Abstract
Divorce and remarriage have reshaped the American family giving rise to questions about the place of stepchildren in remarried families. In this article, we examine money transfers from a couple to each of their children. We introduce characteristics of the family and estimate the role of shared family membership affecting all children in the family as well as the difference that stepchild status and other individual characteristics make in transfer flows. Data are from the Health and Retirement Study. There are two central results in the analysis. Overall, provision of financial help from parents to children is a family phenomenon. While help to a particular child is episodic, differences between families in provision of help were much greater than the differences in helping one child versus another within families. Second, stepchild status does differentiate one child from another within a family. Stepchildren are disadvantaged, particularly stepchildren of the wife.
Changing patterns of parenthood and domestic partnership have reshaped the American family (Cherlin, 2004; Thornton & Young-DeMarco, 2001). In the past decade, families in the United States have experienced high levels of partnership turnover (Cherlin, 2009) with three-quarters of men (78%) and two-thirds of women (69%) remarrying following divorce (Schoen & Standish, 2001). Remarriage is an “incomplete institution”, particularly when one or both partners bring children from a previous marriage into the newly formed family (Cherlin, 1978). Blended families formed after a divorce or widowhood may include joint biological children as well as stepchildren of one or the other spouse. Nearly one in five children live with a stepparent at some point during childhood (Björklund, Ginther, & Sundström, 2007; McLanahan & Percheski, 2008). In blended families, remarried or cohabiting couples and their offspring must overcome ambiguities and uncertainties about relationships (Ganong & Coleman, 2004), appropriate kinship terms (Koenig Kellis, LeClair-Underberg, & Lamb Normand, 2008), and family membership boundaries (Boss & Greenberg, 1984; Stewart, 2005).
The diversity of relationships within a family raises questions about the meaning of family membership and possible differential treatment of children. This article focuses on one aspect of family relationships by examining financial flows from parents to young adult children. We examine both the shared aspects of family membership which lead to similar treatment of all children and diversity of parental relationships which may lead to differential treatment of children in the same family.
Parent to child financial help is important for two reasons. First, providing financial assistance to adult children may help to ease their transition to adulthood (Avery, Goldscheider, & Speare 1992; Semyonov & Lewin-Epstein 2001) and assist less economically-successful children (McGarry & Schoeni 1995; 1997; Schoeni 1997). Children not receiving assistance may be handicapped compared to those who do. Second, intergenerational transfers are indicators of the nature and boundaries of the family group (Schwartz 1967). The degree to which all children are treated equally provides insight into the meaning and significance of family. Conversely, evidence that children with certain characteristics are excluded from the family transfer network may indicate their marginality to the family.
Previous Research on Stepfamily Relations
Stepchildren -- particularly stepchildren of the wife -- receive less financial support from their parents than do biological children (Killian 2004; Berry 2008; Clark & Kenney 2010). The implications of stepchild status may depend on the child’s age at the time of the remarriage. The period of elevated stress that coincides with the formation of a stepfamily tends to be more pronounced and longer in duration when stepfamilies are complex and comprised of half- or stepsibling relationships (Ganong & Coleman, 2004; Hetherington & Kelly, 2002). In contrast, the extent of destabilization tends to be shorter when children are relatively young at the time of remarriage (Hetherington & Kelly, 2002).
A possible explanation for lower investments in and transfers to stepchildren of a mother is the evolutionary argument that mothers have greater investment in their own biological children and hence will favor them (Anderson, Kaplan, Lam, & Lancaster 1999; Biblarz & Raftery 1999). Yet, research focusing on cognitive outcomes -- which reflect investments of parental time and effort (Astone & McLanahan 1991) – challenges this explanation, finding that joint children in blended families perform similarly to stepchildren (Gennetian, 2005; Ginther & Pollak 2004; Halpern-Meekin &Tach, 2008; Tillman, 2008), and that parental investments in adopted children are equal to those in two biological-parent families (Hamilton, Cheng, and Powell 2007). These latter findings suggest the possibility that family functioning in blended families or selection of families into blended or step family status may be responsible for the observed poorer performance of stepchildren.
Though there is evidence of lower parent-to-child transfers in families with stepchildren (Eggebeen 1992; Berry 2008; Clark & Kenney 2010), the distinction between being a stepchild and being in a blended family has received limited attention. The most direct evidence comes from Berry’s (2008) fixed-effects estimates indicating that stepchildren, compared to their siblings, receive substantially lower money transfers. On the other hand, indirect evidence suggests that the overall family effect, which leads to equal treatment of all children in a family, is also strong. In addition to the finding noted above that joint children in blended families have cognitive performance similar to their half-siblings who are stepchildren, substantial evidence suggests that transfers of time or money have a strong family component (Hogan, Eggebeen, & Clogg 1993; Grundy & Henretta 2006; Zissimopoulos & Smith 2010) as well as varying between children in a family. Hence there is evidence for both general family characteristics that produce similar treatment for all children in a family and within-family differences that differentiate treatment between children in a family. The analysis presented here estimates the relative magnitude of these two tendencies and identifies some of the sources of both phenomena.
Research Design
Building upon previous studies on transfers to children (e.g., Killian 2004; Berry 2008), our analysis examines the extent to which parental and individual characteristics affect money transfers. We extend this approach in three important ways. First, we develop a fuller characterization of family structure to examine whether the disadvantage of stepchildren stems from the individual child’s stepchild status or affects all children in a family, even those who are not stepchildren. We examine this issue by estimating the effect of being in a blended family – that is, one including both joint biological children and stepchildren of one or the other spouse – as well as estimating the effect of being a stepchild. The most direct previous research on transfers leads us to expect that stepchild status affects transfers over and above the effects of being in a blended family. Second, we extend the measurement of stepchild status by measuring the child’s age at the time a stepparent entered the household. Existing research suggests stress is lower when children enter blended families at younger ages. Extending this reasoning to relationships with adult children, we expect that stepchildren who were young at the time of the marriage are more likely to be treated like biological children.
Third, we consider the more general family context of transfers by partitioning the variance in provision of help into three components: variance due to family membership, variance unique to each child within a family, and variation over time in the help given to a particular child. Hence we are able to estimate the degree to which transfers are a family phenomenon and to what degree they are specific to individual children within a family. As an adjunct to this goal, we estimate the extent to which financial transfers to children in a family are correlated. That is, to what extent are children in a family treated the same? In addition, we examine the degree to which the measured characteristics of parents, children, and families can account for the correlation in transfers within a family. While previous research suggests a strong family component, there is not adequate evidence to hypothesize the relative size of the shared family variance compared to the variance due to individual children.
Data and Measures
The analysis presented here is based on the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) birth cohort of 1931–1941. These respondents constitute the parental generation, and we examine their relations with their children and stepchildren. The 1931–1941 U.S. birth cohort was the first affected by changing marital patterns (US Census Bureau 1992) that have produced an increased number of blended families.
We analyze panel data over four intervals: 1996 to 1998; 1998 to 2000; 2000 to 2002; and 2002 to 2004. Use of four intervals allows for the episodic nature of transfers from parents to children. Covariates are measured either at the beginning of the interval or within it. The outcome measure, provision of $500 or more to a child in the last two years, is assessed at the end of each interval; thus, we use each interval’s ending year as its label. Measurement of the outcome varied before 1998, and therefore these earlier waves are not utilized. The analysis presented below is restricted to sample member families in which the husband and wife were either married or coupled in 1998, and data are included for intervals in which they remained coupled at the end of the interval. To minimize the possible effects of attrition, the analysis utilizes all available data on any dyad. Therefore, data on families that drop out are used until the point that they drop out. Households with more available intervals have greater influence on the analysis because they appear in the data a larger number of times.
There are 14,544 resident and non-resident children in 3812 sample member households who are age 18 and older in the sample, producing 47,891 child observations over the four intervals. After deletion for missing data, the final sample consists of 40,763 observations on 12,334 children in 3447 respondent households. Over one-third (36%) of missing observations result from missing marriage dates for 188 households (affecting 895 individual children and 2591 child observations over the four intervals). These data are required to calculate a child’s age at the time of the marriage.
Table 1 presents means and percentages for the variables used in the analysis. Data are weighted using the household sampling weight. The response variable is a binary indicator of whether the parents report giving the child or the child’s children a total of $500 or more in financial help over the previous two years (excluding shared housing or shared food).1 If respondents asked for a definition of financial help, they were told that it included “giving money, helping pay bills, or covering specific types of costs such as those for medical care or insurance, schooling, down payment for a home, rent, etc. The financial help can be considered support, a gift or a loan.” For nearly 18% of the observations, the respondent couple had given money to the child in that dyad.
Table 1.
Variable | Percent | Mean | S.D. |
---|---|---|---|
Child received money | 17.6% | ||
Respondents' Characteristics | |||
Year of observation | |||
1998 | 26.6% | ||
2000 | 26.4% | ||
2002 | 24.2% | ||
2004 | 22.8% | ||
Older respondent’s age | |||
under 57 | 4.0% | ||
57–61 | 26.3% | ||
62–66 | 34.1% | ||
67–71 | 24.5% | ||
72+ | 11.1% | ||
Ethnicity (vs. white) | |||
White | 85.2% | ||
Black | 5.8% | ||
Hispanic | 7.4% | ||
Other | 1.6% | ||
Female health | |||
excellent | 14.2% | ||
very good | 35.1% | ||
good | 29.8% | ||
fair | 14.8% | ||
poor | 6.1% | ||
Male health | |||
excellent | 12.2% | ||
very good | 30.6% | ||
good | 32.6% | ||
fair | 17.3% | ||
poor | 7.4% | ||
Assets | |||
negative | 1.9% | ||
zero | 0.6% | ||
LT 25K | 7.2% | ||
25–29K | 6.7% | ||
50–99K | 13.7% | ||
100–249K | 27.5% | ||
250K+ | 42.5% | ||
Log income - male | 10.0 | 1.8 | |
Log income -female | 7.7 | 3.7 | |
Log other household income | 5.7 | 4.0 | |
Family Characteristics | |||
N. male children | 2.25 | 1.56 | |
N. female children | 2.20 | 1.62 | |
Blended (joint biological and stepchildren) | 13.0% | ||
Children's aggregate characteristics. | |||
within family | |||
% college | 54.5% | ||
% male | 51.2% | ||
% married | 63.6% | ||
% have children | 66.6% | ||
Male-family received help | 12.6% | ||
Female-family received help | 12.7% | ||
Individual Child Characteristics | |||
Child's characteristics | |||
Male | 51.2% | ||
Married | 63.7% | ||
Has children | 66.7% | ||
Attend college | 54.6% | ||
Child's age at respondents' marriage and relationship to female | |||
own child | 83.0% | ||
step-ages 0–9 | 3.1% | ||
step- ages 10–17 | 5.2% | ||
step-age 18 and over | 8.7% | ||
Child's age at respondents' marriage and relationship to male | |||
own child | 84.2% | ||
step-ages 0–9 | 3.1% | ||
step- ages 10–17 | 4.7% | ||
step-age 18 and over | 8.1% | ||
Child's age | |||
18–24 | 6.2% | ||
25–34 | 37.2% | ||
35–49 | 55.0% | ||
50–64 | 1.6% | ||
Child was born in a marriage that ended | |||
divorce | 23.7% | ||
widowhood | 4.7% | ||
not classified | 4.4% | ||
born in current marriage | 67.2% |
Respondents’ characteristics
Characteristics of the respondent couple are included because they may affect the willingness or ability of the parents to provide financial help. They include: year of observation; the age of the older respondent in the couple, coded in five-year categories with under 57 as the reference category; ethnicity measured in four categories: non-Hispanic white, non-Hispanic black, Hispanic, and other. Non-Hispanic whites are the reference category. Two categorical variables measure wife’s and husband’s self-rated health, with five categories: excellent (the reference category), very good, good, fair, and poor. Net worth measures housing and financial assets of the respondent couple, coded in seven categories: negative; zero; $1–24,999; $25,000–49,999; $50,000–99,999; $100,000–249,999 (the reference category); and over $250,000. Three income measures: log husband’s earned income, log wife’s earned income, and log other household income measure income of the household, excluding children’s income. Unlike other variables that are measured at the beginning of the interval, income is measured within the interval. The measure refers to the calendar year preceding each interview. To address negative values for other household income, we logged the absolute value of the negative values, multiplied them by negative 1 (−1) and then combined them with the positive values. Zero values were given a log value of zero. The result is a metric in which changes in both large negative and large positive values have declining effects on the probability of providing transfers to children.
Family context measures
Characteristics of the family context are included because it is expected that the characteristics of the family as a group will affect transfers to individual children. They include: whether the family is a blended family including both joint biological children and stepchildren of one or the other spouse; the size of the family measured as the number of male children and number of female children listed by the respondent household; six aggregate characteristics of the children in the family measured as the proportion who attended college, are male, married; and two indicator variables of whether the female or male respondents’ families were helped by relatives while they were growing up. The survey question used is: “Before age 16, was there a time when you or your family received help from relatives because of financial difficulties?” We conceptualize these respondent reports of their family of orientation as measures of the family culture the respondents propagate in their family of procreation, making them more than simply individual characteristics.
Individual child measures
Characteristics of each individual child that may affect parents’ willingness to help financially include the child’s sex; marital status; parental status; college attendance; stepchild status; and age. Stepchild status is measured as the child’s age at the time of the parents’ current marriage based on the wife’s report of the marriage date. The biological child of the respondent is the reference category and is contrasted with under age 10, ages 10–17, and age 18 or older. Children’s characteristics are measured at the beginning of each interval, and both resident and non-resident children of the household are included. We also include an indicator, child status, to measure whether the marriage in which the child was born ended in widowhood or divorce or whether it was not possible to identify the marriage. This variable allows for a difference in parental help to children who were orphaned by the death of a biological parent or who are children of divorce. The reference category is divorce. Of those who were not born in the current marriage, over 70% are children of divorce. We code unknown as an additional category on the child status variable. HRS asks respondents how each marriage ended, and it is possible to identify the marriage into which a particular child was born. HRS collects child’s age, not year of birth. Hence there is some ambiguity in imputing an age at birth, and we allowed births one year before or after a reported marriage to count as born in that marriage. We include college attendance as a measure of the child’s economic status. HRS also asks child’s income, but we have not included it because a number of characteristics make it difficult to include in the analysis.2
Table 2 provides information on the structure of families in the sample. While Table 1 includes observations on individual children in each year, Table 2 includes respondent households once in each year, and the data are weighted using the household weight. The upper panel cross-classifies the number of children brought to the marriage by the husband and by the wife. Slightly over two-thirds of families do not include stepchildren and in nearly 9% each spouse brought two children to the marriage. The bottom panel indicates the proportion of marriages that have biological children of both spouses in addition to stepchildren. All families included in the analysis have at least one child; thus, couples who did not bring children to the marriage all have children born in the marriage. The bottom panel indicates that the probability of having a child in the marriage declines as the number of stepchildren brought to the marriage increases. There is little association between which parent brought the children to the marriage and whether children have been born in the marriage.
Table 2.
Number of Children Wife | ||||
Brings to Marriage | ||||
0 | 1 | 2 or more | ||
Number | 0 | 69.6% | 2.0% | 5.4% |
Husband | 1 | 2.2% | 1.0% | 1.7% |
Brings | 2 or more | 6.6% | 3.0% | 8.7% |
Number of Children | Proportion with Child | |||
Brought to Marriage by | Born in Current Marriage | |||
Husband | Wife | |||
0 | 0 | 100%b | ||
0 | 1 | 74.0% | ||
1 | 0 | 70.9% | ||
1 | 1 | 47.8% | ||
0 | 2 or more | 41.4% | ||
2 or more | 0 | 42.4% | ||
1 | 2 or more | 10.2% | ||
2 or more | 1 | 22.2% | ||
2 or more | 2 or more | 7.7% |
Notes:
Households are observed once at each wave
Only households with children are included in the analysis. Hence households with no stepchildren must have at least one child in the marriage.
Model Specification
Parental money transfers to adult children may involve unequal distributions to different children within the family as well as help to any one child that varies over time. It is also likely that there is variation from one family to the next in their overall tendency to help their children. We estimate a multilevel random intercept model to allow all three types of variability. The model allows estimates of differences between children within the family and differences between families in provision of support. In addition, the estimates within the family are conditional on the specific family context estimated as a family effect (Rabe-Hesketh & Skrondal, 2005, pp. 120 – 124). The approach also accounts for the clustering created by multiple observations within a family and on any one child (Goldstein, Rasbash, Browne, Woodhouse, & Poulain, 2000; Goldstein, Bourne, & Rasbash, 2002).
There are three levels to the data: multiple observations across waves on each child’s receipt of financial help, multiple children in a family, and many families. The baseline variance components model separates variability in the binary response Y into these three levels defined as:
Eq. 1a Eq. 1b Eq. 1c
The subscript i refers to repeated observations of each child’s receipt of money, j indexes children in a family, and k indexes families. Level one (Eq. 1a) concerns within-child variability, i.e. the probability a child receives money, with the random coefficient (Bjk) producing a correlation among observations on a child across waves. Level two (Eq. 1b) concerns child-to-child variability within a family. The child effect, Bjk, equals a family effect (δk) plus an error term for each child (ujk). The family effect, which is shared by all children in a family, produces the correlation between children in a family. In the model shown, the within-child correlation and the correlation between children in the same family are assumed to be positive. Level three (Eq. 1c) describes variation between families equal to a constant (ϕ0) plus an individual term for each family (vk). Combining equations 1a–c, the full model for the distribution of the binary response Y can be expressed as:
Eq. 2 |
When the model is elaborated by adding covariates measured at each level, money transfers to a child are conditional on the parents’, child’s, and family’s characteristics, and unique elements for each child (ujk), and each family (vk) not captured by covariates. Because the behavior of an individual child within a family depends on the family context as well as the child’s own unique element, this is a subject-specific model (Rabe-Hesketh & Skrondal, 2005, p. 120).
Estimation results for multilevel models with a binary outcome vary by estimation method (Guo & Zhao, 2000). The models presented in this paper are maximum likelihood estimates and were derived using the GLLAMM adaptive quadrature procedure in STATA (Rabe-Hesketh, Skrondal, & Pickles, 2004, 2005). Guo and Zhao (2000) treat maximum likelihood estimates as the standard for comparing approximation methods that are computationally more efficient. The implications of weighting in multilevel models are unsettled (Rabe-Hesketh & Skrondal 2006; Brumback et al. 2010), and therefore we present unweighted results.
Results
We began by estimating the intercept-only variance components model in Table 3. Family membership accounted for 47.3% of the variance in transfers.3 This statistic is the same as the residual intra-class correlation (Snijders & Bosker, 1999, p. 224) which measures the degree of similarity between siblings – i.e., the family effect. The result indicates that family transfer behavior differs substantially across families such that differences between families accounts for nearly half of total variance. In contrast, 13.3% of the variance is between children in families and the remainder results from variation in what an individual child receives from one wave to the next, reflecting the episodic nature of transfers. Hence, the overall picture is that family membership is the predominant factor in transfers – suggesting it is a family phenomenon – and, while help to an individual child is episodic, differences between children in a family (including an individual child’s stepchild status) are relatively small contributors to total variance.
Table 3.
Coef. | Std. Err. | ||
---|---|---|---|
Constant | −2.457 | 0.049 | ** |
Variance within families | 1.106 | 0.081 | |
Variance between families | 3.943 | 0.117 | |
Between family as % of variance | 47.30% | ||
Within family as % of variance | 13.30% |
Table 4 elaborates the model by adding covariates to the multilevel logistic regression models for money transfers from parent to child. Model 1 adds parents’ characteristics to the intercept-only equation reported above. Year of observation indicates that transfers were more likely in the 2002–2004 period (the reference category) than in earlier periods and that transfers were least likely during the 2000–2002 period. Interpretation based on macroeconomic trends is speculative, particularly because economic conditions may affect the older and younger family generations differently. It is tempting to suggest, however, that the low point in 2000–2002 may have interrupted the secular trend toward greater transfers because of the US recession between March and November 2001 (National Bureau of Economic Research, 2010) which would have affected the transfers reported in 2002. Older age of the older member of the parent couple is associated with lower transfers. However, the reduction in the size of the age contrasts in Model 3, which includes child’s age, indicates that most of the parents’ age effect results from younger parents having younger adult children.
Table 4.
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Coef. | Std. Err. | Coef. | Std. Err. | Coef. | Std. Err. | ||||
Year of observation (vs. 2004) | |||||||||
1998 | −0.189 | 0.065 | ** | −0.175 | 0.063 | ** | −0.276 | 0.063 | ** |
2000 | −0.155 | 0.056 | ** | −0.143 | 0.055 | ** | −0.205 | 0.056 | ** |
2002 | −0.296 | 0.052 | ** | −0.290 | 0.052 | ** | −0.314 | 0.052 | ** |
Older respondent’s age (vs under 57) | |||||||||
57–61 | −0.389 | 0.102 | ** | −0.250 | 0.101 | * | −0.094 | 0.101 | |
62–66 | −0.612 | 0.115 | ** | −0.331 | 0.113 | ** | −0.055 | 0.115 | |
67–71 | −0.969 | 0.133 | ** | −0.597 | 0.129 | ** | −0.255 | 0.131 | |
72+ | −1.335 | 0.162 | ** | −0.904 | 0.156 | ** | −0.475 | 0.158 | ** |
Ethnicity (vs. white) | |||||||||
Black | −0.137 | 0.133 | −0.010 | 0.122 | −0.065 | 0.121 | |||
Hispanic | −0.859 | 0.156 | ** | −0.572 | 0.142 | ** | −0.790 | 0.141 | ** |
Other | 0.176 | 0.307 | −0.014 | 0.279 | −0.092 | 0.274 | |||
Female health (vs. excellent) | |||||||||
very good | −0.015 | 0.07 | 0.031 | 0.068 | 0.035 | 0.068 | |||
good | −0.165 | 0.078 | * | −0.104 | 0.076 | −0.092 | 0.076 | ||
fair | −0.294 | 0.095 | ** | −0.196 | 0.093 | * | −0.178 | 0.092 | |
poor | −0.273 | 0.132 | * | −0.129 | 0.128 | −0.109 | 0.126 | ||
Male health (vs. excellent) | |||||||||
very good | −0.032 | 0.073 | −0.028 | 0.071 | −0.026 | 0.071 | |||
good | 0.018 | 0.078 | 0.047 | 0.076 | 0.053 | 0.076 | |||
fair | −0.108 | 0.092 | −0.036 | 0.089 | −0.042 | 0.089 | |||
poor | −0.132 | 0.124 | −0.014 | 0.120 | −0.040 | 0.120 | |||
Assets (vs. 100–249K) | |||||||||
negative | −0.768 | 0.188 | ** | −0.643 | 0.184 | ** | −0.689 | 0.185 | ** |
zero | −0.742 | 0.393 | −0.680 | 0.390 | −0.637 | 0.387 | |||
LT 25K | −0.872 | 0.122 | ** | −0.697 | 0.120 | ** | −0.724 | 0.119 | ** |
25–29K | −0.318 | 0.107 | ** | −0.180 | 0.104 | −0.213 | 0.104 | * | |
50–99K | −0.154 | 0.075 | * | −0.064 | 0.074 | −0.074 | 0.074 | ||
250K+ | 0.340 | 0.061 | ** | 0.303 | 0.060 | ** | 0.319 | 0.059 | ** |
Log income - male | 0.076 | 0.013 | ** | 0.074 | 0.013 | ** | 0.075 | 0.013 | ** |
Log income -female | 0.027 | 0.007 | ** | 0.022 | 0.007 | ** | 0.026 | 0.007 | ** |
Log other household incomea | 0.039 | 0.007 | ** | 0.032 | 0.007 | ** | 0.034 | 0.007 | ** |
Male-family received help | 0.291 | 0.115 | * | 0.293 | 0.103 | ** | 0.281 | 0.101 | ** |
Female-family received help | 0.240 | 0.117 | * | 0.301 | 0.105 | ** | 0.291 | 0.103 | ** |
Blended family (joint and step) | −0.031 | 0.112 | 0.314 | 0.105 | ** | 0.569 | 0.123 | ** | |
Children's aggregate characteristics within family | |||||||||
% college | 0.470 | 0.090 | ** | 0.519 | 0.108 | ** | |||
% male | 0.191 | 0.240 | 0.279 | 0.241 | |||||
% married | −0.686 | 0.097 | ** | −0.036 | 0.111 | ||||
% have children | −0.400 | 0.105 | ** | −0.521 | 0.120 | ** | |||
N. male children | −0.331 | 0.042 | ** | −0.273 | 0.042 | ** | |||
N. female children | −0.330 | 0.043 | ** | −0.301 | 0.043 | ** | |||
Child's characteristics | |||||||||
Attend college | −0.120 | 0.061 | * | ||||||
Male | −0.159 | 0.049 | ** | ||||||
Married | −0.541 | 0.055 | ** | ||||||
Has children | 0.394 | 0.060 | ** | ||||||
Child's age (vs. 18–24) | |||||||||
25–34 | −0.981 | 0.078 | ** | ||||||
35–49 | −1.440 | 0.090 | ** | ||||||
50–64 | −1.857 | 0.249 | ** | ||||||
Child's age at respondents' marriage and relationship to female (vs. own child) | |||||||||
step-ages 0–9 | −0.792 | 0.222 | ** | ||||||
step- ages 10–17 | −0.934 | 0.154 | ** | ||||||
step-age 18 and over | −1.046 | 0.136 | ** | ||||||
Child's age at respondents' marriage and relationship to male (vs. own child) | |||||||||
step-ages 0–9 | 0.430 | 0.195 | * | ||||||
step- ages 10–17 | −0.243 | 0.150 | |||||||
step-age 18 and over | −0.510 | 0.139 | ** | ||||||
Child was born in a marriage that ended in: (vs. divorce) | |||||||||
widowhood | 0.210 | 0.176 | |||||||
not classifiable | 0.107 | 0.151 | |||||||
Blended family interaction with: | |||||||||
Child's age at respondents' marriage and relationship to female (vs. own child) | |||||||||
step-ages 0–9 | −1.047 | 0.316 | ** | ||||||
step- ages 10–17 | −0.842 | 0.302 | ** | ||||||
step-age 18 and over | −0.502 | 0.342 | |||||||
Child's age at respondents' marriage and relationship to male (vs. own child) | |||||||||
step-ages 0–9 | −1.285 | 0.289 | ** | ||||||
step- ages 10–17 | −0.349 | 0.306 | |||||||
step-age 18 and over | 0.101 | 0.405 | |||||||
Constant | −2.608 | 0.223 | ** | −1.378 | 0.269 | ** | −0.598 | 0.271 | |
Variance within families | 1.132 | 0.083 | 1.165 | 0.084 | 0.735 | 0.069 | |||
Variance between families | 3.021 | 0.155 | 2.168 | 0.12 | 2.205 | 0.117 | |||
Between family as % of variance | 40.6% | 32.7% | 35.4% | ||||||
Within family as % of variance | 15.2% | 17.6% | 11.8% |
Notes:
Other household income has negative values. We logged the absolute value of negative incomes. The logged absolute value was then multiplied by negative 1 (−1) and combined with the positive values. Zero values were given a log value of zero.
Hispanics are less likely to provide money to children. Poor health for the mother is associated with a reduced probability of helping children, but this relationship is non-significant once children and family characteristics are added to the equation. Higher wealth levels are associated with a higher probability of help to children. These relationships are attenuated somewhat once child and family characteristics are added to the equation, indicating that higher asset levels are associated with family characteristics such as the number of children and proportion who have attended college. Income level is measured separately for men, women, and other shared household income (excluding children’s income). Income of the male has a substantially larger effect than either female income or other income. The associations of these variables with transfers are not substantially changed by the addition of family characteristics.
The parent’s experience while growing up also is associated with transfer behavior. If either parent’s family received help from a family member when he or she was growing up, the family is more likely to help their children. The blended family variable is not significant in Model 1, indicating that, net of parents’ characteristics there is no overall difference in transfers between blended families that include both joint children and stepchildren and other families. Blended status is significant and positive in Model 2 which includes the aggregate children’s characteristics. It is also significant in Model 3, but Model 3 includes interactions involving this variable. We delay discussion of the blended results until later so that the implications of the interactions are included. The inclusion of parental characteristic in Model 1 reduces the proportion of residual variance due to family membership to 40.6% of total variance compared to 47.3% in the intercept-only model.
Model 2 adds children’s aggregate characteristics that also measure the composition of the sibship. Measures of the aggregate characteristics of the children in the family indicate that each child is more likely to receive help in smaller families. Coefficients for number of male children and number of female children are nearly equal. Having a higher proportion of children who attended college – possibly an indicator of parental willingness to pay for a college education for children – is associated with a higher probability of transfers. In Model 2, having a higher proportion of children who are married is associated with a lower probability of transfers. However, this relationship is not significant in Model 3, which suggests that much of the effect of the proportion of married children is attributable to the age or marital status of individual children, as opposed to aggregate family characteristics. Having a higher proportion of children who have produced grandchildren is associated with a lower probability of transfers. The bottom of the column indicates that the residual variance due to family membership is reduced to 32.7% in this model. Hence the composition of the sibship is an important reason why families differ from each other.
Model 3 adds the individual child’s characteristics, including an interaction of blended family status with the individual child’s stepchild status. Examining individual child characteristics, the model indicates that younger, female, and unmarried children, as well as those with lower levels of education, are more likely to receive help. Holding these characteristics constant, children who have produced grandchildren receive higher levels of financial help. In combination with the negative coefficient for the proportion of children who have produced grandchildren, the positive coefficient for the individual child’s having produced grandchildren suggests that the value of grandchildren as attractors of gifts declines as the characteristic becomes more common in the sibship. The negative coefficient for an individual child’s having attended college, controlling for the proportion of children in the family who attended college, indicates a slight advantage in the family for children who have not attended college.
We measure stepchild status with two variables. For each spouse we created a categorical measure of whether the child is a biological child or a stepchild who was aged 0–9, 10–17, or 18 and over at the time of the marriage. The effect of these variables differs between blended and non-blended families so we also include the interaction of each variable with blended status.
Because interaction results are difficult to interpret by simple inspection of coefficients, Table 5 presents these interactions as predicted probabilities of a transfer to a child depending on the child’s stepchild status. The table is for an unmarried female child in a four child family.4 The top half of the Table shows the predicted probability of a transfer to a joint child in a four child family, comparing children in step families to those in non-stepfamilies. A transfer to a joint child has a greater probability of occurring in families with step children. Joint biological children in families without stepchildren have a predicted probability of transfer receipt of 21.8%. In contrast, a joint child in a family with stepchildren has a predicted probability of 33%.
Table 5.
Predicted probability of a transfer to a joint child in a family |
||
with stepchildren |
without stepchildren |
|
33.0% | 21.8% | |
Predicted probability of a transfer to a stepchild in a family |
||
with joint children |
without joint children |
|
Step of male | ||
Child's age at marriage | ||
0–9 | 17.3% | 30.0% |
10–17 | 21.4% | 17.9% |
18 and older | 24.6% | 14.3% |
Step of female | ||
Child's age at marriage | ||
0–9 | 7.2% | 11.2% |
10–17 | 7.7% | 9.8% |
18 and older | 9.5% | 8.9% |
Stepchildren in a family with joint children have a substantially lower probability of receiving transfers compared to a joint child. Stepchildren of the male respondent have predicted probabilities of receipt ranging from 17.3% to 24.6%. Surprisingly, these probabilities are higher among children who were older at the time of the marriage. Stepchildren of the female have probabilities of transfer receipt that are less than half of those of the male’s stepchildren. Probability of receipt for the female’s stepchildren are also slightly higher for those who were older at the time of the parental marriage.
In families without joint children, the probability of receiving help is higher than in families with joint children but the stepchildren of the female remain disadvantaged. In addition, the association with age at the parental marriage reverses direction. Those who are younger at the time of the marriage are more likely to receive help.
Returning to Table 4, the model with children’s characteristics and interactions indicates that 35.4% of the residual variance is due to family membership, 11.8% is due to variation between one child and another in the family, and nearly 53% results from the episodic nature of help to any one child. The estimate of variance due to family membership is slightly higher than the preceding model as can happen in maximum likelihood estimation.
Discussion
There are two central results in the analysis. First, provision of financial help from parents to children is a family phenomenon. While help to a particular child is episodic, differences between families in provision of help were much greater than the differences in helping one child versus another within families. As a result, research on which child in a family receives help addresses only one part of the phenomenon. Overall, nearly half of the variance in helping children is accounted for by family membership and only 13.3% results from differences among siblings within a family. Even after adjusting for parental characteristics, including income, the family history of giving in both spouses’ families, and the aggregate characteristics of children, about one-third of the residual variance still resulted from family membership. Hence, this family effect reflects more than measured characteristics. Some parents give and others do not, a phenomenon that has been observed in other studies as well (Henretta, Soldo, & Van Voorhis, 2011; Henretta, Wolf, Van Voorhis, & Soldo, 2012; Seltzer et al., 2005). An important question for future research is whether the lack of money transfers in some families is associated with lower levels of solidarity measured in other dimensions.
Second, stepchildren are disadvantaged within families, particularly stepchildren of the wife. One possible explanation is that this pattern reflects the predominance of mothers as custodial parents after divorce (Kreider 2005). If a child lives with her mother following the biological parents’ divorce, the biological father and stepmother will have relatively less contact with her and might be less likely to provide money help after the child reaches adulthood. The husband’s children from a previous marriage are disadvantaged after remarriage compared to children born in the present marriage or children the wife brings to the marriage. Moreover, stepchildren who are younger at the time of the new marriage – who are the ones who may lose contact if they live with the other biological parent – are less likely to receive help than children who were older at the time of the marriage. An alternative explanation for the finding that blended families are more likely to aid stepchildren who were older at the time of the marriage may lie in the comparisons parents make. Younger stepchildren may be relatively disadvantaged because they are more likely to be compared to joint children in the new family and may be in more direct competition with them because they are closer in age. This explanation has the advantage of being consistent with the finding that in families without joint children, younger stepchildren at the time of the marriage are more likely to receive money help than similarly-aged children in families with joint children.
Both the relatively privileged position of stepchildren of the male and the tendency toward coresidence with the mother after a divorce are consistent with the genetic argument that women are more concerned for their biological children – that is, they are more altruistic toward them – than are men. Overall, the disadvantaged position of the wife’s stepchildren suggests their marginal position in the family.
In addition to these central findings, the analysis provides additional insight into between-family differences as well as within-family differences. While much of the family effect is unexplained by covariates, the family histories of both husband and wife are important. Those who report that their families received help while they were growing up are more likely to assist children. This measure may be considered a direct measure of family culture. Family differences appear to persist across generations, and future data collection might well devote more attention to measuring this culture.
The research has several limitations. As noted in the earlier definition of the variables used, our measure of child’s need is child’s education, a limited measure. We have not utilized child’s income because it was measured inconsistently over the waves used and has extensive missing data. In addition, we have used a binary indicator of money help to parents, and have not utilized the full information on amount because we do not have suitable instruments to identify a selection equation to address the large majority of respondents who do not provide any money help. It is not clear what the effect of these two data issues on the results might be. Finally, the analysis is limited to the households of the birth cohort of 1931–41 during the period 1996–2002. Hence there may be both cohort and period effects. This cohort, as parents of the post-war baby boom, had higher fertility than subsequent cohorts and therefore have more children whom they might assist. The period observed was a relatively prosperous one economically with the exception of a short recession in 2001, and therefore these results might not be duplicated in a different period.
Based on the two main findings, the results of this analysis suggest an important agenda for family research. First, the results suggest a need to refocus research on intergenerational transfers to examine family differences instead of differences between children in a family. Most of the variance in providing help to either an ascending (Henretta, Soldo, & Van Voorhis 2011) or descending generation occurs between families, but we currently have only a limited understanding of the family differences that produce this variance. Second, there are important within-family differences that result from stepchild status. These differences in relationship continue after children become adults and differ depending on whether the remarriage produced joint children. Hence there is an interaction between the family characteristic of a blended family and the individual child’s status, suggesting a need to consider the diversity of family structures in order to develop a fuller understanding of the implications of being a stepchild.
Acknowledgments
This research was supported by NIH/NIA grants to Henretta (R01 AG 024051) and Soldo (R01 AG024046).
Footnotes
HRS does collect amount of money given to a child if the amount is greater than $500 in the last two years. Amounts are unobserved for those receiving less than $500, over 80% of the observations. Robust estimation of actual amount would be more complex than the multilevel logit model we have estimated.
The question on child’s income was omitted in one of the waves we used and the question format changed from dollar amount to brackets over the waves used. Moreover, there are high levels of missing data on the measure; both the level of missingness and the lack of auxiliary income information make imputation of missing data difficult.
Total variance arises from three sources: variation across waves in transfers to an individual child, variation between children within a family, and variation from one family to another. The estimated total variance is the sum of the variance at all three levels, but the first level is not estimated in the multilevel logistic regression model. Hence we estimate the first level variance to be 3.29 using the threshold model approach (Goldstein, Browne, & Rabash, 2002; Snijders & Bosker, 1999).
Other covariates are set at common values: a 2004 observation for the older parent 57–61, white, very good health for both husband and wife, assets of $100,000–$249,000, at the mean income. The child is unmarried, has children, attended college, is aged 25–34, and if a stepchild was a child of divorce. Each aggregate child characteristic is set at 50% of the children. We also assume a zero family effect.
Contributor Information
John C. Henretta, University of Florida
Matthew F. Van Voorhis, University of Florida
Beth J. Soldo, University of Pennsylvania
References
- Anderson KG, Kaplan H, Lam D, Lancaster J. Paternal care by genetic fathers and stepfathers II: Reports by Xhosa High School students. Evolution and Human Behavior. 1999;20:433–451. [Google Scholar]
- Astone NM, McLanahan SS. Family structure, parental practices and high school completion. American Sociological Review. 1991;56:309–320. [Google Scholar]
- Avery R, Goldscheider FK, Speare A. Feathered nest/gilded cage: Parental income and leaving home in the transition to adulthood. Demography. 1992;29:375–388. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Berry B. Financial transfers from living parents to adult children: Who is helped and why? American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 2008;67:207–239. [Google Scholar]
- Biblarz TJ, Raftery AE. Family structure, educational attainment, and socioeconomic success: Rethinking the ‘pathology of matriarchy’. American Journal of Sociology. 1999;105:321–365. [Google Scholar]
- Biblarz TJ, Raftery AE, Bucur A. Family structure and social mobility. Social Forces. 1997;75:1319–1341. [Google Scholar]
- Björklund A, Ginther D, Sundström M. Family structure and child outcomes in the USA and Sweden. Journal of Population Economics. 2007;20:183–201. [Google Scholar]
- Boss P, Greenberg J. Family boundary ambiguity: A new variable in family stress theory. Family Process. 1984;23:535–546. doi: 10.1111/j.1545-5300.1984.00535.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Brumback BA, Dailey AB, He Z, Brumback LC, Livingston MD. Efforts to adjust for confounding by neighborhood using complex survey data. Statistics in Medicine. 2010;29:1890–1899. doi: 10.1002/sim.3946. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Case A, Lin I-F, McLanahan S. Household resource allocation in stepfamilies: Darwin reflects on the plight of Cinderella. American Economic Review. 1999;89:234–248. [Google Scholar]
- Cherlin AJ. Remarriage as an incomplete institution. American Journal of Sociology. 1978;84:634–650. [Google Scholar]
- Cherlin AJ. The deinstitutionalization of American marriage. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2004;66:848–861. [Google Scholar]
- Cherlin AJ. The Marriage-go-round: The state of marriage and the family in America today. New York: Knopf; 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Clark S, Kenney C. Is the United States experiencing a ‘matrilineal tilt?’: Gender, family structures and financial transfers to adult children. Social Forces. 2010;88:1753–1776. [Google Scholar]
- Cooney TM. Young adults' relations with parents: The influence of recent parental divorce. Journal of Marriage and Family. 1994;1994:45–56. [Google Scholar]
- Eggebeen D. Family structure and intergenerational exchanges. Research on Aging. 1992;14:427–447. [Google Scholar]
- Ganong LH, Coleman M. Stepfamily relationships: Development, dynamics, and interventions. New York: Kluwer Academic; 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Gennetian L. One or two parents? Half or step siblings? The effect of family structure on young children’s achievement. Journal of Population Economics. 2005;18:415–436. [Google Scholar]
- Ginther DK, Pollak RA. Family structure and children’s educational outcomes: Blended families, stylized facts, and descriptive regressions. Demography. 2004;41:671–696. doi: 10.1353/dem.2004.0031. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Goldstein H, Browne W, Rasbash J. Partitioning variance in multilevel models. Understanding Statistics. 2002;1:223–231. [Google Scholar]
- Goldstein H, Rasbash J, Browne W, Woodhouse G, Poulain M. Multilevel models in the study of dynamic household structures. European Journal of Population. 2000;16:373–387. [Google Scholar]
- Grundy E, Henretta JC. Between elderly parents and adult children: a new look at the intergenerational care provided by the ‘sandwich generation’. Ageing & Society. 2006;26:707–722. [Google Scholar]
- Guo G, Zhao H. Multilevel modeling for binary data. Annual Review of Sociology. 2000;26:441–462. [Google Scholar]
- Halpern-Meekin S, Tach L. Heterogeneity in two-parent families and adolescent wellbeing. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2008;70:435–451. [Google Scholar]
- Henretta JC, Soldo BJ, Van Voorhis MF. Why do families differ? Children’s help to an unmarried mother. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2011;73:383–395. doi: 10.1111/j.1741-3737.2010.00813.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Henretta JC, Wolf DA, Van Voorhis MF, Soldo BJ. Family structure and the reproduction of inequality: Parents’ contribution to children’s college costs. Social Science Research. 2012;41:876–887. doi: 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2012.02.008. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Hetherington EM, Kelly J. For better or for worse: divorce reconsidered. 1st ed. New York: W.W. Norton; 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Hamilton L, Cheng S, Powell B. Adoptive parents, adaptive parents: Evaluating the importance of biological ties for parental investment. American Sociological Review. 2007;72:95–116. [Google Scholar]
- Hogan DP, Eggebeen DJ, Clogg CC. The structure of intergenerational exchanges in American families. American Journal of Sociology. 1993;98:1428–1458. [Google Scholar]
- Killian TS. Intergenerational monetary transfers to adult children and stepchildren. Journal of Divorce & Remarriage. 2004;42:105–130. [Google Scholar]
- Koenig Kellis J, LeClair-Underberg C, Lamb Normand E. Stepfamily address terms: 'Sometimes they mean something and sometimes they don't.'. Journal of Family Communication. 2008;8:238–263. [Google Scholar]
- Kreider RM. Number, timing, and duration of marriages and divorces: 2001. Washington, DC: U.S. Census Bureau; 2005. Current Population Reports, P70–97. [Google Scholar]
- McGarry K, Schoeni RF. Transfer behavior in the Health and Retirement Study: Measurement and the redistribution of resources within the family. Journal of Human Resources. 1995;30:S184–S226. [Google Scholar]
- McGarry K, Schoeni RF. Transfer behavior within the family: Results from the Asset and Health Dynamics Study. Journal of Gerontology, Social Sciences. 1997;52B:S82–S92. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- McLanahan S, Percheski C. Family structure and the reproduction of inequalities. Annual Review of Sociology. 2008;34:257–276. [Google Scholar]
- National Bureau of Economic Research. US business cycle expansions and contractions”. [Accessed December 2, 2010];2010 http://www.nber.org/cycles/cyclesmain.html.
- Rabe-Hesketh S, Skrondal A. Multilevel and longitudinal modeling using Stata. College Station, TX: Stata Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Rabe-Hesketh S, Skrondal A. Multilevel modeling of complex survey data. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society A. 2006;169(Pt. 4):805–827. [Google Scholar]
- Rabe-Hesketh S, Skrondal A, Pickles A. GLLAMM manual. [Accessed August 30, 2012];University of California Berkeley Division of Biostatistics Working Paper Series. Paper 160. 2004 http://http://biostats.bepress.com/ucbbiostat/paper160/.
- Rabe-Hesketh S, Skrondal A, Pickles A. Maximum likelihood estimation of limited and discrete dependent variable models with nested random effects. Journal of Econometrics. 2005;128:301–323. [Google Scholar]
- Schoeni RF. Private interhousehold transfers of money and time: NeweEmpirical evidence. Review of Income and Wealth. 1997;43:423–448. [Google Scholar]
- Schwartz B. The social psychology of the gift. American Journal of Sociology. 1967;73:1–11. doi: 10.1086/224432. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Seltzer JA, Bachrach CA, Bianchi SM, Bledsoe CH, Casper LM, Chase-Lansdale P, DiPrete TA, Hotz VJ, Morgan SP, Sanders SG, Thomas D. Explaining family change and variation: Challenges for family demographers. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2005;67:908–925. doi: 10.1111/j.1741-3737.2005.00183.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Semyonov M, Lewin-Epstein N. The impact of parental transfers onlLiving standards of married children. Social Indicators Research. 2001;54(2):115–137. [Google Scholar]
- Snijders T, Bosker R. Multilevel analysis: An introduction to basic and advanced multilevel modeling. London: Sage; 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Stewart SD. Boundary ambiguity in stepfamilies. Journal of Family Issues. 2005;26:1002–1029. [Google Scholar]
- Sweeney MM. Remarriage and stepfamilies: Strategic sites for family scholarship in the 21st century. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2010;72:667–684. [Google Scholar]
- Tillman KH. ‘‘Non-traditional’’ siblings and the academic outcomes of adolescents. Social Science Research. 2008;37:88–108. [Google Scholar]
- Thornton A, Young-DeMarco L. Four decades of trends in attitudes toward family issues in the United States: The 1960s through the 1990s. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2001;63:1009–1037. [Google Scholar]
- US Census Bureau. Marriage, divorce, and remarriage in the 1990's. Washington, DC: U.S. Census Bureau; 1992. [Accessed November 18, 2010]. Current Population Reports P23–180. http://www.census.gov/prod/1/pop/p20-484.pdf. [Google Scholar]
- US Census Bureau. Number, timing, and duration of marriages and divorces: Fall 1996. Washington, DC: U.S. Census Bureau; 2002. [Accessed November 18, 2010]. Current Population Reports, P70–80. http://www.census.gov/prod/2002pubs/p70-80.pdf. [Google Scholar]
- Zissimopoulos JM, Smith JS. Forschungsinstitutzur Zukunft der Arbeit (IZA) Germany: Bonn; 2010. Unequal giving: Monetary gifts to children across countries and over time”. Discussion Paper 4698. [Google Scholar]