Abstract
Conceptions of fairness vary across the world. Identifying the drivers of this variation is key to understanding the selection pressures and mechanisms that lead to the evolution of fairness in humans. Individuals' varying fairness preferences are widely assumed to represent cultural norms. However, this assumption has not previously been tested. Fairness norms are defined as culturally transmitted equilibria at which bargainers have coordinated expectations from each other. Hence, if fairness norms exist at the level of the ethno-linguistic group, we should observe two patterns. First, cultural conformism should maintain behavioural homogeneity within an ethno-linguistic group. Second, bargainers' expectations should be coordinated such that proposals and responses to proposals should covary. Here we show that neither of these patterns is observed across 21 populations of the same ethno-linguistic group, the Pahari Korwa of central India. Our findings suggest that what constitutes a fair division of resources can vary on smaller scales than that of the ethno-linguistic group. Individuals' local environments may play a central role in determining conceptions of fairness.
Keywords: evolution of fairness, cultural norms, bargaining behaviour, cultural group selection, cultural conformism
1. Introduction
Variation in cooperative and bargaining behaviour across human populations [1–7] is assumed to reflect culturally transmitted fairness norms. This untested assumption has been widely used to interpret results from empirical studies of bargaining behaviour across disciplines [1–3,5–9]. There are at least two ways of defining fairness in the context of a bargaining situation. The first is an absolute definition whereby a fair outcome is one where a pie is always divided equally between bargainers. The second is a relativist definition whereby a fair outcome is any division of a pie that is mutually agreed upon by bargainers, irrespective of whether the shares are equal or not. An absolute fairness norm cannot account for the variation in bargaining behaviour observed across human populations. Thus, here we consider whether relativist fairness norms operating at the level of the ethno-linguistic group drive bargainers behaviour.
Relativist fairness norms are defined as culturally transmitted equilibria at which bargainers have coordinated expectations from each other [10,11]. Hence, if fairness norms at the level of the ethno-linguistic group drive behaviour in a bargaining situation, then we should observe two patterns. First, cultural conformity should maintain behavioural homogeneity within the ethno-linguistic collective despite variation in the characteristics of individuals and their local environments. Second, proposals and responses to proposals should be coordinated in the sense that first-movers should only make high offers because second-movers would reject low offers. We show that neither of these patterns is observed empirically in a set of real-world populations. Thus, we find no evidence for the operation of a fairness norm at the level of the ethno-linguistic collective. Our findings suggest that environmental factors may be more important determinants of fairness in humans than cultural norms.
We implemented one-shot, anonymous ultimatum games (UGs) in 21 discrete populations of the same ethno-linguistic group, a forager-horticulturist society called the Pahari Korwa of central India (details are provided in the electronic supplementary material). The UG is a two-player bargaining experiment that has been extensively used as a behavioural measure of fairness across disciplines [e.g. 3,5–7,12–14]. One of a pair of individuals, the ‘proposer’, must divide a sum of money (the stake, S) between herself and an unknown ‘responder’. If the responder accepts the proposer's offer (x), the responder earns x, and the proposer earns S−x. If the responder rejects the offer, neither player earns anything. In this game, the income-maximizing strategy entails that a responder accepts any offer made by the proposer. Assuming that the responder will play the income-maximizing strategy, the income-maximizing strategy for a proposer is to make the smallest possible offer.
We find significant variation in proposers’ offers across these populations. By contrast, responders rarely rejected any offers and their behaviour varies little across the same 21 populations. Thus, proposer behaviour does not covary with responder behaviour. Our finding that proposer behaviour varies significantly across populations of the same ethno-linguistic group demonstrates an absence of cultural conformity within the ethno-linguistic group as a collective. Moreover, proposer behaviour does not covary with responder behaviour, which demonstrates that bargainers do not have coordinated expectations. Hence, we do not find any evidence for the operation of a fairness norm at the level of the ethno-linguistic group in these populations.
2. Material and methods
(a). Study populations
Pahari Korwa populations present an excellent model system for this study: a set of real-world, uni-ethnic meta-populations of the same endogamous ethno-linguistic group with distinct population boundaries. Pahari Korwas are heavily reliant on gathered forest products, which are a primary source of food and income, but they also practice agriculture on small tracts of land [15]. These economic resources are supplemented by opportunistic hunting, fishing and wage labour. They live in mostly uni-ethnic villages that have well-defined boundaries; tracts of forest and hills separate neighbouring villages. In this endogamous society, exogamous marriages usually incur severe penalties, entailing ostracism and expulsion from the tribe and village. Table 1 presents summary statistics for our study populations (see the electronic supplementary material for further details).
Table 1.
village number | village name | population sizea | percentage of migrants in sampleb | percentage of non-Korwasc | distance from the major town (km)d | proposers (n) | responders (n) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | Chipni Paani | 27 | 92 (12) | 0 | 24 | 6 | 6 |
2 | Mahua Bathaan | 61 | 32 (22) | 16 | 44 | 11 | 11 |
3 | Jog Paani | 64 | 53 (19) | 25 | 47 | 10 | 9 |
4 | Semar Kona | 64 | 29 (17) | 17 | 24 | 9 | 8 |
5 | Bihidaand | 73 | 48 (21) | 21 | 33 | 11 | 10 |
6 | Khunta Paani | 97 | 52 (31) | 27 | 36 | 16 | 15 |
7 | Kaua Daahi | 102 | 41 (32) | 0 | 46 | 16 | 16 |
8 | Pareva Aara | 111 | 44 (36) | 14 | 42 | 18 | 18 |
9 | Musakhol | 117 | 37 (30) | 26 | 35 | 15 | 15 |
10 | Kharranagar | 125 | 42 (38) | 0 | 50 | 19 | 19 |
11 | Tedha Semar | 141 | 40 (30) | 3 | 45 | 15 | 15 |
12 | Jamjhor | 144 | 37 (30) | 44 | 25 | 15 | 15 |
13 | Vesra Paani | 157 | 25 (44) | 25 | 27 | 22 | 22 |
14 | Mirgadaand | 163 | 56 (32) | 35 | 5 | 16 | 16 |
15 | Barghaat | 194 | 31 (42) | 10 | 41 | 21 | 21 |
16 | Gotidoomar | 195 | 36 (50) | 0 | 31 | 25 | 25 |
17 | Cheur Paani | 197 | 40 (30) | 1 | 33 | 15 | 15 |
18 | Aama Naara | 207 | 33 (43) | 6 | 69 | 21 | 22 |
19 | Bakrataal | 254 | 54 (39) | 7 | 26 | 19 | 18 |
20 | Kheera Aama | 290 | 29 (42) | 18 | 31 | 20 | 21 |
21 | Ghatgaon | 957 | 15 (47) | 5 | 13 | 24 | 23 |
aIncludes all adults and children residing in the focal village.
bNumbers in parentheses indicate size of sample used to estimate the proportion of migrants. Migrants are individuals (Pahari Korwas) currently residing in the focal village but born in another village. Migration often follows marriage, particularly for females.
cPercentage of the focal village population who were not Pahari Korwas.
dDistance from Ambikapur, the largest town in the study region.
(b). Experimental set-up
The size of the stake (S) for each game was 100 Indian rupees (henceforth rupees), equivalent to a little over 2 days' wages in the region. Offer values were restricted to multiples of five. Each individual played the game once and in one role, as a proposer or a responder, under anonymous conditions. Pairs of players were constituted by randomly matching token numbers. In 16 of the 21 populations where the UG was played, once a responder had made her decision regarding whether she wished to accept or reject the offered amount, we additionally asked her what minimum offer from a proposer she was willing to accept; this was recorded as the minimum acceptable offer (MAO) for that individual. The game outcome and payoffs were determined on the basis of the accept/reject response and players were fully aware of this. Hence, the MAO is a self-reported figure and players knew that its value did not affect their actual payoffs in the game. We use MAO values to examine whether players' self-reported behavioural strategies agree with their game behaviour.
To summarize the key features of our standardized protocol. (i) Instructions were delivered from standardized scripts and real money was used to demonstrate game rules and examples. Only individuals who correctly answered a set of questions played the game; the questions were designed to assess their understanding of the game and experimental set-up. (ii) Decisions were made individually at a private location and no names were recorded; a player's only identification was a numbered token. (iii) Those who had played the games were prevented from interacting with those who had not yet played. (iv) All games in all villages were administered by S.L. usually on the second and third day after arrival in the village and usually completed in 2 days; prior to this study, S.L. had no contact with any individual from any of the 21 villages included in this study.
Our study design excludes the following confounding causes of variation across populations (see the electronic supplementary material for details): (i) context and framing effects, (ii) experimenter variation, (iii) experimenter familiarity, (iv) differences in recruitment methods and time periods over which games were conducted in different populations, and (v) differences in protocols. Previous cross-cultural studies [5–7,16], mostly administered by multiple researchers, did not exclude and could not test for these confounding causes of variation between their study populations.
(c). Demographic and individual data
Demographic and other data on individuals were collected via a standardized questionnaire administered by a research assistant. Descriptions of the village and individual descriptors are in the electronic supplementary material. Once all games in a village had been completed, a population census was conducted and the geographical coordinates for every house in the village were recorded using a global positioning system (Garmin GPS 12XL). Geographical information systems (GIS) data were processed and analysed in ArcGIS (v. 9.2; Environmental Systems Research Institute).
(d). Analyses
We employ multilevel normal linear models [17] to explicitly analyse variation in UG behaviour at the village and individual levels in our data (structured as individuals within villages). We mainly use an information-theoretic model-fitting approach [18] to analyse data and interpret results. The Deviance Information Criterion (DIC) was used to compare models [19]. The DIC is a Bayesian measure of model fit and complexity; it accounts for the change in degrees of freedom between nested models. Models with a lower DIC value provide a better fit to the data and, as a rule of thumb, a difference in DIC values of 5–10 units or more is considered substantial [18,19]. Details of the analyses are in the electronic supplementary material.
The income-maximizing offer (IMO) was calculated as follows [20]. A binary logistic regression was run with responder response (accept/reject) as the dependent variable and proposer offer as the only explanatory variable. This regression estimates the relationship between the probability of acceptance and proposer offer, from the distribution of offers accepted and rejected. The parameter values derived from the regression equation (β and c) were used to estimate the probability of acceptance (pi) for each offer value (i) from 0 to 100 (pi = exp(βi+c)/{1+exp(βi + c)}), with i increasing in increments of five. The estimated probability of acceptance (pi) for each offer value (i) was multiplied with the payoff received by a proposer if that offer value was accepted; this is the expected payoff (payoffi) from an offer (payoffi = pi(S−i) = pi(100 – i)) given its probability of acceptance. The IMO is then the offer value with the highest expected payoff.
3. Results
(a). Proposer behaviour varies across populations of the same ethno-linguistic group
Distributions of proposer offers (figure 1) vary significantly across villages. Offers vary from 5 to 80 per cent of the stake across villages. The modal offer across all villages is 50 rupees (50% of the stake). While the primary mode (the most frequently made offer) varies little across villages, the secondary mode (the second most frequently made offer) varies between 30 and 70 rupees across villages. Mean offers vary between about 31 and 52 rupees. 14.4 per cent (95% Bayesian confidence interval (BCI) = 6.3, 27.3) of the variance in offers occurs between villages (table 2b; null model (multilevel)). The DIC value for the null model with village-level intercepts (multilevel) is about 44 units lower than for the null model without village-level intercepts (single level), indicating that the multilevel model accounting for village effects provides a significantly better fit to the data (table 2a; null models). Once village and individual descriptors are included in the model, the unexplained between-village variance reduces to 11.2 per cent (95% BCI = 4, 22.8) (table 2b; full model (multilevel)).
Table 2.
(a) | proposer offer (Indian rupees) |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|
fixed effect | β±s.e. | 95% BCIb | DICc | |
null models | ||||
intercept (single level) | 46.624±0.562*** | 45.506, 47.717 | 2590.199 | |
intercept (multilevel) | 46.928±1.031*** | 44.903, 49.037 | 2546.072 | |
full model (multilevel) | 2528.601 | |||
intercept | 45.888±1.853*** | 42.304, 49.607 | ||
proportion of non-Korwas | 13.821±7.256* | −1.045, 27.509 | ||
household size (individuals) | −0.400±0.213* | −0.819, 0.024 | ||
day on which game was played: day 2+ (ref: day 1) | 4.940±1.162*** | 2.658, 7.189 |
(b) | village-level |
individual-level |
||
---|---|---|---|---|
variance±s.e. | 95% BCIb | variance±s.e. | 95% BCIb | |
null model (multilevel) | 15.720±7.090 | 6.314, 33.725 | 91.781±7.310 | 78.660, 107.180 |
full model (multilevel) | 11.234±5.674 | 3.705, 25.155 | 87.018±6.873 | 74.694, 101.473 |
aFor the two multilevel models (null and full), fixed-effect parameters in each model are specified in table 2a, while table 2b presents the village- and individual-level variances in proposer offers for each model, respectively. For instance, in table 2a, the full model (multilevel) has four fixed effects including the intercept; for each fixed effect (column 1), the associated β-value (column 2) and its 95% BCIb (column 3) can be read in the corresponding row. The DICc value for the model is presented in column 4 of table 2a. The variance components for the full model (multilevel) can be read in the last row of table 2b; column 2 represents the village-level variance in proposer offers with its 95% BCIb (column 3), and column 4 represents the individual-level variance in proposer offers with its 95% BCIb (column 5). The fixed effect parameters for the single-level null model are presented in table 2a; this model does not have variance components.
bBayesian credible interval.
cDeviance Information Criterion.
We tested whether properties of populations and individuals are associated with proposer offers (details are presented in table 2a, and a discussion of these results is provided in the electronic supplementary material). One population descriptor and two individual descriptors are associated with proposer offers. The proportion of non-Korwas (village residents who are not Pahari Korwas) has a substantial positive effect on proposer offers. Each additional non-Korwa living in the village is associated with offer values that are about 14 rupees (14% of the stake) higher on average. Note that non-Korwas did not participate in the games in any village. A player's household size has a small negative effect on her offer. Each additional person in the household reduces offers by about half a rupee on average. Finally, people who played on the second or third day of the games in any village made offers that were about five rupees higher on average. Pseudo-r2 values indicate that about 22 per cent of variance between populations and 9 per cent of variance within populations are explained by these three descriptor variables. Players' migration histories, frequency of market contact and multiple measures of wealth have little effect on their offers. The size of a player's social network and the number of kin that she has living, living in the same village, or living elsewhere, are also not associated with her offers.
(b). Responder behaviour does not vary across populations of the same ethno-linguistic group
In contrast to proposer offers, we find almost no variation in response distributions across villages. Of the 340 offers that responders were presented with across 21 villages, only five offers of any value were rejected (table 3); three of these five rejected offers had a value of 50 rupees (50% of the stake) and the remaining two rejected offers had values of 25 and 35 rupees, respectively. Individuals virtually never reject offers in these populations, despite the fact that offers vary from 5 to 80 per cent of the stake. Only 1.5 per cent of responders across 21 Pahari Korwa villages rejected offers of any value. Thus, there is no variation in responder behaviour across villages. Hence, responders across this ethno-linguistic group appear to follow the same income-maximizing strategy. Given the small number of rejections, no further analyses were conducted on responders' game responses.
Table 3.
village number | village name | responses |
||
---|---|---|---|---|
total (n) | accept (n) | reject (n)a | ||
1 | Chipni Paani | 6 | 6 | 0 |
2 | Mahua Bathaan | 11 | 11 | 0 |
3 | Jog Paani | 9 | 9 | 0 |
4 | Semar Kona | 8 | 8 | 0 |
5 | Bihidaand | 10 | 10 | 0 |
6 | Khunta Paani | 15 | 15 | 0 |
7 | Kaua Daahi | 16 | 16 | 0 |
8 | Pareva Aara | 18 | 18 | 0 |
9 | Musakhol | 15 | 15 | 0 |
10 | Kharranagar | 19 | 19 | 0 |
11 | Tedha Semar | 15 | 15 | 0 |
12 | Jamjhor | 15 | 15 | 0 |
13 | Vesra Paani | 22 | 22 | 0 |
14 | Mirgadaand | 16 | 15 | 1 : 35 |
15 | Barghaat | 21 | 21 | 0 |
16 | Gotidoomar | 25 | 23 | 2 : 25, 50 |
17 | Cheur Paani | 15 | 14 | 1 : 50 |
18 | Aama Naara | 22 | 22 | 0 |
19 | Bakrataal | 18 | 18 | 0 |
20 | Kheera Aama | 21 | 20 | 1 : 50 |
21 | Ghatgaon | 23 | 23 | 0 |
aValues listed after the colons are the values of the offers (in rupees) rejected.
Responders' self-reported strategies confirm this pattern. The modal self-reported MAO across all villages is zero (figure 2). Eighty per cent of responders reported that they were willing to accept either nothing or the smallest possible division of the stake, i.e. five rupees. In fact, the modal MAO in all villages is either zero or five rupees and very few individuals stated MAOs greater than 10. 4.9 per cent of the variance in MAOs occurs between villages (table S3B; null model (multilevel)). The DIC value for the null model with village-level intercepts (multilevel) is about 3.5 units lower than for the null model without village-level intercepts (single level), indicating that the multilevel model accounting for village effects provides only a slightly better fit to the data (see the electronic supplementary material, table S3A; null models). Once individual descriptors are included in the full model, the unexplained between-village variance reduces to 2.7 per cent (see the electronic supplementary material, table S3B; full model (multilevel)). Considering the low rate of actual rejections in these populations (even of small offers), these results suggest that the Pahari Korwa do as they say. If responders were simply justifying their accept/reject decisions, then we should expect a closer resemblance between the distributions of proposer offers and responder MAOs; we find no relationship between the two.
(c). Proposer behaviour is not contingent on responder behaviour
While UG responders in our study populations played the income-maximizing strategy, proposers did not. Proposers often offered substantial proportions of the stake, even though responders rarely rejected offers and appeared willing to accept any offer. Responder behaviour did not vary across the 21 populations even though proposer offers vary significantly across the same populations. The IMO, the offer that provides the highest expected payoff to a proposer given the distribution of rejections across offer values, is zero rupees as estimated from the distribution of rejections pooled across all 21 villages. Hence, the mean proposer offer for every village (figure 1) was much higher than the IMO; this confirms that proposers were not maximizing their income by making such high offers and their offers were not coordinated with responders' responses. In fact, all 344 offers made across 21 villages were higher than the IMO. We estimated the village-specific IMO for the four villages where at least one offer was rejected (see the electronic supplementary material, table S4). The mean proposer offer was much greater than the IMO for all four villages. Moreover, the modal self-reported MAO across populations (zero rupees) is equal to the IMO. Thus, proposer and responder behaviour in the UG is not coordinated across these populations.
4. Discussion
(a). Behavioural variation across populations
We find significant variation in UG proposer behaviour across 21 populations of the same ethno-linguistic group. This result is consistent with our previous findings [21] that contributions to public goods games and decisions regarding the distribution of salt, a locally valued resource, vary significantly and to a similar extent across 16 of the same villages. Thus, congruent results from three measures of behaviour administered in up to 21 populations provide evidence that levels of cooperation and bargaining behaviour vary substantially across populations of the same ethno-linguistic group.
The low frequency of rejections in UGs observed in Pahari Korwa populations is comparable to that found in several other populations, including populations of the Ache (0%), Tsimane (0%), Kazakh (0%), Quichua (0%), Isanga (3%), Orma (3.5%), Sanquianga (4%), Machiguenga (4.7%), Sangu herders (5%) and Samburu (5%) [7,22]. In about half of the 15 populations sampled in a cross-cultural study [7], responder behaviour was comparable to that observed in our study populations. A meta-analysis of 75 UG studies [3] conducted across 26 countries, largely sampling university students, reveals that the average rejection rate across studies is 16 per cent. However, rejection rates vary significantly by region (group of neighbouring countries). The meta-analysis also demonstrates that, across studies, rejection rates are far more sensitive to changes in the relative proportion of the stake offered than the absolute value of the offered share.
Thus, while responders in some parts of the world are willing to accept any offer made to them and follow the income-maximizing strategy, those in other places care about relative payoffs. What appear to be culturally transmitted fairness norms may be inequity-averse behavioural strategies that are individually adaptive in certain, but not all, environments. The finding that variation in inequality aversion explains some part of the variation in UG behaviour across 15 small-scale societies [22] is consistent with this hypothesis.
(b). Absence of coordination between bargainers' behaviour
Proposer and responder behaviour in the UG are not coordinated across our study populations. Our findings agree with those of previous studies demonstrating that mean offers in most populations of small-scale societies are much higher than IMOs [7] and mean MAOs [5,6]. In populations of large-scale societies, there is much greater variation in rejection rates than in offers [3]; we find the reverse pattern in our study populations. The absence of coordination between bargainers' behaviour observed in previous studies [3,5–7] and this study, contradicts economic models that assume that proposer behaviour is a best response to responder behaviour in a bargaining situation [23,24]. Proposer and responder strategies in a bargaining situation may not simply reflect dyadic relations but may be affected by different factors, especially if they are not wholly regulated by fairness norms. For instance, a recent study demonstrates that while proposers in the UG respond to reputation concerns by increasing their offers in a public context, responders do not do so [25].
(c). Fairness norms
A fairness norm is a culturally transmitted equilibrium at which bargainers have coordinated expectations from each other [10,11]. We do not find evidence of cultural conformism within the ethno-linguistic group as a collective, nor do we find that proposals and responses covary across this collective. Our findings make clear that current empirical data do not support the hypothesis that fairness norms at the level of the ethno-linguistic group account for the behavioural variation observed across human populations or the homogeneity observed within them.
It is possible that culturally transmitted behavioural norms exist at the level of the village rather than at the level of the ethno-linguistic group. Our finding that responder behaviour is uniform across the ethno-linguistic collective may suggest that responder behaviour is regulated by a norm. However, we find that the behaviour of proposers and responders in the UG did not covary even within our study villages. Thus, since we find that bargainers do not have coordinated expectations even at the level of the village, our findings suggest either that fairness norms do not regulate the behaviour of bargainers, or that behaviour observed in the experimental UG does not reflect the fairness norms that regulate individuals' behaviour in everyday life. It is therefore premature to conclude [1–3,5–9] that behaviour in a bargaining situation is regulated by fairness norms, based on evidence from the experimental UG.
As we have argued before [21], cross-cultural studies that have sampled from one or a few populations per culture confound cultural and environmental (demographic and ecological) differences between populations. Thus, the variation in cooperative and bargaining behaviour across human populations that is currently ascribed to culturally transmitted fairness norms may, in fact, be driven by individuals' sensitivity to local environmental conditions. This process presents a competing hypothesis as an explanation for patterns of behavioural variation that have previously been attributed to conformity to cultural norms.
Many characteristics of individuals are associated with cooperative behaviour, such as age [26], wealth [27] and sex (reviewed in [28]). Substantial empirical evidence demonstrates that individuals share socio-economic traits with their neighbours, a phenomenon termed homophily (reviewed in [29]). If individuals choose their place of residence based on their similarity to others in a neighbourhood, and if such residential homophily is based on individual characteristics that also correlate with cooperative behaviour, this process will give rise to geographically structured (e.g. neighbourhoods, populations) patterns of cooperation. For instance, if individuals buy houses based on where they can best afford to live and an individual's wealth is correlated with how likely they are to cooperate, then we should expect to observe neighbourhoods that are both uniform in their levels of wealth and levels of cooperation; several studies have noted an association between measures of neighbourhood wealth and levels of cooperation [30–32]. Thus, observed within-population similarity and between-population variation in cooperation does not necessarily arise from the cultural transmission of cooperative norms, or even direct assortation on how cooperative an individual's neighbours are, but rather may arise indirectly owing to homophilic residence on individual characteristics that correlate with cooperative behaviour.
Our findings caution against assuming that the modal behaviour in a human population reflects the operation of a cultural norm without explicitly testing this hypothesis. The independent, evolutionarily adaptive responses of individuals to shared local environments or homophilic residence patterns may produce behavioural homogeneity within populations and variation across them even if individuals do not share a cultural norm. Moreover, our findings suggest that what constitutes a fair division of resources can vary on smaller scales than that of the ethno-linguistic group. Individuals' local environments may play a central role in determining what constitutes fair behaviour and explaining the varying conceptions of fairness across the world.
Acknowledgements
This study has full approval from the Research Ethics Committee at University College London, and informed consent was obtained from all participants.
We are grateful to the Pahari Korwa for their hospitality. We thank Anil Kumar, Kundal Singh, Laxman Shastri, Narendra Das, Shivcharan Das and Petrus Lakra for assistance with running the experiments, Ganga Ram Paikra for help with setting up the fieldwork, Mai Stafford and Christian Hennig for advice on statistical modelling and Andrew Bevan for advice on GIS analyses. We thank David Lawson and two anonymous reviewers for comments on the manuscript. The Cogito Foundation and Parkes Foundation provided financial support for this study. R.M. is currently funded by a European Research Council grant. S.L. and R.M. designed the study. S.L. set up and conducted the fieldwork and analyses. S.L. and R.M. co-wrote the paper.
References
- 1.Cardenas JC, Carpenter JP. 2005. Experiments and economic development: lessons from field labs in the developing world. Middlebury College Working Paper Series, Paper no. 05-05, Middlebury College, Middlebury, VT, USA
- 2.Roth AE, Prasnikar V, Okuno-Fujiwara M, Zamir S. 1991. Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: an experimental study. Am. Econ. Rev. 81, 1068–1095 [Google Scholar]
- 3.Oosterbeek H, Sloof R, van de Kuilen G. 2004. Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: evidence from a meta-analysis. Exp. Econ. 7, 171–188 10.1023/B:EXEC.0000026978.14316.74 (doi:10.1023/B:EXEC.0000026978.14316.74) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 4.Marlowe FW, et al. 2008. More ‘altruistic’ punishment in larger societies. Proc. R. Soc. B 275, 587–592 10.1098/rspb.2007.1517 (doi:10.1098/rspb.2007.1517) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Henrich J, et al. 2010. Markets, religion, community size, and the evolution of fairness and punishment. Science 327, 1480–1484 10.1126/science.1182238 (doi:10.1126/science.1182238) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Henrich J, et al. 2006. Costly punishment across human societies. Science 312, 1767–1770 10.1126/science.1127333 (doi:10.1126/science.1127333) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Henrich J, et al. 2005. ‘Economic man’ in cross-cultural perspective: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behav. Brain Sci. 28, 795–815 10.1017/S0140525x05000142 (doi:10.1017/S0140525x05000142) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Fehr E, Fischbacher U. 2003. The nature of human altruism. Nature 425, 785–791 10.1038/nature02043 (doi:10.1038/nature02043) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 9.Fehr E, Fischbacher U. 2004. Social norms and human cooperation. Trends Cogn. Sci. 8, 185–190 10.1016/j.tics.2004.02.007 (doi:10.1016/j.tics.2004.02.007) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Binmore KG. 1998. The Evolution of fairness norms. Ration. Soc. 10, 275–301 10.1177/104346398010003001 (doi:10.1177/104346398010003001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Binmore KG. 2010. Social norms or social preferences? Mind Soc. 9, 139–157 10.1007/s11299-010-0073-2 (doi:10.1007/s11299-010-0073-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Sanfey AG, Rilling JK, Aronson JA, Nystrom LE, Cohen JD. 2003. The neural basis of economic decision-making in the ultimatum game. Science 300, 1755–1758 10.1126/science.1082976 (doi:10.1126/science.1082976) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Crockett MJ, Clark L, Tabibnia G, Lieberman MD, Robbins TW. 2008. Serotonin modulates behavioral reactions to unfairness. Science 320, 1739. 10.1126/science.1155577 (doi:10.1126/science.1155577) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 14.Wallace B, Cesarini D, Lichtenstein P, Johannesson M. 2007. Heritability of ultimatum game responder behavior. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 15631–15634 10.1073/pnas.0706642104 (doi:10.1073/pnas.0706642104) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Rizvi BR. 1989. Hill Korwas of Chhattisgarh. New Delhi, India: Gian Publishing House [Google Scholar]
- 16.Herrmann B, Thöni C, Gächter S. 2008. Antisocial punishment across societies. Science 319, 1362–1367 10.1126/science.1153808 (doi:10.1126/science.1153808) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Snijders TAB, Bosker RJ. 1999. Multilevel analysis: an introduction to basic and advanced multilevel modeling. London, UK: Sage Publications [Google Scholar]
- 18.Burnham KP, Anderson DR. 2002. Model selection and multi-model inference: a practical information-theoretic approach, 2nd edn. New York, NY: Springer-Verlag [Google Scholar]
- 19.Spiegelhalter DJ, Best NG, Carlin BP, van der Linde A. 2002. Bayesian measures of model complexity and fit. J. R. Stat. Soc. B 64, 583–639 10.1111/1467-9868.00353 (doi:10.1111/1467-9868.00353) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 20.Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H. 2004. Foundations of human sociality: economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press [Google Scholar]
- 21.Lamba S, Mace R. 2011. Demography and ecology drive variation in cooperation across human populations. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 108, 14426–14430 10.1073/pnas.1105186108 (doi:10.1073/pnas.1105186108) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Barr A, et al. 2009. Homo Æqualis: a cross-society experimental analysis of three bargaining games. The Centre for the Study of African Economies Working Paper Series, Paper 316, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
- 23.Fehr E, Schmidt KM. 1999. A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q. J. Econ. 114, 817–868 10.1162/003355399556151 (doi:10.1162/003355399556151) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 24.Bolton GE, Ockenfels A. 2000. ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 166–193 10.1257/aer.90.1.166 (doi:10.1257/aer.90.1.166) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 25.Lamba S, Mace R. 2010. People recognise when they are really anonymous in an economic game. Evol. Hum. Behav. 31, 271–278 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2010.02.002 (doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2010.02.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 26.List JA. 2004. Young, selfish and male: Field evidence of social preferences. Econ. J. 114, 121–149 10.1046/j.0013-0133.2003.00180.x (doi:10.1046/j.0013-0133.2003.00180.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Cardenas JC. 2003. Real wealth and experimental cooperation: experiments in the field lab. J. Dev. Econ. 70, 263–289 10.1016/s0304-3878(02)00098-6. (doi:10.1016/s0304-3878(02)00098-6.) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 28.Croson R, Gneezy U. 2009. Gender differences in preferences. J. Econ. Lit. 47, 448–474 10.1257/jel.47.2.448. (doi:10.1257/jel.47.2.448.) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 29.McPherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook JM. 2001. Birds of a feather: homophily in social networks. Ann. Rev. Sociol. 27, 415–444 10.1146/annurev.soc.27.1.415 (doi:10.1146/annurev.soc.27.1.415) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 30.Holland J, Silva AS, Mace R. 2012. Lost letter measure of variation in altruistic behaviour in 20 neighbourhoods. PLoS ONE 7, e43294. 10.1371/journal.pone.0043294 (doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0043294) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 31.Nettle D, Colléony A, Cockerill M. 2011. Variation in cooperative behaviour within a single city. PLoS ONE 6, e26922. 10.1371/journal.pone.0026922 (doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0026922) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 32.Wilson DS, O'Brien DT, Sesma A. 2009. Human prosociality from an evolutionary perspective: variation and correlations at a city-wide scale. Evol. Hum. Behav. 30, 190–200 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2008.12.002 (doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2008.12.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]