Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2013 Aug 1;8(8):e64653. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0064653

Network Effects of Risk Behavior Change Following Prophylactic Interventions

Rajmohan Rajaraman 1, Zhifeng Sun 2, Ravi Sundaram 3, Anil Kumar S Vullikanti 4,*
Editor: Luís A Nunes Amaral5
PMCID: PMC3731323  PMID: 23936290

Abstract

We formulated a network-based model to understand how risk behavior change in conjunction with failure of prophylactic interventions can lead to unintended outcomes where “less (intervention) is more (effective).” Our model captures the distinction between one- and two-sided risk behavior change. In one-sided situations (e.g. influenza/H1N1) it is sufficient for either individual in an interaction to exhibit risk behavior change whereas in two-sided situations (e.g. AIDS/HIV) it is necessary for both individuals in the interaction to exhibit risk behavior change, for a potential transmission of the disease. A central discovery is that this phenomenon occurs at differing levels of intervention coverage depending upon the “sidedness” of the interaction. We find that for one-sided interactions, sufficiently high vaccination coverage is necessary for mitigating the effects of risk behavior; for two-sided interactions, it is essential to combine prophylactic treatments with programs aimed at reducing risky behavior. Furthermore, again dependent on the “sidedness,” targeting highly connected nodes can be strictly worse than uniformly random interventions at the same level of coverage.

Introduction

For many diseases, such as influenza and HIV, interventions using anti-virals and vaccinations are commonly used to control the spread of the diseases, and are usually universally recommended, barring individual constraints. Recent studies have shown significant benefits of anti-retrovirals for reducing the spread of HIV [1]. Such vaccination or anti-viral treatments have very widely varying levels of efficacy (25–75% in the case of HIV [1],[2], 80–85% in the case of Pertussis [3], and between 10–80% in the case of influenza [4], depending on the demographics and the specifics of the flu strain). Most studies about the efficacy of such interventions do not take individual behavior into account in a realistic manner, though many researchers have pointed out that it is an important issue, e.g., [5]. Systematic research and data analysis on this aspect are limited. Petrie et al. [6] observe that people are not very well aware of this limitation, and studies often over-estimate the efficacy of vaccines. Further, Reiber et al. [7] have recently documented significant changes in behavior in vaccinated individuals (possibly because of perceived protection offered by the vaccination), leading to an increase in contact by a treated individual; such a behavioral change following vaccination could also be a natural evolutionary response [8], [9]. Regardless of the underlying reasons, failure of prophylactic interventions in conjunction with increased social behavior can have significant unexpected effects on the disease dynamics. In a series of important papers [10], [11] Blower and her collaborators demonstrated that risk behavior change, in the context of HIV vaccinations, could lead to unintended outcomes. Subsequently, several independent studies have confirmed this phenomenon of perversity in the use of HIV vaccines and anti-virals, and vaccines for the human papillomavirus (HPV) [2], [5], [12][21]. The phenomenon of an increase in risky behavior following protection is also referred to as “moral hazard” and has been studied extensively in a number of areas, such as insurance (e.g., [22]); in the epidemiology literature, this is referred to more commonly as “risk behavior” (e.g., [10]), and we will adopt this terminology for most of the paper.

A fundamental question in mathematical epidemiology is to determine the fraction of the population that needs to be vaccinated or treated with anti-virals in order to minimize the impact of the disease, especially when the supply is limited. Modern epidemiological analysis is largely based on an elegant class of models, called SIR (susceptible-infected-recovered), which was first formulated by Reed and Frost in the 1920 s, and developed over the subsequent decades. The SIR model and its variants have been highly influential in the study of epidemics [11], [23][27]. These models, however, do not attempt to capture the rich structure of the contact network over which interactions occur. Network structure has a direct effect on both the spread of diseases as well as the nature of interactions, which has been observed by a number of researchers, e.g. [28], [29]. In the emerging area of contact network epidemiology, an underlying contact graph captures the patterns of interactions which lead to the transmission of a disease [30][37]. Many studies have predicted the spread of diseases through networks using mathematical analysis or simulations. As we have argued above, moral-hazarding/risky behavior clearly plays an important role in the effectiveness of such interventions. While the impact of risky behavior on prophylactic treatments has been studied in previous work, the extent of the perversity and its dependence on network structure as well as the precise nature of the behavior change has remained largely unknown. Similar issues arise in the context of the spread of malware through infected computers. Several studies, e.g., [38], have found that computer and smart-phone users do not relate bot infections to risky behavior, such as downloading spam mails, though a large fraction of users have updated anti-virus software. It is plausible that such phenomena can also be associated with risky behavior in many cases.

In this paper, we study the impact of risk behavior change on the spread of diseases in networks and observe a rich and complex structure dependent both on the underlying network characteristics as well as the nature of the change in behavior. We use a discrete-time SIR model of disease transmission on a contact network, in which each edge has a certain probability of disease transmission. An infected node is assumed to recover in one time step. We consider both uniform random vaccination (where each node is vaccinated independently with the same probability) as well as targeted vaccinations (where nodes are vaccinated based on their degree of connectedness). Vaccines are assumed to fail uniformly and randomly. Though we focus on vaccinations and disease transmission, the basic results apply to other prophylactic treatments such as anti-virals, and other phenomena such as malware spread. We model risk behavior change by an increase in the disease transmission probability, with no change in the contacts. We emphasize here that the change in risk behavior is only a function of whether a node is vaccinated, and is independent of the failure of the vaccination. Any adverse impact of a risk behavior change, however, manifests only when the vaccination of the node that indulged in increased risky behavior fails.

A significant aspect of our work is the consideration of the “sidedness” of risk behavior change. We classify risk behavior as one-sided or two-sided based on whether the increase in disease transmission probability requires an increase in risk behavior of both the infector and the infectee or just the infector. As examples: influenza (H1N1) may be modeled as a one-sided disease since a vaccinated individual may be motivated to behave more riskily in terms of increased contact (e.g., going to crowded places, increasing travel on planes), thus increasing the chance of infecting all the individual comes in contact with; whereas AIDS (HIV) may be modeled as a two-sided disease since the increase in disease transmission requires both the individuals participating in the interaction to engage in risky behavior. Of course, these examples are simplistic and most diseases have elements of both one-sided as well as two-sided risk behavior. An important caveat is that in this study, we assume the network is static (i.e., the contacts remain unchanged, though their intensity is changed, which alters the transmission probability), and does not co-evolve with the behavioral change – we note that even this restricted setting is quite non-trivial and poorly understood, especially in the context of network effects.

Our main findings are threefold, and are described at a high level here. We discuss them in more detail in Section 0, after describing our model and simulation setup in Section 0. First, we find that the severity of the epidemic often varies non-monotonically as a function of the vaccinated fraction. The specific dynamics depend on the nature of risky behavior, as well as the efficacy of the vaccine and the contagiousness of the disease (the less reliable the vaccine, and more contagious the disease, the greater the non-monotonicity). Therefore, in general, we observe that increased vaccination rate does not immediately imply less severity; in some cases, the severity could increase by as much as a factor of two. Second, we find that one-sided risk behavior change leads to unintended outcomes at low levels of vaccination, while two-sided risk behavior change leads to unintended outcomes at high levels of vaccination. Our analysis indicates that effective prophylactic interventions against diseases with one-sided risk behavior change need to have sufficiently high coverage; on the other hand, for diseases with two-sided risk behavior change, it is essential to combine treatments with education programs aimed at reducing risky behavior. Our third and, perhaps, most surprising finding is that interventions that target highly connected individuals can sometimes be worse than random interventions for the same level of coverage and that this phenomenon occurs both for one-sided as well as two-sided risk behavior change. Given prior work on targeting vaccine distributions, this finding flies in the face of intuition that expects that targeted vaccination would confer greater benefits. Thus, our results offer new insights and directions for public policy on containing epidemic spread through prophylactic interventions.

Comparison with Related Work

The study of spread of diseases and the ways to control them has been a major research topic for centuries. Modern epidemiological analysis is largely based on an elegant class of models, called SIR (susceptible-infected-recovered), which was first formulated by Reed and Frost in the 1920s, and developed over the subsequent decades. The SIR model and its variants have been highly influential in the study of epidemics [11], [23][27]. These models, however, do not attempt to capture the rich structure of the contact network over which interactions occur. Network structure has a direct effect on both the spread of diseases as well as the nature of interactions, which has been observed by a number of researchers, e.g. [28], [29]. In the emerging area of contact network epidemiology, an underlying contact graph captures the patterns of interactions which lead to the transmission of a disease [30][37]. Many studies have predicted the spread of diseases through networks using mathematical analysis or simulations.

Implications of risk behavior in public health have been examined earlier. In particular, the counterintuitive impact of vaccination owing to risky behavior was first discovered by Blower and McLean [10], [11], [39] in the case of HIV. Subsequently, several independent studies have confirmed this phenomenon and have offered potential explanations [12][15]. However, the extent of the perversity and its dependence on network structure as well as the precise nature of the behavior change has remained largely unknown. Our paper will go some way towards the resolution of these issues.

The analyses conducted in prior studies of risk behavior in public health are based on differential equation models, which divide the population into a fixed set of groups and model the interaction between different groups in a uniform way. The epidemic spread is then characterized by the “reproductive number,” denoted by Inline graphic (see [40] for a discussion on Inline graphic in static and dynamic networks), with the expected epidemic size exhibiting a threshold behavior in terms of Inline graphic. In contrast, we use a network model that captures the fine structure of interactions between (an arbitrary number of) individuals rather than (a fixed set of) groups, and find that the network structure has a significant impact on the resulting dynamics. The heterogeneous network model extends to a larger range of real-life situations but the increased fidelity comes at a price. The outcomes are more complicated and varied and the general approach of lowering Inline graphic does not appear to be directly applicable. Another new contribution of our study is the focus on the sidedness inherent in risk behavior change, which has not been considered before. Prior research has implicitly assumed one-sided risk behavior change where vaccinated individuals engage in risky behavior increasing the chances of infection of those they come in contact with. This work explicitly treats both one-sided and two-sided risk behavior changes and shows that their differing impact needs to be considered in public intervention policies.

Our Model

We obtain our results through both analytical techniques and simulations on a range of networks including preferential attachment networks [41] and large synthetic and real-world networks. For our theoretical analyses, we adopt the SIR model of epidemics defined on networks. Let Inline graphic denote an undirected social contact graph, where Inline graphic denotes a set of people (referred to as nodes henceforth) and Inline graphic denotes a contact between nodes Inline graphic and Inline graphic (see Figure 1(a) for an example). If node Inline graphic becomes infectious, it will infect each of its susceptible neighbors independently with probability Inline graphic (referred as base transmissivity). Each node in the graph is either vaccinated (e.g., nodes Inline graphic or Inline graphic in Figure 1(b)) or not (e.g., nodes Inline graphic or Inline graphic in Figure 1(b)). If a node Inline graphic is not vaccinated, we label it as UV. The vaccine fails with probability Inline graphic; for convenience, we also define vaccine success probability Inline graphic Inline graphic. If a node Inline graphic's vaccine fails, we label it as VF; otherwise, we label it VS. Both UV and VF nodes are susceptible. We assume that vaccine failure is a stochastic event and that (vaccinated) nodes do not know if (their own) vaccination succeeded or not. When a node is vaccinated, its risk behavior changes; i.e., it increases its contact to some of its neighbors. If the vaccination is successful, this increase in risky behavior has no impact on disease transmission. If the vaccination fails, however, then the increased contact results in boosted transmissivity Inline graphic along the contact edges – in the one-sided model a node infects all its susceptible neighbors with boosted transmissivity Inline graphic, while in the two-sided model, it only infects those neighbors with boosted transmissivity Inline graphic that have also had a failed vaccination. In the rest of the paper, we use Inline graphic to denote the probability that a node is vaccinated, under a campaign of uniformly random vaccination. For easy reference, we list the different probability parameters in Table 1.

Figure 1. Sidedness of risk behavior change: the one-sided and two-sided models.

Figure 1

Table 1. Probability parameters.

Notation Parameter
P base transmissivity, the probability of disease transmission along an edge
pm boosted transmissivity, the transmission probability following risk behavior change
pv probability that a given node is vaccinated
pf probability that the vaccination of an arbitrary node fails
ps vaccine efficacy ( = 1−pf)

The disease transmission process is thus defined by the tuple Inline graphic in the following manner: every node is labeled with UV,VS VF, with probability Inline graphic, Inline graphic Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, respectively. All nodes labeled are removed from the graph. Each edge Inline graphic connecting two surviving nodes Inline graphic and Inline graphic, is “open” (or retained in the graph, in the language of percolation, which corresponds to disease transmission on this edge), or “closed” (or removed from the graph), with some probability depending on the model – (i) in the one-sided model, edge Inline graphic is open with probability Inline graphic, if both Inline graphic and Inline graphic are labeled UV, and is open with probability Inline graphic if one of Inline graphic and Inline graphic is labeled VF; (ii) in the two-sided model, edge Inline graphic is open with probability Inline graphic, unless both Inline graphic and Inline graphic are labeled VF. Following the well known correspondence between bond percolation and disease transmission, the connected component containing a specific node Inline graphic is the (random) subset of nodes infected, if the disease starts at Inline graphic. If the components resulting from one random instance of the above stochastic process are Inline graphic, then Inline graphic denotes the expected outbreak size of the disease starting from a random initial node. In our analysis, we use this as a measure of epidemic severity.

Results and Discussion

We summarize our analytical and simulation based findings that both one-sided and two-sided behavior changes can lead to unintended outcomes (less vaccination is more effective) across a wide range of contact networks. These are discussed in greater detail in Sections Simulation Results for Diverse Networks and Analytical Results for the Erdös-Rényi Model, respectively.

1. Simulation results in a wide range of networks

We study the impact of risky behavior in a wide range of networks, including random graph models (such as the Erdös and Rényi [42] and Preferential attachment [41] models), and realistic networks, such as social contact networks and peer-to-peer networks. We find that one-sided behavior change leads to unintended outcomes at low levels of intervention, in which the epidemic severity increases with Inline graphic, up to a point, while two-sided behavior change leads to unintended outcomes at high levels of intervention, in which the epidemic severity starts increasing beyond a threshold value of Inline graphic. Further, we find that targeted vaccination can be strictly worse than random vaccination for some level of vaccine coverage, and this phenomenon occurs both for one-sided as well as two-sided behavior change. In the literature it has been observed that targeting highly connected individuals for vaccination lead to better outcomes as opposed to random coverage [31], [36], [43]. Our finding adds nuance to the existing results when risky behavior is taken into account. This counterintuitive phenomenon can also be explained by the tug of war between successful vaccination and risky behavior. If the effect of risky behavior is dominant then one would expect that targeted vaccination ends up being worse than random coverage since it is the targeted high-degree individuals that are the most responsible for creating additional contagion. And, in fact the evidence supports this explanation in that we see targeted coverage being inferior to random coverage at low levels of vaccination in the one-sided case but at high levels in the two-sided case.

2. Analytical results

We mathematically establish the phenomena of perversity and non-monotonicity for graphs generated according to the Erdös-Renyi model [28], denoted by Inline graphic, in which each edge between a pair of nodes is chosen independently with probability Inline graphic. We prove rigorously that there exist Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, such that (i) in the one-sided model, it almost surely holds that the epidemic severity is Inline graphic for both Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic Inline graphic, yet Inline graphic for some Inline graphic in Inline graphic; (ii) in the two-sided model, the epidemic severity is Inline graphic for both Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic Inline graphic, yet Inline graphic for some Inline graphic in Inline graphic. This implies that there is a choice of parameters (which turns out to be be quite broad), such that as the vaccinated fraction Inline graphic is varied, the epidemic severity shows a non-monotone behavior.

In [44], we show that the phenomenon of perversity exists in a broad class of graphs. Specifically, we consider locally finite graphs, which have been widely studied in percolation theory (e.g., see [45]). Locally finite graphs include infinite graphs in which each node has bounded degree. Using techniques from percolation theory, we show that in every locally finite graph Inline graphic, there exist Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, such that: (i) the epidemic severity is finite for both Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic Inline graphic, yet infinite for some Inline graphic in Inline graphic in the one-sided model; (ii) the epidemic severity is infinite for both Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic Inline graphic, yet finite for some Inline graphic in Inline graphic in the two-sided model. This result (which is discussed in [44], since it is beyond the scope of this paper) provides strong evidence of the universality of the phenomenon and begs for a natural and intuitive explanation. Our best structural understanding at this point is that this is the consequence of two competing tensions – vaccine success that serves to contain the spread and risky behavior that, exacerbated by vaccine failure, serves to boost the contagion. In the one-sided situation since it is sufficient for infection spread to have just the one party in an interaction exhibiting risky behavior we see perversity manifesting itself at low levels of vaccination. Whereas, in the two-sided situation since it is necessary for both the interacting parties to exhibit risky behavior we see perversity manifesting itself only at high vaccination levels which is a prerequisite for a non-trivial fraction of parties with failed vaccines to exist.

Simulation Results for Diverse Networks

In this section, we examine the impact of risk behavior in a wide range of networks. Recall from Section that the disease transmission is a random process, defined by the parameter set (Inline graphic). We study the epidemic severity for the networks described in Table 2, and our main goals are to study empirically: (i) the extent of unintended outcomes, and (ii) the impact of target vaccination strategies in the one-sided and two-sided scenarios. For each network in Table 2, we run simulations over wide range of parameter set (Inline graphic). Our main results are summarized below.

Table 2. Descriptions of the networks used in the paper.

name n m description
Human contact NewRiverValley [50] 74,375 1,888,833 Synthetic human contact network for New River Valley county in Virginia.
Social communication Enron mail [51], [52] 36,691 367,666 Email communication network in a company.
Peer-to-peer network Gnutella [53], [54] 10,876 39,994 Gnutella peer-to-peer file sharing network from August 2002
Random graphs Preferential attachment [41] 100,000 300,000 Generated using Python NetworkX library.
Erdös and Rényi [42] 100,000 5,000,000

For each network we show its type, name, number of nodes Inline graphic and edges Inline graphic.

  • We find that the unintended outcome in both the one- and two-sided settings increase with the boosted transmissivity Inline graphic. This seems to be uniformly true for all the networks we study.

  • The unintended outcomes in both the settings increases with the vaccine failure rate in all the networks.

  • Targeted vaccination strategies (based on degree) can be strictly worse than random vaccination for various parameter values. This is an important observation, since targeted interventions have been strongly advocated.

We discuss our simulation based results in more detail below. For simplicity, we show the results for each network mentioned in Table 2 separately, but summarize the main observations below. In order to capture real disease transmission through simulations, we find typical values of Inline graphic, the basic reproduction number, for many diseases such as influenza and HIV [46][48]. Then, we divide Inline graphic by the average degree of the network, and use it as the base transmissivity Inline graphic. For vaccination success probability, we use the efficacy for real vaccines [1], [2], [4].

1. Impact of the boosted transmissivity Inline graphic

Figure 2 shows how the change of boosted transmissivity affect the unintended outcomes for the different networks. The Inline graphic-axis is Inline graphic (percentage of vaccinated population) and the Inline graphic-axis is the epidemic severity (expected percentage of nodes getting infected). We fix the base transmissivity Inline graphic and the vaccination success probability Inline graphic, then plot the curves for different boosted transmissivity. As these results show, the unintended outcome increases with Inline graphic in both settings.

Figure 2. Impact of the boosted transmissivity parameter Inline graphic.

Figure 2

Epidemic severity with different boosted transmissivities in one-sided (left) and two-sided (right) risk behavior models. Inline graphic-axis is the percentage of nodes taking interventions, and Inline graphic-axis is the expected percentage of nodes getting infected.

2. Impact of the base transmissivity

Figure 3 shows how the change of base transmissivity affect the unintended outcomes. The Inline graphic-axis is Inline graphic and the Inline graphic-axis is the epidemic severity. We fix the vaccination success probability Inline graphic and keep the boosted transmissivity Inline graphic twice the base transmissivity Inline graphic (i.e. Inline graphic), then plot the curves for different base transmissivity.

Figure 3. Impact of base transmissivity parameter Inline graphic.

Figure 3

Epidemic severity with different transmissivities in one-sided (left) and two-sided (right) risk behavior models. Inline graphic-axis is the percentage of nodes taking interventions, and Inline graphic-axis is the expected percentage of nodes getting infected.

3. Impact of the vaccination efficacy

Figure 4 shows how the change of vaccination success probability affect the unintended outcomes. The Inline graphic-axis is Inline graphic and the Inline graphic-axis is the epidemic severity. We fix the base transmissivity Inline graphic and the boosted transmissivity Inline graphic, then plot the curves for different vaccination success probability. We observe that the perversity increases with the vaccination failure rate.

Figure 4. Impact of the vaccination efficacy parameterInline graphic.

Figure 4

Epidemic severity with different intervention success probabilities in one-sided (left) and two-sided (right) risk behavior models. Inline graphic-axis is the percentage of nodes taking interventions, and Inline graphic-axis is the expected percentage of nodes getting infected.

4. Targeted vs random interventions

Figure 5 shows that the efficacy of targeted vaccination (relative to random vaccinations) can vary significantly in the presence of such one-/two-sided behavior. For various parameter choices, targeted vaccination can even be worse. The Inline graphic-axis is Inline graphic and the Inline graphic-axis is the ratio between the epidemic severity under targeted vaccination strategy and the epidemic severity under random vaccination strategy. If Inline graphic value is bigger than Inline graphic, it means targeted strategy is worse than random strategy. We fix the base transmissivity Inline graphic and the vaccination success probability Inline graphic, then plot the curves for different boosted transmissivity.

Figure 5. Targeted vs random interventions.

Figure 5

Epidemic severity comparison of random and targeted intervention strategies in one-sided (left) and two-sided (right) risk behavior models. Inline graphic-axis is the percentage of nodes taking interventions, and Inline graphic-axis is the ratio of the epidemic severity in targeted intervention strategy and the epidemic severity in random intervention strategy.

Analytical Results for the Erdös-Rényi Model

In this section, we give formal proofs of perversity and non-monotonicity in Erdös-Rényi random graphs. We have observed the non-monotonicity is pervasive in wide range of contact graphs, including scale-free graphs, Erdös-Rényi graphs, and other synthetic or real world graphs. Theorem 3 gives the rigorous proof of one-sided model and two-sided model for Erdös-Rényi random graphs. We establish two key lemmas that apply to complete graphs, from which we derive the results for random graphs.

Lemma 1

Given a complete graph as the contact network, for intervention with any success probability Inline graphic, there exists parameter set Inline graphic such that there is non-monotonicity in two-sided risk behavior model.

Proof

We set the disease transmission probability Inline graphic Inline graphic where Inline graphic Inline graphic. Let Inline graphic be the number of nodes in the network. We first show that the expected epidemic size is Inline graphic in two extreme cases: when nobody takes interventions, and when everybody takes interventions. We then show that there exists an intermediate vaccination point, where the expected epidemic size is Inline graphic, thus establishing non-monotonicity.

When nobody takes interventions, then the impact of disease transmission is captured by an Erdös-Rényi graph over Inline graphic nodes in which each edge exists independently with probability Inline graphic. By [42], there is a giant connected component with high probability (size of the connected component is Inline graphic), implying a Inline graphic bound on the expected epidemic size.

When everybody takes interventions, Inline graphic nodes will have successful interventions with high probability, and thus removed from the graph. The remaining Inline graphic nodes will all exhibit risk behavior changes. Thus, the disease transmission probability between each pair of nodes is Inline graphic, where Inline graphic. By [42], there is a giant connected component with high probability (size of the connected component is Inline graphic), again implying a Inline graphic bound on the expected epidemic size.

Now we are going to show there exists a Inline graphic, such that, if we apply interventions to each node independently with probability Inline graphic, the epidemic severity will be Inline graphic with high probability. Let Inline graphic be the set of nodes that haven't taken interventions, Inline graphic be the set of nodes that have taken interventions but failed, and Inline graphic be the set of nodes that have taken interventions and succeeded. Inline graphic represents the probability of a random node being in set Inline graphic, Inline graphic represents the probability of a random node being in set Inline graphic, and Inline graphic represents the probability of a random node being in set Inline graphic. In the two-sided model, disease transmits with probability Inline graphic between nodes in set Inline graphic, and Inline graphic otherwise. Set Inline graphic and Inline graphic. Let

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e169.jpg

This yields a model of inhomogeneous random graphs with 3 types of vertices (Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic). By [49] Theorem 1, if all the eigenvalues of Inline graphic are less than 1 in absolute value, then the size of the largest connected component is Inline graphic. Let Inline graphic be the eigenvalues of Inline graphic.

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e177.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e178.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e179.jpg

Solving Inline graphic, we have

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e181.jpg

where Inline graphic. Since Inline graphic, it is sufficient to show there exists a set of parameters that yields Inline graphic. Set Inline graphic Inline graphic Inline graphic.

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e188.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e189.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e190.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e191.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e192.jpg

When Inline graphic, Inline graphic is a constant smaller than 1. We can find Inline graphic that satisfies Inline graphic. Thus, for intervention with success probability Inline graphic, there exist parameters Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, such that the epidemic size is Inline graphic. This completes our proof of this lemma.

Lemma 2

Given a complete graph as the contact network, for intervention with any success probability Inline graphic, there exists parameter set Inline graphic, such that there is non-monotonicity in one-sided risk behavior model.

Proof

We set the disease transmission probability Inline graphic where Inline graphic. Let Inline graphic be the number of nodes in the network. We first show that the expected epidemic size is Inline graphic in two extreme cases: when nobody takes interventions, and when everybody takes interventions. We then show that there exists an intermediate vaccination point, where the expected epidemic size is Inline graphic, thus establishing non-monotonicity.

When nobody takes interventions, then the impact of disease transmission is captured by an Erdös-Rényi graph over Inline graphic nodes in which each edge exists independently with probability Inline graphic. By [42], the size of the largest connected component is Inline graphic with high probability, implying an Inline graphic bound on the expected epidemic size.

When everybody takes interventions, Inline graphic nodes will have successful interventions with high probability, and thus removed from the graph. The remaining Inline graphic nodes will exhibit risk behavior changes. Thus, the disease transmission probability between each pair of nodes is Inline graphic, where Inline graphic. By [42], the size of the largest connected component is Inline graphic with high probability, again implying an Inline graphic bound on the expected epidemic size.

Now we are going to show there exists a Inline graphic, such that, if we apply interventions to each node independently with probability Inline graphic, the epidemic severity will be Inline graphic with high probability. Let Inline graphic be the set of nodes that haven't taken interventions, Inline graphic be the set of nodes that have taken interventions but failed, and Inline graphic be the set of nodes that have taken interventions and succeeded. Inline graphic represents the probability of a random node being in set Inline graphic, Inline graphic represents the probability of a random node being in set Inline graphic, and Inline graphic Inline graphic represents the probability of a random node being in set Inline graphic. In the one-sided model, disease transmit with probability Inline graphic between nodes in set Inline graphic, and Inline graphic otherwise. Set Inline graphic and Inline graphic. Let

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e237.jpg

This yields a model of inhomogeneous random graphs with 3 types of vertices (Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic). By [49] Theorem 1, if some eigenvalue of Inline graphic is larger than 1, then the size of the largest connected component is Inline graphic. Let Inline graphic be the eigenvalues of Inline graphic.

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e245.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e246.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e247.jpg

Solving Inline graphic, we have

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e249.jpg

where Inline graphic. Since Inline graphic, it is sufficient to show there exists a set of parameters that yields Inline graphic. Let Inline graphic.

graphic file with name pone.0064653.e254.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e255.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e256.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e257.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e258.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0064653.e259.jpg

When Inline graphic, Inline graphic is a constant greater than 1. We can find Inline graphic that satisfies Inline graphic. Thus, for vaccination with success probability Inline graphic, there exist parameters Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, such that the epidemic size is Inline graphic. This completes our proof of this lemma.

Theorem 3

For the Erdös-Rényi random graph model Inline graphic, there exist Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, such that (i) in the one-sided model, it almost surely holds that the epidemic severity is Inline graphic for both Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic Inline graphic, yet Inline graphic for some Inline graphic in Inline graphic; (ii) in the two-sided model, the epidemic severity is Inline graphic for both Inline graphic Inline graphic and Inline graphic Inline graphic, yet Inline graphic for some Inline graphic in Inline graphic.

Proof

We claim the disease transmission process on Erdös-Rényi random graph Inline graphic with parameter set Inline graphic is the same as the disease transmission process on a complete graph with parameter set Inline graphic. It's simply because the edge between each pair of nodes “opens” with the same probability in both random processes. Thus, for any disease transmission process on Erdös-Rényi random graph, we can reduce it to the corresponding process on a complete graph. Then by Lemma 0 and 0 we can conclude the statement of this theorem holds.

Conclusion

In conclusion, risk behavior change in conjunction with failure of prophylactic interventions can have unintended non-monotone effects on the spread of diseases. This study has explicitly identified sidedness as an attribute of risk behavior change that needs to be taken into account in public policies for vaccinations and anti-viral treatments. For one-sided risk behavior change, it is imperative to have sufficiently high levels of coverage, while two-sided situations require both high coverage as well as programs aimed at reducing risky behavior. Our results echo the central premise of Blower-McLean that the development of efficacious prophylactic treatments and increasing their coverage need to go hand in hand with behavioral intervention strategies. These issues need to be revisited in the context of new anti-retroviral treatments being considered for HIV [1].

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the referees for their detailed comments, which have greatly improved the quality of the paper.

Funding Statement

The work of Rajmohan Rajaraman and Zhifeng Sun has been partially supported by NSF NETS CNS-0915985. Rajmohan Rajaraman and Ravi Sundaram have also been partially supported by NSF CCF-1216038. The work of Anil Vullikanti has been partially supported by DTRA CNIMS Grant HDTRA1-11-D-0016-0001, NIH MIDAS Grant 2U01GM070694-09, NSF CAREER Grant CNS-0845700, NSF NETSE Grant CNS-1011769, NSF ICES CCF-1216000 and DOE DE-SC0003957. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1. Karim QA, Karim SSA, Frohlich JA, Grobler AC, Baxter C, et al. (2010) Effectiveness and safety of tenofovir gel, an antiretroviral microbicide, for the prevention of HIV infection in women. Science 329 (5996): 1168–1174. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2. Gray RH, Li X, Wawer MJ, Gange SJ, Serwadda D, et al. (2003) Stochastic simulation of the impact of antiretroviral therapy and HIV vaccines on HIV transmission; Rakai, Uganda. AIDS 17: 1941–51. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Pertussis (whooping cough) vaccination (2013) Available: www.cdc.gov/vaccines/vpd-vac/pertussis/default.htm.Accessed 2013 May 27.
  • 4.CDC flu vaccine effectiveness (2011) Available: http://www.cdc.gov/flu/professionals/vaccination/effectivenessqa.htm.Accessed 2013 May 27.
  • 5. Brewer NT, Cuite CL, Herrington JE, Weinstein ND (2007) Risk compensation and vaccination: can getting vaccinated cause people to engage in risky behaviors? Ann Behav Med 34: 95–9. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6. Petrie JG, Ohmit SE, Johnson E, Cross RT, Monto AS (2011) Efficacy studies of influenza vaccines: Effect of end points used and characteristics of vaccine failures. Journal of Infectious Diseases 203(9): 1309–15. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7. Reiber C, Shattuck EC, Fiore S, Alperin P, Davis V, et al. (2010) Change in human social behavior in response to a common vaccine. Ann Epidemiol 20: 729–33. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8. Klein S (2003) Parasite manipulation of the proximate mechanisms that mediate social behavior in vertebrates. Physiol Behav 79: 441–9. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Moore J (2002) Parasites and the behavior of animals. New York: Oxford University Press.
  • 10. Blower S, McLean A (1994) Prophylactic vaccination, risk behavior change, and the probability of eradicating HIV in San Francisco. Science 265(5177): 1451–1454. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11. McLean A, Blower S (1993) Imperfect vaccines and herd immunity to HIV. Proceedings Biological Sciences 253(1336): 9–13. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12. Smith RJ, Blower SM (2004) Could disease-modifying HIV vaccines cause population-level perversity? Lancet Infect Dis 4: 636–9. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13. Bezemer D, Wolf F, Boerlijst M, Sighem A, Hollingsworth T, et al. (2008) A resurgent HIV-1 epidemic among men who have sex with men in the era of potent antiretroviral therapy. AIDS 22(9): 1071–1077. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14. Wilson D, Coplan P, Wainberg M, Blower S (2008) The paradoxical effects of using antiretroviral-based microbicides to control HIV epidemics. PNAS 105(28): 9835–9840. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15. Velasco-Hernandez J, Gershengorn H, Blower S (2002) Could widespread use of combination antiretroviral therapy eradicate HIV epidemics? Infectious Diseases 8: 487–93. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16. van der Straten A, Gómez CA, Saul J, Quan J, Padian N (2000) Sexual risk behaviors among heterosexual HIV serodiscordant couples in the era of post-exposure prevention and viral suppressive therapy. AIDS 14: F47–54. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17. Andersson KM, Owens DK, Vardas E, Gray GE, McIntyre JA, et al. (2007) Predicting the impact of a partially effective HIV vaccine and subsequent risk behavior change on the heterosexual HIV epidemic in low- and middle-income countries: A South African example. J Acquir Immune Defic Syndr 46: 78–90. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18. Crosby RA, Holtgrave DR (2006) Will sexual risk behaviour increase after being vaccinated for AIDS? Int J STD AIDS 17: 180–4. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19. Halloran ME, Longini IMJ, Haber MJ, Struchiner CJ, Brunet RC (1994) Exposure efficacy and change in contact rates in evaluating prophylactic HIV vaccines in the field. Stat Med 13: 357–77. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20. Mei S, Quax R, van de Vijver D, Zhu Y, Sloot PMA (2011) Increasing risk behaviour can outweigh the benefits of antiretroviral drug treatment on the HIV incidence among men-having-sex-with-men in Amsterdam. BMC Infectious Diseases 2011 11: 118. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21. Forster A, Wardle J, Stephenson J, Waller J (2010) Passport to promiscuity or lifesaver: press coverage of hpv vaccination and risky sexual behavior. J Health Commun 15: 205–17. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 22. Mirrlees JA (1999) The theory of moral hazard and unobservable behaviour: Part i. Review of Economic Studies 66: 321. [Google Scholar]
  • 23. Yang Y, Sugimoto J, Halloran M, Basta N, Chao D, et al. (2009) The transmissibility and control of pandemic inuenza A (H1N1) virus. Science 326(5953): 729–733. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24. Manski C (2010) Vaccination with partial knowledge of external effectiveness. PNAS 107 (44): 18753–18754. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 25. Medlock J, Galvani A (2009) Optimizing influenza vaccine distribution. Science 325(5948): 1705–1708. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 26. Kaplan E, Craft D, Wein L (2002) Emergency response to a smallpox attack: The case for mass vaccination. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 99(16): 10935–10940. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27. Grassly N, Fraser C (2008) Mathematical models of infectious disease transmission. Nature Reviews Microbiology 6: 477–487. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Newman M (2003) The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM Review 45.
  • 29.Jackson M, Yariv L (2010) Diffusion, strategic interaction, and social structure. In: The Handbook of Social Economics.
  • 30. Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2001) Epidemic spreading in scale-free networks. Phys Rev Lett 86: 3200–3203. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Dezso Z, Barabási A (2002) Halting viruses in scale-free networks. Physical Review E 65(5). [DOI] [PubMed]
  • 32. Lloyd AL, May RM (2001) How viruses spread among computers and people. Science 292(5520): 1316–1317. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33. Meyers L (2007) Contact network epidemiology: Bond percolation applied to infectious disease prediction and control. Bull Amer Math Soc 44: 63–86. [Google Scholar]
  • 34. Meyers L, Pourbohloul B, Newman M, Skowronski D, Brunham R (2005) Network theory and SARS: Predicting outbreak diversity. J Theor Biol 232(1): 71–81. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Newman M (2002) Spread of epidemic disease on networks. Phys Rev E 66(1). [DOI] [PubMed]
  • 36. Wang Y, Xiao G, Hu J, Cheng T, Wang L (2009) Imperfect targeted immunization in scale-free networks. Physica A 388 (12): 2535–2546. [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Ganesh A, Massoulie L, Towsley D (2005) The effect of network topology on the spread of epidemics. In: Proceeding of INFOCOM.
  • 38.Consumers dont relate bot infections to risky behavior as millions continue to click on spam. Available: www.maawg.org/consumers-don%E2%80%99t-relate-bot-infections-risky-behavior-millions-continue-click-s. Accessed 2013 May 27.
  • 39.Blower S, Koelle K, Mills J (2002) Health policy modeling: epidemic control, HIV vaccines and risky behavior. In: Quantitative Evaluation of HIV Prevention Programs, Yale University Press.
  • 40.Volz E, Meyers L (2008) Epidemic thresholds in dynamic contact networks. Journal of the Royal Society Interface. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 41. Barabási A, Albert R (1999) Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286: 509–512. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 42. Erdös P, Rényi A (1960) On the evolution of random graphs. Publications of the Mathematical Institute of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences 5: 17–61. [Google Scholar]
  • 43. Berger N, Borgs C, Chayes J, Saberi A (2005) On the spread of viruses on the internet. In: Proceedings of ACM SODA 2005: 301–310. [Google Scholar]
  • 44.Rajaraman R, Sun Z, Sundaram R, Vullikanti AKS (2012) Network effects of risk behavior change following prophylactic interventions in locally-finite graphs. Technical report, Virginia Bioinformatics Institute, Virginia Tech.
  • 45.Bollobas B, Riordan O (2006) Percolation. Cambridge University Press.
  • 46. Fraser C, Donnelly CA, Cauchemez S, Hanage WP, Kerkhove MDV, et al. (2009) Pandemic potential of a strain of influenza a (h1n1): Early findings. Science 324(5934): 1557–1561. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 47. Chowell G, Nishiura H, Bettencourt L (2007) Comparative estimation of the reproduction number for pandemic inuenza from daily case notification data. J Royal Society Interface 4(12): 155–166. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 48. Vynnycky E, Trindall A, Mangtani P (2007) Estimates of the reproduction numbers of spanish inuenza using morbidity data. International Journal of Epidemiology 36(4): 881–889. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Soderberg B (2002) A general formalism for inhomogeneous random graphs. Phys Rev E 66(6). [DOI] [PubMed]
  • 50.Barrett C, Beckman R, Khan M, Kumar VA, Marathe M, et al.. (2009) Generation and analysis of large synthetic social contact networks. In: Rossetti MD, Hill RR, Johansson B, Dunkin A, Ingalls RG, editors, Proceedings of the 2009 Winter Simulation Conference.
  • 51.Klimt B, Yang Y (2004) Introducing the enron corpus. In: CEAS.
  • 52.Enron email network. Available: http://snap.stanford.edu/data/email-enron.html. Accessed 2013 May 27.
  • 53. Ripeanu M, Foster I, Iamnitchi A (2002) Mapping the gnutella network: Properties of large-scale peer-to-peer systems and implications for system design. IEEE Internet Computing Journal 6(1): 50–57. [Google Scholar]
  • 54.Gnutella peer-to-peer network. Available: http://snap.stanford.edu/data/p2p-gnutella04.html. Accessed 2013 May 27.

Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES