Skip to main content
Elsevier Sponsored Documents logoLink to Elsevier Sponsored Documents
. 2013 Sep;32(5):922–937. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2013.07.001

Longitudinal methods to investigate the role of health determinants in the dynamics of income-related health inequality

Paul Allanson a,, Dennis Petrie a,b
PMCID: PMC3794167  PMID: 24036199

Abstract

The usual starting point for understanding changes in income-related health inequality (IRHI) over time has been regression-based decomposition procedures for the health concentration index. However the reliance on repeated cross-sectional analysis for this purpose prevents both the appropriate specification of the health function as a dynamic model and the identification of important determinants of the transition processes underlying IRHI changes such as those relating to mortality. This paper overcomes these limitations by developing alternative longitudinal procedures to analyse the role of health determinants in driving changes in IRHI through both morbidity changes and mortality, with our dynamic modelling framework also serving to identify their contribution to long-run or structural IRHI. The approach is illustrated by an empirical analysis of the causes of the increase in IRHI in Great Britain between 1999 and 2004.

Keywords: Health inequality, Health determinants, Income-related health mobility, Longitudinal data, Great Britain

1. Introduction

Significant socioeconomic inequalities in health have persisted, or even increased, in many European countries despite considerable improvements in average health (Van Doorslaer and Koolman, 2004; Kunst et al., 2005), leading governments to recognise the need to tackle health inequalities. For example, England committed to reduce socioeconomic inequalities in both infant mortality and life expectancy at birth (Department of Health, 2008). Marmot (2010) argues that such goals cannot be achieved through health policies and health care systems alone but will require action across all the socioeconomic determinants of health because health inequalities are caused by social and economic inequalities in society. It is therefore important to understand how wider changes in socioeconomic conditions impact on health inequalities in order to shape the design of an effective set of public policies to tackle the issue.

There is a considerable body of work in health economics on socioeconomic health inequalities and their determinants (O’Donnell et al., 2008), which focuses primarily on income-related health inequality (IRHI). The main measure of IRHI within this literature is the concentration index (CI), which captures the extent to which good health in any period is concentrated among the rich compared to the poor and is equal to twice the covariance between health and income rank normalised by average health. However the value of this simple bivariate measure is determined not only by the direct relationship between income and health but also by other factors, such as age, gender and lifestyle choices, to the extent that they affect health and are correlated with income. This has led to the development of cross-sectional regression-based decomposition techniques to identify the contribution of inequalities in the individual determinants of health to overall health inequality (see Gravelle, 2003, for an exposition).

This methodology has subsequently been extended to identify the source of changes in IRHI in a population over time by comparing the decompositions from repeated cross-sectional surveys (see, e.g., Wagstaff et al., 2003; Gravelle and Sutton, 2003). In particular, Wagstaff et al. (2003) propose a ‘total differential’ decomposition of the change in the cross-sectional CI between two periods that serves to reveal the contributions of changes not only in the distribution of the determinants of health across income classes but also in the cross-sectional effects of those determinants on health. However, while this type of comparative analysis can be helpful in identifying the determinants of changes in IRHI in a population over time, certain limitations compel a degree of caution. First, as is recognised in Wagstaff et al. (2003), the causal interpretation of the results is problematic because, among other things, the cross-sectional regression model estimates will generally be biased if the health function is dynamic rather than static.1 There is now considerable evidence of the state-dependence of health (see, e.g. Benzeval and Judge, 2001; Contoyannis et al., 2004), due to the persistence of health conditions, to suggest that dynamic models are more appropriate than static ones.2 Second, there are important aspects of the underlying determinants of IRHI changes that cannot be revealed by simply examining changes in cross-sectional relationships and inequalities. In particular, the repeated cross-sectional approach cannot be used to identify the effect of deaths on IRHI (Petrie et al., 2011) and hence the impact of the determinants of mortality on IRHI are also not separately identifiable.

The main aim of this paper is to establish alternative procedures, based on longitudinal or panel data, to investigate the socioeconomic determinants of the health transition process that in part drives changes in cross-sectional IRHI.3 The use of longitudinal data allows the analysis of changes in IRHI to be based on a regression model that captures both the dynamics of morbidity changes and mortality. Our dynamic modelling framework also generates a measure of steady-state or equilibrium health that provides the basis for a complementary analysis of the structural determinants of chronic or persistent IRHI.

Our starting point is the decomposition procedure in Petrie et al. (2011), which shows how the change in IRHI between two periods arises from a combination of changes in health outcomes (i.e. “income-related health mobility”) and changes in individuals’ positions in the income distribution (i.e. “health-related income mobility”). We briefly review this procedure in Section 2 before showing, in the main contribution of the current paper, how it can be expanded upon to explore the contributions from health determinants through the use of regression-based decomposition techniques analogous to those available in the literature for the CI (see Gravelle, 2003). Specifically, we first explain health changes in Section 3 by considering a Two-Part Model which accounts for both morbidity changes and mortality and then show in Section 4 how this may be used to further decompose income-related health mobility into the individual contributions of the various health determinants.4 In addition, we demonstrate how our dynamic modelling framework can also be used to analyse the health determinants of chronic or equilibrium IRHI. We employ our procedures in Section 5 to investigate the dynamics of IRHI in Great Britain over the five year period 1999 to 2004 using Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs). The final section discusses the contribution of the paper.

2. Review of methods to account for changes in IRHI using longitudinal data

Petrie et al. (2011) propose a decomposition procedure to identify the contributions of health changes and income re-ranking to changes in IRHI between two periods. This section briefly outlines their procedure in order to provide the basis for our subsequent analysis.

Assigning the dead a health status of zero5, Petrie et al. (2011) propose the following decomposition of the change in CI from an initial period s to a final period f:

CI˜ffhCIssh=(CI˜ffhCIfsh)+(CIfshCIssh)=MRMH (1)

where a tilde above a measure indicates that it is defined only over the sub-population in the initial period who survive to the final period ΩsΩf rather than the entire population in the initial period Ωs.6 Thus the CI in the initial period CIssh=2cov(his,Ris)/h¯s is defined over Ωs and is twice the covariance between individuals’ health his and fractional income rank Ris normalised by average health h¯s, whereas the CI in the final period CI˜ffh=2cov˜(hif,R˜if)/h¯˜f is analogously defined but only over the sub-set of individuals who survive to the final period ΩsΩf. Finally, CIfsh=2cov(hif,Ris)/h¯f is defined over Ωs as the CI of final period health hif with respect to initial period income ranks Ris.7

The index MR in (1) provides a measure of health-related income mobility, which captures the effect on IRHI changes of income reranking not only due to the re-shuffling of survivors within the income distribution, but also due to the loss of individuals from the population as a result of death (see Petrie et al., 2011, for further discussion). MH is interpreted as a measure of income-related health mobility, which captures the effect on IRHI changes of differences in relative health changes between individuals with different levels of initial income. For the rest of the paper we focus on explaining the determinants of income-related health mobility rather than health-related income mobility.

MH will be zero if relative health changes are unrelated to initial income rank and will be positive if health changes are equalising, which will be the case if the poor either enjoy a larger share of total health gains or suffer a smaller share of total health losses compared to their initial share of health. MH in turn depends on the progressivity and scale of health changes:

MH=Pq=CIsshCIfsΔhΔh¯fh¯f (2)

where CIfsΔh=2cov(Δhif,Ris)/Δh¯f is the CI of health changes Δhif = hif − his ranked by initial income, and Δh¯f is the average health change between the two periods. Progressivity is captured by the disproportionality index P=CIsshCIfsΔh, which will be positive if the poor experience a larger share of total net health changes than their initial share of health. For any given P, the gross redistributive effect MH is proportional to the scale of net health changes q=Δh¯f/h¯f. Note that positive values of P imply that health changes will be equalising for net health improvements and disequalising for net health deteriorations.

MH is defined over Ωs and therefore captures the effect on the CI of relative health changes due to both morbidity changes and mortality. To distinguish ex-post the impact of these two distinct health outcomes on income-related health mobility these health change types are denoted by the superscripts MB and MT, respectively, with their separate contributions to MH identified as:

MH=Pq=PMBqMB+PMTqMT=CIsshCIfsΔMBΔh¯fMBh¯f+CIsshCIfsΔMTΔh¯fMTh¯f (3)

where Δh¯f=Δh¯fMB+Δh¯fMT, with ΔhifMB set equal to the morbidity change for survivors and zero for those that die, and ΔhifMT defined as the loss of health due to mortality for those who die and zero for survivors; and CIfsΔMB and CIfsΔMT are the CIs of health changes due to morbidity changes and mortality, respectively.

Finally, we note that if there are no deaths then (1) yields the Allanson et al. (2010) decomposition:

CI˜ffhCI˜ssh=CI˜ffhCI˜fsh+CI˜fshCI˜ssh=M˜RCI˜sshCI˜fsΔhΔh¯˜fh¯˜f=M˜RP˜q˜=M˜RM˜H (4)

where not just CI˜ffh but also all other statistics have been defined over ΩsΩf, which will be identical to Ωs in this special case. More generally, (4) will prove useful in providing the basis for the analysis of the impact of morbidity changes on IRHI within the initial period sub-population that survive until the final period.8

In the following two sections we expand upon the Petrie et al. (2011) decomposition analysis by developing a regression-based decomposition procedure to identify the socioeconomic determinants of income-related health mobility. This is useful since MH is determined not only by the direct relationship between health changes and initial income but also by other factors that affect health mobility and are correlated with initial income.

3. Modelling the determinants of mortality and morbidity changes

To identify the socioeconomic determinants of MH, we first need a model which explains health changes due to both mortality and morbidity changes. We use a Two-Part Model (TPM; see Leung and Yu (1996) or Puhani (2000) for a discussion) for this purpose:

Si,t+1*=γ0+k=1Kγkxkit+γhhit+ϑi,t+1;ϑi,t+1N0,1; (5a)
Δhit+1=hit;if   Si,t+1*<0f(Δxki,t+1,xki,t,hit);if   Si,t+1*0iΩ1Ωt   for   t=1,...T1(5b)(5c)

which is defined over a T-period panel that is only unbalanced due to death and hence, in period t, comprises the subset of individuals Ω1Ωt remaining alive through to that period. The first part of the TPM, (5a), determines the probability of survival until period t + 1 as a function of health hit in the preceding period and a set of mortality risk factors xkit (k = 1,…,.K). This is assumed to take the form of a standard probit model, with the link between the value of the latent index variable Si,t+1* and observable survival status Si,t+1 following the rule that Si,t+1 = 1 (alive in period t + 1) if Si,t+1*0 and Si,t+1 = 0 (dead in period t + 1) otherwise. For those who die, the change in health Δhit+1 is equal to −hit in (5b) since their health status in period t + 1 is zero by definition. For those who survive, Δhit+1 is given by the dynamic health function fxki,t+1, xki,t, hit) in (5c), where it is plausible to assume that the set of morbidity determinants is the same as the survival function risk factors.9

To model the dynamic health changes of the surviving population we follow Hauck and Rice (2004) and Contoyannis et al. (2004), among others, in assuming the existence of a stable dynamic health function. We specify a similar but less restrictive health function that takes the form of a first-order autoregressive distributed lag model with fixed effects, which allows for both current and lagged effects of health determinants xk (k = 1,…K), health persistence and individual heterogeneity:10

hi,t+1=α0+k=1Kδkxki,t+1+k=1Kαkxkit+(1λ)hit+ηi,t+1;iΩ1Ωt+1;t=1,,T1 (6)

which is defined over an unbalanced panel that in period t comprises the subset of the original population who survive until at least the following period; and where ηi,t+1 = λμi + ɛi,t+1 is an error term, composed of a fixed individual effect λμi and a period specific disturbance ηi,t+1. Eq. (6) may also usefully be expressed in the form of an Error Correction Model (ECM) of the change in health:

Δhi,t+1=k=1KδkΔxki,t+1+λhit*hit+εi,t+1 (7)

where

hit*=β0+k=1Kβkxkit+μi (8)

may be interpreted as a long-run steady-state or equilibrium health function with parameters β0=α0/λ and βk=αk+δk/λ, such that hit*hit corresponds to the ‘equilibrium error’ in period t and λ   0λ1 determines the rate of adjustment towards equilibrium. Hence, the change in health depends on the effects of contemporaneous changes in the determinants, the initial extent of any disequilibrium in health and the size of the idiosyncratic health shock. Eq. (6) collapses to the static model hi,t+1=hi,t+1*+εi,t+1 if there are no lagged effects of health determinants and full adjustment/no persistence in health (i.e. if the αk s (k = 1,…,K) all equal zero and λ = 1).

ECMs are applicable to stationary, as well as co-integrated non-stationary, series where changes in exogenous factors have differing short and long-term effects or there is persistence of shocks (see Castle et al., 2010; De Boef and Keele, 2008; Hendry, 2006; Banerjee et al., 1990; Wickens and Breusch, 1988). For example, in the current context, when a regular smoker quits there are likely to be both short-term as well as long-term benefits for health: In the ECM, the short-term effects are captured by the impact on health from the contemporaneous change in cigarette consumption, while the long-term effects are captured through the impact of the equilibrium error such that the individual's health slowly improves back to that of a non-smoker. Similarly, it might take the individual a number of periods to fully recover from the effects of an exogenous health shock, such as a car accident, with the degree of persistence inversely related to the rate of adjustment towards equilibrium λ. More generally, current health is determined not only by current health shocks and levels of health determinants but also by the health shocks and levels of health determinants experienced over the entire life course of an individual (see e.g. Galobardes et al., 2007).

The ECM, thus, provides a parsimonious representation of the complex lagged response to health from changes in health determinants and the persistence of health shocks. For our analytical purposes, the main attraction of this representation is the clear distinction between the short-run dynamics and the implied long-run health relationship (see Wickens and Breusch, 1988). In particular, it is possible using the ECM to identify both the short-term impact on IRHI due to contemporaneous changes in health determinants and also how these factors contribute to chronic or persistent IRHI.11

4. Analysing the determinants of income-related health mobility

This section shows how the Two-Part Model may be used to analyse the role of health determinants in driving changes in IRHI through both morbidity changes and mortality, and to identify their contribution to long-run or structural IRHI. We first consider the impact of morbidity changes on IRHI changes within the sub-population in the initial period that survive until the final period, as this serves to clarify links with existing procedures for the decomposition of the CI.

4.1. An analysis of the determinants of morbidity changes conditional on survival

The ECM model of morbidity changes (7) may be used to analyse the socioeconomic determinants of income-related health mobility conditional upon survival. Specifically, if we consider consecutive periods such that f = s + 1 (s = 1, ..., T − 1) then M˜H in the sub-population Ω1Ωf12 may be decomposed to yield:

M˜H=P˜q˜k=1KCI˜sshCI˜fsΔkδˆkΔx¯˜kfΔh¯˜f+CI˜sshCI˜ssEqEλˆ(hc*hs¯˜)Δh¯˜f+CI˜sshCI˜fseˆe¯˜fΔh¯˜fΔh¯˜fh¯˜f (9)

where Δx¯˜kf is the average change in morbidity determinant k, with CI˜fsΔk being the corresponding CI ranked by initial income; the δˆk s, and λˆ are estimates of the corresponding parameters of the dynamic health function (7); hˆs*hs¯˜ is the mean predicted equilibrium error in period s, with CI˜ssEqE=2cov˜hˆis*his,R˜is/(hˆs*hs¯˜) the corresponding CI ranked by initial income; and e¯˜f is the mean regression residual eif=εˆif, with CI˜fse the corresponding CI ranked by initial income.13 Hence (9) may be written as:

M˜H=P˜q˜=k=1KCI˜sshCI˜fsΔkδˆkΔx¯˜kfh¯˜f+CI˜sshCI˜ssEqEλˆ(hˆs*hs¯˜)h¯˜f+CI˜sshCI˜fsee¯˜fh¯˜f=k=1KP˜Δkq˜Δk+P˜EqEq˜EqE+P˜eq˜e (10)

where M˜H can be viewed as the sum of contributions due to changes in the K health determinants, the predicted disequilibrium error and contemporaneous health shocks in (7). Each term in (10) is expressed in terms of the scale and progressivity of the health changes due to that element, with this further decomposition revealing how the average level of health changes and their distribution across initial income ranks respectively impact on income-related health mobility. For example, a positive scale index q˜Δk implies a positive average health impact due to the changes in the kth health determinant and if the poor enjoy a larger share of these health gains than their initial share of health then the progressivity index P˜Δk will also be positive giving rise to a positive impact on M˜H and thus a reduction in IRHI.

The interpretation of P˜EqE and q˜EqE are similar in terms of the impacts of health changes due to the process of adjustment towards the equilibrium levels of health implied by individuals’ initial conditions, where this process may generally be expected to have a negative impact on M˜H and hence exacerbate IRHI. To see this point, note that the contribution of the equilibrium error to M˜H can be expressed as

P˜EqEq˜EqE=CI˜sshhˆ¯˜s*CI˜sshˆ*h¯˜CI˜ssh(hˆs*hs¯˜)λˆ(hˆs*hs¯˜)h¯˜f=CI˜sshCI˜sshˆ*λˆhˆ¯˜s*h¯˜f (11)

where hˆ¯˜s* and CI˜sshˆ* are the mean and CI respectively of implied equilibrium health in the initial period. Interpreting CI˜sshˆ* as a measure of chronic IRHI then one would expect CI˜sshCI˜sshˆ*<0 in the light of the empirical evidence that IRHI is worse in the long-run than in the short-run (see e.g. Jones and Lopez Nicolas, 2004; Allanson et al., 2010).14 Thus, P˜EqEq˜EqE will generally be negative since λˆhˆ¯˜s*/h¯˜f will be positive if, as will usually be the case, average health is positive and 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1.

4.2. Incorporating the determinants of mortality

Extending the regression decomposition analysis to incorporate those who die is more problematic as the inherent non-linearity of the TPM (5) does not lend itself to being used in a simple decomposition of MH into its determinants. To address this problem we adopt a hierarchical decomposition procedure in which we first break down MH into elements due to health changes resulting from expected morbidity changes, expected mortality and health shocks, and then further decompose the first two of these elements to determine the separate contributions of the health determinants.

For this purpose, we note that individual health changes between any two consecutive periods, s and f (s = 1, ..., T − 1), may be written from (5) and (7) as

Δhif=EΔhif+υif=EΔhifMB+EΔhifMT+υif=ProbSif=1EΔhif|Sif=1+ProbSif=00his+υif=Φzisk=1KδkΔxkif+λhis*his1Φzishis+υif;iΩ1Ωs (12)

where zis=γ0+k=1Kγkxkis+γhhis, and Φ denotes the cumulative density function of the standard normal distribution. Hence, the health change of an individual from the original population who has survived until period s will be the sum of the expected health change EΔhif and an error term υif that captures the effect of health shocks.15 The decomposition of the former into morbidity-related and mortality-related components, EΔhifMB and EΔhifMT respectively, parallels that underlying (3).16 Thus the first stage of the decomposition procedure straightforwardly yields:

MH=CIsshCIfsΔhq=CIssΔh2Δh¯fcovΔmbif+Δmtif+uif,Ris   Δh¯fh¯f=CIsshCIfsΔmbΔmb¯fh¯f+CIsshCIfsΔmtΔmt¯fh¯f+CIsshCIfsuu¯fh¯f=PE(MB)qE(MB)+PE(MT)qE(MT)+Puqu=Pq;iΩ1Ωs (13)

where ΔmbifΔhˆifMB, ΔmtifΔhˆifMT and uifυˆif are the sample counterparts of EΔhifMB, EΔhifMT and υif respectively, with corresponding means, Δmb¯f, Δmt¯f and u¯f, and CIs, CIfsΔmb, CIfsΔmt and CIfsu, defined over all those from the original population who survive until the initial period s.17 We note that (13) provides estimators of the progressivity and scale indices in (3), given that CIfsΔmb and CIfsΔmt only depend on expected morbidity-related and mortality-related health changes conditional on income rank (see Duclos et al., 2003).

In the second stage we make use of the Taylor-series expansions of EΔhifMB and EΔhifMT to obtain the following linear approximations:

EΔhifMB=k=1KρkisΔxkif+ρEqE,ishis*his+π0is+k=1Kπkisxkis+πhishis+ϖif; (14a)
EΔhifMT=τ0is+k=1Kτkisxkis+τhishis   +ωif; (14b)

where the ρs, πs and τs are the parameters from the linearisation, for which definitions are given in Appendix A, and ϖif and ωif are approximation errors. The terms in the first bracket of (14a) capture the influence on expected morbidity changes of the determinants of morbidity change conditional on survival EΔhif|Sif=1, while those in the second bracket may be interpreted as selection effects that capture the influence on expected morbidity changes of the determinants of survival ProbSif=1.

Hence PE(MB)qE(MB) and PE(MT)qE(MT) in (13) can be decomposed to reveal the progressivity and scale indices of the various health determinants of expected morbidity changes and mortality:

PE(MB)qE(MB)=k=1KCIsshCIfsΔmbΔkΔmb¯fΔkh¯f+CIsshCIfsΔmbEqEΔmb¯fEqEh¯f+k=1KCIsshCIfsΔmb0Δmb¯f0h¯f+CIsshCIfsΔmbkΔmb¯fkh¯f+CIsshCIfsΔmbhΔmb¯fhh¯f+CIsshCIfsvv¯fh¯f=k=1KPΔkE(MB)qΔkE(MB)+PEqEE(MB)qEqEE(MB)+P0E(MB)q0E(MB)+k=1KPkE(MB)qkE(MB)+PhE(MB)qhE(MB)   +PvE(MB)qvE(MB)=k=1KPΔkE(MB)qΔkE(MB)+PEqEE(MB)qEqEE(MB)+PzE(MB)qzE(MB)+PvE(MB)qvE(MB); (15a)
PE(MT)qE(MT)=k=1KCIsshCIfsΔmt0Δmt¯f0h¯f+CIsshCIfsΔmtkΔmt¯fkh¯f+CIsshCIfsΔmthΔmt¯fhh¯f+CIsshCIfsww¯fh¯f=   P0E(MT)q0E(MT)+k=1KPkE(MT)qkE(MT)+PhE(MT)qhE(MT)   +PwE(MT)qwE(MT) (15b)

where ΔmbifΔkρˆkisΔxkif, ΔmbifEqEρˆEqE,ishis*his, Δmbif0πˆ0is, Δmbifkπˆkisxkis, Δmbifhπˆkishis, Δmtif0τˆ0is, Δmtifkτˆkisxkis and Δmtifhτˆhishis are the sample counterparts of the corresponding expressions in (14), with means and CIs defined in terms of the morbidity-related and mortality-related health change effects of the various health determinants, rather than the determinants themselves, because the linearisation parameter values (which capture the marginal effects) vary across individuals in the Taylor series approximations;18 and vif and wif are the approximation residuals, which will in general not equal zero on average. In the final line of (15a), we combine terms to yield PzE(MB)qzE(MB), which captures the overall influence on MH of the expected morbidity changes due to the combined effect of the selection terms in (14a), with qzE(MB) equal to the sum of the individual scale indices of the selection terms and PzE(MB) to the weighted sum of the progressivity indices with weights in proportion to the individual scale indices.19

4.3. Analysing the determinants of structural IRHI

The contribution of the equilibrium error PEqEE(MB)qEqEE(MB) in (15a) could be further broken down to identify the ‘apparent’ contribution of each equilibrium health determinant to MH through the adjustment process, but this is misleading inasmuch as the causes of the disequilibrium in the initial period are unknown.20 Instead, it is more meaningful to simply analyse the determinants of structural or equilibrium IRHI in the initial period. Following Gravelle (2003), the CI of equilibrium health in the sub-set of the original population that has survived until period s (s = 1, T  1) may be decomposed to yield:

CIsshˆ*=2hˆ¯s*k=1KβˆkCovxkis,Ris+Covμˆi,Ris=k=1Kβˆkx¯kshˆ¯s*CIssk+GCfsμˆhˆ¯s*=k=1KηˆksCIssk+GCfsμˆhˆ¯s*;iΩ1Ωs; (16)

where CIssk is the CI of xks ranked by initial income and ηˆks is the corresponding elasticity of health evaluated at sample means, which is equal to the share of equilibrium health attributable to that determinant; and GCfsμˆ is the generalised concentration index of the estimated fixed effects μˆi ranked by initial income. Hence the contribution of each health determinant to equilibrium IRHI is simply the product of the health elasticity and the CI of that determinant with respect to initial income rank.

5. Empirical analysis

We employ the decomposition procedures to analyse the health determinants of IRHI changes in Great Britain between 1999 and 2004, treated as a single five year transition period as in Petrie et al. (2011). Our empirical analysis employs data from the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS; University of Essex, Institute for Social and Economic Research, 2007), which is a nationally representative longitudinal survey of private households in Great Britain. Specifically, we use the data from 1999 and 2004 to construct an unbalanced panel consisting of observations on the sub-set of individuals in the BHPS for whom full information on health, income and a range of other socioeconomic variables was available in both 1999 and 2004 or for whom full information was available in 1999 and the individual was known to have died by 2004. The analysis is restricted to these two waves by the availability of data to construct our preferred health measure, which is defined in terms of Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) and derived from the responses to the SF-36 questionnaire using the SF-6D preference-based algorithm (Brazier et al., 2002).

To prevent outlier incomes exerting undue influence, we follow common practice when using the BHPS (see e.g. Jones and Lopez Nicolas, 2004; Jenkins and Van Kerm, 2011) by excluding individuals from the panel if their equivalised income fell in the top 1% or bottom 1% of the distribution in either wave. Sample weights were used throughout the analysis with these being given by a set of adjusted BHPS cross-sectional weights for 1999, where the adjustments were made using inverse probability weights (see Wooldridge, 2002) to allow both for missing data in either 1999 or 2004 and for non-mortality related sample attrition between 1999 and 2004 (see Petrie et al. (2011) for further discussion). Standard errors for all inequality and mobility measures were generated using a bootstrap procedure in which re-sampling was carried out at the cluster (Primary Sampling Unit) rather than individual level within each major stratum, reflecting the sample design.21

5.1. Definition of variables

The trimmed sample comprises observations on 9677 individuals of whom 599 had died by 2004, representing 6.3% of the weighted sample. Table 1 provides definitions and descriptive statistics for all the variables used in the empirical analysis. The health variable is bounded in the unit interval with full health corresponding to a value of one, the lowest possible health utility of anyone alive being equal to 0.301, and with death assigned a QALY of zero. The average QALY score fell among those who survived until 2004, with this morbidity-related decline being reinforced by health utility losses due to mortality.

Table 1.

Variable definitions and summary statistics.

Variable Attribute Mean Std. Dev Min Max
HEALTH99 Health 1999 0.800 0.128 0.301 1
ΔHEALTH Change in health −0.052 0.202 −1 0.495
LNINCOME99 Logarithm of income 1999 2.893 0.616 0.322 4.403
SMOKING99 Cigarettes smoked per day 1999 3.494 7.340 0 60
AGE99 Age 1999 47.823 18.729 16 96
AGESQ99 Age squared 1999 2637.779 1900.315 256 9216
MALE Gender (Male = 1) 0.477 0.499 0 1
NONWHITE Race (Non White = 1) 0.161 0.367 0 1
ADVEDUC Advanced qualifications 1999 0.350 0.477 0 1
STDEDONLY Standard qualifications 1999 0.312 0.463 0 1
SURVIVAL Survival status (Alive in 2004 = 1) 0.937 0.243 0 1



Survivors only
HEALTH99 Health 1999 0.809 0.120 0.301 1
ΔHEALTH Change in health −0.010 0.118 −0.699 0.495
LNINCOME99 Logarithm of income 1999 2.917 0.615 0.322 4.403
ΔLNINCOME Income growth 0.127 0.735 −11.043 3.439
SMOKING99 Cigarettes smoked per day 1999 3.525 7.370 0 60
ΔSMOKING Change in smoking −0.440 4.760 −40 30
AGE99 Age 1999 46.056 17.731 16 93
AGESQ99 Age squared 1999 2435.548 1737.122 256 8649
MALE Gender (Male = 1) 0.476 0.499 0 1
NONWHITE Race (Non White = 1) 0.169 0.375 0 1
ADVEDUC Advanced qualifications 1999 (At least A Levels) 0.366 0.482 0 1
STDEDONLY Standard qualifications 1999 (GCSEs/O levels/CSEs only) 0.324 0.468 0 1

Source: Authors’ calculations from BHPS data.

The income variable was defined as the natural logarithm of annual household income, equivalised using the McClements scale (Taylor, 1995) to take account of household composition and deflated by the CPI to take account of inflation. Other determinants of health and survival included in the analysis were the number of cigarettes usually smoked each day, age in years, the square of age, gender, ethnicity and highest level of educational attainment. Changes in log income and smoking were also included in the specification of the dynamic health function to capture the possible short-run effects of changes in these variables on health. Of those alive in both years, average incomes rose by 13.5% from an average of £18494, while smoking fell by 0.44 cigarettes per day from an average of 3.53 per day. Both average incomes and cigarette consumption were higher in 1999 among those who survived until 2004 compared to those who did not.22

5.2. Accounting for changes in IRHI using longitudinal data

Table 2 shows that cross-sectional IRHI was 0.02095 in 1999 and 0.02523 in 2004.23 The remainder of the table presents results from the Petrie et al. (2011) decomposition of the increase in IRHI of 0.00492 between the two years. This reveals three main points of interest, where all the reported measures are significantly different from zero at conventional significance levels. First, the negative value (−0.02506) for the income-related health mobility index MH indicates that health changes among the initial population had a disequalising effect. Average health depreciation was 0.05170 with the progressivity index P value (0.36285) implying that relative health losses were concentrated among the worse-off. Second, 86.4% of the income-related health mobility was due to selective mortality, while 13.6% was due to selective morbidity changes of the survivors: mortality accounted for 82.2% of the net loss in health over the period and these losses were more concentrated among the poor than net morbidity losses. Third, the negative value for the health-related income mobility index MR (−0.02078) indicates that health inequality among the population alive in 2004 was reduced by the combined effect of the dead no longer contributing to the calculation of IRHI and of income re-ranking among the survivors.24

Table 2.

Decomposition of IRHI changes.

Average health 1999 (h¯s) 0.80016***
0.00190
Average health change (Δh¯f) −0.05170***
0.00286
Conc. index of health changes (CIfsΔh) −0.34191***
0.03064
Concentration index 1999 (CIssh) 0.02095***
0.00129
Concentration index 2004 CI˜ffh 0.02523***
0.00128
Change in inequality CI˜ffhCIssh 0.00429***
0.00133
Income-related health mobility (MH) −0.02506***
0.00231
 Due to:Morbidity changes (PMBqMB) −0.00342***
0.00106
    Mortality (PMTqMT) −0.02164***
0.00200
  Progressivity index (P) 0.36285***
0.03038
     Due to: Morbidity changes (PMB) 0.28790***
0.10211
      Mortality (PMT) 0.38101***
0.02731
  Scale index (q) −0.06907***
0.00410
  Due to: Morbidity changes (qMB) −0.01227***
0.00205
   Mortality (qMT) −0.05680***
0.00326
Health-related income mobility (MR) −0.02078***
0.00246

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Eqs. (1)–(3). Bootstrapped standard errors in italics based on 2000 replications. Statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels are denoted by ***, ** and *, respectively.

5.3. Two-Part Model of health changes

The further decomposition to analyse the determinants of the income-related health mobility index MH in Table 4 is based on the estimates of the Two-Part Model.

Table 4.

Decomposition of the income-related health mobility index.

Progressivity, P Scale, q Mobility, MH Share
Income-related health mobility 0.36285*** 0.06907*** 0.02506*** 100.0%
0.03038 0.00410 0.00231
Resulting from health changes due to:
Expected morbidity changes 0.23853** 0.01219*** 0.00291** 11.6%
0.10446 0.00206 0.00113
Due to:
 ΔLNINCOME 1.11026*** 0.00112*** 0.00124*** −4.9%
0.11261 0.00036 0.00037
 ΔSMOKING −0.13404 0.00010 −0.00001 0.1%
0.09091 0.00015 0.00002
 Equilibrium error 0.31376*** −0.01146*** −0.00359*** 14.3%
0.10168 0.00178 0.00105
 Combined selection 0.27703*** −0.00195*** −0.00054*** 2.2%
0.10416 0.00033 0.00018
 Approx. error −0.39082 0.00000 0.00000 0.0%
0.25487 0.00001 0.00000
Expected mortality 0.36967*** 0.05713*** 0.02112*** 84.3%
0.02807 0.00334 0.00206
Due to:
 HEALTH99 0.08482*** −0.07083*** −0.00601*** 24.0%
0.00823 0.01655 0.00163
 LNINCOME99 −0.00450 0.01806 −0.00008 0.3%
0.01364 0.01678 0.00036
 SMOKING99 0.14770*** −0.00469*** −0.00069*** 2.8%
0.02236 0.00139 0.00021
 AGE99 0.17361*** 0.14460** 0.02510** −100.2%
0.01386 0.06641 0.01166
 AGESQ99 0.22695*** −0.19432*** −0.04410*** 176.0%
0.01423 0.03409 0.00820
 MALE 0.05458*** −0.01486*** −0.00081*** 3.2%
0.01394 0.00292 0.00026
 NONWHITE −0.01568 0.00112 −0.00002 0.1%
0.02509 0.00130 0.00005
 ADVEDUC −0.18551*** 0.00522** −0.00097** 3.9%
0.01791 0.00217 0.00043
 STDEDONLY 0.03335* 0.00324* 0.00011 −0.4%
0.01863 0.00190 0.00009
 Intercept 0.11475*** 0.05533* 0.00635 −25.3%
0.01353 0.03706 0.00426
 Approx. error −0.42125* 0.00000 0.00000 0.0%
0.24637 0.00026 0.00007
Residual health shocks 4.13427 0.00025* 0.00103** 4.1%
93.92231 0.00014 0.00044

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Eqs. (13), (15a) and (15b). Bootstrapped standard errors in italics based on 2000 replications. Statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels are denoted by ***, ** and *, respectively.

5.3.1. Estimation methods

We estimate the ECM (7) by ordinary least squares (OLS)25 and the probit model by maximum likelihood. Consideration of individual heterogeneity in the ECM is problematic as we only have a single transition and individual-specific effects are therefore not identifiable.26 However, we did experiment on a reduced sample with a Mundlak (1978) type parameterisation of the unobserved individual effect as a function of within-individual 3-year averages of the time-varying levels of smoking, income and self-assessed health over the period 1996–98, and found that this made little difference to the conclusions.27 Another estimation issue with the ECM is the potential endogeneity of the contemporaneous changes in smoking and income given that health shocks may influence both income and smoking status (see e.g. Kapteyn et al., 2008; García-Gómez, 2011). Others have suggested that conditioning on initial health may limit the bias due to reverse causation (see e.g. Contoyannis et al., 2004; Van Ourti et al., 2009). We further explored this issue by excluding individuals from the sample whose economic activity status changed to long-term sick in 2004, as their change in income was mostly likely driven by a change in health, and found that this had a relatively small effect on the results.28 Finally, we note that heterogeneity and endogeneity may also arise in the estimation of the probit model (see Balia and Jones, 2008) but consideration of these econometric issues lies beyond the scope of the current study.

5.3.2. Empirical results

Column [1] in Table 3 reports the results from the estimation of the probit survival model (5a) over the entire sample of individuals alive in 1999, where the dependent variable is 2004 survival status. All other things equal, the survival chances of those who were in better health in 1999 were, as would be expected, significantly better than those in worse health. Higher levels of income and education improved survival chances, though the effect for income was not significant, while smoking had a significant negative effect. The quadratic in age implies that those who were in their early twenties in 1999 had the highest probability of survival, with survival chances declining with age at an increasing rate thereafter. Finally, men were less likely to survive than women, while the effect of ethnicity was insignificant.

Table 3.

Two-Part Model and the implied Equilibrium Health Function.

[1] Probit survival model [2] Error Correction Model conditional on survival [3] Equilibrium health function
Left hand side variable SURVIVAL ΔHEALTH hs*



Explanatory variables Coeff. Coeff. Coeff.
Std error Std error Std error



ΔLNINCOME 0.00819***
0.00237
ΔSMOKING −0.00022
0.00034
HEALTH99 2.03316*** −0.51034***
0.23017 0.01340
LNINCOME99 0.07344 0.01623*** 0.03179***
0.06229 0.00274 0.00539
SMOKING99 −0.01485*** −0.00092*** −0.00181***
0.00413 0.00021 0.00040
AGE99 0.02964** 0.00050 0.00098
0.01315 0.00044 0.00080
AGESQ99 −0.00064*** −0.00002*** −0.00004***
0.00011 0.00000 0.00001
MALE −0.33276*** 0.01456*** 0.02854***
0.06746 0.00270 0.00519
NONWHITE 0.11852 −0.00494 −0.00967
0.14809 0.00391 0.00680
ADVEDUC 0.21339** 0.01048*** 0.02054**
0.09378 0.00397 0.00817
STDEDONLY 0.14268 0.01389*** 0.02722***
0.09265 0.00391 0.00811
Constant 0.63080 0.36988*** 0.72478***
0.42130 0.01552 0.02447



Sample size 9677 9078
Pseudo R2/R2 0.3656 0.2617
Wald χ2(9) 650.76***
F(11,398) 139.44***

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Eqs. (5a), (7) and (8), with the coefficient estimates in column [3] derived by manipulation of the estimation results in column [2]. Robust standard errors in columns [1] and [2] allow for the sample design. Bootstrapped standard errors in column [3] are based on 2000 replications. Statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels are denoted by ***, ** and *, respectively.

Column [2] reports the results for the dynamic health function conditional upon survival (7) with the dependent variable being the change in morbidity between 1999 and 2004. The first two regression coefficients show the short-run impact of changes in income and smoking on health.29 Thus increases in income led to contemporaneous improvements in health, consistent with other evidence that short run movements in individual health are related to transitory income shocks (see e.g. Benzeval and Judge, 2001). Conversely, increases in smoking are estimated to have had a contemporaneous negative impact on health, though this effect was small and not significant.

The remainder of the dynamic health function relates to the equilibrium error, where the specification of steady-state or equilibrium health in (8) includes the same set of determinants as the probit survival model. The initial health coefficient provides an estimate of the adjustment parameter λˆ equal to 0.51, implying that just over half of the gap between any individual's actual and equilibrium health in 1999 was closed by 2004. Dividing the coefficients on the initial period levels of the health determinants by λˆ yields the parameters of the implied equilibrium health function reported in Column [3]. Thus the implied long-run effect on health of a 1% increase in income (0.03179) was nearly four times as large as the contemporaneous effect (0.00819), while the implied long-term effect of smoking an additional cigarette per day (−0.00181) was over eight times the contemporaneous impact (−0.00022). The quadratic in age implies that equilibrium health levels peak before twenty, with health declining at an increasing rate thereafter. Men had significantly higher equilibrium levels of health than women all other things equal. Non-whites had lower equilibrium levels of health though the coefficient was not significantly different from zero. Finally, higher levels of educational attainment are associated with better long-term health than the omitted case of no educational qualifications.

Overall, the Two-Part Model results are credible with expected signs on all coefficients that are significantly different from zero. Parameter estimates from the linearization of the model, which are employed in the hierarchical decomposition of the Petrie et al. (2011) income-related health mobility index, are reported in Appendix A.

5.4. Determinants of income-related health mobility

Table 4 expands upon the Petrie et al. (2011) decomposition analysis by reporting the results from our further hierarchical decomposition of the income-related health mobility index MH by both morbidity change and mortality determinants using the TPM.

The first-stage decomposition results reveal that health changes due to expected morbidity changes, expected mortality and residual health shocks were all estimated to have had the effect of increasing IRHI over the period, with positive contributions of 11.6%, 84.3% and 4.1% respectively to income-related health mobility. Thus the TPM explains the vast majority of observed income-related health mobility, with the residual term making only a minor contribution.30 Moreover, the estimated progressivity, scale and mobility indices of health changes due to expected morbidity changes and expected mortality closely match the corresponding non-parametric estimates reported in Table 2. Health changes due to expected mortality accounted for over four fifths of overall income-related health mobility, as a result of both the scale of expected health losses due to death and their concentration among the poor.

The second-stage decomposition results suggest that the effects of age on mortality was the principal contributor to income-related health mobility (75.8% = 176.0%–100.2%), with the old in 1999 more likely both to be poor and to die in the following five year period. Health in 1999 also made a disequalising contribution (24.0%) because the marginal effects of initial health on mortality-related health losses were negatively correlated with initial income rank,31 such that mortality-related health losses due to initial health were concentrated among the poor even though initial health was not. Similarly, gender contributed to increasing IRHI (3.2%) because the marginal effect of being male tended to be larger for the poor, such that mortality-related health losses due to being male were concentrated among the poor even though men tended to be better off than women on average.32 More obviously, advanced educational attainment also contributed to the disequalising effect of expected deaths (3.9%) because the highly educated were both more likely to be better off and less likely to die. This is also the case for smoking (2.8%) but for the opposite reason—smokers were both less likely to be better off and more likely to die. None of the remaining determinants – income, race and standard qualifications – make significant contributions, consistent with the insignificant effects of these factors on survival. Finally, the intercept term in (14b), which varies across individuals, makes an equalising contribution to income-related health mobility (−25.3%) given that the positive impact of the constant in the survival model varies across individuals with the reduction in the chance of death tending to be larger among the poor due to the non-linearity of the probit function.33

Expected morbidity changes also made a disequalising contribution to income-related health mobility (11.6%). However, income growth provided a significant equalising contribution to this (−4.9%), with the positive values of q and P arising because income growth improved health and these health gains were concentrated among the poor whereas health in 1999 was concentrated among the rich.34 In contrast, reductions in smoking over the period increased health inequalities, since the distribution of health gains due to the fall in smoking were more concentrated among the rich than the distribution of health in 1999, although the effect was both very small and insignificant. The largest contribution to MH, of 14.3%, was from the equilibrium error term which, consistent with our expectations based on the discussion of (11), exacerbated IRHI. Specifically, adjustments from observed health in 1999 towards equilibrium health as defined by the socioeconomic determinants in 1999 resulted in a disequalising net health loss as these losses were concentrated among the poor. Finally, the combined effect of survival selection on expected morbidity made only a minor contribution to overall income related health mobility (2.2%) given that the average predicted chance of survival was 93.7%.

5.5. Determinants of implied 1991 equilibrium IRHI

Given the major contribution to income-related health mobility from the adjustment toward equilibrium health (14.3%), it is of interest to further consider the socioeconomic determinants of 1999 equilibrium IRHI per se. The observed and equilibrium CIs in Table 5 show that structural IRHI in 1999 (0.02982) was more severe than would be inferred from the cross-sectional measure (0.02095), which is consistent with the empirical literature on the relationship between long-run and short-run IRHI (see e.g. Jones and Lopez Nicolas, 2004). The decomposition of the equilibrium CI further reveals that just under half (47.2%) of structural IRHI in 1999 was attributable to income differences, with this resulting from income being both concentrated among the rich (by definition), as indicated by the positive CI for the logarithm of initial income (0.11934), and beneficial to health leading to a positive equilibrium health share (0.11799). A further two fifths (39.7% = 50.0–10.3%) of the equilibrium CI was attributable to income-related inequalities in age, with the old more likely to be both poorer and, all other things equal, in worse health. Finally, smoking, education and gender also made significant positive contributions to overall levels of equilibrium IRHI, with smokers more likely to be poor and smoking detrimental to health, while well-qualified individuals and men were more likely to be both richer and have better underlying levels of health.

Table 5.

Decomposition of the implied equilibrium IRHI in 1999.

Decomposition Analysis
Conc. Index Health share Contribution
CI η Share
IRHI in 1999: CIssh 0.02095***
0.00129
Equilibrium IRHI: CIsshˆ* 0.02982*** 0.02982*** 100.0%
0.00240 0.00240
of which due to:
LNINCOME99 0.11934*** 0.11799*** 0.01408*** 47.2%
0.00165 0.02013 0.00239
SMOKING99 −0.07904*** −0.00810*** 0.00064*** 2.1%
0.01647 0.00183 0.00020
AGE99 −0.05111*** 0.06015 −0.00307 −10.3%
0.00351 0.04739 0.00247
AGESQ99 −0.11029*** −0.13519*** 0.01491*** 50.0%
0.00631 0.02769 0.00329
MALE 0.05409*** 0.01744*** 0.00094*** 3.2%
0.00536 0.00313 0.00020
NONWHITE 0.07027*** −0.00199 −0.00014 −0.5%
0.01858 0.00143 0.00011
ADVEDUC 0.24303*** 0.00923** 0.00224** 7.5%
0.01074 0.00369 0.00090
STDEDONLY 0.02010* 0.01089*** 0.00022 0.7%
0.01110 0.00328 0.00014
constant 0 0.92958*** 0 0%
0.03032

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Eq. (16) using all those present in 1999. Bootstrapped standard errors in italics based on 2000 replications. Statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels are denoted by ***, ** and *, respectively.

6. Discussion

The traditional approach to understanding the causes of changes in health inequality has been based on repeated cross-sectional analysis using regression decomposition techniques such as those proposed in Wagstaff et al. (2003). This paper develops new regression-based procedures that exploit the additional information contained within longitudinal data to estimate a dynamic health function that captures the persistence of health states and to identify important aspects of the underlying determinants of IRHI changes such as those relating to mortality. Specifically, we employ a Two-Part Model – a probit model of survival together with a dynamic health function conditional upon survival – that provides a unified framework for understanding the role of health determinants in driving changes in IRHI through both morbidity changes and mortality. Our analysis reveals the contribution of each health determinant to income-related health mobility, which in turn are shown to depend on the progressivity and scale of the health changes attributable to that determinant. Moreover, our dynamic modelling framework also serves to identify how each health determinant contributes to long-run or structural IRHI.

We applied our procedures to the investigation of the causes of changes in IRHI in Great Britain over the five year period 1999 to 2004, using Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) as our health measure. Health changes due to expected mortality and expected morbidity changes both had a disequalising effect over this period, with the overall effect dominated by health losses due to expected deaths. This finding points to the importance of understanding the determinants of mortality in the evaluation of policies designed to tackle health inequalities. Consistent with Balia and Jones (2008) we find that the major driver of the disequalising effects of mortality was the positive association between (old) age and poverty given that the old were at greater risk of death, with other significant contributors including initial health status, advanced levels of educational attainment, gender and smoking. Health service interventions that improve the survival rates of the old and chronically sick are likely to reduce excess deaths among the poor yet, paradoxically, may also result in higher future levels of cross-sectional health inequalities if they do not also improve their average levels of morbidity. Programmes that act on the distribution of health determinants in the population, for example targeted smoking cessation programmes, may reduce both excess deaths among the poor and long term levels of IRHI.

The disequalising effect of morbidity related health changes was driven by the lagged process of adjustment to changes in health determinants and health shocks prior to 1999. However, this effect was moderated by the poor enjoying a disproportionately large share of the contemporaneous gains in relative health due to pro-poor real income growth between 1999 and 2004. This period largely coincided with New Labour's second term in office, which was characterised by income growth rates that were highest at the very bottom of the income distribution (Joyce et al., 2010: 25; see also Jenkins and Van Kerm, 2011) as a result of a range of factors including low unemployment, the introduction of the minimum wage and an assortment of new and enhanced social security benefits.

The findings further indicate that just under half of the equilibrium level of IRHI in 1999 was attributable to income inequality, providing some support for the conclusions of the Independent Inquiry into Inequalities in Health Report (Acheson, 1998) ‘that without a shift of resources to the less well off, both in and out of work, little will be accomplished in terms of a reduction of health inequalities by interventions addressing particular “downstream” ‘influences’. However, like Adams et al. (2003), we are unable to show a significant direct influence of income on the risk of mortality after controlling inter alia for the protective effect of initial health.35

These empirical findings illustrate the value of the proposed approach for understanding how changes in individuals’ determinants of health impact on health inequalities in order to shape the design of an effective set of public policies to tackle the issue. Nevertheless, the proposed approach offers only a partial analysis of changes in IRHI in that it establishes the causes of income-related health mobility but not of health-related income mobility, with the latter also playing a significant role in the determination of the overall rise in IRHI in Great Britain between 1999 and 2004. Extension of the approach to incorporate a decomposition of health-related income mobility by the determinants of changes in income (ranks) would require a joint model of the determination of health and income changes that accounts for dual causality, but this lies beyond the scope of the current paper.

Funding

Chief Scientist Office (CSO) Grant 2012CB416603CZG/2/451: ‘Development of tools to measure and explain changes in health inequalities in Scotland and benchmark performance”.

Acknowledgements

The work for this paper was undertaken with the financial support of the CSO under small grant CZG/2/451 “Development of tools to measure and explain changes in health inequalities in Scotland and benchmark performance”. The authors bear sole responsibility for the further analysis and interpretation of the British Household Panel Survey data employed in this study. We would like to thank Luigi Siciliani, two anonymous referees, Arnab Bhattacharjee, Ulf Gerdtham and participants at the BHPS Conference and at seminars at the Universities of York, Stirling and Dundee for providing valuable feedback on this paper.

Footnotes

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-No Derivative Works License, which permits non-commercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

1

The cross-sectional health model will only be valid if the health observations on individuals represent health state equilibria at each survey date, rather than the individuals being in a state of adjustment.

2

Grossman (1972) assumes that health depreciates with age and can be improved by investment.

3

Van Ourti et al. (2009) propose an alternative decomposition procedure based on the use of longitudinal data, but focus their analysis on how the effect of income changes on IRHI varies depending on the nature of income growth and the assumed form of the relationship between health and income.

4

While it may also be interesting to examine the determinants of health-related income mobility we leave this for future work. In the Wagstaff et al. (2003) type decomposition approach income re-ranking effects are not separately identified but are instead subsumed within the changes in the distribution of the determinants of health across income classes.

5

Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) are used in the current paper as the measure of health because they allow both the quality and quantity of health individuals experience to be combined into a single meaningful measure. Full health is given a QALY of one and death a QALY of zero and the QALYs for all other health states are derived in relation to these two benchmark values—see Drummond et al. (2011) for further details.

6

Ωt is the population alive in period t (t=s, f), such that ΩsΩf denotes the population alive in both periods. Longitudinal data in general will not capture the longitudinal experience of those who enter the population after the initial period such as newborns or migrants. Consideration of sources of sample attrition other than mortality is postponed until the empirical section.

7

Note that the notation CIabh refers to the CI obtained when health h in period a is ordered by income rank in period b.

8

Allanson and Petrie (2012) propose analogous decompositions for a range of commonly used rank-dependent measures of IRHI. It is a trivial exercise to extend the analytical procedures developed in this paper to these alternative measurement frameworks.

9

If (5a) and (5c) are assumed to be conditionally independent (Leung and Yu, 1996) this would serve to identify the latter unconditionally in the absence of any variables that might conceivably influence mortality but not morbidity. However, for the current purposes we are more interested in modelling actual health outcomes rather than modelling the ‘potential’ health of the dead had they not died and therefore identification is less relevant in this context.

10

Eq. (6) could readily be extended to include higher-order lagged terms in the xks and h, leading to more complicated error correction models in which the short-run dynamics are a function not only of contemporaneous but also of lagged changes in the health determinants.

11

Exploring the long-term consequences of changes in determinants is also possible in terms of the equilibrium impacts. However it is more meaningful to evaluate such consequences using lifetime measures of health attainment, such as health adjusted life expectancy, which lies beyond the scope of this paper.

12

The analysis is restricted to the population in period 1 that survive until period f by the definition of the TPM in (5) but is consistent with the definition of M˜H in (4) since all individuals identified will also have been part of the population in period s.

13

The decomposition is feasible so long as the dynamic health function is linear in the parameters with an additive error term. Note that if health changes are a linear function not of xk itself but of g(xk), which may be so in the case of income for example, then the results in this sub-section will go through unchanged but with g(xk) replacing xk throughout.

14

Measures of chronic or long-run IRHI in these and similar studies are calculated using health and income data averaged over a number of years, to average out the effects of transitory shocks on individuals.

15

Eυf=0 since Eεi,t+1|Si,t+1*0=0 in (5c) by assumption for the TPM.

16

The probability of survival impacts on both components such that neither EΔhifMB nor EΔhifMT will typically be zero for any individual since matters of life and death are rarely certain. In the case of individuals who die before the final period, EΔhifMBis evaluated on the assumption that they would have experienced the average change in each health determinant of those who did survive. Note that here we are not considering sources of sample attrition other than death.

17

Note that the mean prediction error u¯fwill not in general equal zero due to the non-linearity of the TPM.

18

For the same reason, there are terms relating to initial health hs in both (15a) and (15b).

19

In our empirical application we choose to report the combined selection effect as the individual effects are relatively small.

20

For example, the decomposition would identify the contribution of the kth health determinant to the change in health attributable to the disequilibrium error as PEqE(k)E(MB)qEqE(k)E(MB)=(CIsshCIfsΔmbEqE(k))(Δmb¯fEqE(k)/h¯f), where ΔmbifEqE(k)ρˆEqE,isβˆkxkis, irrespective of whether the initial disequilibrium had arisen due to past changes in that determinant or not.

21

However, the bootstrapping procedure did not include re-estimation of the individual weights that were constructed from the original sample. See Biewen (2002) on the use of bootstrap inference for inequality and mobility measurement.

22

The finding about cigarettes may appear surprising but, after controlling for other factors, we show later that smoking reduces the chance of survival.

23

The concentration indices in the current paper are similar in magnitude to those found in other studies (see e.g. Van Doorslaer and Koolman, 2004). If there was a linear relationship between health and income rank then these levels of IRHI would imply that the difference in health utility between the poorest and richest individuals in the population was 0.1006 in 1999 and of 0.1133 in 2004, or just less than one standard deviation in health in both years. This follows as the Slope Inequality Index is equal to approximately six times the product of the health CI and mean health (see, e.g. Allanson and Petrie, 2012).

24

Petrie et al. (2011) further decompose MR to show that those who moved up the income distribution tended to be healthier in 2004 than those who moved down, giving rise to a positive contribution to IRHI in 2004, but that this effect was outweighed by the dead dropping out of the population.

25

See Banerjee et al. (1990) on the applicability of the one-step OLS estimation of the ECM.

26

Additional waves of data would permit the estimation of a dynamic model with individual-specific effects but this will introduce additional complexities that are not considered here (see Baltagi, 2005).

27

The inclusion of data from previous waves results in a substantial fall in sample size, from 9677 to 5794 observations, given that the BHPS sample was boosted in 1999. Additionally, the unavailability of our preferred health measure necessitated the use of a set of health dummies based on self-assessed health instead. Controlling for individual heterogeneity using this approach led to very similar conclusions about the contributions of the various health determinants to MH, with the biggest change being in the contribution due to income growth which falls in the restricted sample from −4.7% to −3.2% but remains significant at the 5% level. As expected, there was a positive gradient in the estimated individual effects moving from very poor to excellent health.

28

The coefficient on income falls from 0.00819 to 0.00644, resulting in a fall in the contribution of income growth to MH from −4.9% in Table 4 to −3.9% although this remains significant at the 1% level. The contribution of changes in smoking remains insignificant throughout.

29

We do not include changes in age and the square of age as these are perfectly collinear with the constant and initial age respectively. The remaining health determinants are treated as time invariant.

30

The TPM is an accurate predictor of health changes in (12) on average – as indicated by the small q value for the residual – although the residuals are positively correlated with income rank leading to the large – though poorly determined – value of the progressivity index.

31

Note that the marginal effect of initial health on mortality-related health losses in the linearised version of the TPM is given in (14b) by τhis, which varies across individuals based on their characteristics. In particular, for any given level of initial health, the poor tend to have a higher chance of dying and hence of suffering health losses due to mortality given their other characteristics. This leads to the concentration of mortality-related health losses due to initial health among the poor even though initial health was concentrated among the rich.

32

This follows from the non-linearity of the survival model whereby the marginal effect of any determinant in the probit function tends to be larger for the poor since their probability of survival tends to be closer to 0.5 (the point where the derivative of the probit function with respect to z is at its maximum). That men were better off on average than women can be inferred from the positive CI for MALE reported in Table 5.

33

Balia and Jones (2008) investigate the contribution of socioeconomic, demographic and lifestyle determinants to total inequality in mortality rates defined as a linear index of predicted death from a probit model, i.e. zˆis in our notation. Applying their decomposition methodology to the survival model estimates reported in Table 3, we similarly find that age is the predominant contributor (69.2%) but that initial health plays a larger role (16.8%) than in their study, perhaps due to our shorter follow up period (5 years rather than 19). All other factors make only a minor contribution as in their results when, similar to our approach, initial health and lifestyle choices (including smoking) are treated as exogenous. Repeating their decomposition on income-related inequality in mortality yields broadly similar results but with initial income unsurprisingly making a larger contribution.

34

Note that pro-poor distribution of relative health gains in this case can be inferred from the result that P>CIssh, where CIssh is reported in Table 2.

35

Note the absence of a direct link between income and mortality does not rule out the existence of socioeconomic inequalities in age and sex standardised mortality rates, as reported in the literature (see e.g. Leyland, 2004; Norman et al., 2011), given our model implies that initial health is determined in part by income.

36

One could instead employ a Taylor series expansion about the sample means but our preferred approach is analytically simpler and thus readily allows computation of the approximation to any desired level of accuracy.

Appendix A. Linearisation of the Two-Part Model

The linearisation of the TPM is based on the Taylor series expansion of the standard normal cumulative distribution function Φz about zero (see e.g. Marsaglia, 2004):

Φz=12+12πj=01jz2j(2j+1)2jj!z12+12πj=0θjzz

Hence EΔhifMB and EΔhifMB in (13) may be written as36

EΔhifMB=k=1KρkisΔxkif+ρEqE,ishis*his+π0is+k=1Kπkisxkis+πhishis+ϖif;EΔhifMT=τ0is+k=1Kτkisxkis+τhishis+ωif; (A1)

where

ρkis=12+12πj=0J12j+2θjziszisδk;k=1,...,K
ρEqE,is=12+12πj=0J12j+2θjziszisλ;
πmis=12πj=0J2j+12j+2θjzisk=1KδkΔxkif+λhis*hisγm;m=0,1,...,K,h
τkis=12πj=0J2j+12j+2θjzishisγk;k=0,1,...,K
τhis=12πj=0J2j+12j+2θjzishisγh+12+12πj=0J12j+2θjziszis;

and the size of the approximation errors ϖif and ωif can be controlled by the choice of J, which determines the order of the expansions. Table A1

Table A1.

Average linearization parameter estimates.

Dependent variable EΔhifMB EΔhifMT



Explanatory variables Av. coeff Av. coeff
Std error Std error
ΔLNINCOME ρˆ¯ΔLNINCOME 0.0065034***
0.0019225
ΔSMOKING ρˆ¯ΔSMOKING −0.0001762
0.0002636
Equilibrium error ρˆ¯EqE 0.4050026***
0.0108085
HEALTH99 πˆ¯HEALTH99 −0.0015027*** τˆ¯HEALTH99 −0.0729326***
0.0004362 0.0154532
LNINCOME99 πˆ¯LNINCOME99 −0.0000543 τˆ¯LNINCOME99 0.0048212
0.0000559 0.0044940
SMOKING99 πˆ¯SMOKING99 0.0000110** τˆ¯SMOKING99 −0.0009746***
0.0000048 0.0002588
AGE99 πˆ¯AGE99 −0.0000219* τˆ¯AGE99 0.0019456**
0.0000121 0.0009053
AGESQ99 πˆ¯AGESQ99 0.0000005*** τˆ¯AGESQ99 −0.0000420***
0.0000002 0.0000077
MALE πˆ¯MALE 0.0002459*** τˆ¯MALE −0.0218441***
0.0000902 0.0039315
NONWHITE πˆ¯NONWHITE −0.0000876 τˆ¯˜NONWHITE 0.0077807
0.0001211 0.0098915
ADVEDUC πˆ¯ADVEDUC −0.0001577* τˆ¯ADVEDUC 0.0140080**
0.0000915 0.0062602
STDEDONLY πˆ¯STDEDONLY −0.0001055 τˆ¯STDEDONLY 0.0093661
0.0000741 0.0057983
Constant πˆ¯0 −0.0004662 τˆ¯0 0.0414092
0.0004105 0.0277510

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Eqs. (14a) and (14b) as further defined in Appendix A. The reported coefficient values are sample weighted averages of the individual-specific coefficient values obtained from the Taylor series expansion with J = 20. Bootstrapped standard errors based on 2000 replications. Statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels are denoted by ***, ** and *, respectively.

reports estimates of the linearisation parameters with J = 20, which serves to reduce the magnitude of the contributions of the approximation errors to income-related health mobility reported in Table 4 to the order of 10−8. Note that τˆ¯HEALTH99 is approximately equal to minus the average probability of death given that the better an individual's initial health the more they lose from dying and that the protective effect of better initial health on the risk of mortality is small.

References

  1. Acheson, D., 1998. Inequalities in Health: Report of an Independent Inquiry. HMSO, London, 1998.
  2. Adams P., Hurd M.D., McFadden D., Merrill A., Ribeiro T. Healthy, wealthy, and wise? Tests for direct causal paths between health and socioeconomic status. Journal of Econometrics. 2003;112:3–56. [Google Scholar]
  3. Allanson P., Gerdtham U.-G., Petrie D. Longitudinal analysis of income-related health inequality. Journal of Health Economics. 2010;29:78–86. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2009.10.005. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  4. Allanson P., Petrie D. On the choice of health inequality measure for the longitudinal analysis of income-related health inequalities. Health Economics. 2012;22:353–365. doi: 10.1002/hec.2803. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  5. Balia S., Jones A.M. Mortality, lifestyle and socio-economic status. Journal of Health Economics. 2008;27:1–26. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2007.03.001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  6. Baltagi B. third ed. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd; England: 2005. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data. [Google Scholar]
  7. Banerjee A., Galbraith J., Dolado J. Dynamic specification and linear transformation of the autoregressive-distributed lag model. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. 1990;52:95–104. [Google Scholar]
  8. Benzeval M., Judge K. Income and health: the time dimension. Social Science & Medicine. 2001;52:1371–1390. doi: 10.1016/s0277-9536(00)00244-6. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  9. Biewen M. Bootstrap inference for inequality, mobility and poverty measurement. Journal of Econometrics. 2002;108:317–342. [Google Scholar]
  10. Brazier J., Roberts J., Deverill M. The estimation of a preference-based measure of health from the SF-36. Journal of Health Economics. 2002;21:271–292. doi: 10.1016/s0167-6296(01)00130-8. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  11. Castle J., Fawcett N., Hendry D. Forecasting with equilibrium-correction models during structural breaks. Journal of Econometrics. 2010;158:25–36. [Google Scholar]
  12. Contoyannis P., Jones A.M., Rice N. The dynamics of health in the British Household Panel Survey. Journal of Applied Econometrics. 2004;19:473–503. [Google Scholar]
  13. De Boef S., Keele L. Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science. 2008;52:184–200. [Google Scholar]
  14. Department of Health, 2008. Health Inequalities: Progress and Next Steps. <http://www.dh.gov.uk/en/Publicationsandstatistics/Publications/PublicationsPolicyAndGuidance/DH/. (accessed on 31/08/11).
  15. Drummond M., Sculpher S., Torrance G., O’Brien B., Stoddart G. third ed. Oxford University Press; Oxford: 2011. Methods for the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programmes. [Google Scholar]
  16. Duclos J.Y., Jalabert V., Araar A. Classical horizontal inequity and reranking: an integrating approach. Research on Economic Inequality. 2003;10:65–100. [Google Scholar]
  17. Galobardes B., John Lynch J., Davey Smith G. Measuring socioeconomic position in health research. British Medical Bulletin. 2007;81–82:21–37. doi: 10.1093/bmb/ldm001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  18. García-Gómez P. Institutions, health shocks and labour market outcomes across Europe. Journal of Health Economics. 2011;30:200–213. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2010.11.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. Gravelle H. Measuring income related inequality in health: standardisation and the partial concentration index. Health Economics. 2003;12:803–819. doi: 10.1002/hec.813. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  20. Gravelle H., Sutton M. Income related inequalities in self assessed health in Britain: 1979–1995. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health. 2003;57:125–129. doi: 10.1136/jech.57.2.125. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  21. Grossman M. On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy. 1972;80:223–255. [Google Scholar]
  22. Hauck K., Rice N. A longitudinal analysis of mental health mobility in Britain. Health Economics. 2004;13:981–1001. doi: 10.1002/hec.939. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  23. Hendry D. Robustifying forecasts from equilibrium-correction models. Journal of Econometrics. 2006;135:399–426. [Google Scholar]
  24. Jenkins, S.P., Van Kerm, P., 2011. Trends in Individual Income Growth: Measurement Methods and British Evidence. ISER Working Paper Series 2011-06. Institute for Social and Economic Research.
  25. Jones A.M., Lopez Nicolas A. Measurement and explanation of socioeconomic inequality in health with longitudinal data. Health Economics. 2004;13:1015–1030. doi: 10.1002/hec.904. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  26. Joyce, R., Muriel, A., Phillips, D., Sibieta, L., 2010. Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2010. IFS Commentary C116. London: Institute for Fiscal Studies. http://www.ifs.org.uk/comms/comm116.pdf.
  27. Kapteyn A., Smith J.P., Van Soest A. Dynamics of work disability and pain. Journal of Health Economics. 2008;27:498–509. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2007.05.002. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  28. Kunst A., Bos V., Lahelma E., Bartley M., Lissau I., Regidor E., Mielck A., Cardano M., Dalstra J., Geurts J., Helmert U., Lennartsson C., Ramm J., Spadea T., Stonegger W., Mackenbach J. Trends in socio-economic inequalities in self-assessed health in 10 European countries. International Journal of Epidemiology. 2005;34:295–305. doi: 10.1093/ije/dyh342. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  29. Leung S., Yu S. On the choice between sample selection and two-part models. Journal of Econometrics. 1996;72:197–229. [Google Scholar]
  30. Leyland A.H. Increasing inequalities in premature mortality in Great Britain. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health. 2004;58:296–302. doi: 10.1136/jech.2003.007278. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  31. Marmot, M., 2010. Fair Society, Healthy Lives: Strategic Review of Health Inequalities in England Post 2010. Marmot Review. London.
  32. Marsaglia G. Evaluating the normal distribution. Journal of Statistical Software. 2004;11(4):1–11. [Google Scholar]
  33. Mundlak Y. On the pooling of time series and cross-section data. Econometrica. 1978;46:69–85. [Google Scholar]
  34. Norman P., Boyle P., Exeter D., Feng Z., Popham F. Rising premature mortality in the UK's persistently deprived areas: only a Scottish phenomenon. Social Science and Medicine. 2011;73:1575–1584. doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2011.09.034. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  35. O’Donnell O., Wagstaff A., Van Doorslaer E., Lindelow M. The World Bank; Washington, DC: 2008. Analyzing Health Equity using Household Survey Data: A Guide to Techniques and their Implementation. [Google Scholar]
  36. Petrie D., Allanson P., Gerdtham U.-G. Accounting for the dead in the longitudinal analysis of income-related health inequalities. Journal of Health Economics. 2011;30:1113–1123. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2011.07.004. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  37. Puhani P. The Heckman correction for sample selection and its critique. Journal of Economic Surveys. 2000;14:53–68. [Google Scholar]
  38. Taylor, M.F., 1995. British Household Panel Survey User Manual Volume A: Introduction. Technical Report and Appendices. University of Essex, Colchester.
  39. University of Essex Institute for Social and Economic Research, 2007. British Household Panel Survey: Waves 1–15, 1991–2006 [computer file]. 3rd Edition. Colchester, Essex: UK Data Archive [distributor], June. SN: 5151.
  40. Van Doorslaer E., Koolman X. Explaining the differences in income-related health inequalities across European countries. Health Economics. 2004;13:609–628. doi: 10.1002/hec.918. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  41. Van Ourti T., Van Doorslaer E., Koolman X. The effect of income growth and inequality on health inequality: theory and empirical evidence from the European panel. Journal of Health Economics. 2009;28:525–539. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.12.005. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  42. Wagstaff A., Van Doorslaer E., Watanabe N. On decomposing the causes of health sector inequalities with an application to malnutrition inequalities in Vietnam. Journal of Econometrics. 2003;112:207–223. [Google Scholar]
  43. Wickens M., Breusch T. Dynamic specification, the long-run and the estimation of transformed regression models. Economic Journal. 1988;98:189–205. [Google Scholar]
  44. Wooldridge J.M. MIT Press; Cambridge, MA: 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross-section and Panel Data. [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES