Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2013 Dec 6;8(12):e80303. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0080303

Spontaneous Centralization of Control in a Network of Company Ownerships

Sebastian M Krause 1,*, Tiago P Peixoto 1, Stefan Bornholdt 1
Editor: Eduardo G Altmann2
PMCID: PMC3855616  PMID: 24324594

Abstract

We introduce a model for the adaptive evolution of a network of company ownerships. In a recent work it has been shown that the empirical global network of corporate control is marked by a central, tightly connected “core” made of a small number of large companies which control a significant part of the global economy. Here we show how a simple, adaptive “rich get richer” dynamics can account for this characteristic, which incorporates the increased buying power of more influential companies, and in turn results in even higher control. We conclude that this kind of centralized structure can emerge without it being an explicit goal of these companies, or as a result of a well-organized strategy.

Introduction

The worldwide network of company ownership provides crucial information for the systemic analysis of the world economy [1], [2]. A complete understanding of its properties and how they are formed has a wide range of potential applications, including assessment and evasion of systemic risk [3], collusion and antitrust regulation [4], [5], market monitoring [6], [7], and strategic investment [8]. Recently, Vitali et al [9] inferred the network structure of global corporate control, using the Orbis 2007 marketing database [10]. Analyzing its structure, they found a tightly connected “core” consisting of a small number of large companies (mostly financial institutions) which control a significant part of the global economy. A central question which arises is what is the dominant mechanism behind this centralization of control. The answer is not obvious, since the decision of firms to buy other firms can be driven by diverse goals: Banks act as financial intermediaries doing monitoring for uninformed investors [6], [7], managers can improve their power by buying other firms instead of paying dividends [11], speculation on stock prices, as well as dividend earnings can be a significant source of revenue [11][13], and companies can have strategic advantages, e.g. due to knowledge sharing [8], [14], [15]. Another possible hypothesis for control centralization is that managers collude to form influential alliances: Indeed, agents (e.g. board members) often work for different firms in central positions [16]. Although all these factors are likely to play a role, we here investigate a different hypothesis, namely that a centralized structure may arise spontaneously, as a result of a simple “rich-get-richer” dynamics [17], without any explicit underlying strategy from the part of the companies. We consider a simple adaptive feedback mechanism [18] which incorporates the indirect control that companies have on other companies they own, which in turn increases their buying power. The higher buying power can then be used to buy portions of more important companies, or a larger number of less important ones, which further increases their relative control, and progressively marginalizes smaller companies. We show that this simple dynamical ingredient suffices to reproduce many of the qualitative features observed in the real data [9], including the emergence of a core-periphery structure and the relative portion of control exerted by the dominating core. Although this does not preclude the possibility that companies may take advantage and further consolidate their privileged positions in the network, it does suggest that deliberate strategizing may not be the dominating factor which leads to global centralization.

Model Description

We consider a network of Inline graphic companies, where a directed edge between two nodes Inline graphic means company Inline graphic owns a portion of company Inline graphic. The relative amount of Inline graphic which Inline graphic owns is given by the matrix Inline graphic (i.e. the ownership shares), such that Inline graphic. We note that it is possible for self-loops to exist, i.e. a company can in principle buy its own shares. In the following, we describe a model with two main mechanisms: 1. The evolution of the relative control of companies, given a static network; 2. The evolution of the network topology via adaptive rewiring of the edges.

1.1 Evolution of control

Here we assume that if Inline graphic owns Inline graphic, it exerts some influence on Inline graphic in a manner which is proportional to Inline graphic. If we let Inline graphic describe the relative amount of control a company Inline graphic has on other companies, we can write

graphic file with name pone.0080303.e015.jpg (1)

where Inline graphic is the adjacency matrix, the parameter Inline graphic determines the propagation of control and Inline graphic is an intrinsic amount of independence between companies. Eq. 1 can be seen as a weighted version of the Katz centrality index [19], which is one of many ways of measuring the relative centrality of nodes in a directed network, such as PageRank [20] and HITS [21]. It converges for Inline graphic and we enforce normalization with Inline graphic. We further assume that the control value Inline graphic directly affects other features such as profit margins, and overall market influence, such that the buying power of companies with large Inline graphic is also increased. This means that the ownership of a company Inline graphic is distributed among the owners Inline graphic, proportionally to their control Inline graphic, i.e.

graphic file with name pone.0080303.e026.jpg (2)

(see Fig. 1). These equations are assumed to evolve on a faster time scale, such that equilibrium is reached before the topology changes, as described in the next section.

Figure 1. Illustration of control and ownership.

Figure 1

Left: The company Inline graphic owns portions of three other companies. The relative control over a company Inline graphic is proportional to the ownership share represented by the weight Inline graphic. The relative control value Inline graphic of Inline graphic partially inherits the value Inline graphic of the owned company Inline graphic. In this way, indirect control is included. Right: The control weights Inline graphic are themselves distributed in a manner which is proportional to the overall relative control of the corresponding controlling company, such that more important companies tend to have bigger shares.

1.2 Evolution of the network topology

Companies may decide to buy or sell shares of a given company at a given time. The actual mechanisms regulating these decisions are in general complicated and largely unknown, since they may involve speculation, actual market value, and other factors, which we do not attempt to model in detail here. Instead, we describe these changes probabilistically, where an edge may be deleted or inserted randomly in the network, and such moves may be accepted or rejected depending on how much it changes the control of the nodes involved. For simplicity, we force the total amount of edges in the network to be kept constant, such that a random edge deletion is always accompanied by a random edge insertion. Such “moves” may be rejected or accepted, based on the change they bring to the Inline graphic values of the companies involved. If we let Inline graphic be the company which buys new shares of company Inline graphic, and Inline graphic which sells shares of company Inline graphic, the probability that the move is accepted is

graphic file with name pone.0080303.e040.jpg (3)

where Inline graphic is computed before the move and Inline graphic afterwards, and the parameter Inline graphic determines the capacity companies have to foresee the advantage of the move, such that for Inline graphic all random moves are accepted, and for Inline graphic they are only accepted if the net gain is positive (see Fig. 2). Note that in Eq. 3 it is implied that companies with larger control will tend to buy more than companies with smaller control, which is well justified by our assumption that control is correlated with profit and wealth.

Figure 2. Illustration of the adaptive process.

Figure 2

Snapshots before the rewiring (left) and afterwards (right), where the edge Inline graphic was deleted from the graph (company Inline graphic gave up its shares of Inline graphic), and new edge Inline graphic was added (company Inline graphic bought shares of company Inline graphic). Important links with high values Inline graphic are favored according to the replacement probability of Eq. 3.

The overall dynamics is composed by performing many rewiring steps as described above, until an equilibrium is reached, i.e. the observed network properties do not change any longer. In order to preserve a separation of time scales between the control and rewiring dynamics, we performed a sufficiently large number of iterations of Eqs. 1 and 2 before each attempted edge move. For this we introduced an additional parameter Inline graphic which incorporates separation of time scales in the limit Inline graphic, and the exact iterative rules were performed as follows. In each time step we choose one of the two options:

  1. With probability Inline graphic, a rewiring move is considered as follows. An edge is chosen at random, where the owner (source of the edge) Inline graphic attempts to give up the shares of the owned company (target of the edge) Inline graphic, i.e. the edge Inline graphic is deleted from the network. Additionally, two non-adjacent companies Inline graphic and Inline graphic are chosen at random, and Inline graphic attempts to buy new shares of company Inline graphic, i.e. the edge Inline graphic is inserted in the network. If the move is accepted due to Eq. 3 (with the additional requirement that Inline graphic is not the last remaining owner of Inline graphic), the number of owners of Inline graphic and Inline graphic both change. Therefore, all weights Inline graphic and Inline graphic with Inline graphic denoting the owners are updated via Eq. 2.

  2. With probability Inline graphic, the control values Inline graphic and weights Inline graphic are updated as follows. A company Inline graphic is randomly chosen, its control value Inline graphic is updated via Eq. 1, and the weights of the owners Inline graphic of Inline graphic, Inline graphic, are updated via Eq. 2.

We performed simulations with Inline graphic and found, that the results do not differ significantly in this range. Thereafter we used Inline graphic for all simulations presented in this paper, as it is sufficient to separate the time scales.

Centralization of Control

A typical outcome of the dynamics can be seen in Figs. 3 and 4 for a network with Inline graphic nodes, average degree Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic (results for Inline graphic are shown additionally for comparison in (a)), after an equilibration time of about Inline graphic time steps. In contrast to the case with Inline graphic, which results in a fully random graph, for a sufficiently high value of Inline graphic the distribution of firm ownerships (i.e. the out-degree of the nodes) becomes very skewed, with a bimodal form. We can divide the most powerful companies into a broad range which owns shares from Inline graphic to about Inline graphic other companies, and a separate group with Inline graphic. The correlation matrix of this network shows that these high-degree nodes are connected strongly among themselves, and own a large portion of the remaining companies (see Figs. 3 and 4). This corresponds to a highly connected “core” of about 45 nodes with Inline graphic, which is highlighted in red in Fig. 4a and can be seen separately in Fig. 4b. The distribution of in-degree (not shown) is bimodal as well with highest values for the inner core. With values up to Inline graphic, the highest in-degree (number of owners) is considerably below the highest out-degree (number of firms owned at once).

Figure 3. Emergence of a core-perephery structure.

Figure 3

(a) Degree distribution of the resulting network for Inline graphic, a control propagation value of Inline graphic, Inline graphic and different values of prior knowledge Inline graphic; (b) Degree correlation matrix for Inline graphic, showing the resulting core-periphery structure. See also Fig. 4.

Figure 4. Emergence of a core-perephery structure.

Figure 4

(a) Graph layout of the whole network, with red nodes representing a chosen fraction of the most highly connected core, and blue ones the periphery, for Inline graphic, a control propagation value of Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic; (b) Subgraph of the most powerful companies with Inline graphic (about 100). The node colors and sizes correspond to the Inline graphic values.

Similarly to the out-degree, the distribution of control values Inline graphic is also bimodal for the network with Inline graphic discussed above (Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic), as can be seen in Fig. 5, and is strongly correlated with the out-degree values. The total fraction of companies controlled by the most powerful ones is very large, as shown on the right panel of Fig. 5. For instance, we see that a fraction of around Inline graphic of the central core controls about Inline graphic of all companies. The companies with intermediary values of control (and out-degree) also possess a significant part of the global control, e.g. around Inline graphic of the most powerful control an additional Inline graphic of the network. It is important to emphasize the difference between these two classes of companies for two reasons: Firstly the inner core inherits control from intermediate companies without the need to gather up all the minor companies. In fact the ownership links going out from the inner core (about Inline graphic) is enough to cover the direct control of only a third of all companies, while the effective control is more than a half. Secondly, the fraction of intermediary companies increases for larger networks. For a network with Inline graphic and the same parameter values as above of Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic, the inner core includes a fraction of only Inline graphic, controlling an effective Inline graphic of the total companies. Nonetheless, all the most powerful companies together account for around Inline graphic of the network and Inline graphic of the total control; values which do not change considerably with system size.

Figure 5. Centralization of control.

Figure 5

Results for the same networks as shown in Fig. 2 (a) with Inline graphic, Inline graphic, Inline graphic and different values of Inline graphic. Left: Probability density of inherited control values Inline graphic; Right: Relative fraction of control as a function of fraction of most powerful companies.

Let us compare the results presented so far with empirical data presented in [9]. For different reasons, this comparison can only be qualitative. First of all, the empirical data includes economic agents with different functions (shareholders, transnational companies and participated companies) out of different sectors (eg. financial and real economy), while we consider identical agents. Secondly, we force every company to be owned 100%, while the empirical data neglects restrained shares and diversified holdings. Thirdly, the control analysis in [9] is done somewhat differently: All the Inline graphic economic agents were considered for the topological characterization, while many companies (80% of all agents there) were neglected for the control analysis. In the empirical data, a strongly connected component of Inline graphic companies controls more than a half of all companies arranged in the out component. This concentration is compatible with the core-periphery structure presented in Fig. 3, however the empirical data does not show a distinct bimodal structure. Nonetheless, there are highly connected substructures in the core, e.g. a structure with 22 highly connected financial companies (Inline graphic) was highlighted in [3]. The control concentration in the empirical data was reported as a fraction of Inline graphic which controls Inline graphic of the network. This is similar to the results of our model (see Fig. 5 on the right). There are, however, features that our model does not reproduce, the most important of which being the out-degree distribution of the network, which in [9] is very broad, and displays no discernible scales, where in our case it is either bimodal or Poisson-like. One possible explanation for this discrepancy is that we have focused on equilibrium steady-state configurations of the dynamics, whereas the real economy is surely far away from such an equilibrium. A more precise model would need to incorporate such transient dynamics in a more realistic way. Nevertheless, the general tendency of the control to be concentrated on relatively few companies is evident in such equilibrium states, and features very prominently in the empirical data as well.

2.1 Transition to centralization

To investigate the transition from homogeneous non-centralized networks with increasing Inline graphic, we measured the inverse participation ratio Inline graphic with the time Inline graphic summing over a sufficiently long time window of length Inline graphic after equilibration. Since Inline graphic, we expect Inline graphic in the perfectly homogeneous case where Inline graphic for all nodes, and Inline graphic if only one node has Inline graphic, and the control is maximally concentrated. As can be seen in Fig. 6, we observe a smooth transition from very homogeneous companies connected in fully random manner for Inline graphic, to a pronounced concentration of control for increased Inline graphic, for which the aforementioned core-periphery is observed. Results are shown for networks of size Inline graphic with Inline graphic and Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (left), respectively, with Inline graphic and Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic (right). The transition becomes more abrupt when either the average degree Inline graphic is increased or the parameter Inline graphic (which determines the fraction of inherited control) is decreased.

Figure 6. Transition to control centralization.

Figure 6

Inverse participation ratio Inline graphic as a function of Inline graphic, for a network with Inline graphic, and for (left) Inline graphic and different values of Inline graphic and (right) Inline graphic and different values of Inline graphic.

Centralization of control can emerge in different ways depending on the parameters Inline graphic and Inline graphic. In Fig. 7, it is shown that different values of Inline graphic for a high value of Inline graphic (with Inline graphic and Inline graphic as in Fig. 3 and 5) can lead to a detached controlling core (Inline graphic) or to broadly distributed control values (Inline graphic). With smaller values of Inline graphic, indirect control is suppressed and companies can gain power only by owning large numbers of marginal companies. E.g.: for Inline graphic, this leads to a highly connected core of Inline graphic companies having Inline graphic, the rest of the companies have very little influence. For larger values of Inline graphic, indirect control has a larger effect, which leads to a hierarchical network where companies with small numbers of owned firms Inline graphic may nevertheless inherit large control values Inline graphic. The case with Inline graphic and Inline graphic shown in Figs. 3 and 5 exhibits a mixture of these two scenarios. The transition to a centralized core also occurs when increasing Inline graphic and keeping Inline graphic constant (see right panel in Fig. 6).

Figure 7. Centralization for different model parameters.

Figure 7

Distribution of out-degrees Inline graphic (left) and inherited control Inline graphic (right) for Inline graphic, Inline graphic and Inline graphic as in Fig. 3 and 5, but for different values of Inline graphic.

One interesting aspect of the centralization of control as we have formulated is that it is not entirely dependent on the adaptive dynamics, and occurs also to some extent on graphs which are static. Simply solving Eqs. 1 and 2 will lead to a non-trivial distribution of control values Inline graphic which depend on the (in this case fixed) network topology and the control inheritance parameter Inline graphic. In Fig. 8 is shown on the left the control values obtained for a square Inline graphic lattice with Inline graphic having periodic boundary conditions and bidirectional edges, propagated with Inline graphic. What is observed is a spontaneous symmetry breaking, where despite the topological equivalence shared between all nodes, a hierarchy of control is formed, which is not unique and will vary between each realization of the dynamics. A similar behavior is also observed for fully random graphs, as shown on the right of Fig. 8. Results are presented for static Poisson graphs with Inline graphic, Inline graphic and values of Inline graphic, Inline graphic, and Inline graphic. The distribution of control values becomes increasingly broader for larger values of Inline graphic, asymptotically approaching a power-law Inline graphic for Inline graphic. This behavior is similar to a phase transition at Inline graphic, where at this point Eq. 1 no longer converges to a solution.

Figure 8. Spontaneous symmetry breaking for static graphs.

Figure 8

Left: Graph layout of a Inline graphic lattice with Inline graphic. The vertex sizes and colors correspond to the Inline graphic values, and the edge thickness to the Inline graphic values. Right: Distribution of inherited control Inline graphic for static Poisson graphs having Inline graphic and Inline graphic, with different values of Inline graphic (for Inline graphic and Inline graphic shifted). The dashed line is a power law with exponent Inline graphic.

Conclusion

We have tested the hypothesis that a rich-get-richer process using a simple, adaptive dynamics is capable of explaining the phenomenon of concentration of control observed in the empirical network of company ownership [9]. The process we proposed incorporates the indirect control that companies have on other companies they own, which increases their buying power in a feedback fashion, and allows them to gain even more control. In our model, the system spontaneously organizes into a steady-state comprised of a well-defined core-periphery structure, which reproduces many qualitative observations in the real data presented in [9], such as the relative portion of control exerted by the dominating companies. Our model shows that this kind of centralized structure can emerge without it being an explicit goal of the companies involved. Instead, it can emerge simply as a result of individual decisions based on local knowledge only, with the effect that powerful companies can increase their relative advantage even further.

It is interesting to note that the topology obtained with our model differs significantly from those resulting from preferential attachment implemented in network growth models, which often lead to scale-free degree distributions [22][24]. This type of broad distribution is also present in the empirical network of corporate control [9], [25]. In these growth models condensation is only observed if the preferential attachment is super-linear, which leads to a “winner takes all” situation with central hub composed of a single node [26]. However, our results are compatible with non-growth models with linear preferential attachment, where condensation occurs via a bimodal degree distribution if the edge rewiring rate is sufficiently large [27], [28]. It is also fruitful to compare our model to other agent based models featuring agents competing for centrality. The emergence of hierarchical, centralized states with interesting patterns of global order was reported for agents creating links according to game theory [29][31] as well as for very simple effective rules of rewiring according to measured centrality [32], [33]. The stylized model of a society studied in [33] shows a hierarchical structure, if the individuals have a preference for social status. The intuitive emergence of hierarchy is associated with shrinking mobility of single agents within the hierarchy. This effect is present in our model as well and deserves further investigation. Another open question is the effect of a superlinear rich get richer dynamics for Inline graphic as well as the effect of nonlinearly increasing control with ownership shares (especially high shares above 50% are believed to be connected with highly increasing control). The latter is known to play only a minor role for the real network of corporate control [9] and therefore should not affect the general behavior of the model.

Our results may shed light on certain antitrust regulation strategies. As we found that a simple mechanism without collusion suffices for control centralization, any regulation which is targeted to diminish such activities may prove fruitless. Instead, targeting the self-organizing features which lead to such concentration, such as e.g. limitations on the indirect control of shareholders representing other companies, may appear more promising.

Funding Statement

The authors have no additional support or funding to report.

References

  • 1. Schweitzer F, Fagiolo G, Sornette D, Vega-Redondo F, Vespignani A, et al. (2009) Economic networks: The new challenges. science 325: 422. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2. Farmer JD, Gallegati M, Hommes C, Kirman A, Ormerod P, et al. (2012) A complex systems approach to constructing better models for managing financial markets and the economy. The European Physical Journal Special Topics 214: 295–324. [Google Scholar]
  • 3. Battiston S, Puliga M, Kaushik R, Tasca P, Caldarelli G (2012) Debtrank: Too central to fail? financial networks, the fed and systemic risk. Scientific reports 2: 541. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4. Gulati R, Nohria N, Zaheer A (2000) Strategic networks. Strategic management journal 21: 203. [Google Scholar]
  • 5. Gilo D, Moshe Y, Spiegel Y (2006) Partial cross ownership and tacit collusion. RAND Journal of Economics 37: 81–99. [Google Scholar]
  • 6. Diamond DW (1984) Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. The Review of Economic Studies 51: 393–414. [Google Scholar]
  • 7. Chirinko RS, Elston JA (2006) Finance, control and profitability: the influence of german banks. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 59: 69–88. [Google Scholar]
  • 8. Teece DJ (1992) Competition, cooperation, and innovation: Organizational arrangements for regimes of rapid technological progress. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 18: 1–25. [Google Scholar]
  • 9. Vitali S, Glattfelder JB, Battiston S (2011) The network of global corporate control. PLoS ONE 6: e25995. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.http://www.bvdinfo.com/products/company-information/international/orbis
  • 11. Jensen MC (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review 76: 323–329. [Google Scholar]
  • 12. Modigliani F, Miller MH (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American economic review 48: 261–297. [Google Scholar]
  • 13. La Porta R, Lopez-de Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (2000) Agency problems and dividend policies around the world. The Journal of Finance 55: 1–33. [Google Scholar]
  • 14. Hamel G (1991) Competition for competence and interpartner learning within international strategic alliances. Strategic management journal 12: 83–103. [Google Scholar]
  • 15. Dyer JH, Singh H (1998) The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of management review 23: 660–679. [Google Scholar]
  • 16. Battiston S, Catanzaro M (2004) Statistical properties of corporate board and director networks. The European Physical Journal B-Condensed Matter and Complex Systems 38: 345–352. [Google Scholar]
  • 17. Simon HA (1955) On a class of skew distribution functions. Biometrika 42: 425–440. [Google Scholar]
  • 18. Gross T, Blasius B (2008) Adaptive coevolutionary networks: a review. Journal of The Royal Society Interface 5: 259–271. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19. Katz L (1953) A new status index derived from sociometric analysis. Psychometrika 18: 39–43. [Google Scholar]
  • 20. Page L, Brin S, Motwani R, Winograd T (1999) The PageRank citation ranking: Bringing order to the web. STANFORD INFOLAB 17. [Google Scholar]
  • 21. Kleinberg JM (1999) Authoritative sources in a hyperlinked environment. J ACM 46: 604–632. [Google Scholar]
  • 22. Price DJdS (1965) Networks of scientific papers. Science 149: 510–515. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23. Barabási AL, Albert R (1999) Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286: 509–512. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24. Giammatteo P, Donato D, Zlatic V, Caldarelli G (2010) A pagerank-based preferential attachment model for the evolution of the world wide web. EPL 91: 18004. [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Glattfelder JB (2013) Decoding Complexity: Uncovering Patterns in Economic Networks. Springer. [Google Scholar]
  • 26. Krapivsky PL, Redner S, Leyvraz F (2000) Connectivity of growing random networks. Phys Rev Lett 85: 4629. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27. Evans TS (2007) Exact solutions for network rewiring models. Eur Phys J B 56: 65–69. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28. Evans TS, Plato ADK (2007) Exact solution for the time evolution of network rewiring models. Phys Rev E 75: 056101. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29. Holme P, Ghoshal G (2006) Dynamics of networking agents competing for high centrality and low degree. Physical review letters 96: 098701. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30. Lee S, Holme P, Wu ZX (2011) Emergent hierarchical structures in multiadaptive games. Physical Review Letters 106: 028702. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31. Do AL, Rudolf L, Gross T (2010) Patterns of cooperation: fairness and coordination in networks of interacting agents. New Journal of Physics 12: 063023. [Google Scholar]
  • 32. König MD, Tessone CJ (2011) Network evolution based on centrality. Physical Review E 84: 056108. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33. Bardoscia M, De Luca G, Livan G, Marsili M, Tessone CJ (2013) The social climbing game. Journal of Statistical Physics 151: 440–457. [Google Scholar]

Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES