Abstract
We examine how the relationship between development and inequality at the societal level is perceived and evaluated by ordinary Chinese people. We hypothesize that because the Chinese have recently experienced rapid increases in both economic growth and social inequality, they tend to view economic development as a driving force of social inequality. To address this question, we conducted a social survey in 2006 in six Chinese provinces (n = 4,898). The survey data reveal that a large proportion of Chinese people have internalized a causal model in which they project high levels of inequality onto countries they view as more developed and low levels of inequality onto countries they see as less developed. However, results also show that a smaller proportion of Chinese believe in a negative relationship between development and inequality. Hence, the study reveals heterogeneity among ordinary Chinese in their perceptions of the causal relationship between development and inequality. Surprisingly, socioeconomic and demographic characteristics provide no explanatory power in explaining this heterogeneity.
Keywords: China, Development, Inequality, Attitudes
By all indicators, the Chinese economy has been growing rapidly over the last thirty years. Between 1978 and 2006, for example, China’s GDP increased at an average rate of 9.8% per year after adjusting for inflation (State Statistical Bureau 2006, Table 3.3). This is a very high level of economic growth for a sustained period of time. Factoring in the huge population size of China (currently at 1.3 billion), the scale and the pace of economic expansion still underway in China is staggering. In fact, China’s economic growth has been so large and rapid that it has played a major role in the shrinking of world income inequality (Firebaugh 2003).
Accompanying the rapid economic growth in China since 1978 has been a sharp rise in economic inequality (Han 2004; Hauser and Xie 2005; Khan and Riskin 1998). It has been estimated that China’s Gini index, a standard measure of income inequality, jumped steadily from .310 in 1985 to .415 in 2001 (Wu and Perloff 2005). Much of the existing literature in sociology on contemporary China has focused on social inequality in the past fifteen years (for a review, see Bian 2002), attempting to address the distributional question of “who wins and who loses” during the transition (Wu and Xie 2003, p.427).1 More recently, researchers have begun trying to understand Chinese subjective attitudes toward inequality, yielding the general finding that overall, ordinary Chinese are surprisingly tolerant of high levels of inequality (Whyte 2010; Wu 2009).
In this paper, we examine how the relationship between development and inequality at the societal level is perceived and evaluated by ordinary Chinese people. In particular, we are interested in whether their attitudes towards social inequality are shaped by their views of the relationship between development and inequality. We hypothesize that views of inequality in China are affected by whether people believe that development and inequality are positively or negatively related. Given China’s recent history of experiencing rapid increases in both economic development and social inequality, we expect that large numbers of Chinese view economic development as driving social inequality. At the same time, some other Chinese may believe economic development and social inequality to be negatively related because of the earlier doctrine and policy of the Chinese state in negatively linking the two phenomena together. To test these hypotheses, we conducted a survey in 2006 in six Chinese provinces (n = 4,898). This paper reports the results from the survey.
Theoretical Issues
Development and Inequality
We begin our theoretical discussion with a set of interrelated ideas or worldviews that have permeated—even dominated—the social sciences for centuries under the labels of developmentalism, social evolution, and modernization theory (Burrow 1981; Harris 1968; Mandelbaum 1971; Nisbet 1975; Sanderson 1990; Smith 1973; Stocking 1968, 1987; Thornton 2001, 2005). Central to these ideas is the developmental paradigm that suggests that all societies go through the same uniform and necessary stages of development, social evolution, or modernization, but at different rates. These ideas suggest that societies at many developmental stages could be observed in a single cross-section of time. Scholars using this framework believed that the most developed countries were in northwest Europe and the northwest European diasporas; they believed that other societies were located at various levels of development below the most advanced northwest European countries. These scholars used cross-sectional variation among countries to infer a developmental trajectory by assuming that in the past the most advanced countries had been like the currently less developed countries and that in the future the less advanced countries would become like the currently more developed countries (Berkhofer 1978; Carniero 1973; Gordon 1994; Harris 1968; Manuel 1962; Sanderson 1990; Sheehan 1980; Thornton 2001, 2005).
The developmental model and the use of cross-sectional data to describe the trajectory of development led to beliefs about how societal inequality changed as development increased. It was commonly believed that societal inequality was very low at the beginning of societal development, increased as development increased, and then declined again as societies moved from medium to high levels of development (Hobbes [1642]1991; [1651]1996; Locke [1690]1988; Montaigne [1580]1946; Robertson [1777]1780; Rousseau [1775]1984; Tylor 1781).2 This viewpoint suggested that at the earliest stages of development—which was believed to be observable among some of the indigenous peoples of Africa, America, Asia, and Australia of the seventeenth, eighteenth, and nineteenth centuries—there was very little inequality and that it was only after people obtained a certain level of development that social hierarchy appeared, with unequal distribution of resources and power. It was believed that at higher stages of development, like those in northwest Europe and its overseas populations, inequality declined again. This view of decreasing inequality at higher levels of development was exemplified by Marx and Engels' ([1848]2002) grand theory of history that associated decreasing income inequality with higher levels of development, at the pinnacle of which full equality was to be achieved under communism. Such modernization models posited not only a relationship between societal development and equality/inequality but also causal connections between these two factors.
The ideas associated with developmentalism, societal evolution, and modernization have been sharply and effectively criticized during the twentieth century (Bock 1956; Hodgen 1964; Mandelbaum 1971; Cesaire 1972; Jennings 1975; Nisbet 1975; Tilly 1984; Wallerstein 1991; Szreter 1993; Böröcz 2000; Chakrabarty 2000). These models were strongly criticized as being teleological, and the assumption of uniform and directional change was challenged as being unsupportable. Although these models are still sometimes used in academic treatises, their use in academia is now much less common than during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries (Thornton 2005). Even the language of developmentalism and modernization and the practice of labeling countries according to their levels of development have been criticized severely in recent decades (Thornton 2005).
Recent research has also called into question the claim that inequality increases in early periods of modernization and then declines as societies reach high levels of development. There is a substantial empirical literature on this topic today, some of which is supportive of this standard inverted-U relationship (Kuznets 1955; Barro 2000; Chiswick 1971; Lenski 1984; Szirmai 1988). However, other research suggests that economic growth at high levels of income is often associated with increasing rather than decreasing levels of income inequality within countries (Fishlow 1972; Executive Yuan 1990; Deininger and Squire 1998; Barro 2000; Firebaugh 2003). Adding nuance and complexity, this recent empirical research thus challenges any simple uniform relationship between societal inequality and income growth.
China presents an interesting case consistent with the general prediction that economic growth in the early years of industrialization is accompanied by increases of inequality. Under a strong government program for economic development initiated in 1978, China has experienced very rapid economic growth in recent decades, and during the same period, social inequality in China has increased significantly (Han 2004; Hauser and Xie 2005; Khan and Riskin 1998; Wu and Perloff 2005). Much of the social inequality in China today consists of large disparities across group boundaries (Wang 2008), such as the urban/rural divide (Wu and Treiman 2004), region (Xie and Hannum 1996), and work unit (Xie and Wu 2008). Indeed, social inequality has become one of the most frequently discussed topics by the Chinese public in recent years (Whyte 2010; Wong and Lee 2000; Wu 2009). Chinese media, particularly print and internet media, also frequently discuss social inequality, although the public is much more concerned about perceived unfairness and its institutional mechanisms, such as corruption, than about high levels of inequality per se (Sun 2008; Whyte 2010; Wong and Lee 2000; Wu 2009; Xie 2010; Zeng and Yue 2006; Zhao 1994).
Inequality and Social Justice in the Chinese Context
Social equality, like development, is a commonly cited indicator of societal well-being. Indeed, according to some elite writers, equality is so central to human integrity and values that inequality is equated with injustice, even immorality (Rakowski 1991; Szirmai 1988; Jasso 2007; Evans and Kelley 2007). In discussing world culture—beliefs and values that have been widely disseminated around the world – John Meyer and his colleagues include equality among a larger package of ideas concerning development, individualism, freedom, justice, and human rights that is rapidly spreading internationally (Krücken and Drori 2009; Meyer et al. 1997; Thomas et al. 1987).
Although equality is generally seen as desirable, many people also view certain levels and dimensions of inequality as being justified (Jasso 2000; Evans and Kelley 2007; Kluegel and Matějů 1995). This is particularly true when people see inequality as resulting from such factors as education, experience, talent, or effort (Jasso 2000; Han and Whyte 2008; Whyte 2010; Jasso and Rossi 1977; Swift et al. 1995; Alwin et al. 1995). Acceptance of inequality is likely to be higher if people believe that it helps to make the overall pie bigger through development or it is a normal and expected result of this (Jasso 1999, 2000).
The People’s Republic of China, founded following a Communist Revolution, still treats Marxism as its official ideology. Although Marx and his followers never advocated the establishment of a totally equal society in which everyone received exactly the same proportion of societal goods (Whyte 2010), they did support a strong reduction in inequality. Consequently, “when the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) gained national power in 1949, its leaders saw the transformation of the existing stratification hierarchy as one of their primary goals” (Whyte 2010, p.141). During the first few years of the CCP’s rule, the emphasis on egalitarianism was fairly moderate, but beginning in the middle 1950s and extending through the late 1970s, efforts in this direction increased, exceeding egalitarian drives in other socialistic societies (Whyte 2010). These efforts included active leveling of society through reducing the resources and positions of previously privileged classes (Parish 1984). During this period before the economic reform, the country experienced economic and demographic catastrophes, and the overall rate of economic growth through the late 1970s was significantly lower than the original goal. Although inequality in earnings and marketable commodities was low during the period, the government introduced its own forms of inequality, and the country continued to be stratified in many ways (Whyte 2010). Particularly, the role of danwei -- the work unit and its association with the state – was prominent (Bian 1994; Walder 1986; Xie and Wu 2008).
Beginning in 1978, China experienced what Whyte (2010) describes as a second revolution, a sequel to the one that brought communism to power in 1949. In this second revolution, many of the elements of socialism previously established were dismantled and replaced with a market economy and capitalism. Most relevant to our purposes was the abandonment of the old emphasis on egalitarianism and its replacement with a philosophy and policy that accepted, even endorsed, inequalities in the reward system and in the distribution of goods (Friedman 2002; Tang and Parish 2000; Whyte 2010; Xie 2010).
This may be best exemplified in the statement of Deng Xiaoping, the leader of the second revolution, that “it is good for some people to get rich first” (as quoted in Whyte 2010, p.31). These few words contain multiple messages. First, and most importantly, they indicate that inequality is not only acceptable but good. Second, they suggest that getting rich is also good and that all people will eventually get rich, although not equally quickly. Third, they imply that some people getting rich quickly will facilitate the economic advancement of others. In this way Deng endorsed unequal rewards as an important factor in achieving the development goals of the country. As a result of this second revolution, both overall income and income inequality in China have dramatically increased.
Like most people elsewhere, most Chinese value equality and think that the current level of inequality in China is excessive (Whyte 2010, p.44). At the same time, Chinese are tolerant of what they perceive as excessive inequality, and most are opposed to redistribution of income from rich to poor (Whyte 2010, p.51). How do we reconcile the seeming contradiction that Chinese value equality but tolerate inequality? The answer lies in a belief, held by most Chinese that inequality is a necessary stimulus for economic development, as unequal rewards motivate individuals to work hard. While a substantial minority sees current inequalities as unfair, most Chinese think that today's inequality is justified, fair, and better than the circumstances existing before the 1978 reforms. To a survey question asking whether people agreed or disagreed that “Only when income differences are large enough will individuals have the incentive to work hard,” about half of the respondents agreed, less than 20 percent disagreed, and 30 percent stayed neutral (Whyte 2010, p.53). In summary, Whyte’s (2010) extensive study of subjective inequality in China reveals that while ordinary Chinese value equality, they prefer equality of opportunity to equality of economic outcomes and thus have high tolerance for actual inequality.
However, given the complex and changing history of official rhetoric and actual experience in China concerning the relationship between societal development and inequality, there is likely to be considerable variation in the ways ordinary people perceive this relationship, a fact also documented by Whyte (2010). We hypothesize that the combination since 1978 of strong official rhetoric propounding a positive relationship between development and inequality and rapid increases in both income and inequality has led most Chinese to believe in a positive association between development and inequality. That is, both official rhetoric and experience across three recent decades support this positive relationship, which has probably permeated the beliefs of the majority of ordinary people in China today. At the same time, we expect that the strong communist rhetoric endorsing economic equality and its correlation with economic development and well-being prior to 1978 has had a lasting impact upon many people. Consequently, we expect that a substantial minority of ordinary Chinese still perceive a negative correlation between economic development and societal inequality. Finally, we acknowledge that many other Chinese will either be confused about the relationship between societal development and inequality or will perceive the relationship to be either very small or nonexistent.
The “Societal Projection” Hypothesis
As we argued before, development has become a core concept in world culture today. A country’s level of development is perhaps one of its most salient features, known to ordinary people in other countries. A large literature now documents that the estimates of development held by ordinary people closely follow the composite measures constructed by the United Nations (UNDP 2009) (Binstock and Thornton 2007; Melegh et al. forthcoming; Thornton, Binstock, and Ghimire 2008; Thornton et al. 2011). Using survey data in a comparative study, Thornton and his colleagues (2011) have found that ordinary people in thirteen diverse countries (spread across Africa, Asia, Europe, Latin America, and North America) can rate countries on development, and their ratings match closely the Human Development Index (HDI) assembled and reported by the United Nations (UNDP 2009). Chinese are no different. As we will show later in the paper, Chinese have views about development and rate countries on a development scale in ways that are similar to the UN.
However, inequality is a more difficult concept for ordinary people to grasp and is a less salient feature of a society. As we will show later, ordinary Chinese have no real knowledge about the level of inequality in other countries. This raises the question of what happens when we ask respondents in a survey to rate inequality levels of various countries. In general, how do individuals form opinions about inequality in other societies with which they have no direct contact?
Psychological research on survey responses provides us with valuable clues. When respondents are presented with cognitively challenging tasks, they are forced to undergo a comprehension process and give reports they deem logical (Krosnick 1991; Schwarz 1999; Sudman, Bradburn, and Schwarz 1996; Tourangeau, Rips, and Rasinski 2000). In a sense, they construct answers on the spot in response to survey questions, answers that they had often not thought about previously and did not actually possess before being asked. In constructing answers, the respondents make use of the context in which survey questions are asked. Schwarz (1999) writes, “[Respondents] construct these judgments [on survey questions] on the spot, when needed, by drawing on the information that is most accessible at that point in time” (p. 103).
Thus, we expect that respondents construct their answers about other countries’ levels of inequality when they do not, in fact, know what they are. How do they derive their answers? We postulate that ordinary Chinese people derive their understanding of inequality as a secondary feature from their understanding of the relationship between development and inequality. This is made possible by a cognitive process: simplification. Indeed, Allport ([1954]1979) developed a psychological theory of “direct projection” about prejudice based on this very idea. According to Allport, humans tend to focus on salient features, “visible” differences across social groups, and to make associations between the known features and the unknown features. He called this the “condensation of attitudes around visible cues” (p.133). In order for people to do this, they need a mechanism that associates the unknown with the known. This mechanism can be an abstract principle held by the individual or an empirical generalization that connects the unknown attribute to the known one or both. In Allport’s language this is a projection, or generalization, from the known to the unknown, a process that humans tend to base on their previous understanding of the world. Although Allport’s theory is concerned with prejudice based on social categories such as race and gender, his work on the cognitive process is useful for our study on subjective beliefs about inequality in China. In attempting to understand opinion formation among ordinary Chinese about unknown characteristics of other countries, we borrow Allport’s theory of projection.
Projection is an apt explanation of how we expect ordinary Chinese persons to estimate the level of inequality and other features of foreign societies. As we show below, ordinary Chinese have little or no direct knowledge about the level of income inequality within other countries. Yet, they are quite willing to rate other countries in this respect. We suggest that one way that people in China and elsewhere do this is by relying on their understanding of a particular society’s level of economic development and by drawing inferences about income inequality from this knowledge. In this way, people make projections concerning another country’s level of inequality from their understanding of that country’s development and the relationship they believe to exist between development and income inequality.
Of course, the outcome of this projection will depend upon the beliefs that people have concerning the relationship between societal development and inequality. If they believe that this relationship is positive, their ratings of countries on inequality will tend to parallel their ratings of the same countries on development, but if they believe that the development-inequality relationship is negative, they will tend to rate countries they believe to be highly developed as being low on inequality. The positive or negative correlation between a person’s development and inequality ratings, therefore, reflects whether they believe that the relationship between income inequality and development is positive or negative. We call this process “Societal Projection.”
Because Chinese society has recently experienced rapid increases in both economic well-being and social inequality, we expect that a very large fraction of Chinese extract from this experience an understanding that development necessarily goes hand in hand with increases in inequality (Whyte 2010), projecting their own understanding onto the rest of the world and ranking inequality levels high for countries they consider to be highly developed and low for countries they consider less developed. However, diverse opinions about inequality exist within China. Previous decades of government and party emphasis on development and inequality being inversely related may have led many people today to believe in a negative relationship between development and inequality (Whyte 2010, p.53). However, we believe that the fraction perceiving a negative relationship will be smaller than that believing in a positive relationship.
Our hypothesis that Chinese people project views of inequality from their views of development is buttressed by the fact that there is evidence that many ordinary people in diverse countries believe that such factors as low fertility, high age at marriage, gender equality, and self-choice of a spouse are related to development levels and are seen as both causes and effects of development (Binstock and Thornton 2007; Mitchell 2009; Thornton, Binstock, and Ghimire 2008; Thornton et al. forthcoming). Our hypothesis of Chinese people relating development and inequality fits with these other observations.
It would be naïve to assume that the relationship between development and inequality are homogeneous in the Chinese population. As argued earlier, the communist teachings about the importance of equality may have affected more strongly the older cohorts of Chinese who grew up and were socialized before the 1978 revolution than the younger cohorts. As a result, we expect that younger cohorts who have lived most of their lives during the period of both rhetoric and reality indicating a positive correlation between income levels and inequality will be more likely than older people to believe that a positive correlation exists. Also, one important element of China’s rapid economic growth in recent decades has been its uneven geographical distribution (Xie and Hannum 1996). This expansion of the economy has been much more rapid in China’s urban areas and eastern provinces than in rural areas and western provinces. We expect that this uneven distribution of actual economic growth has affected people’s views of the relationship between development and inequality, with residents of cities and eastern provinces being more likely than others to believe in a positive relationship between development and inequality and less likely to believe in a negative relationship.
Position in the social hierarchy may also be related to views of the relationship between development and inequality. Most importantly, we predict that educated people will have a greater understanding of both rhetoric and empirical realities concerning the trends in income growth and inequality during recent decades. Our expectation is that this greater understanding will lead them more frequently to believe that income inequality and development are positively related. However, we also recognize that the most educated people may have been the most susceptible to the ideology of the party concerning a negative relationship between development and inequality that existed prior to the revolution beginning in the late 1970s. This tendency may counteract our main hypothesis of highly educated people being more likely to believe in a positive relationship between inequality and development. We also expect that the well-educated and those with knowledge of actual levels of income, education, and health in different countries will be the most likely to believe that development is related to income inequality—either positively or negatively—rather than to see no relationship at all.
Before proceeding, we need to clarify that development and developmental hierarchies are not physical facts or realities like income, education, and life expectancy, but are social constructions like justice, equity, and human rights. As such, the social constructs of development provide models for evaluating countries and for understanding social change. Like many other social constructs, the ideas of development and developmental hierarchies have become so engrained in people’s worldviews that they are often accepted as real and taken-for-granted attributes of countries and other entities. However, the social construction nature of development is made evident by the fact that no direct indicators of development exist and people must construct their estimates of development levels through indirect indicators such as income, technology, education, and health. This is what happens with the UN’s construction of development as a composite of income, education, and life expectancy. There is evidence that many people around the world follow a similar approach, as they construct estimates of development levels for countries that closely match the UN HDI scores (Thornton et al. 2011). Of course, there are also substantial differences among individuals in the extent to which their construction of development scores matches the scores of the UN.
Furthermore, our research is concerned about ordinary people’s beliefs about the relationship of societal development and inequality, not the actual relationship between development and inequality in China, which has been the focus of extensive previous research (reviewed above). In addition, our research is not about whether development and income inequality are good or bad. We are also not concerned with people’s attitudes towards the fairness or unfairness of income inequality, which is the focus of Whyte’s (2010) research, although we will consider more fully how our findings may be important in interpreting Whyte’s results.
Data and Methods
We conducted a survey in 2006, with key items designed to address our research question, as part of a larger survey on fertility in six Chinese provinces. For simplicity, we refer to the survey as the 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey. A probability sample was drawn using a multi-stage, stratified, systematic sampling method. From a total of 31 provinces, autonomous regions, and directly governed municipalities, six were chosen to represent China’s diversity in geography, income and education levels, and the urban/rural divide: Beijing, Hebei, Qinghai, Hubei, Sichuan, and Guangdong. Within each province (or its administrative equivalent), 3 counties (or districts in Beijing municipality) were randomly selected. Within each selected county (or district), 6 villages (or neighborhood communities in urban areas), and within each village (or neighborhood community), 30–50 households were randomly selected. The survey then interviewed a married respondent of reproductive age (15–49), with a preference for women over men. The survey was conducted through face-to-face interviews in May 2006. Out of a total of 5,400 attempted interviews, 4,898 interviews were successfully conducted, yielding a response rate of 90.7%. We examine the data using a variety of strategies. To achieve analytical consistency, all the methods utilize the same restricted sample (n = 4,583) that contains valid information for all the key variables. Key survey items are provided in English in the Appendix. Descriptive statistics about the analytical sample are given in the Appendix Table. We note that women are overrepresented in the sample given the design of the survey. However, this over-representation of women should not bias the results, as gender is not a significant predictor in any of the analyses conducted for this study.
A key survey item is the Development Scale (Appendix), which has been verified in surveys conducted in thirteen diverse countries (Thornton et al. 2011). For this scale, the interviewer asked the respondent to rate the level of development in the following five countries using a scale from zero to ten, with zero representing the least developed and ten representing the most developed: China, Japan, Brazil, United States, and Pakistan. We then compared the respondents’ responses to ratings given by the United Nations (UNDP 2009). To study the respondent’s attitudes towards inequality, we also designed and implemented an Inequality Scale (Appendix), a 0–10 scale on which the respondents were asked to rate the level of inequality for the same five countries. We then compared their responses to Gini coefficients from other sources that measured the actual level of income inequality in the five countries. While some respondents had difficulty performing the task due to their unfamiliarity with all the countries about which they were asked, the number of cases missing on the items is remarkably small. Across the ten ratings (two scales for five countries), 71 did not provide all ratings, with more than half of them (42) not even rating China. Because we knew that the Development Scale had good validity and were concerned that we might induce consistency in responses to the scales in favor of our hypothesis, we placed the questions for the Inequality Scale ahead of those for the Development Scale in the survey.
To test our societal projection hypothesis, we use a variety of statistical methods in analyzing the data from the 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey. We vary statistical methods when data analysis of the study calls for different methods, ranging from comparisons of averages, comparisons of individual-level correlations, multi-level models, and multinomial logistic models. Since each method is integrated with a separate substantive analysis, it is easier to discuss the methods in connection with the analyses. That is, we will discuss specific statistical methods when we present the results from the study in the following section.
Results
Direct Questions about the Relationship between Development and Income Inequality
We begin by examining the answers from the direct questions we asked respondents about the relationship between development and income inequality. In the Six Chinese Province Survey, we asked respondents to tell us whether they strongly agreed, agreed, disagreed, or strongly disagreed with the statement that “Income inequality is larger in developed countries than in underdeveloped countries.” In this survey, 62 percent agreed or strongly agreed with the statement, whereas 37 percent disagreed or strongly disagreed. These results are consistent with our expectations in that people’s views on the relationship between development and inequality vary, but with more people believing in a positive relationship than in a negative one.
We also asked respondents to strongly agree, agree, disagree, or strongly disagree with the statement that “in order for an underdeveloped country to achieve economic development, it should increase income differences.” A majority of respondents, 71 percent, disagreed or strongly disagreed with this statement. This result suggests a belief that increases in income inequality hurt rather than help efforts for economic development. However, interpretation of the result is ambiguous, as our question did not ask whether increases in income inequality “would” help economic development, but asked whether an underdeveloped country “should” increase income differences to achieve economic development. This way of asking the question may have mixed evaluations of the consequence, with those of the desirability, of increasing inequality. Further research is required to separate evaluations of the desirability of income inequality and perceptions of its influence on economic development.
Rating Countries on Development
In Table 1, we present the average scores of the survey respondents on development (column 1), along with the UN HDI scores (column 2). We multiplied the UN scores by ten to make them more comparable with the average respondent scores, but we emphasize that the metrics of both the UN scores and the respondent averages are arbitrary, making direct comparisons difficult. As we observed earlier, Chinese respondents, like people in other countries, have conceptions of development and rate country-level development very similarly to the way the UN rates it. With our scaling metrics, Chinese respondents tend to report lower scores on development than the UN reports, but the pattern of average ratings given by Chinese respondents is very similar to the pattern of HDI scores. As a summary measure, we calculated a Pearson correlation between the average respondent ratings and the UN HDI ratings. That correlation is .94.
Table 1.
Respondents’ Rating on Levels of Development and Inequality, in Comparison to Human Development Index (HDI) and Gini Coefficient
Rated country | Average development rating (0–10)a |
United Nations 2006 HDI (×10) (0–10)b |
Average inequaltiy rating (0–10)a |
Gini coefficient (×10) (0–10)c |
---|---|---|---|---|
China | 5.54 | 7.63 | 6.24 | 4.69 |
Japan | 7.78 | 9.58 | 5.90 | 3.81 |
Brazil | 5.48 | 8.08 | 5.43 | 5.67 |
United States | 9.18 | 9.55 | 6.80 | 4.50 |
Pakistan | 3.77 | 5.68 | 5.04 | 3.06 |
Sources:
2006 Six Chinese Province Survey (N=4,583);
United Nations' (2009) Human Development Report: 2009, Table G;
CIA's (2007) World Factbook: 2007. The Gini coefficients of China and the US are for the year 2004, Japan and Pakistan 2002, and Brazil 2005.
We now turn our attention to individual rather than average ratings of the development of countries. Just as we calculated a Pearson correlation between average respondent scores and UN HDI scores for the five countries, we calculated a similar correlation for each respondent in the data set. We present in column 1 of Table 2 summary statistics for the distribution of the individual Pearson correlations between the HDI scores and each respondent’s ratings across the five countries.3 We report these individual-level correlations by deciles of the correlation size (in ten rows). These data indicate that most respondents in China rate countries on development very similarly to the HDI scores. Less than ten percent of the respondents have correlations of their scores with the HDI scores of .55 or less, more than one-half have correlations greater than .88, and forty percent have correlations at .90 or greater. The average correlation is .78.
Table 2.
Distributions of Individual-level Correlations
Development rating & UN 2006 HDIa |
Inequality rating & Gini coefficientb |
Development rating & inequality ratingc |
|
---|---|---|---|
Percentile | |||
10th | 0.55 | −0.36 | −0.94 |
20th | 0.73 | −0.19 | −0.78 |
30th | 0.81 | −0.09 | −0.30 |
40th | 0.85 | 0.01 | 0.22 |
50th | 0.88 | 0.09 | 0.58 |
60th | 0.90 | 0.18 | 0.79 |
70th | 0.92 | 0.28 | 0.91 |
80th | 0.94 | 0.36 | 0.96 |
90th | 0.95 | 0.53 | 1.00 |
Mean | 0.78 | 0.08 | 0.24 |
Relative frequency (%) | |||
Negative correlations | 3.40 | 38.84 | 35.59 |
Positive correlations | 96.60 | 61.60 | 64.41 |
Notes:
The correlation between respondents' ratings on the level of development of five countries and the corresponding 2006 Human Dvelopment Indices released by the United Nations.
The correlation between respondents' raings on the level of economic inequality of five countries and the corresponding Gini coefficients reporteb by the CIA.
The correlation between respondents' ratings on development and their ratings on economic inequality on the same five countries.
Source: 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey (N=4,583).
Ratings of Countries on Income Inequality
We now turn our attention to columns 3–4 of Table 1, where we have listed the average ratings of the respondents on income inequality and the Gini coefficients (multiplied by 10) taken from the CIA's (2007) World Factbook. Almost all of the average inequality ratings (except for Brazil) are higher than the actual Gini coefficients. This is likely related to the fact that respondents were asked to use the full eleven-point scale while country Gini coefficients seldom fall within the highest levels. Despite the use of different scales, comparison of columns 3 and 4 in Table 1 provides an opportunity to evaluate the extent of agreement between the two sets of distributions.
The country-by-country comparisons show very little association between the average respondent ratings of countries on income inequality and the actual levels of inequality in those countries. Specifically, on average, respondents rated either the U.S. or China at the top, Japan and Brazil in the middle, and Pakistan at the bottom. Comparing their subjective rankings on inequality with objective measures of the United Nations, we observe that respondents generally believe, incorrectly, that income inequality is higher in the United States and lower in Brazil than in China. In fact, the overall Pearson correlation between average respondent ratings and actual Gini coefficients is only .27. This confirms our expectation that people in China do not have conceptions of comparative income inequality that match the real world, whereas their constructions of development scores quite closely match those of the UN.
Just as we calculated a Pearson correlation between average respondent inequality scores and actual Gini coefficients for the five countries, we calculated a similar correlation for each respondent in the data set. Column 2 of Table 2 displays the distribution of individual correlations between country inequality ratings and Gini coefficients for the same countries. These data provide further evidence of the low level of knowledge about the distribution of income inequality. Those data indicate that between 30 percent and 40 percent of the respondents actually have negative correlations between their income inequality ratings and country Gini coefficients. Both the median and mean correlations are just slightly above zero. In addition, only ten percent of the respondents had individual correlations above .53.
Is it possible that the respondents’ inaccurate ratings of inequality in other countries reflects misinformation of state-controlled media in China more than a general lack of knowledge of inequality in other countries? After all, official channels of Chinese media, such as China Central Television (CCTV) stations, often broadcast negative images of the United States and Japan, although we do not have evidence that these negative images pertain specifically to higher levels of inequality.4 In an earlier unpublished paper comparing China and the U.S. (Thornton and Xie 2010), we reported that Americans gave ratings on country inequality that were similarly uninformed as those of Chinese. In the data from a 2006 U.S. nationally representative telephone survey, the correlation between the average inequality rating and the Gini coefficient is 0.22, with less than 10 percent of the respondents having individual correlations beyond 0.5 (Thornton and Xie 2010). Thus, the U.S.-China comparison results reveal that lack of understanding of inequality in other countries is a general phenomenon, rather than one specific to China and the nature of Chinese media.
In summary, the data that we have considered so far in Tables 1 and 2 reveal that the respondents have understandings of development that overlap with the UN HDI scores at both the aggregate and individual levels. By contrast, the respondents do not have understandings about income inequality that overlap with actual Gini coefficients at either the aggregate or the individual levels. This suggests that the Chinese respondents did not report their own direct understanding of income inequality across the countries but derived their inequality ratings from a different source. Our hypothesis is that they derived their inequality ratings from their development ratings for each country.
Comparing Ratings of Countries on Development with Ratings of Countries on Inequality
We now examine how the ratings of countries on development correlate with ratings on income inequality, following similar procedures as used above, but focusing only on respondent reports without reference to external indicators. One interesting pattern in Table 1 is that ordinary Chinese’s average ratings of inequality levels in the five countries resemble more closely their average ratings of development than actual inequality measures. Whereas, as noted earlier, the correlation between average individual ratings of income inequality and actual Gini coefficients is merely .27, the correlation of country averages on development and income inequality is .84. The high correlation is consistent with the hypothesis that at the aggregate level Chinese people couple development and income inequality very closely.
Column 3 in Table 2 provides summary results on individual correlations between each individual’s development and inequality ratings for the various countries, with the distributions of these correlations reported in deciles. These data show an enormous range of correlations between individual development and individual income inequality ratings. Some respondents had very large negative correlations between ratings of development and inequality while others had very large positive correlations. For example, twenty percent of the survey respondents had correlations of −.78 or lower. Even more respondents had large positive correlations. For example, 50 percent had correlations of .58 or greater while 30 percent had correlations of .91 or above.
We interpret these individual-level correlations as suggesting that many respondents in China extrapolate from development ratings to income inequality ratings positively while others extrapolate negatively. That is, although the respondents had very little information about actual income inequality levels in the five particular countries, they were nevertheless quite willing to provide numerical ratings of income inequality in those countries. It appears that when asked about inequality levels in unfamiliar countries, respondents tried to formulate estimates based on salient cues – development levels in this case. Their estimates, we hypothesize, involved projections from their own ideas about the relationship between development and inequality rather than their actual knowledge about inequality in these countries.
The data not only seem to support our hypothesis about societal projection, they also suggest that projection from development to inequality is largely positive rather than negative. This is reflected in the distributions discussed above, as positive correlations are more frequent than negative ones. This result suggests that many Chinese respondents may have based their projections on recent government rhetoric about the development-inequality relationship and/or on the actual experience of China in its recent history, i.e., concurrent growth in development and inequality. It is the preponderance of positive over negative correlations at the individual level that aggregates into a very substantial positive correlation between average development ratings and average income inequality ratings (at .84) that we observe from Table 1.
Multilevel Models Predicting Inequality Ratings
In the preceding analyses, we have shown that, taken as a whole, our Chinese respondents did not possess accurate knowledge about inequality in the five countries they were asked to rate, as their ratings have little correlation on average with the Gini coefficient, a widely used indicator of inequality reported in the CIA’s (2007) World Factbook. However, their inequality ratings are still meaningful. We conjecture that they were somewhat based on the respondents’ ratings of development and the implicit models of the respondents projecting inequality from development. Of course, individuals may be heterogeneous in both development ratings and models linking development and inequality. In this section, we explore the individual-level heterogeneity with a multivariate, multilevel model.
For the jth respondent, we denote his/her rating of inequality in country i as yij. Our basic projection model states that, for each (i, j) combination, inequality rating (yij) is a function of the development rating for that individual for a particular country, denoted as xij. This gives rise to the following basic form of a multilevel model:
(1) |
Equation (1) is the level-1 model. We further specify a level-2 model, in which we assume that the person-specific parameters, ℩1j and ℩2j, depend on person-specific attributes, a vector of w’s, plus a person-specific residual ςj:
(2) |
Note that ℩1j is the individual-level heterogeneity in normalizing scale, i.e., the tendency to use either high or low numbers in ratings inequality. Since ℩1j reflects a person’s idiosyncrasies or taste in responding to the 11-point scale, it is not of scientific interest and will be treated as a nuisance parameter. In contrast, ℩2j measures the direction and the extent to which a person’s rating of inequality depends on his/her rating of development. Our focus is on how ℩2j depends on a person’s observed attributes that will be explained below.
We begin with a simple model in which we do not allow any individual covariates at level 2 to have any effects in equation (2), that is, we set all γ at zero. This specification simplifies the multilevel model to a random coefficient model. The model states that a respondent’s rating of inequality is derived from his/her rating of development, plus three noise components: a noise giving a specific inequality rating (εij), a person-specific noise in tendency to give high versus low ratings (ς1j), and a person-specific noise in projecting from development rating to inequality rating (ς2j).
We present the results for the random-coefficient model, in the first two columns in Table 3. The intercept coefficient (γ11) is estimated to be 4.279 (with a standard error of .063), and the coefficient of development rating is estimated to be .250 (with a standard error of .010). These results show that a respondent’s inequality rating does depend overall on his/her development rating statistically, but the dependence is much less than one-to-one. For someone who rates a country’s development level at 0, he/she would likely rate the country’s inequality at 4.3. For a full 10-point increase in his/her development rating, he/she would increase his/her inequality rating by 2.5, to 6.8. Hence, it is clear that development rating is limited as a linear predictor of inequality rating.
Table 3.
Multilevel Models Predicting Inequality Rating
Random-coefficient model |
Full model | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coef. | SE | Coef. | SE | |
Level-1 variable: | ||||
Intercept (γ11) | 4.279 *** | 0.063 | 2.327 *** | 0.637 |
Development rating (γ21) | 0.250 *** | 0.010 | 0.553 *** | 0.105 |
Cross-level interactions: | ||||
Male (γ22) | −0.031 | 0.023 | ||
Age (γ23) | −0.002 | 0.001 | ||
Marital status (married=excluded) | ||||
Never married, divorced, or widowed (γ24) | 0.096 | 0.063 | ||
Urban residence (γ25) | −0.001 | 0.025 | ||
Province/city (Beijing=excluded) | ||||
Hebei (γ26) | −0.149 *** | 0.037 | ||
Hubei (γ27) | −0.392 *** | 0.037 | ||
Guangdong (γ28) | −0.513 *** | 0.037 | ||
Sichuan (γ29) | −0.427 *** | 0.037 | ||
Qinghai (γ210) | −0.302 *** | 0.038 | ||
Logged per capita family income (γ211) | 0.004 | 0.010 | ||
Level of education (elementary school or less=excluded) | ||||
Secondary education (γ212) | 0.052 | 0.027 | ||
Post-secondary education (γ213) | 0.005 | 0.045 | ||
Development rating correlation (γ214) | 0.037 | 0.034 | ||
Model χ2 (df) | 8920.15 (3) | 9378.96 (29) | ||
Sample size | 4,583 | 4,583 |
Notes: The level-1 and level-2 error terms are allowed to be correlated during estimation. Main effects of the level-2 covariates are estimated but not presented.
p < .05,
p < .01,
p < .001.
Source: 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey.
We next estimate our full multilevel model, with level-2 covariates measuring the respondent’s attributes. We present the results in the last two columns in Table 3. We include the following observed level-2 covariates (w’s) in the full model: gender, age, marital status, urban residence status, geographical location (with five dummy variables), family income (logged per-capita income), education (with two dummy variables), and development rating correlation. Most of these variables and their coding are self-evident from the variable labels in Table 3, except for the last one. Development rating correlation is the individual-level correlation (across the five countries) between a respondent’s individual development ratings and the UN HDI scores. A high correlation means that a respondent’s ratings more closely resemble those of the UN HDI scores.5 We interpret the coefficient to indicate the extent to which a respondent’s construction of development levels in the different countries matches understandings of elite international organizations such as the UN.
According to goodness-of-fit statistics, the multilevel model overall improves upon the random coefficient model (with an increase of 458.81 in model chi-square for 26 degrees of freedom); a closer examination reveals that most of the gain in goodness of fit lies in nuisance parameters. Cross-level interaction parameter (γ’s) are statistically significant either for the main effects (not reported), or for geographical location only. For example, the geographical location estimates mean that residents in Beijing base their inequality ratings more closely on their development ratings than residents elsewhere (as noted by the fact that coefficients for other places are all negative). Is this because Beijing residents tend to believe in a model in which development causes inequality? We cannot be sure. Regional differences are known to be large in China. Some of these may be associated with levels of income, education, and related factors, while others may be due to other unknown reasons (Xie and Hannum 1996). Thus, it is very difficult to interpret the location parameters theoretically.
Surprisingly, all other observed attributes, from age and gender to education and income, do not affect the baseline model of simple positive projection as expressed in equation (1). Earlier, we hypothesized that educated people have a greater understanding of both rhetoric and empirical realities concerning the trends in income growth and inequality and thus are more likely than less educated people to believe that income inequality and development are positively related. We also expected that the persons whose development scores are more closely aligned to the UN HDI scores would be more likely to believe that development causes income inequality. The results in Table 3 clearly reject these hypotheses: none of the covariates other than geographical location alters the effects of a respondent’s development rating on his/her inequality rating.
Unpacking Population Heterogeneity
From the negative results of the multilevel model presented in Table 3, should we dismiss offhand the predictive power of individual-level observed covariates? Not yet.
Sociology is a population science. In a population science, the scientist should not assume that all concrete units in a population are essentially the same – or homogeneous. Rather, units of analysis in a population should be treated as different from one another – or heterogeneous (Xie 2007). One possibility for our failure to find individual covariates that affect the dependence of inequality ratings on development ratings is that the population may be heterogeneous with respect to the perceived relationship between development and inequality. In other words, the failure of the multilevel model may lie in lumping heterogeneous people together.
Earlier, when we discussed results shown in Table 2, we already identified one potential dimension of heterogeneity that was not considered in the multilevel model: while a larger portion of individuals assume a positive association between development and inequality, another sizable proportion believe in a negative association between the two. Could our null finding in Table 3 result from mixing the two very different groups at the population level?
To answer this question, we first distinguish two extreme types of respondents. Here, we first focus on detailed response patterns in ranking orders rather than on numerical responses. For five countries, there can be a total of 120 (5!) possible rank-ordered combinations. We find four prevalent patterns: (1) U.S. ≥ Japan ≥ China ≥ Brazil ≥ Pakistan, (2) U.S. ≥ Japan ≥ Brazil ≥ China ≥ Pakistan, (3) Japan ≥ U.S. ≥ Brazil ≥ China ≥ Pakistan, and (4) Japan ≥ U.S. ≥ China ≥ Brazil ≥ Pakistan.6 Together, these four patterns account for 71.5 percent of all respondents in our data. The first two patterns are particularly popular, chosen by 34.2 and 33.6 percent respectively of the respondents. Patterns 3 and 4 are chosen by much smaller percentages of respondents, at 2.2 and 1.4 percent respectively. These results show that Chinese tend to rate the U.S. as more developed than Japan, but they are equally divided in rating China in contrast with Brazil.
We next examine response patterns to the inequality scale, i.e., the extent to which rankings on inequality very closely follow rankings on development and the extent to which rankings on inequality are very close to the opposite of rankings on development. The results are reported in Table 4, which cross-classifies response patterns to inequality (rows) by response patterns to development (columns). The first four rows, in the first panel, represent the four response patterns to the inequality scale that respectively correspond to the four major response patterns to the development scale. Pattern 1, for example, means that respondents rated inequality the highest in the U.S., followed by Japan, China, Brazil, and Pakistan. In the second panel, we present patterns (in rows 5 through 8) that are, respectively, reverses of patterns 1–4. For example, row 5 represents the following pattern in rated inequality level: U.S. ≤ Japan ≤ China ≤ Brazil ≤ Pakistan. “All Others” is the residual category. We observe that there is much scattering in response patterns to the two scales, indicating the role of ambiguity, uncertainty, or noise in our respondents' responses.
Table 4.
Main Response Patterns of Inequality Rating by Response Patterns to Development Rating
Development response pattern | Total | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Inequality response pattern | Pattern 1 | Pattern 2 | Pattern 3 | Pattern 4 | All othersb | |
Pattern 1 US > JP > CN > BZ > PKa | 31.10 | 7.53 | 4.90 | 17.19 | 10.09 | 13.16 |
Pattern 2 US > JP > BZ > CN > PK | 8.35 | 23.51 | 5.88 | 3.13 | 7.80 | 16.41 |
Pattern 3 JP > US > BZ > CN > PK | 0.70 | 0.45 | 8.82 | 3.13 | 0.31 | 0.72 |
Pattern 4 JP > US > CN > BZ > PK | 0.64 | 0.32 | 0.00 | 4.69 | 0.46 | 0.52 |
Reverse of Pattern 1 | 9.94 | 3.31 | 5.88 | 4.69 | 2.14 | 6.90 |
Reverse of Pattern 2 | 3.38 | 13.31 | 11.76 | 0.00 | 3.52 | 5.32 |
Reverse of Pattern 3 | 0.45 | 1.75 | 12.75 | 3.13 | 0.46 | 1.20 |
Reverse of Pattern 4 | 0.57 | 0.58 | 0.00 | 9.38 | 0.38 | 0.63 |
All othersc | 44.87 | 49.22 | 50.00 | 54.69 | 74.85 | 55.14 |
Total | 100.00 (1,569) |
100.00 (1,540) |
100.00 (102) |
100.00 (64) |
100.00 (1,308) |
100.00 (4,583) |
Notes:
BZ = Brazil, CN = China, JP = Japan, PK = Pakistan, US = United States.
All the 116 remaining response patterns on development.
All the 112 remaining response patterns on inequality.
All numbers in this table are percentages, except the last row, which contains frequency counts Numbers in bold are cases of positive projection; numbers in italic are cases of negative project
Source: 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey.
An interesting finding emerges from Table 4: a significant portion of a person’s responses to the inequality scale correspond exactly to the same person’s responses to the development scale, either positively or negatively. Take the column labeled “pattern 1” as example. Respondents in this column reported their ratings of development for the five countries that conform to the ranking pattern of U.S. ≥ Japan ≥ China ≥ Brazil ≥ Pakistan. Among those respondents, 31.10 percent rated the same countries in inequality as conforming to exactly the same pattern: a positive projection. Furthermore, another 9.94 percent also rated inequality for the same countries as conforming to the exact opposite pattern: U.S. ≤ Japan ≤ China ≤ Brazil ≤ Pakistan. We call the second association a “negative projection.” Thus, we observe both positive and negative projections for all four modal patterns of response to the development scale. For patterns 1 and 2 (for development), which are much more prevalent than the other two, positive projection is very large and dominates negative projection. For patterns 3 and 4 (for development), negative projection seems to be more prevalent than positive projection.
These results suggest that while there is much noise in respondents’ ratings of inequality, a significant proportion of the respondents derived their inequality ratings rather closely from their development ratings. Their derivations were based on their own understanding concerning either a positive or a negative association between the two. Because China has recently experienced increases in both development and inequality and has established some public policies connecting the two positively, many Chinese project this experience onto other countries, making a positive association dominant over a negative association.
We next ask whether there are social determinants that help distinguish positive projections from negative projections. As shown in the descriptive Appendix Table, among the 4,583 respondents in our analytical sample, 19.0 percent rated inequality in the same ranking orders as found in their development ratings (i.e. positive projections), and 7.3 percent in the opposite ranking orders (i.e. negative projections). In Table 5, we present a multinomial model predicting the type of projection, either positive or negative, with neither as the reference outcome category. Again, we observed strong and significant effects of geographical location in this model. For positive projection, age seems to have a marginally significant effect, with older respondents, as expected, less likely to associate inequality positively with development. For an increment of one-year increase in age, there is a 1% reduction in the odds of positive projection. Also for positive projection, as expected, logged per capita family income has a moderate positive effect. With each unit increase in logged per capita family income, which means an increment of 2.7 times in per capita family income, the odds of positive projection increase by 12%. That is, higher-income Chinese, who themselves have benefitted more from economic growth, are more likely to associate inequality positively with development than are lower-income Chinese. Neither age nor income has any significant effect on negative projection.
Table 5.
Multinomial Models Predicting Type of Development-to-Inequality Projection
Positive projection | Negative projection | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coef. | SE | Coef. | SE | |
Male | −0.069 | 0.089 | 0.148 | 0.130 |
Age | −0.011 * | 0.005 | 0.003 | 0.007 |
Marital status (married=excluded) | ||||
Never married, divorced, or widowed | 0.147 | 0.229 | −0.047 | 0.363 |
Urban residence | 0.043 | 0.094 | 0.219 | 0.146 |
Province/city (Beijing=excluded) | ||||
Hebei | −0.384 ** | 0.132 | 1.242 ** | 0.411 |
Hubei | −0.878 *** | 0.142 | 1.495 *** | 0.393 |
Guangdong | −0.759 *** | 0.143 | 2.302 *** | 0.378 |
Sichuan | −0.375 ** | 0.136 | 2.305 *** | 0.384 |
Qinhai | 0.054 | 0.134 | 2.451 *** | 0.385 |
Logged per capita family income | 0.114 ** | 0.044 | 0.051 | 0.065 |
Level of education (elementary school or less=excluded) | ||||
Secondary education | 0.114 | 0.107 | −0.169 | 0.148 |
Post-secondary education | −0.110 | 0.175 | −0.129 | 0.250 |
Development rating correlation | 1.060 *** | 0.187 | 0.762 ** | 0.263 |
Constant | −2.416 *** | 0.447 | −5.367 *** | 0.739 |
Model χ2 (df) | 292.02(26) | |||
Sample size | 4,583 |
Note: The reference category is neutral projection.
p < .05,
p < .01,
p < .001.
Source: 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey.
One particularly interesting finding in Table 5 is concerned with development rating correlation, a variable we interpret as individuals having constructions of development that are consistent with the constructions of international elites. In Table 4, we already observed that this variable does not help predict a respondent’s overall projection from development to inequality. In Table 5, however, we observe that it has strong positive effects on both positive projection and negative projection. An increase in the full range, from 0 to 1, in the development rating correlation, would increase the odds of positive projection almost threefold. For negative projection, the same increase would increase the odds twofold. Hence, we have found that consistency with the larger world in views of development does foster projection from development to inequality, but in two opposing directions. We failed to observe this consistency effect in the multilevel model of Table 4 because the multilevel model forces the variable to have an overall effect, either positive or negative, as shown in equation 2. This bipolar pattern fits well with Converse’s (1964) classic theory that elites are far more coherent in their beliefs than non-elite.7 It also fits with Sidanius and Lau’s (1989) finding that people on both ends of a left-wing and right-wing continuum have stronger cognitive skills than those nearer the middle. In our Chinese survey data, we find that consistency of constructions with the world’s elites can significantly boost a respondent’s confidence in making projections about inequality based on development, but these projections are both positive and negative.
Conclusion
Although extensive social science research has been focused on the causes and consequences of actual economic growth, very little attention has been directed toward attitudes and beliefs concerning the effect of economic development on social inequality. Such attitudes and beliefs, however, can have important political implications, influencing how people respond to inequality increases or declines in the course of economic growth and whether they will favor or oppose policy measures designed to encourage development.
In this paper, we propose that the developmental paradigm serves the important cognitive need of simplifying societal differences (historical or cross-national), so that development level becomes a salient cue characterizing a society. When a person does not know much about other aspects of an unfamiliar society, he/she may draw inferences about the society from his/her views of its development level. While this cognitive device would serve most people well, as it frees them from the impossible task of fully understanding all societies in detail, there is also an obvious risk: Misunderstanding and mistrust of people across different societies could arise from the cognitive need to rely on salient cues and the usual tendency to project from one’s own understanding and experience.
We developed four propositions in this paper. First, ordinary Chinese have conceptions of development and are able to rate different countries on a development scale in ways that are consistent with the ratings of international elites such as the UN. Second, their ratings of inequality do not reflect actual levels of inequality, and are derivative of their development ratings based on their understanding of the relationship between development and inequality. Third, given both rapid economic growth and a sharp rise of inequality in China’s recent history, many Chinese project this experience of a positive association onto other countries. Fourth, given long-term practice and rhetoric during the 1950s through the 1970 about negative links between development and inequality, we expect that many Chinese may also project development negatively on inequality.
For our empirical work, we designed two key items to test these ideas and implemented them in a survey in six Chinese provinces, asking the respondents to rate the levels of development as well as inequality in five countries: the United States, Japan, Brazil, China, and Pakistan. Four main findings emerge from our survey data. First, the respondents’ average ratings of development resemble those released by the United Nations. Second, the respondents’ ratings of inequality in the five countries are not well informed and accurate when compared to the CIA’s (2007) Gini measures of inequality. Third, a significant portion of the respondents seem to project their ratings of inequality from their ratings of development, on the basis of their understanding of either a positive or a negative relationship between the two. Fourth, when the respondents project inequality from development, the majority tends to make a positive projection, presumably reflecting China’s recent experience. The last finding shows that an overall model that assumes homogeneity about the perceived relationship between development and inequality would be misleading.
Of all individual-level covariates, we find geographic location to be the only consistent predictor affecting a respondent’s projection of inequality from development. Surprisingly, demographic and socioeconomic characteristics play only a small role: we find that youth and high incomes are associated with a higher likelihood of a positive projection. We did show that development-rating consistency with the UN predicted projection patterns, with this consistency understood as an indicator of both interest in the issue (Converse 1964) and better cognitive functioning (Sidanius 1985, Sidanius and Lau 1989). Our work showed this consistency to be a double-edged sword: it increases the likelihood of both a positive projection and a negative projection of inequality from development. In other words, persons whose views of developmental levels in other countries match the constructions of the UN also believe strongly in either a positive or a negative relationship between inequality and development. As Converse pointed out long ago (1964), most ordinary people are not intrinsically interested in public affairs, and only a minority of our sample (though a non-trivial proportion) provided sharp opinions. In our study, we found that both positive and negative projections are associated with higher development-rating consistency with the UN.
While a modest minority believes in a negative association between development and income inequality, the predominant view is that there is a positive correlation between the two variables. This asymmetry may be rooted in China’s recent history. Since the early 1980s, China has been experiencing rapid economic growth over an extended period and on a large scale, while inequality has also increased dramatically. In our survey data, the majority of people perceive income inequality to be higher in more developed than in less developed countries. Respondents did not endorse increases in income inequality as a way of facilitating development, but that may have been due more to an overall aversion to increasing income inequality than to a belief that income inequality decreases development. Our research suggests a plausible socio-psychological explanation to the question of why Chinese today have such a high tolerance for inequality despite their strong aversion of it: many Chinese accept a rise in inequality as a necessary, albeit undesirable, product of economic development, which they welcome. We welcome further research to test this conjecture in the future.
Acknowledgments
The research is also supported by an NIH Fogarty International Center Grant (2 D43 TW000657), a grant from the National Institute of Child Health and Human Development (R21-HD-050-259), and internal grants from the Population Studies Center, the Survey Research Center, and the Center for Chinese Studies of the University of Michigan. The authors have benefited from suggestions and assistance from Miranda Brown, Cindy Glovinsky, Alexandra Killewald, Katherine King, Yang Jiang, and Linda Young-DeMarco.
Appendix
Key Question Items on Developmental Idealism in the 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey
Appendix
Appendix Table.
Descriptive Statistics
Variable | Mean | SD |
---|---|---|
Gender | ||
Female | 70.4% | 0.456 |
Male | 29.6% | 0.456 |
Age | 38.360 | 8.550 |
Marital status | ||
Married | 97.3% | 0.162 |
Never married, divorced, or widowed | 2.7% | 0.162 |
Residence | ||
Rural | 62.3% | 0.485 |
Urban | 37.7% | 0.485 |
Province/city | ||
Beijing | 16.5% | 0.372 |
Hebei | 16.7% | 0.373 |
Hubei | 16.6% | 0.372 |
Guangdong | 16.0% | 0.366 |
Sichuan | 17.5% | 0.380 |
Qinghai | 16.8% | 0.374 |
Per capita family income (RMB) | 4,489.857 | 13,352.320 |
Logged per capita family income | 7.905 | 1.163 |
Level of education | ||
Elementary school or less | 24.5% | 0.430 |
Secondary education | 63.3% | 0.482 |
Post-secondary education | 12.3% | 0.328 |
Development rating correlationa | 0.784 | 0.298 |
Type of development-to-inequality projection | ||
Positive (exactly the same ranking) | 19.0% | 0.392 |
Neutral | 73.7% | 0.440 |
Negative (exactly reversed ranking) | 7.3% | 0.260 |
Inequality ratingb | 5.881 | 2.453 |
Development ratingb | 6.352 | 2.512 |
Sample size | 4,583 |
Notes:
The correlation between respondents' rating on development and the UN 2006 Human Development Index of the five countries.
Each respondent rates development and inequality in 5 countries. The means are calculated based on a total of 4,583×5 records.
Source: 2006 Six Chinese Province Survey.
Footnotes
Publisher's Disclaimer: This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final citable form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
In response to Nee’s (1989) market transition theory, there is already a very large literature on this topic, albeit with no consensus answer to the question (e.g., Bian and Logan 1996; Walder 1996; Xie and Hannum 1996; Zhou 2000). Much of this literature was reviewed by Bian (2002).
For commentary on these issues, see Axtell (1981), Berkhofer (1978), Myres (1916), Pagden (1982), and Sheehan (1980).
We realize that this is an unusual correlation coefficient to calculate, as it is based on only five observations, with only 4 degrees of freedom. However, in Table 2, we analyze the distribution of the coefficients across a large number of cases in the sample. If individual respondents’ ratings do not match UN scores, as is the case for inequality measures, we would find low correlations for most of the cases. Thus, a high percentage of cases with high correlation coefficients between the HDI scores and ratings of development indicates a good fit between respondents’ ratings with the HDI scores.
Negative images about the U.S. in official Chinese media focus mostly on American hegemonism and domestic issues such as protests, riots, and natural or human disasters (Chang, Wang, and Chen 1994; Lee 2003). However, as a reviewer pointed out, Chinese respondents may associate these negative images to higher levels of inequality.
Again, the summary results of these individual correlations were presented in Table 2.
For convenience, we made the classification mutually exclusive in the results reported here. If a respondent could be classified as fitting more than one pattern due to equality conditions, we gave priority to the less frequent pattern.
Sidanius (1985) also argues that the acquisition of polarized ideology must be motivated by more genuine interest in social and political affairs and requires slightly greater intellectual abilities, whereas citizens who lack both the will and the ability to confront such a cognitive task tend to assume the middle ground of the political spectrum.
Contributor Information
Yu Xie, University of Michigan.
Arland Thornton, University of Michigan.
Guangzhou Wang, Chinese Academy of Social Science.
Qing Lai, University of Michigan.
References
- Allport Gordon W. The Nature of Prejudice. Reading MA: Addison-Wesley; [1954] 1979. [Google Scholar]
- Alwin Duane F, Gornev Galin, Khakhulina Ludmila. Comparative Referential Structures, System Legitimacy, and Justice Sentiments: An International Comparison. In: Kluegel J, Mason D, Wegener B, editors. Social Justice and Political Change: public opinion in capitalist and post-communist states. New York: Aldine de Gruyter; 1995. pp. 109–130. [Google Scholar]
- Amin Samir. Eurocentrism. New York: Monthly Review Press; 1989. [Google Scholar]
- Axtell James. The European and the Indian: Essays in the Ethnohistory of Colonial North America. New York: Oxford University Press; 1981. [Google Scholar]
- Barro Robert. Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries. Journal of Economic Growth. 2000;5:5–32. [Google Scholar]
- Berkhofer Robert F. The White Man's Indian: Images of the American Indian from Columbus to the Present. New York: Knopf; 1978. [Google Scholar]
- Bian Yanjie. Work and Inequality in Urban China. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press; 1994. [Google Scholar]
- Bian Yanjie. Chinese Social Stratification and Social Mobility. Annual Review of Sociology. 2002;28:91–116. [Google Scholar]
- Bian Yanjie, Logan John R. Market Transition and the Persistence of Power: The Changing Stratification System in Urban China. American Sociological Review. 1996;61:739–758. [Google Scholar]
- Binstock Georgina, Thornton Arland. Knowledge and Use of Developmental Thinking about Societies and Families Among Teenagers in Argentina. Demografia. 2007;50(5):75–104. [Google Scholar]
- Bock Kenneth Elliott. The Acceptance of Histories: Toward a Perspective for Social Science. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1956. [Google Scholar]
- Böröcz József. The Fox and the Raven: The European Union and Hungary Renegotiate the Margins of ‘Europe.'. Comparative Studies in Society and History. 2000;42(4):847. [Google Scholar]
- Burrow John W. Evolution and Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1981. [Google Scholar]
- Carneiro Robert L. Classical Evolution. In: Naroll R, Naroll F, editors. Main Currents in Cultural Anthropology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc.; 1973. pp. 57–121. [Google Scholar]
- Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) The World Factbook. Washington, DC: 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Cesaire Aimé. Discourse on Colonialism. New York: Monthly Review Press; 1972. [Google Scholar]
- Chakrabarty Dipesh. Provincializing Europe: Postcolonial Thought and Historical Difference. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press; 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Chang TK, Wang J, Chen CH. News as Social Knowledge in China: The Changing Worldview of Chinese National Media. Journal of Communication. 1994;44:52–69. [Google Scholar]
- Chiswick Barry. Earnings Inequality and Economic Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1971;85:21–39. [Google Scholar]
- Converse Philip E. The Nature of Mass Belief System in Mass Publics. In: Apter DE, editor. Ideology and Discontent. London: Collier-Macmillan; 1964. pp. 206–261. [Google Scholar]
- Deininger Klaus, Squire Lyn. New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality and Growth. Journal of Development Economics. 1998;57:259–287. [Google Scholar]
- Evans MDR, Kelley Jonathan. Population Size, Economic Development, and Attitudes Towards Inequality: Evidence from 30 Nations. Population Review. 2007;46:1–21. [Google Scholar]
- Executive Yuan. Report on the Survey of Personal Income Distribution in Taiwan Area of the Republic of China. Taipei: Directorate-General of Budget, Accounting, and Statistics; 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Firebaugh Glenn. The New Geography of Income Distribution in the World. In: Müller W, Scherer S, editors. Expanding Markets, Welfare State Retrenchment, and Their Impact on Social Stratification. Frankfurt: Campus-Verlag; 2003. [in German]. [Google Scholar]
- Fishlow Albert. On the Emerging Problems of Development Policy: Brazilian Size Distribution of Income. American Economic Review. 1972;62:391–410. [Google Scholar]
- Friedman Edward. In China’s “Credibility Gap”: Public Opinion and Instability in China. Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars; 2002. How to Understand Public Opinion in China. Asia Program Special Report No. 104. [Google Scholar]
- Gordon Daniel. Citizens without Sovereignty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; 1994. [Google Scholar]
- Han Wenxiu. Income Disparities in China: An OECD Perspective. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development; 2004. The Evolution of Income Distribution Disparities in China Since the Reform and Opening-Up; pp. 9–25. edited and published by. [Google Scholar]
- Han Chunping, Whyte Martin King. The Social Contours of Distributive Injustice Feelings in Contemporary China. In: Davis DS, Wang F, editors. Creating Wealth and Poverty in Post-Socialist China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press; 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Harris Marvin. The Rise of Anthropological Theory. New York: Thomas Y. Crowell Company; 1968. [Google Scholar]
- Hauser Seth, Xie Yu. Temporal and Regional Variation in Earnings Inequality: Urban China in Transition between 1988 and 1995. Social Science Research. 2005;34:44–79. [Google Scholar]
- Hobbes Thomas. In: Man and Citizen. Gert B, editor. Indianapolis: Hackett Publishing Company; [1642] 1991. [Google Scholar]
- Hobbes Thomas. In: Leviathan. Gaskin JCA, editor. Oxford: Oxford University Press; [1651] 1996. [Google Scholar]
- Hodgen Margaret T. Early Anthropology in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries. Philadelphia: University of Philadelphia Press; 1964. [Google Scholar]
- Jasso Guillermina. How Much Injustice is There in the World? Two New Justice Indexes. American Sociological Review. 1999;64(1):133–168. [Google Scholar]
- Jasso Guillermina. Trends in the Experience of Injustice: Justice Indexes About Earning in Six Societies, 1991–1996. Social Justice Research. 2000;13(2):101–121. [Google Scholar]
- Jasso Guillermina. Theoretical Unification in Justice and Beyond. Institute for the Study of Labor. 2007 Discussion Paper Series No. 2641. [Google Scholar]
- Jasso Guillermina, Rossi Peter. Distributive justice and earned income. American Sociological Review. 1977;42:639–651. [Google Scholar]
- Jennings Francis. The Invasion of America: Indians, Colonialism, and the Cant of Conquest. Chapel Hill: Published for the Institute of Early American History and Culture by the University of North Carolina Press; 1975. [Google Scholar]
- Khan Azizur R, Riskin Carl. Income and Inequality in China: Composition, Distribution and Growth of Household Income, 1988 to 1995. The China Quarterly. 1998;154:221–253. [Google Scholar]
- Kluegel James R, Matějů Petr. Principles of Distributive Justice in Comparative Perspective. In: Kluegel JR, Mason DS, Wegener B, editors. Social Justice and Political Change: Public Opinion in Capitalist and Post-Communist States. Hawthorne, NY: Aldine deGruyter; 1995. pp. 209–238. [Google Scholar]
- Krosnick Jon A. Response Strategies for Coping with the Cognitive Demands of Attitude Measures in Surveys. Applied Cognitive Psychology. 1991;5:213–236. [Google Scholar]
- Krücken Georg, Drori Gili S., editors. World Society: The Writings of John W. Meyer. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Kuznets Simon. Economic Grown and Income Inequality. American Economic Review. 1955;45:1–28. [Google Scholar]
- Lee Chin-chuan. The Global and the National of the Chinese Media. In: Lee Chin-chuan., editor. Chinese Media, Global Contexts. New York: Routledge; 2003. pp. 1–31. [Google Scholar]
- Lenski Gerhard. Power and Privilege: A Theory of Social Stratification. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press; 1984. [Google Scholar]
- Locke John. Two Treatises of Government. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press; [1690] 1988. [Google Scholar]
- Mandelbaum Maurice. History, Man, and Reason: A Study in Nineteenth-Century Thought. Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press; 1971. [Google Scholar]
- Manuel Frank E. The Prophets of Paris. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press; 1962. [Google Scholar]
- March James G, Simon Herbert A. Organizations. New York: John Wiley; 1958. [Google Scholar]
- Marx Karl, Engels Friedrich. The Communist Manifesto. Penguin Books; [1848] 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Melegh Attila, Thornton Arland, Philipov Dimiter, Young-DeMarco Linda. Perceptions of Societal Developmental Hierarchies in Europe and Beyond: A Bulgarian Perspective. European Sociological Review. doi: 10.1093/esr/jcs010. Forthcoming. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Meyer John W, Boli John, Thomas George M, Ramirez Francisco O. World Society and the Nation-State. American Journal of Sociology. 1997;103(1):144–181. [Google Scholar]
- Mitchell Colter. Dissertation. Department of Sociology, Rackham Graduate School, University of Michigan; 2009. Three Essays on Worldviews, Autonomy and the Family in Nepal. [Google Scholar]
- Montaigne Michel de. Essays. New York: The Heritage Press; [1580] 1946. [Google Scholar]
- Myres John Linton. The Influence of Anthropology on the Course of Political Science. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1916. [Google Scholar]
- Nee Victor. A Theory of Market Transition: From Redistribution to Markets in State Socialism. American Sociological Review. 1989;54:663–681. [Google Scholar]
- Nisbet Robert A. Social Change and History. New York: Oxford University Press; 1975. [Google Scholar]
- Pagden Anthony. The Fall of Natural Man: The American Indian and the Origins of Comparative Ethnology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1982. [Google Scholar]
- Parish William L. Destratification in China. In: Watson J, editor. Class and Social Stratification in Post-Revolution China. New York: Cambridge University Press; 1984. [Google Scholar]
- Rakowski Eric. Equal Justice. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press; 1991. [Google Scholar]
- Robertson William. The History of America. London, Edinburgh: W. Strahan [etc.] and J. Balfour; [1777] 1780. printed for. [Google Scholar]
- Rousseau Jean-Jacques. In: A Discourse on Inequality. Cranston M, editor. England: Penguin Books, Ltd.; [1755] 1984. Reprint, Harmondsworth. [Google Scholar]
- Sanderson Stephen K. Social Evolutionism: A Critical History. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Schwarz Norbert. Self-Reports. American Psychologist. 1999;5:93–105. [Google Scholar]
- Sheehan Bernard W. Savagism and Civility: Indians and Englishmen in Colonial Virginia. New York: Cambridge University Press; 1980. [Google Scholar]
- Sidanius James. Cognitive Functioning and Sociopolitical Ideology Revisited. Political Psychology. 1985;6:637–661. [Google Scholar]
- Sidanius Jim, Lau Richard R. Political Sophistication and Political Deviance: A Matter of Context. Political Psychology. 1989;10:85–109. [Google Scholar]
- Smith Anthony D. The Concept of Social Change. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul; 1973. [Google Scholar]
- State Statistical Bureau. China Statistical Yearbook. Beijing, China: Statistics Press; 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Stocking George W., Jr . Race, Culture, and Evolution. New York: The Free Press; 1968. [Google Scholar]
- Stocking George W., Jr . Victorian Anthropology. New York: The Free Press; 1987. [Google Scholar]
- Sudman Seymour, Bradburn Norman M, Schwarz Norbert. Thinking about Answers: The Application of Cognitive Processes to Survey Methodology. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass; 1996. [Google Scholar]
- Sun Liping. Characters and Reasons for Continuing Increases in China’s Economic Inequality. [Retrieved March 22, 2008];2008 (In Chinese.) ( http://vip.bokee.com/20070228244162.html). [Google Scholar]
- Swift Adam, Marshall Gordon, Burgoyne Carole, Routh David. Distributive Justice: Does it matter what the people think? In: Kluegel JR, Mason DS, Wegener B, editors. Social justice and political change: public opinion in capitalist and post-communist states. New York: Aldine de Gruyter; 1995. [Google Scholar]
- Szirmai Adam. Inequality Observed. A Study of Attitudes towards Income Inequality. Aldershot, UK: Avebury Press; 1988. [Google Scholar]
- Szreter Simon. The Idea of Demographic Transition and the Study of Fertility Change. Population and Development Review. 1993;19(4):659–702. [Google Scholar]
- Tang Wenfang, Parish William L. Chinese Urban Life Under Reform: The Changing Social Contract. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Thomas George M, Meyer John W, Ramirez Francisco O, Boli John. Institutional Structure: Constituting State, Society, and the Individual. Newberry Park: Sage Publications; 1987. [Google Scholar]
- Thornton Arland. The Developmental Paradigm, Reading History Sideways, and Family Change. Demography. 2001;38(4):449–465. doi: 10.1353/dem.2001.0039. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Thornton Arland. Reading History Sideways: The Fallacy and Enduring Impact of the Developmental Paradigm on Family Life. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Thornton Arland, Binstock Georgina, Ghimire Dirgha. International Dissemination of Ideas about Developmental and Family Change. In: Jayakody R, Thornton A, Axinn W, editors. International Family Change: Ideational Perspectives. New York: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates: Taylor & Francis Group; 2008. pp. 19–44. [Google Scholar]
- Thornton Arland, Binstock Georgina, Abbasi-Shavazi Mohammad Jalal, Ghimire Dirgha, Gjonca Arjan, Melegh Attila, Mitchell Colter, Moaddel Mansoor, Xie Yu, Yang Li-shou, Young-DeMarco Linda, Yount Kathryn. Knowledge and Beliefs about National Development and Developmental Hierarchies: the Viewpoints of Ordinary People in Thirteen Counties. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan; 2011. Unpublished manuscript. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Thornton Arland, Xie Yu. Knowledge and Beliefs Concerning Development and Income Inequality in China and the United States. 2010 Jul; PSC Research Report No. 10-714. 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Thornton Arland, Binstock Georgina, Yount Kathryn M, Abbasi-Shavazi Mohammad Jalal, Ghimire Dirgha, Xie Yu. International Fertility Change: New Data and Insights From the Developmental Idealism Framework. Demography. doi: 10.1007/s13524-012-0097-9. Forthcoming. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Tilly Charles. Big Structures, Large Processes, Huge Comparisons. New York: Russell Sage Foundation; 1984. [Google Scholar]
- Tourangeau Roger, Rips Lance L, Rasinski Kenneth. The Psychology of Survey Response. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Tylor Edward B. Primitive Culture. London: John Murray; 1781. [Google Scholar]
- United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) Human Development Report: Overcoming barriers: Human mobility and development. New York: Oxford University Press; 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Walder Andrew G. Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese Industry. University of California Press; 1986. [Google Scholar]
- Walder Andrew G. Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Toward Testable Theories. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;101:1060–1073. [Google Scholar]
- Wallerstein Immanuel. Geopolitics and Geocultures: Essays on the Changing World System. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1991. [Google Scholar]
- Wang Feng. Boundaries and Categories: Rising Inequality in Post-Socialist China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press; 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Whyte Martin. Myth of the Social Volcano: Perceptions of Inequality and Distributive Injustice in Contemporary China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Wong Chack Kie, Lee Nan Shong Peter. Popular Belief in State Intervention for Social Protection in China. Journal of Social Policy. 2000;29:109–116. [Google Scholar]
- Wu Xiaogang. Income Inequality and Distributive Justice: A Comparative Analysis of Mainland China and Hong Kong. The China Quarterly. 2009;200:1–20. [Google Scholar]
- Wu Xiaogang, Treiman Donald. The Household Registration System and Social Stratification in China: 1955–1996. Demography. 2004;41:363–384. doi: 10.1353/dem.2004.0010. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Wu Xiaogang, Xie Yu. Does the Market Pay Off? Earnings Returns to Education in Urban China. American Sociological Review. 2003;68:425–442. [Google Scholar]
- Wu Ximing, Perloff Jeffrey. Berkeley: CUDARE Working Papers, University of California; 2005. [Retrieved April 1, 2009]. China’s Income Distribution, 1985–2001. ( http://www.uoguelph.ca/~xiwu/china_wu&perloff.pdf). [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu. Otis Dudley Duncan’s Legacy: the Demographic Approach to Quantitative Reasoning in Social Science. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility. 2007 [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu. Understanding Inequality in China. Society. 2010;30:1–20. (In Chinese.) [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu, Hannum Emily. Regional Variation in Earnings’ Inequality in Reform-Era Urban China. American Journal of Sociology. 1996;102:950–992. [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu, Wu Xiaogang. Danwei Profitability and Earnings Inequality in Urban China. The China Quarterly. 2008;195:558–581. doi: 10.1017/S0305741008000775. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Zeng Xiangquan, Yue Ying. Establishing an Income Distribution System in a Society that is Scientifically Fair and Just. [Retrieved November 24, 2007];2006 (In Chinese.) Xinhua Net 2006-07-14. ( http://news.xinhuanet.com/theory/2006-07/14/content_4831556.htm). [Google Scholar]
- Zhao Zhenyu. On Several Issues of Inequality in Social Distribution. Shehui Kexue Zhanxian. 1994;1:112–21. (In Chinese.) (Changchun) [Google Scholar]
- Zhou Xueguang. Economic Transformation and Income Inequality in Urban China: Evidence From Panel Data. American Journal of Sociology. 2000;105(4):1135–1174. [Google Scholar]