Skip to main content
PLOS One logoLink to PLOS One
. 2013 Aug 5;8(8):e69580. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0069580

Distance to the Scaling Law: A Useful Approach for Unveiling Relationships between Crime and Urban Metrics

Luiz G A Alves 1, Haroldo V Ribeiro 1,*, Ervin K Lenzi 1, Renio S Mendes 1
Editor: Matjaz Perc2
PMCID: PMC3734155  PMID: 23940525

Abstract

We report on a quantitative analysis of relationships between the number of homicides, population size and ten other urban metrics. By using data from Brazilian cities, we show that well-defined average scaling laws with the population size emerge when investigating the relations between population and number of homicides as well as population and urban metrics. We also show that the fluctuations around the scaling laws are log-normally distributed, which enabled us to model these scaling laws by a stochastic-like equation driven by a multiplicative and log-normally distributed noise. Because of the scaling laws, we argue that it is better to employ logarithms in order to describe the number of homicides in function of the urban metrics via regression analysis. In addition to the regression analysis, we propose an approach to correlate crime and urban metrics via the evaluation of the distance between the actual value of the number of homicides (as well as the value of the urban metrics) and the value that is expected by the scaling law with the population size. This approach has proved to be robust and useful for unveiling relationships/behaviors that were not properly carried out by the regression analysis, such as Inline graphic the non-explanatory potential of the elderly population when the number of homicides is much above or much below the scaling law, Inline graphic the fact that unemployment has explanatory potential only when the number of homicides is considerably larger than the expected by the power law, and Inline graphic a gender difference in number of homicides, where cities with female population below the scaling law are characterized by a number of homicides above the power law.

Introduction

The study of social complex systems has been the focus of intense research in the last decades [1][3]. Elections [4], [5], population growth [6], [7], economy [8][10], and language [11][13] are just a few examples of social activities that have been recently investigated. Such investigations are expected to provide a better understanding of how our society is organized and also to point out better strategies for resource management, service allocation, and political strategies. In this social context, crime is one of the most worrying activity for our society and to understand and to prevent crime acts is a huge challenge [14][16]. Moreover, since nowadays more than a half of the human population lives in cities [17], [18], it is crucial to analyze possible connections between criminality and urban metrics.

In fact, there exist several works that point out relationships between the number of crime acts and urban indicators such as income, unemployment and inequality [19][23]. Most of these papers employ regression analysis, where the dependent variable is the crime indicator (usually the number of a particular crime act) and the independent variables are urban indicators [24][33]. However, most of these studies does not take into account the functional form of the relationships between crime, urban indicators and the population; usually assuming these relationships to be linear [34]. On the other hand, several works have shown that crime and urban indicators obey scaling laws with the population size of the cities and also between themselves [35][39]. For instance, the number of homicides grows super-linearly with the population [39], [40]. Do not consider these scaling laws may be one of the reasons that several regression-based analysis led to controversial conclusions [34]. Furthermore, if we assume that these scaling laws with the population size are somehow a natural expression of how cities are organized, accounting for the scaling phenomenon is also very important for achieving a fairer comparison between cities with different population sizes.

Here we investigate a procedure that may help to solve this problem. The approach consists of defining a “distance” between the crime or urban indicators and the main tendency expected by the scaling laws with the population size. This approach is based on the recent idea of relative competitiveness proposed by Podobnik et al. [41] in the economic context. Our paper is thus organized as follows. We start by presenting our data of urban and crime indicators of Brazilian cities and also an intensive characterization of the scaling laws existing between these indicators and the population size. We also employ a linear regression model for explaining the number of crime acts (homicides) in terms of the urban indicators. Next, we use the previously-discussed distance in an attempt to investigate relationships/patterns between crime and urban metrics that do not appear in the regression analysis. Finally, we present a summary of our results.

Materials and Methods

Data presentation

We have accessed data of the Brazilian cities in the year of 2000 made freely available by the Brazil's public healthcare system – DATASUS [42]. These data are also attached to our paper in Table S1. Here, despite there being other definitions [43], we have considered that cities are the smallest administrative units with a local government and it is not our intention to discuss the role of other definitions. The data consist of the population size (Inline graphic) and the number of homicides (Inline graphic) as well as ten urban indicators (Inline graphic) at city level: number of cases of child labour, elderly population size (older than 60 years), female population size, gross domestic product (GDP), GDP per capita, number of illiterate (older than 15 years), average family income, male population size, number of sanitation facilities, and number of unemployed (older than 16 year). More details about urban indicators can be found in Text S1. Observe that we have chosen the number of homicides as our crime indicator. This is a widely used choice [39] due the fact that homicide data are more reliable, since this ultimate expression of violence is almost always reported. Also, our ten urban indicators are usually listed as crime determinants [34]. Furthermore, we have considered only cities with at least one case of homicide in our analysis.

Results and Discussion

Scaling laws between crime, urban metrics and population

We start by revising the question of whether homicides and urban metrics present scaling relations with the population size (see also Refs. [35][40]). For the sake of simplicity, let us denote the population size by Inline graphic and the urban indicators by Inline graphic. We thus want to check if Inline graphic is a power law function of Inline graphic, that is, Inline graphic, where Inline graphic is the power law exponent. Figure 1 shows a scatter plot of Inline graphic versus Inline graphic for all urban indicators, starting with the number of homicides and passing through all the ten urban metrics. We note that, despite the existence of considerable noise in some relationships, the scaling laws with the population size are perceptible. In order to overcome the noise and uncover the main tendency in these relationships, we have binned the data in Inline graphic windows equally spaced in Inline graphic and evaluated the average values of the points within each window. The square symbols shown in Fig. 1 represent these average values and the dashed lines are linear fits. Note that linear functions describe quite well all the average relations, that is, the equation

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e033.jpg (1)

holds for all the urban indicators. Here, Inline graphic is the average value of Inline graphic within each one of the Inline graphic windows, Inline graphic is a constant and Inline graphic is the power law exponent (shown in Fig. 1). We have thus confirmed that there are scaling laws between the average values of the urban indicators Inline graphic and the population Inline graphic. It is worth to remark that these average relationships are very robust when varying the number of windows Inline graphic (see Fig. S1).

Figure 1. Scaling laws between the population size and the urban indicators.

Figure 1

In each plot, the green dots are base-10 logarithmic of the values of the urban indicator (Inline graphic) versus the population size (Inline graphic) for a given city. The black squares are average values of the data binned in 10 equally spaced windows and the error bars are 95% confidence intervals for these average values obtained via bootstrapping [44]. The values of the Pearson correlation coefficients Inline graphic (as well as the 95% confidence intervals) of these relationships are shown in each plot. The straight dashed lines are linear fits (by least square method) to the average relationships and the slope of these lines are equal to the power law exponent Inline graphic (shown in each plot).

Another striking feature of Fig. 1 is the fluctuation around the power law tendency. We have observed that the standard deviation

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e050.jpg (2)

within each window practically does not change with the population size Inline graphic for all urban indicators (Fig. 2A). We have also verified that the normalized residuals around the power law,

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e052.jpg (3)

are normally distributed with zero mean and unitary standard deviation (Fig. 2B). In particular, the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test [45] cannot reject the normality of Inline graphic for all the urban indicators (the Inline graphic-values are all larger than 0.51).

Figure 2. Fluctuations around the scaling laws.

Figure 2

(A) Standard deviation Inline graphic of the fluctuations around the scaling laws (in base-10 logarithmic scale) in each one of the Inline graphic equally spaced windows. We note that the standard deviation is almost a constant function of the population for all urban indicators. The average value of Inline graphic over the population windows are shown in the plot legends. (B) Cumulative distributions of the normalized fluctuations Inline graphic around the scaling laws. In this plot, each gray line is a distribution for a given indicator, the squares are the average values of these cumulative distributions and the error bars are 95% confidence intervals obtained via bootstrapping [44]. We note that the Gaussian distribution (dashed line) describes quite well these distributions. In particular, the smallest Inline graphic-value of the Kolmogorov-Smirnov tests is Inline graphic, showing that we cannot reject the normality of the fluctuations.

Our previous analysis thus enable an elegant formulation to the average scaling laws and also to the noise around these tendencies. Mathematically, we can write

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e055.jpg (4)

or, equivalently

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e056.jpg (5)

where Inline graphic and Inline graphic. Notice that, since Inline graphic is normally distributed, Inline graphic should be distributed according to a log-normal distribution. In addition to describe the average scaling laws, Eq. (4) represents a stochastic-like process where the urban indicator Inline graphic follows a power law relation with the population Inline graphic driven by a multiplicative noise log-normally distributed.

Regression model: homicides versus urban metrics

As we have mentioned in the introduction, a considerable part of the literature about criminality tries to correlate crime indicators to other urban metrics. Usually, these relationships are obtained from linear regression models, despite the explicit nonlinearities present in these variables such as the previous scaling laws. In this context, it is not uncommon to observe linear regression-based analysis leading to controversial conclusions [34]. A simple alternative that may overcome these nonlinearities is to employ the logarithmic of the variables, that is,

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e063.jpg (6)

Here, Inline graphic is the number of homicides in the city Inline graphic, Inline graphic is the Inline graphic-th (Inline graphic) urban indicator of the city Inline graphic, Inline graphic is the intercept coefficient, Inline graphic (Inline graphic) is the linear coefficient that quantifies the explicative effect of Inline graphic, and Inline graphic is the noise term accounting for the effect of unmeasurable factors.

We have applied the previous model to our data by using ordinary least-squares fit with a correction to heteroskedasticity [46] and the results are summarized in Table 1. We first note that, except for sanitation and unemployment, all the urban indicators have explanatory potential for describing the number of homicides. Also, the value of the adjusted Inline graphic points out that the model account for about 62% of the observed variance in number of homicides. When analyzing the individual effects of the urban indicators, we note that child labour, elderly population, female population, GDP per capita, and male population are negatively correlated with the number of homicides (Inline graphic decreases with the increasing of these indicators). On the other hand, GDP, illiteracy, and income are positively correlated with the number of homicides (Inline graphic increases with the increasing of these indicators). Despite the lack of a more adequate comparison with our data, our regression results agree but also disagree with some empirical findings of the criminology literature. For instance, we have found that there is no statistically significant correlation between unemployment and homicides, while a positive and statistically significant correlation between illiteracy and homicides was observed. However, these indicators are among those leading to controversial conclusions, as pointed out by Gordon [34].

Table 1. Regression model coefficients.

k Indicator Yk Coefficient Ck Standard Error t p>|t|
95% Confidence Interval
Gray 0 Intercept 322.932 84.653 3.81 0.000
Gray [156.944, 488.920]
1 Child labour −0.146 0.035 −4.11 0.000
[−0.216, −0.076]
Gray 2 Elderly population −0.647 0.066 −9.81 0.000
Gray [−0.777, −0.518]
3 Female population −56.644 15.488 −3.66 0.000
[−87.015, −26.274]
Gray 4 GDP 121.127 31.375 3.86 0.000
Gray [59.605, 182.648]
5 GDP per capita −120.987 31.375 −3.86 0.000
[−182.509, −59.465]
Gray 6 Illiteracy 0.213 0.051 4.11 0.000
Gray [0.111, 0.314]
7 Income 0.223 0.073 3.05 0.002
[0.079, 0.367]
Gray 8 Male population −62.459 16.068 −3.89 0.000
Gray [−93.967, −30.952]
9 Sanitation −0.665 0.929 −0.72 0.474
[−2.487, 1.156]
Gray 10 Unemployment −0.026 0.028 −0.94 0.347
Gray [−0.082, 0.028]
Adjusted R2 = 0.62

Values of the linear coefficients Inline graphic obtained via ordinary least-squares fits with a correction to heteroskedasticity. Here, Inline graphic is the value of the Inline graphic-statistic and Inline graphic is the two-tail Inline graphic-value for testing the hypothesis that the coefficient Inline graphic is different from zero.

Naturally, our regression model is quite simple and several improvements are possible. For instance, some of these metrics may display correlations and, consequently, one metric may affect the predicability of another, a phenomenon known as mediation [47]. A possible manner for reducing this effect is by combining some of the metrics and running different regression models. Another possibility is to employ principal component analysis (PCA) for reducing redundancy among the urban metrics. Nevertheless, other problems such as bias in the selection of urban metrics and difficulties in drawing qualitative conclusions in terms of the PCA axis are still present. Here, instead of discussing the possible controversies that Table 1 may exhibit as well as possible manner of improving our regression results, we will compare this simple regression analysis with our new approach based on the deviations of the scaling laws.

A relative metric: distance to the scaling laws

In addition to overcome the nonlinearities by employing the logarithmic of the urban indicators, we may also account for the scaling behavior between the urban indicators, homicides and the population size (Fig. 1) aiming a fairer comparison between cities with different population sizes. We thus have proposed to evaluate the differences between the actual value of the urban indicators and the expected by the adjusted power law, that is,

graphic file with name pone.0069580.e078.jpg
graphic file with name pone.0069580.e079.jpg (7)

Note that Inline graphic identifies whether a urban indicator for the given city is above (Inline graphic) or below (Inline graphic) the average scaling law as well as how far it is. We have also evaluated this distance for the number of homicides, that is, Inline graphic (note that we are committing an abuse of terminology when denoting Inline graphic as a distance). This is the same idea recently proposed by Podobnik et al. [41] for quantifying the competitiveness among countries.

We have thus studied the relations between the distance evaluated from the homicide indicator (Inline graphic) and the other urban metrics (Inline graphic). Figure 3 shows a scatter plot of Inline graphic versus Inline graphic, where we note that all of the urban metrics distances (except unemployment) have statistically significant correlations with the homicide distance (see the values of Pearson correlation Inline graphic in these plots). We have also observed that the sign of the correlation coefficient Inline graphic agrees with value of the linear coefficient Inline graphic for the indicators child labour, elderly population, female population, GDP, income, sanitation, and unemployment. However, for the indicators GDP per capita, illiteracy and male population, the sign of Inline graphic is opposite to the signal of Inline graphic. This result means, for instance, that while the regression analysis suggests that the increase in the male population is followed by a decrease in the number of homicides, the results when considering the relative distances point out that the more the male population is above the power law tendency, the more the number of homicides is above the power law tendency. Similar controversial conclusions are obtained for the indicators GDP per capita and illiteracy.

Figure 3. Distance to the scaling laws evaluated for the urban indicators versus the distance evaluated for the number of homicides.

Figure 3

Scatter plot of the distances to the scaling laws evaluated for the urban indicators (Inline graphic) versus the distance evaluated for the number of homicides (Inline graphic). The color code represents the density of points, going from blue (low density) to red (hight density). We show in each plot the value and the 95% confidence intervals for the Pearson correlation coefficient Inline graphic. We note that Inline graphic evaluated for GDP, GDP per capita, income, and male population are positively correlated with Inline graphic, while Inline graphic related to child labour, elderly population, female population, illiteracy, sanitation, and unemployment are negatively correlated with Inline graphic. We further observe the bimodal distributions of the relationships for GDP, GDP per capita, illiteracy, and income.

In addition to the value of the Pearson correlation Inline graphic, the scatter plots in Fig. 3 reveals other intriguing patterns. We note that the relation between the homicide distance and the indicators GDP, GDP per capita, illiteracy, and income are characterized by two peaks in the density of points, while for all the other indicators the density of points displays only one peak. We also note that both peaks of these bimodal distributions are located around Inline graphic. This result indicates that, despite the positive values of Inline graphic, there is a considerable number of cities that displays distance values for Inline graphic above and below the power law tendency with approximately the same value for the distance Inline graphic, suggesting that such indicators may not be as good as the other ones for describing the number of homicides.

Another manner of extracting meaningful information from Fig. 3 is by evaluating average values. In order to do so, we have grouped the cities in two sets: those having Inline graphic (homicides above the power law) and those with Inline graphic (homicides below the power law). We next evaluate the average value of Inline graphic for each group and considering the cities with absolute value of Inline graphic larger than a threshold Inline graphic. Figure 4 shows these average values as a function of the threshold Inline graphic. We have observed that for the indicators child labour, illiteracy and sanitation, the average values of Inline graphic are significantly different between the two groups of cities and also that the average of Inline graphic increases as Inline graphic increases for the cities with Inline graphic and decreases for those ones with Inline graphic. The opposite occurs for the indicators GDP, GDP per capita and income, that is, the average of Inline graphic decreases as Inline graphic increases for the cities with Inline graphic and increases for those ones with Inline graphic. Intriguingly, for the indicator elderly population we observe that cities with Inline graphic below the power law present an average value of Inline graphic larger than those with Inline graphic above the power law; however, this difference is only statistically significant for Inline graphic. This result suggests that, for cities having a much larger or much smaller number of homicides than the expected by the power law tendency, the elderly population may have no explanatory potential. Similarly, for the unemployment indicator, no difference is observed between the average values of Inline graphic above and below the power law until Inline graphic. For slightly smaller value of Inline graphic, the average value of Inline graphic (for unemployment) for cities above the power law starts to systematically decrease and for Inline graphic a statistically significant difference is observed. This result thus provides us a clue for a better understanding of the explicative potential of the unemployment indicator, by pointing out that (in our data) its effect is only manifested when Inline graphic is much above of the value expected by the scaling law.

Figure 4. Average values of the distances to the scaling laws versus the homicide distance threshold.

Figure 4

The average values of distances evaluated for each urban indicator in function of the homicide distance threshold Inline graphic, after grouping the cities that are above (red continuous lines) and below (blue dashed lines) the scaling laws with the population size. The shaded areas are 95% confidence intervals for these average values obtained via bootstrapping [44].

Figure 4 also provides clues of a gender effect in the number of homicides. For female population, we note that cities with number of homicides above the power law (Inline graphic) are characterized by an average value of Inline graphic that decreases as the value of Inline graphic increases. We also observe that the confidence intervals for the average values of Inline graphic above and below the power law barely overlap each other. These results thus point out that in cities where the number of homicides is above the expected value, the female population is systematically smaller than the value expected by the scaling law. For male population, despite the overlapping in the confidence intervals for the average of Inline graphic, we observe an opposite behavior, that is, cities with number of homicides above the power law are also characterized by a male population above the power law.

Summary and Conclusions

We have extensively characterized some relationships between crime and urban metrics. We have initially shown that urban indicators obey well defined average scaling laws with the population size and also that the fluctuations around these tendencies are log-normally distributed. Using these results, we have shown that the scaling laws can be represented by a multiplicative stochastic-like equation (Eq. 4) driven by a log-normal noise. Next, we have addressed the problem of applying regression analysis for explaining the number of homicides Inline graphic in terms of urban indicators Inline graphic. Because of the intrinsic nonlinearities, we have argued that it is better to employ the logarithms of these variables when performing linear regression analysis (Eq. 4 and Table 1). Furthermore, we have also discussed that accounting for the scaling phenomenon is also important for a fairer comparison among cities with different population sizes. We have thus proposed to evaluate the distances between the actual number of homicides Inline graphic (Inline graphic) as well as the value of the urban indicator Inline graphic (Inline graphic) and the one expected by the average scaling laws. By investigating the Pearson correlations (Inline graphic) of the relationships between Inline graphic and Inline graphic, we have found that the value of Inline graphic have the same signal of the linear coefficient Inline graphic for the indicators child labour, elderly population, female population, GDP, income, sanitation, and unemployment. On the other hand, for GDP per capita, illiteracy and male population the signal of Inline graphic and Inline graphic are opposite. In addition to the values of Inline graphic, we have analyzed the average values of Inline graphic after grouping the cities in two sets: those with number of homicides above the power law (Inline graphic) and those below the power law (Inline graphic). This analysis has unveiled intriguing patterns that were not carried out by the linear regression. In particular, our results for Brazilian cities pointed out that Inline graphic the elderly population may have no explanatory potential when the number of homicides is much above or much below of the expected values by the scaling law, Inline graphic that the effect of unemployment in the number of homicides is only observed for cities with Inline graphic considerably larger than the expected by the power law, and Inline graphic that there are gender differences in the number of homicides, where cities with female population below the expected value are characterized by a number of homicides above the power law and that cities with number of homicides above the power law are also characterized by a male population above the power law. We further believe that the present approach can be applied to other datasets in order to produce more robust relationships between crime indicators and urban metrics.

Supporting Information

Figure S1

Robustness of the power law exponent versus the number of windows employed in the average relationships. The value of power law exponent Inline graphic versus the number of windows Inline graphic employed to evaluate the average relationships between Inline graphic and Inline graphic. The error bars are 95% confidence intervals for the value of Inline graphic and the horizontal red lines are the average values of Inline graphic over Inline graphic. We note the almost constant behavior of Inline graphic in function of Inline graphic.

(TIF)

Table S1

Data used in our analysis. This comma separated file (CSV) has 13 columns where the first one contains the names of the cities and the other columns contains the urban metrics used here. The first line is a header indicating the urban metrics.

(CSV)

Text S1

Details about the urban indicators used here.

(PDF)

Funding Statement

This work has been supported by the agencies Conselho Nacional de Desenvolvimento Cientifico e Tecnologico, Coordenacao de Aperfeicoamento de Pessoal de Nivel Superior, and Fundacao Araucaria. HVR is especially grateful to Fundacao Araucaria for financial support under grant number 113/2013. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1. Amaral LAN, Ottino JM (2004) Augmenting the framework for the study of complex systems. The European Physical Journal B 38: 147–162. [Google Scholar]
  • 2. Castellano C, Fortunato S, Loreto V (2009) Statistical physics of social dynamics. Reviews of Modern Physics 81: 591–646. [Google Scholar]
  • 3. Conte R, Gilbert N, Bonelli G, Cioff-Revilla C, Deffuant G, et al. (2012) Manifesto of computa-tional social science. The European Physical Journal Special Topics 214: 325–346. [Google Scholar]
  • 4. Mantovani MC, Ribeiro HV, Moro MV, Picoli Jr S, Mendes RS (2011) Scaling laws and univer-sality in the choice of election candidates. Europhysics Letters 96: 48001. [Google Scholar]
  • 5. Chatterjee A, Mitrović M, Fortunato S (2013) Universality in voting behavior: an empirical analysis. Scientific Reports 3: 1049. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6. Rozenfeld HD, Rybski D, Andrade Jr JS, Batty M, Stanley HE, et al. (2008) Laws of population growth. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences U. S. A. 105: 1870218707. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7. Rybski D, Buldyrev SV, Havlin S, Liljeros F, Makse HA (2009) Scaling laws of human interaction activity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences U. S. A. 106: 1264012645. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8. Stanley MHR, Amaral LAN, Buldyrev SV, Havlin S, Leschhorn H, et al. (1996) Scaling behaviour in the growth of companies. Nature 379: 804–806. [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Mantegna RN, Stanley HE (2007) Introduction to Econophysics: Correlations and Complexity in Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • 10. Peron TKD, Costa LF, Rodrigues FA (2012) The structure and resilience of financial market networks. Chaos 22: 013117. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11. Wichmann S (2008) The emerging field of language dynamics. Language and Linguistics Compass 2: 442–455. [Google Scholar]
  • 12. Petersen AM, Tenenbaum J, Havlin S, Stanley HE (2012) Statistical laws governing fluctuations in word use from word birth to word death, Scientific Reports. 2: 313. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13. Amancio DR, Oliveira Jr ON, Costa LF (2012) Unveiling the relationship between complex net-works metrics and word senses. Europhysics Letters 98: 18002. [Google Scholar]
  • 14. Kates RW, Parris TM (2003) Long-term trends and a sustainability transition. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences U. S. A. 100: 8062–8067. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15. Gordon MB, Iglesias JR, Semeshenko V, Nadal JP (2009) Crime and punishment: the economic burden of impunity. The European Physical Journal B 68: 133–144. [Google Scholar]
  • 16. Iglesias JR, Semeshenko V, Scheneider EM, Gordon MB (2012) Crime and punishment: does it pay to punish? Physica A 391: 3942–3950. [Google Scholar]
  • 17. Crane P, Kinzig A (2005) Nature in the metropolis. Science 308: 1225. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.World Resources Institute website. Available: http://www.wri.org. Accessed 2013 Feb 1.
  • 19. Becker GS (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. Journal of Political Economy 76: 169–217. [Google Scholar]
  • 20. Ehrlich I (1975) The deterrent effect of capital punishment: a question of life and death. The American Economic Review 65: 397–417. [Google Scholar]
  • 21. Ehrlich I (1996) Crime, punishment, and the market for offenses. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10: 43–67. [Google Scholar]
  • 22. Glaeser EL, Sacerdote B, Scheinkman JA (1996) Crime and social interactions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 111: 507–548. [Google Scholar]
  • 23. Glaeser EL, Sacerdote B (1999) Why is there more crime in cities? Journal of Political Economy 107: S225–S258. [Google Scholar]
  • 24. Blau JR, Blau PM (1982) The cost of inequality: metropolitan structure and violent crime. American Sociological Review 47: 114–129. [Google Scholar]
  • 25. Bailey W (1984) Poverty, inequality and homicide rates. Criminology 22: 531–550. [Google Scholar]
  • 26. Levitt SD (1997) Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. The American Economic Review 87: 270–290. [Google Scholar]
  • 27. Kennedy BP, Kawachi I, Prothrow-Stith D, Lochner K, Gupta V (1998) Social capital, income inequality, and firearm violent crime. Social Science & Medicine. 47: 7–17. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28. Kelly M (2000) Inequality and crime. The Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 530–539. [Google Scholar]
  • 29. Levitt SD (2001) Alternative strategies for identifying the link between unemployment and crime. Journal of Quantitative Criminology 17: 377–390. [Google Scholar]
  • 30. Hojman DE (2002) Explaining crime in Buenos Aires: the roles of inequality, unemployment, and structural change. Bulletin of Latin American Research 21: 121–128. [Google Scholar]
  • 31. Hojman DE (2004) Inequality, unemployment and crime in Latin American cities. Crime, Law & Social Change 41: 33–51. [Google Scholar]
  • 32. Sachsida A, Mendonça MJC, Loureiro PRA, Gutierrez MBS (2010) Inequality and criminality revisited: further evidence from Brazil. Empirical Economics 39: 93–109. [Google Scholar]
  • 33. Poveda AC (2012) Violence and economic development in Colombian cities: a dynamic panel data analysis. Journal of International Development 24: 809–827. [Google Scholar]
  • 34. Gordon MB (2010) A random walk in the literature on criminality: a partial and critical view on some statistical analysis and modelling approaches. European Journal of Applied Mathematics 21: 283–306. [Google Scholar]
  • 35. Bettencourt LMA, Lobo J, Helbing D, Kuhnert C, West GB (2007) Growth, innovation, scaling, and the pace of life in cities. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences U. S. A. 104: 7301–7306. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 36. Bettencourt LMA, Lobo J, West GB (2008) Why are large cities faster? Universal scaling and self-similarity in urban organizations and dynamics. The European Physical Journal B 63: 285–293. [Google Scholar]
  • 37. Bettencourt LMA, West GB (2010) A unified theory of urban living. Nature 467: 912–913. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 38. Bettencourt LMA, Lobo J, Strumsky D, West GB (2010) Urban scaling and its deviations: re-vealing the structure of wealth, innovation and crime across cities. PLoS ONE 5: e13541. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39. Gomez-Lievano A, Youn H, Bettencourt LMA (2012) The statistics of urban scaling and their connections to Zipf's law. PLoS ONE 7: e40393. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Alves LGA, Ribeiro HV, Mendes RS (2013) Scaling laws in the dynamics of crime growth rate. Physica A: 10.1016/j.physa.2013.02.002.
  • 41. Podobnik B, Horvatic D, Kenett DY, Stanley HE (2012) The competitiveness versus the wealth of a country. Scientific Reports 2: 678. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Brazil's Public healthcare System (SUS), Department of Data Processing (DATASUS). Available: http://www.datasus.gov.br/. Accessed 2013 Feb 1.
  • 43.Angel S, Sheppard CS, Civco DL, Buckley P, Chabaeva A, et al.. (2005) The Dynamics of Global Urban Expansion. Washington DC: World Bank.
  • 44.Efron B, Tibshirani R (1993) An Introduction to the Bootstrap. New York: Chapman & Hall.
  • 45.Corder GW, Foreman DI (2009), Nonparametric Statistics for non-Statisticians: a Step-by-Step Approach. New Jersey: Wiley.
  • 46.Davidson R, MacKinnon JG (1993) Estimation and Inference in Econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press.
  • 47. Preacher KJ, Hayes AF (2008) Asymptotic and resampling strategies for assessing and comparing indirect effects in multiple mediator models. Behavior Research Methods 40: 879–891. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Figure S1

Robustness of the power law exponent versus the number of windows employed in the average relationships. The value of power law exponent Inline graphic versus the number of windows Inline graphic employed to evaluate the average relationships between Inline graphic and Inline graphic. The error bars are 95% confidence intervals for the value of Inline graphic and the horizontal red lines are the average values of Inline graphic over Inline graphic. We note the almost constant behavior of Inline graphic in function of Inline graphic.

(TIF)

Table S1

Data used in our analysis. This comma separated file (CSV) has 13 columns where the first one contains the names of the cities and the other columns contains the urban metrics used here. The first line is a header indicating the urban metrics.

(CSV)

Text S1

Details about the urban indicators used here.

(PDF)


Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES