows shows the results for the most concentrated sample, which includes only individuals who left full-time education before the age of 16. This sample is the most important for our estimation strategy, because it should contain the biggest fraction of “compliers”, i.e. those who increase of one years their educational attainment as a consequence of the reform. For this sample, the effect of the reform is large and statistically significant at 1% level for each bandwidth and for both males and females.

The next step is to evaluate the effect of the exogenous increase in education on cognitive outcomes of interest. Table 5 reports estimates of the education effect on cognitive abilities. All test scores have been standardized by subtracting off their mean and dividing by their standard deviation. We make use of the 2SLS estimator in order to obtain directly the correct standard errors, robust to heteroscedasticity and clustered at individual level. The first set of rows shows the estimated education effect for the sample leaving school at or before the age of 16 (that corresponds to the first step in the third row of Table 4), while the second set shows the estimated coeffcients conditional on the broader sample including those leaving school up to age 19. We do not report the results for the full sample because of the weak first step as evident from the F-tests reported in Table 4.

Table 5.

2SLS Estimates of the Effect of Education on Cognitive Abilities.

Males Females

Age < 16 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3
Memory .597 *
(.346)
.511 **
(.227)
.434 **
(.187)
.512
(.341)
.521 *
(.274)
.352 *
(.193)
Exec. func. .635 *
(.357)
.547 **
(.223)
.371 **
(.185)
−.100
(.389)
.020
(.300)
.093
(.210)
N 431 928 1400 491 968 1435

Age < 19

Memory .504
(.872)
.267
(.299)
.174
(.309)
.359 *
(.214)
.213
(.190)
.220
(.147)
Exec. func. 1.085
(1.470)
.512
(.327)
.236
(.309)
−.052
(.229)
−.047
(.207)
.008
(.160)
N 636 1258 1860 718 1424 2163

Notes. Table reports 2SLS estimates of the effect of schooling on cognitive test scores. Columns denote the bandwidth selection h from 1 to 3 years. Rows indicate two different sample selection: (a) conditional on leaving before the age of 19; (b) conditional on leaving before the age of 16. All regressions include: a linear function of month of birth and its interaction with the reform dummy; controls for adult height and for survey year. The standard error in parenthesis are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at individual level. Significance levels:

(*)

p-values between 10 and 5 percent;

(**)

p-values between 5 and 1 percent;

(***)

p-values less than 1 percent.

The effect of education on memory seems to be positive for both males and females in the smallest sample. However, the standard errors for the female sample are larger and so the corresponding coeffcients are significant only at 10% level when we consider 2 or 3 years around the discontinuity. The results are quite di erent for executive functioning, where the coeffcients are statistically significant (at least at 10% level) only for males.

With regard to the magnitudes of these effects, the effect of education on memory is of about half of a standard deviation for males and around 0.4 for females. The effect on executive function for males ranges between 0.37 and 0.63 of the standard deviation.9 When we include individuals with higher level of education attainment in the sample, as in the second set of rows (Age left< 19), the sign and in some case also the magnitude of our coeffcients are similar but the estimated standard errors increase in particular for males. For males, the inclusion of respondents with higher level of educational attainment only increases the standard errors of our estimates. This means that there are no gains in increasing the sample size because there are too few males affected by the reform that left full time after the age of 16 as already evident in the graphical analysis in Section 2.3.

To evaluate the robustness of our results further, Tables 6a and 6b report the estimated treatment effect of education on cognitive abilities using polynomial regression instead of the local linear framework above. We present the results according to different polynomial orders k and bandwidths h. In the smallest sample (age left education<16), the table shows significant coefficients on memory test in particular for males until the fourth order polynomial. Moreover, the size of the coeffcients are around half standard deviation, as before, particularly when we look at the main diagonal where we gradually increase the bandwidth and the polynomial order. Consistent with the local linear estimates, we have significant coeffcients on executive function only for males. But if we consider also higher levels of education attainment (conditional on leaving before 19) we do not find significant effects of education, although in most cases the coefficient are similar in size (in particular if we look at the main diagonal of the 2 tables). And as before, standard errors are larger for females, with coeffcients in many cases significant only at 10% level. On balance, the estimated effects of education on cognitive abilities seem to be robust across specifications and for different estimation methods, particularly for the case of memory.

Table 6a.

Polynomial Regression Estimates of the Education Effect on cognitive test scores (Age left<16).

Age< 16 Males Females

Memory

pol. order h = 5 h = 8 h = 10 h = 5 h = 8 h = 10
k = 2 .491 **
(.221)
.336 *
(.181)
.266
(.162)
.463 **
(.227)
.272
(.170)
.230
(.157)
k = 3 .560 *
(.286)
.586 **
(.238)
.516 **
(.217)
.640 *
(.360)
.543 **
(.266)
.425 **
(.214)
k = 4 .543
(.389)
.582 **
(.283)
.576 **
(.257)
.658
(.411)
.685 **
(.330)
.582 *
(.303)

Exec. func.

k = 2 .391 *
(.217)
.112
(.177)
.228
(.161)
.039
(.250)
.112
(.180)
.209
(.166)
k = 3 .762 ***
(.295)
.484 **
(.232)
.238
(.210)
−.052
(.398)
.099
(.288)
.081
(.231)
k = 4 .412
(.395)
.682 **
(.284)
.584 **
(.256)
−.166
(.467)
−.124
(.362)
−.034
(.335)

N 2280 3430 4126 2528 3837 4629

Table 6b.

Polynomial Regression Estimates of the Education Effect on Cognitive Test Scores (Age left<19).

Age< 19 Males Females

Memory

pol. order h = 5 h = 8 h = 10 h = 5 h = 8 h = 10
k = 2 .414
(.629)
.017
(.235)
−.059
(.228)
.294
(.182)
.155
(.122)
.159
(.108)
k = 3 .242
(.384)
.565
(.691)
.283
(.381)
.270
(.189)
.294
(.204)
.228
(.164)
k = 4 .090
(.523)
.326
(.494)
.427
(.579)
.357
(.218)
.366 *
(.208)
.308
(.210)

Exec. func.

k = 2 .136
(.629)
−.036
(.238)
.059
(.215)
.008
(.196)
.053
(.129)
.109
(.114)
k = 3 .754
(.522)
.425
(.675)
.050
(.395)
−.086
(.210)
.013
(.218)
.024
(.178)
k = 4 .457
(.586)
.719
(.660)
.559
(.666)
−.132
(.239)
−.129
(.224)
−.088
(.231)

N 3110 4720 5692 3638 5546 6809

Notes. Tables report the 2SLS estimates of the effect of schooling on cognitive test scores using polynomial regression. Columns denote the bandwidth selection h: 5, 8 and 10 years. Inside each sample selection (as in Table 5), rows indicate the polynomial order k from 2 to 4. All regressions include: a polynomial function of month of birth (of order k) and its interaction with the reform dummy; controls for adult height and for survey year. The standard error in parenthesis are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at individual level. Significance levels:

(*)

p-values between 10 and 5 percent;

(**)

p-values between 5 and 1 percent;

(***)

p-values less than 1 percent.

Having estimated the impact of reform on cognitive abilities, the final step of our analysis is to evaluate the effect of the same reform on two measures of social participation and quality of life (CASP 19), each standardized in the same manner as the cognitive function scores. Table 7 reports estimates of the education effect on these two measures using local linear regression method as in Table 5. For completeness, Figures 10 and 11 in the Appendix also provide a graphical analysis of the discontinuities in each of the two measures in the same way as was originally presented in Section 2.3 for the cognitive measures.

Table 7.

2SLS Estimates of the Effect of Education on Social Participation and Quality of Life.

Males Females

Age < 16 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3
Soc. part. .484
(.413)
.300
(.263)
.377 *
(.219)
.230
(.360)
−.141
(.313)
−.129
(.229)
Casp 19 −.365
(.442)
−.011
(.289)
−.073
(.236)
−.468
(.506)
−.468
(.388)
−.029
(.277)
N 393 835 1237 406 808 1191

Age < 19

Soc. part. 1.136
(1.915)
.342
(.445)
.564
(.453)
−.110
(.282)
−.564
(.389)
−.331
(.252)
Casp 19 −2.406
(4.265)
−.372
(.499)
−.343
(.452)
−.209
(.278)
−.252
(.280)
−.070
(.204)
N 583 1135 1664 622 1241 1883

Notes. Table reports 2SLS estimates of the effect of schooling on social participation and a subjective measure of quality of life (CASP19). Columns denote the bandwidth selection h from 1 to 3 years. Rows indicate two different sample selection: (a) conditional on leaving before the age of 19; (b) conditional on leaving before the age of 16. All regressions include: a linear function of month of birth and its interaction with the reform dummy; controls for adult height and for survey year. The standard error in parenthesis are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered at individual level. Significance levels:

(*)

p-values between 10 and 5 percent;

(**)

p-values between 5 and 1 percent;

(***)

p-values less than 1 percent.

Fig. 10.

Fig. 10

Effect of 1947 Reform on Social Participation (conditional on Leaving before 16).

Fig. 11.

Fig. 11

Effect of 1947 Reform on Casp19 (Conditional on Leaving before 16).

Table 7 shows a positive but weak effect of the increase in education on our measure of social participation for males in the low educational sample, but not for females. These results are statistically significant at least at 10% level only in the lower educational attainment group when we consider 3 years before and after the reform implementation. When we look at the effect of education on quality of life, however, find negative although not statistically significant effects for both males and females.10

5 Conclusions

In this paper we use data from three waves of the English Longitudinal Study on Ageing (ELSA) to estimate the causal effect of education on cognitive abilities using the 1947 increase in compulsory school leaving age that took place in Britain. This school reform had dramatic effects on educational attainment on a big fraction (around 50%) of the population just after the cut-off point of 1st April of 1947. At the same time this reform shows very small spillover on people with higher level of educational attainment, particularly for males.

We use a fuzzy regression discontinuity design to estimate the causal effect on the additional year of education induced by this policy change. The results show a positive and significant causal effect on old age memory of less-educated people. These results confirm similar findings in Glymour et al. (2006) that found an effect of about 0.33 standard deviation on memory using compulsory school changes in US. We found also a positive effect of the reform on males’ executive function ability measured using an index based on the verbal fluency and letter cancellation tests. These findings seem to be robust to a number of different specifications and methods of estimation.

Whilst some concern may be raised about the fact that our outcome variables are observed at older ages and as such differential mortality patterns of various cohorts may be driving our results, we have argued that our particular econometric method - focusing as it does on discontinuities at the treatment date - is robust to such issues and, if anything, we may be underestimating the true effect given a plausible signing of any possible bias. In addition, our full set of date-of-birth and year controls are flexible enough to adequately capture any broader age-related decline in cognitive abilities that will undoubtedly be present in our sample.

In addition to our analysis we have discussed the possible mechanisms by which education might be thought to affect cognitive abilities at old age. Taking our evidence together with the important evidence from other studies on the effect of this reform on other outcomes (Oreopoulos, 2006; Clark and Royer, 2010; Jürges at al., 2009) it seems possible to say that these effects do not come about via changes to health or mortality. Instead, one needs to look for channels involving earnings (where the reform did have a significant causal effect). Two possibilities emerge. One is that greater earnings and incomes that resulted from the reform have enabled individuals to engage in greater social and cultural participation over their life-course (such as membership of clubs and societies, attendance of events and museums etc.), which in turn have staved off age-related cognitive decline. Our analysis provides some weak evidence for the existence of this channel. But given the strength of our main findings, it seems more natural to conclude that the other possibility is equally if not more important, i.e. increased earnings and incomes from the reform are reflective of either higher employment or more cognitively demanding and productive occupations which themselves have positive implications for life-course trajectories of cognitive function. This would also be consistent with the recent paper of Devereux and Hart (2010) that shows positive financial returns from the same reform only for males and consistent with the lifetime labor market patterns for these cohorts born in the 1930s that show lower female labor force participation. In order to definitely confirm the importance of the employment channel one would want to either consider split samples where the relationship between job characteristics and cognitive demands may vary (for example, by occupation or skill group) or to look jointly at life-cycle earnings and cognition. In the former cases we do not have sufficient samples sizes to facilitate a split-sample analysis. In the latter, the data currently available only relate to respondents at at older ages, mainly when they are already retired. A natural extension of this work, however, would be to exploit the potential of linking ELSA respondents to their National Insurance record data in order to investigate life-time labor market patterns and life-time earnings.

The issue of the particular mechanisms through which the effects are transmitted is particular important given the rather large magnitudes of the effects we estimate in the data, around half of one standard deviation for one additional year of schooling. One reasonable explanation for such a magnitude might be diminishing marginal returns to school inputs – our estimators focus on the effects of the reform on those affected, which are only those in the lower tail of the education distribution. Whether or not such large effects would be found for a reform targeted at a different group, or whether the same mechanisms would apply, is not something that we can address with this data and methodology.

Nevertheless, our findings do add new evidence to that on the evaluation of compulsory school laws which continue to exist and are frequently updated in every developed country. Moreover, the evidence is important for broader issues surrounding the effects of education on old age cognitive abilities which is becoming especially important in an ageing society where preventing or delaying the age related decline in physical and cognitive abilities is becoming a fundamental target for health, labor and fiscal policy.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Janet Currie and Franco Peracchi, as well as two anonymous referees, for comments on earlier drafts of this work. We are also grateful to the audience of the 2010 RAND Workshop on Comparative International Research Based on HRS, ELSA and SHARE. Banks is grateful to the Economic and Social Research Council and the US National Institute on Ageing for funding his research on this project. Data from the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing were supplied by the ESRC Data Archive. ELSA was developed by researchers based at University College London, the Institute for Fiscal Studies and the National Centre for Social Research, with funding provided by the US National Institute on Ageing and a consortium of UK government departments coordinated by the Office for National Statistics. Responsibility for interpretation of the data, as well as for any errors, is the authors’ alone.

A Measure of Quality of Life (CASP19) and Social and Cultural Participation

The questions in the self-completion questionnaire ask about the respondents’ quality of life, social participation and social networks, and the respondents’ mental and psycho-social health. From this questionnaire we construct two indexes that we use in our analysis: CASP 19 and social participation.

The CASP 19 is a theoretically grounded measure of quality of life consisting of 19 Likert scaled agreement items spanning four life domains: control, autonomy, self-realization and pleasure. Each life domain contains four or five items which are presented as statements to ELSA respondents in the self completion questionnaire. Each statement is assessed in a four point Likert scale as to the extent to which the description describes a personal feelings about their life (rated as this applies to me: often, sometimes, not often or never) applies to the respondent. The resulting scale scores are summed to form an index of quality of life where a high score indicates “good” quality of life. The range of the scale is from 0, which represents a complete absence of quality of life, to 57, which represents total satisfaction of all four domains. In our sample the achieved range goes from 7 to 57. The original scale was developed in the context of a postal follow-up to members of the Boyd-Orr sample in 2000 (Hyde et al., 2003). A complete evaluation of the psychometric properties of this measure in terms of internal consistency and reliability was made by Wiggins et al. (2008).

The social participation index is based on a selection of 8 questions from two set of questions intended to measure the social and cultural engagement of the respondent. We select from these questions those activities that should be more cognitive demanding. The first set of questions is presented as statements that may apply or not to the respondent. From this set we select the following ones: (1) I read daily newspaper; (2) I have a hobby or pastime; (3) I use internet and/or email. The second set of question asks to the respondent whether or not he is a member of any of some organizations, clubs or societies. From this second set we select the following ones: (1) Political party, trade union or environmental groups; (2) Tenants groups, resident groups, Neighborhood Watch; (3) Education, art or music groups or evening classes; (4) Social clubs; (5) any other organizations, club or societies. The index is composed summing all the activities or membership in which the respondent reports to be involved. As a consequence the index ranges from 0 to 8.

B Identification Tests

In this section we report the results from two different tests that we perform to verify the validity of our RD design. The first test verifies whether there are discontinuity in pre-determined characteristics for which we have data, known not to be affected by the treatment. This test is particularly important, because in the presence of other discontinuities, the estimated effect may be attributed erroneously to the treatment of interest. Specifically, we tested the assumption of zero effects on father’s last occupation and self-reported childhood health, using the same estimation strategy performed for estimating the treatment effect on cognitive test scores. Table 8 reports the education effect on these two variables using a local linear regression approach around the discontinuity using only the first wave, since there is no time variation in those variables. As shown also in Table 3 the results do not show significant differences in the two groups rejecting the hypothesis of the presence of discontinuity in the observed predetermined characteristics. Moreover, this test should overcome most of the concern about the validity of our sample selection based on values of the endogenous variable. The results, in fact, show that in both the samples the observed predetermined characteristics are the same just before and after the cutoff.

Table 8.

2SLS Estimates of the Effect of Education on Predetermined Characteristics.

Males Females

Age < 16 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3 h = 1 h = 2 h = 3
Father job .684
(.547)
−.124
(.319)
.059
(.259)
−.179(.524) .333
(.384)
−.022
(.263)
Child health .537
(.611)
−.105
(.408)
.020
(.333)
.342
(.551)
−.007
(.426)
−.242
(.328)
N 165 356 542 183 365 534

Age < 19

Father job 1.323
(1.803)
−.300
(.494)
.189
(.534)
.007
(.313)
.362
(.308)
.075
(.217)
Child health −5.236
(49.677)
−1.616
(3.046)
−.591
(1.079)
.268
(.388)
.091
(.347)
.028 (.229)
N 237 478 713 266 531 795

Notes. Table reports 2SLS estimates of the effect of schooling on father’s occupation when the respondent was 14 and self-reported childhood health. Columns denote the bandwidth selection h from 1 to 3 years. Rows indicate two different sample selection: (a) conditional on leaving before the age of 19; (b) conditional on leaving before the age of 16. All regressions include: a linear function of month of birth and its interaction with the reform dummy; a control for adult height. The standard error in parenthesis are robust to heteroskedasticity. Significance levels:

(*)

p-values between 10 and 5 percent;

(**)

p-values between 5 and 1 percent;

(***)

p-values less than 1 percent.

A second test for the validity of our RD design involves estimating jumps at points where there should be no jumps in the treatment distribution. As suggested by Imbens and Lemieux (2008) we test for jumps at the median value of the two subsamples on either side of the cutoff value. Specifically, we test for the presence of jumps five year before and after the cutoff date of 1st April of 1933. Table 9 reports the results of this test. For each sex, each column reports the estimated coefficient of a dummy variable on that identifies cohorts born after one of the two “virtual” cutoff point, namely 1928 and 1938. All regressions include a linear function of month of birth and its interaction with the non-discontinuity dummy, controls for adult height and for survey year. As expected, the results does not show any significant coeffcients.

Table 9.

Test of Discontinuities at Non Discontinuity Points.

Age left< 16 Males Females

before after before after
Non disc. point −.006
(.029)
.004
(.023)
−.046
(.034)
−.003
(.019)
N 1935 2322 2312 2414

Age left< 19

Non disc. point .0.75
(.102)
.042
(.055)
−.116
(.078)
−.017
(.068)
N 2441 3428 3009 3993

Notes. Table reports the coeffcient of a set of OLS regressions with a dummy variable that identifies the cohorts born after two non-discontinuity points, namely five years before the first cohort affected by the 1947 reform (1928) and the second five years after (1938). In each regression the sample includes respondents born five years before and after the non discontinuity point. All regressions include: a linear function of month of birth and its interaction with the virtual reform dummy; controls for adult height and for survey year. The standard error in parenthesis are robust to heteroskedasticity and clustered by month of birth and survey year. Significance levels:

(*)

p-values between 10 and 5 percent;

(**)

p-values between 5 and 1 percent;

(***)

p-values less than 1 percent.

C Cross Validation Procedure

The optimal bandwidth is chosen with a ”leave one out” procedure proposed by Imbens and Lemieux (2008). Basically, for each observation i on the left of the cutoff point, we run a linear regression using only observation with value of X (the treatment determining variable) on the left of Xi (Xi – h ≤ X < Xi), while for observation on the right of the cutoff point we use only those on the right of Xi (Xi ≤ X < Xi + h). We repeat this procedure for each i in order to obtain the whole set of predicted value of Y that can be compared with the actual value of Y. Formally, the cross-validation criterion is defined as

CVY(h)=1Ni=1Nh(Y(i)Y^(X(i)))2,

where Ŷ (X(i)) represent the predicted value of Y using the above described regression. The optimal bandwidth is that value of h that minimizes the criterion function. In our case we have to perform this procedure 3 times: one for the first stage regression, and two for the two cognitive outcome of interest. However, Imbens and Lemieux (2008) suggest to use same bandwidth for both outcome and treatment equation and use the smallest bandwidth selected by the cross-validation procedures. To avoid problem with seasonality in month of birth we apply the cross validation procedure only on bandwidths equal to multiples of year of birth, from 1 to 10 years before and after the cutoff point. Results of this procedures that we do not report to conserve space, suggest that except for females’ executive function (where the optimal bandwidth is 2 year), the optimal bandwidth is equal to 1 year.

D Polynomial Choice

The second estimation procedure is based on polynomial regression. In this case the problem is the choice of the optimal polynomial order. we make use of the well know Akaike information criteria (AIC):

AIC=Nln(σ^)2+2p,

where σ^ is the mean square error of the regression and p is the number of parameters in the model. The results of this polynomial choice are presented in Table 10. It reports the AIC value according to different bandwidths and polynomial orders. From the results presented in the table do not emerge a defined choice for the polynomial order. More in general, for both males and females the optimal order of the polynomial increases as we increase the bandwidth, but it is usually bigger for males then for females.

Table 10.

Polynomial Order Choice according to Different Bandwidths (Years).

Males Females

Memory Years Polynomial N AIC N AIC
5 1 2322 11988.56 2576 13270.69
5 2 2322 11986.11 2576 13271.36
5 3 2322 11989.93 2576 13275.22
5 4 2322 11992.97 2576 13278.85
5 5 2322 11993.03 2576 13271.7

8 1 3492 17918.27 3899 20064.6
8 2 3492 17904.69 3899 20060.93
8 3 3492 17902.90 3899 20060.69
8 4 3492 17902.36 3899 20064.18
8 5 3492 17900.99 3899 20062.61

10 1 4203 21560.50 4698 24158.79
10 2 4203 21553.79 4698 24149.74
10 3 4203 21549.53 4698 24151.26
10 4 4203 21552.44 4698 24149.47
10 5 4203 21551.56 4698 24148.66

Exec. func. Years Polynomial N AIC N AIC

5 1 2322 14574.82 2576 15856.63
5 2 2322 14574.70 2576 15859.4
5 3 2322 14574.42 2576 15862.74
5 4 2322 14576.58 2576 15866.54
5 5 2322 14579.10 2576 15865.46

8 1 3492 21998.15 3899 23970.38
8 2 3492 21997.77 3899 23972.89
8 3 3492 21992.66 3899 23975.09
8 4 3492 21996.23 3899 23975.36
8 5 3492 21996.00 3899 23975.02

10 1 4203 26585.13 4698 28904.11
10 2 4203 26586.59 4698 28901.72
10 3 4203 26585.41 4698 28905.24
10 4 4203 26584.27 4698 28906.14
10 5 4203 26582.06 4698 28902.69

Footnotes

1

This quote also makes it clear that, as well as providing one year of extra schooling this reform will have typically led to a one-year delay in entry into the labour force which may be considered beneficial if paid work at young ages is thought to be harmful. Obviously our analysis will not be able to distinguish between which of these two changes led to any identified effects on outcomes, although we do return to this issue briefly in our discussion.

2

In a more recent paper, Chib and Jacobi (2011) find only very small earnings effects using the same dataset as Oreopolous but with a bayesian estimation approach. However, their use of unbalanced month-of-birth windows on either side of the reform (from January 1932 to March 1933 in comparison to May 1933 to December 1934) may mean the estimates are not directly comparable in the presence of either unobserved socioeconomic characteristics that are correlated with month of birth (see Buckles and Hungerman, 2010 for example), or age at school entry effects on subsequent outcomes (see Crawford et al., 2010).

3

In Northern Ireland the change was not implemented until 1957.

4

Indeed, a similar rule applied also for the age at school exit: students could leave school only at end of the term in which they reached the minimum school leaving age (14 before the reform, 15 after).

5

For instance in the word recall task the words are ’read out’ by the computer at prescribed intervals as opposed to by the interviewer who may be tempted to slow down, emphasise or repeat words according to their perception of the demands of the respondent.

6

In reality, we restrict the sample to 10 years before and after the reform because we have few observations for cohorts before the 1923.

7

The discreetness of our treatment determining variable (month of birth) can introduce a common component of variance for all the observations at any given value of this variable (Lee and Card, 2008).

8

When we do cluster at the month of birth level in specifications with large enough bandwidth to support such a specification the standard errors decrease and we always obtain significant results for males. For this reason we prefer to be conservative and use the individual level clustering in the paper.

9

When we use different methods of construction of the executive function index the coefficient are very similar but the standard errors are usually greater.

10

Since the social participation variables come from the self-completion component of the ELSA instrument there is a concern that non-response patterns to this element of the survey may affect our estimates. In order to verify this we performed the same estimation of the effect of education on the cognitive measures in Table 5 using just the subsample of respondent to self-completion questionnaire. The results, not reported to conserve space,do show differences for females. In particular, the estimated effect of education on memory are no longer statistically significant which may, in turn, explain why we don’t find evidence of social participation mechanism for females in this sample.

JEL codes: C14, I28, J14, J24.

Contributor Information

James Banks, University of Manchester and IFS.

Fabrizio Mazzonna, MEA at the Max-Planck-Institute for Social Law and Social Policy (MPISOC).

References

  1. Acemoglu D, Angrist JD. Consequences of employment protection? The case of the Americans with disabilities act. Journal of Political Economy. 2001;vol. 109(5):915–57. [Google Scholar]
  2. Angrist JD, Krueger AB. Does compulsory school attendance affect schooling and earnings? The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1991;vol. 106(4):979–1014. [Google Scholar]
  3. Ashenfelter O, Rouse C. Income, schooling, and ability: evidence from a new sample Of identical twins. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1998;vol. 113(1):253–84. [Google Scholar]
  4. Banks J, Oldfield Z. Understanding pensions: Cognitive functions, numerical ability and retirement saving. Fiscal Studies. 2007;vol. 28(2):143–70. [Google Scholar]
  5. Buckles K, Hungerman D. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2010. Season of birth and later outcomes: old questions, new answers. NBER Working Paper No. 14573. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  6. Card D. Estimating the return to schooling: progress on some persistent econometric problems. Econometrica, Econometric Society. 2001;vol. 69(5):1127–60. [Google Scholar]
  7. Case A, Paxson C. Early life health and cognitive function in old age. American Economic Review. 2009;vol. 99(2):104–09. doi: 10.1257/aer.99.2.104. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  8. Ceci S, Williams W. Schooling, intelligence, and income. American Psychologist. 1997;vol. 52(10):1051–58. [Google Scholar]
  9. Chib S, Jacobi L. Institute for the Study of Labor; 2011. Returns to compulsory schooling in Britain: evidence from a Bayesian fuzzy regression discontinuity analysis. IZA Discussion paper 5564. [Google Scholar]
  10. Clark D, Royer H. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2010. The effect of education on adult mortality and health: evidence from Britain. NBER Working Paper No. 16013. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  11. Crawford C, Dearden L, Meghir C. Institute for Fiscal Studies; 2010. When you are born matters: the impact of date of birth on educational outcomes in England. IFS Working Paper 10/06. [Google Scholar]
  12. Cunha F, Heckman JJ. The technology of skill formation. American Economic Review. 2007;vol. 97(2):31–47. [Google Scholar]
  13. de Jager CA, Budge MM, Clarke R. Utility of TICS-M for the assessment of cognitive function in older adults. International Journal of Geriatric Psychiatry. 2003;vol. 18(4):318–24. doi: 10.1002/gps.830. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  14. Devereux P, Hart R. Forced to be rich? Returns to compulsory schooling in Britain. ECONOMIC JOURNAL. 2010;vol. 120(549):1345–64. [Google Scholar]
  15. Folstein MF, Folstein SE, McHugh PR. Mini-Mental State: a practical method for grading the cognitive state of patients for the clinician. Journal of Psychiatric Research. 1975;vol. 12(3):189–98. doi: 10.1016/0022-3956(75)90026-6. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  16. Glymour MM, Kawachi I, Jencks C, Berkman L. Does childhood schooling affect old age memory or mental status? Using state schooling laws as natural experiments. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health. 2008;vol. 62(6):532–37. doi: 10.1136/jech.2006.059469. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  17. Grossman M. On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. The Journal of Political Economy. 1972;vol. 80(2):223–55. [Google Scholar]
  18. Heckman JJ, Moon SH, Pinto R, Savelyev PA, Yavitz AQ. The rate of return to the high scope Perry preschool program. Journal of Public Economics. 2010;vol. 94(1-2):114–28. doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.001. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. Herrnstein RJ, Murray C. The Bell Curve. The Free Press; New York: 1994. [Google Scholar]
  20. Hertzog C, Kramer AF, Wilson RS, Lindenberger U. Enrichment effects on adult cognitive developments. Can the functional capacity of older adults be preserved and enhanced? Psychological Science in the Public Interest. 2008;vol. 9(1):1–65. doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6053.2009.01034.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  21. Hyde M, Wiggins R, Higgs P, Blane D. A measure of quality of life in early old age: the theory, development and properties of a needs satisfaction model (CASP-19) Aging and Mental Health. 2003;vol. 7(3):186–94. doi: 10.1080/1360786031000101157. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  22. Harmon C, Walker I. Estimates of the economic return to schooling for the United Kingdom. American Economic Review. 1995;vol. 85(5):1278–86. [Google Scholar]
  23. Imbens G, Angrist JD. Identification and estimation of local average treatment effects. Econometrica. 1994;vol. 62(2):467–75. [Google Scholar]
  24. Imbens G, Lemieux T. Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice. Journal of Econometrics. 2008;vol. 142(2):615–35. [Google Scholar]
  25. Jürges H, Kruk E, Reinhold S. Mannheim Research Institue for Economics of Aging; 2009. The effect of compulsory schooling on health - evidence from biomarkers. MEA Discussion Paper 183-09. [Google Scholar]
  26. Le Carret N, Lafont S, Mayo W, Fabrigoule C. The effect of education on cognitive performances and its implication for the constitution of the cognitive reserve. Developmental Neuropsychology. 2003;vol. 23(3):317–37. doi: 10.1207/S15326942DN2303_1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  27. Lee DS, Card D. Regression discontinuity inference with specification error. Journal of Econometrics. 2008;vol. 142(2):655–74. [Google Scholar]
  28. Lee DS, Lemieux T. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2009. Regression discontinuity designs in economics. NBER Working Papers 14723. [Google Scholar]
  29. Lindeboom M, Llena-Nozalb A, van der Klaauw B. Parental education and child health: evidence from a schooling reform. Journal of Health Economics. 2009;vol. 28(1):109–31. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.08.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  30. Lleras-Muney A. The Relationship between education and adult mortality in the U.S. Review of Economic Studies. 2005;vol. 72(1):189–21. [Google Scholar]
  31. Lochner L, Moretti E. The Effect of education on crime: evidence from prison inmates, arrests, and self-reports. American Economic Review. 2004;vol. 94(1):155–89. [Google Scholar]
  32. Machin S, Marie O, Vujić S. The crime reducing effect of education. ECONOMIC JOURNAL. 2011;vol. 121(552):463–84. [Google Scholar]
  33. Mazzonna F, Peracchi F. EIEF Working. Einaudi Institute for Economic and Finance (EIEF); 2010. Aging, cognitive abilities and retirement in Europe. Papers Series 1015. [Google Scholar]
  34. Oreopoulos P. Estimating average and local average treatment effects of education when compulsory schooling laws really matter. American Economic Review. 2006;vol. 96(1):152–75. [Google Scholar]
  35. Oreopoulos P. Estimating average and local average treatment effects of education when compulsory schooling laws really matter: corrigendum. 2008 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/000282806776157641.
  36. Rohwedder S, Willis R. Mental retirement. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2010;vol. 24(1):119–38. doi: 10.1257/jep.24.1.119. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  37. Rubin D. Inference and missing data. Biometrika. 1976;vol. 63:581–92. [Google Scholar]
  38. Spence A. Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1973;vol. 87(3):355–74. [Google Scholar]
  39. Steel N, Huppert F, McWilliams B, Melzer D. Physical and cognitive function. In: Marmot M, Banks J, Blundell R, Lessof C, Nazroo J, editors. Health, wealth and lifestyles of the older population in England: The 2002 English Longitudinal Study of Ageing. IFS; London: 2003. pp. 249–71. [Google Scholar]
  40. Wiggins RD, Netuveli G, Hyde M, Higgs P, Blane D. The evaluation of a self-enumerated scale of quality of Life (CASP-19) in the context of research on ageing: a combination of exploratory and confirmatory approaches. Social Research Indicators. 2008;vol. 89(1):61–77. [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES