Skip to main content
Scientific Reports logoLink to Scientific Reports
. 2014 Dec 12;4:7470. doi: 10.1038/srep07470

Do good actions inspire good actions in others?

Valerio Capraro 1,a, Alessandra Marcelletti 2
PMCID: PMC4264010  PMID: 25502617

Abstract

Actions such as sharing food and cooperating to reach a common goal have played a fundamental role in the evolution of human societies. Despite the importance of such good actions, little is known about if and how they can spread from person to person to person. For instance, does being recipient of an altruistic act increase your probability of being cooperative with a third party? We have conducted an experiment on Amazon Mechanical Turk to test this mechanism using economic games. We have measured willingness to be cooperative through a standard Prisoner's dilemma and willingness to act altruistically using a binary Dictator game. In the baseline treatments, the endowments needed to play were given by the experimenters, as usual; in the control treatments, they came from a good action made by someone else. Across four different comparisons and a total of 572 subjects, we have never found a significant increase of cooperation or altruism when the endowment came from a good action. We conclude that good actions do not necessarily inspire good actions in others. While this is consistent with the theoretical prediction, it challenges the majority of other experimental studies.


Humans are unique in the animal world for their willingness to help others and collaborate to reach a common goal and these attitudes are among the main reasons why human societies are so successful1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9. Good actions, those which maximise the other's payoff, abound in the everyday life and experiments with anonymous people show that they are common even in the ideal setting of a lab, where confounding factors such as long-term strategies, indirect rewards, communication, signalling, etc., are not present10,11,12,13,14,15,16.

Nevertheless, not everyone behaves in such good ways and clouds of selfish people can often be observed in both the everyday life and the lab17,18. Some people perceive the individual cost of restricting their individual freedom of choice as being too large and decide to free-ride and aim for their personal benefit; consequently, people in connections with these free-riders typically decide to either break the link (via active linking19, when allowed) with the free-riders or to free-ride as well (via direct reciprocity7). Either way, this generates a cloud of defectors in the human social network.

To avoid this suboptimal scenario, scholars have started investigating what mechanisms can promote the evolution of good actions in lab experiments. The underlying motivation is that, in case we knew that mechanism M promotes such behaviours, then institutions could use this mechanism to foster good actions and give rise to more successful societies.

Here we consider three different kinds of good actions: altruism, benevolence, and cooperation. Altruism is defined as paying a cost to increase the benefit of someone else. We measure altruistic attitudes through the (binary) Dictator game (DG)20. Here, one person, named dictator, is given an endowment of 100 Monetary Units (MUs), while the other person is given nothing. The dictator can either take all the 100 MUs for himself and leave the other person with nothing or he can split the money evenly. The other person has no choice and receives what the dictator decides to donate. Benevolence is defined as a strong form of altruism, where you make an action that not only increase the other person's payoff, but also the final payoff of the other person is larger than yours15. We measure benevolent characteristics through the Benevolence game (BG)15. Here a person is given an endowment of 100 MUs and has to decide between burning it or give it to another player. Also in this case, the other person has no say. Finally, cooperation is defined as reciprocal altruism, where you pay a cost to increase someone else's benefit, but the other person has the opportunity to reciprocate your good action. We measure cooperative tendencies through the standard Prisoner's dilemma (PD). Here two people are given 100 MUs each and have to decide between hand it over or not. If a participant hands his money over, the other participant earns 100 k MUs, where k > 1. In the DG, it is optimal to keep all the money, but the good action is to split it; in the BG a money maximiser person is indifferent between his two strategies, while the good action is to let the other person get the endowment; in the PD, participants are better off not handing the money over, but the good action is to hand it over. Altruism, benevolence, and cooperation are often correlated14,15, but they are not the same. For instance, in the BG we usually see about 80% of subjects acting benevolently, while in the DG and the PD the percentage of people acting in a good way is often below 50%.

Many studies have been focused on whether mechanisms such as punishment of defectors21,22,23,24, reward of cooperators25,26,27 or a combination of these two28,29,30,31 can promote cooperative behaviour. Little is known about if and how good actions of possibly different nature can spread from person to person to person. For instance, does being recipient of an altruistic action increase your probability to cooperate with a third party? Answering this kind of questions via lab experiments with anonymous participants is particularly relevant now that we live in a society where a ‘substantial part of our life is spent in the company of strangers and transactions are no longer face-to-face’32.

Plato's quote ‘Good actions give strength to ourselves and inspire good actions in others’ suggests that recipients of good actions should act in a better way with others than people who were recipient of a neutral action. Besides the clear applications that this principle, if true, would have on finding ways to foster good behaviours in human societies, it may potentially have deep consequences also in economic theory: if our actions strongly depend on what others have previously done to us, the stability of our preferences over time would be seriously questioned. Perhaps we were selfish yesterday because someone was mean to us in the early morning, and we are altruist today because someone has been kind to us this morning.

Making this problem even more intriguing is the current discrepancy between theoretical predictions and experimental data. From a theoretical point of view, upstream reciprocity33,34, the particular kind of indirect reciprocity32,35 that allows the spread of a good action from person to person to person, has been shown not to lead to the evolution of cooperation, predicting that Plato's principle has no hope to find empirical support. Yet, with one exception36, finding that Person B is not more likely to cooperate in the Public Goods game after being recipient of a cooperative action from one or more Person(s) A, the few experimental studies that have been performed so far generally agree on the fact that good actions actually spread from Person A to Person B to Person C37,38,39,40,41,42,43,44,45. One of these studies46 suggests that the spread of cooperation may depend on the underlying network structures: cooperative behaviour spreads from Person A to Person B to Person C in fixed networks, but not in dynamic networks.

Here we add to this experimental literature and go beyond it in the following way. Our typical experiment involves three people, A, B, and C. The description of the exact design is postponed to the Methods section. Abstractly speaking, all our experiments have the same basic structure: Person B is, at the same time, the target of a decision made by Person A, and the maker of a decision that can affect only Person C. We investigate whether the nature of A's action (good or neutral) affect the nature of B's action. Since we are interested in seeing how B's altruistic and cooperative tendencies change given the choice of A, Person B will either play a Dictator game or a Prisoner's dilemma. This gives rise to two baseline treatments, where B is asked to play either the DG or the PD, after being the recipient of a neutral action (endowment needed to play given by the experimenter). While previous studies have focused on the spread of the same good action, here, motivated by more realistic scenarios, we also study the spread of good actions of possibly different nature. Specifically, by varying the way the endowment is given to Person B by Person A (either an altruistic act in the DG or a benevolent act in the BG) we created four control treatments, where B is asked to play either the DG or the PD after being the recipient of a good action. Thus, besides addressing the question of whether altruism in the dictator game spreads, which was already done in refs. 38 and 41, we can also address three novel research questions: Does being recipient of an altruistic action increase your probability to cooperate with a third party? Does being recipient of a benevolent action increase your probability to cooperate with a third party? Does being recipient of a benevolent action increase your probability to act altruistically in favour of a third party?

Detailed statistical analysis will be reported in the Results section, but we anticipate that, in all four comparisons and a total of 572 subjects, we have never found statistically significant difference in the behaviour of B towards C, depending on how A behaved towards B. Thus our results are in line with the theoretical predictions, but they challenge the experimental results reported in refs. 38 and 41. In the Discussion section we will compare our study with these two and describe what reasons could have driven this discrepancy.

Methods

We performed two studies. In Study 1 we have investigated whether recipients of a good action behave more cooperatively than recipients of a neutral action. In the baseline treatment, subjects in the role of Person B participated in a neutrally framed one-shot PD. Each participant was given an endowment of $0.20 and paired with another anonymous participant (Person C). They could either keep the $0.20 or hand it over. In this latter case, the other participant would earn $0.40. The two control treatments differed from the baseline treatment only in the way the initial $0.20 was given to the participants. In Control 1, participants were informed that they had been previously paired with another participant (Person A), different from Person C, who was the dictator in a DG. Person A was given $0.40 and could decide between keeping it all or splitting it with Person B and they decided to split it. Thus, in Control 1, the endowment needed to play the PD comes from an altruistic act of Person A. Control 2 was similar to Control 1, with the only difference that the $0.20 comes from a BG. Specifically, participants were informed that they had been previously paired with another anonymous participants (Person A) who had to decide between doing nothing or making the benevolent act of letting the other player getting $0.20 at zero cost to themselves. After making their decision, in each treatment participants entered the demographic questionnaire, where we asked for their gender, age, level of education and, finally, the reason of their choice in the game.

In Study 2 we have tested whether recipients of a good action behave more altruistically than recipients of a neutral action. In the baseline treatment, subjects participated to a binary DG. Each participant was given an endowment of $0.20 and had to decide between keeping it and splitting it evenly with the other participant. Also in this case, the two control treatments differed from the baseline only in the way the initial $0.20 was provided. In Control 1 they came from a donation in a previous DG; in Control 2 they came from a benevolent act in a previous BG. As in Study 1, after making their decision, subjects enter the demographic questionnaire, where we asked for their gender, age, level of education, and the reason of their choice in the game.

We recruited US residents using the online labour market Amazon Mechanical Turk (AMT)47,48,49. As in classical lab experiments, AMT workers receive a baseline payment ($0.30 in our case) and can earn an additional bonus depending on how they perform in the game. AMT experiments are easy to implement and cheap to realise, since AMT workers are paid a substantially smaller amount of money than people participating in physical lab experiments. Nevertheless, it has been shown that data gathered using AMT agree both qualitatively and quantitatively with those collected in physical labs in a variety of different strategical situations17,36,48,49.

Yet there are some issues that may potentially invalidate data obtained using AMT. One of the major issues is that some subjects try to complete the game as fast as they can, to get the bonus in the shortest time, and so they may not fully understand the strategic situation that they are facing, increasing the risk of collecting meaningless data. We have addressed this problem in two different ways, depending on whether subjects acting as Player B had to play the DG or the PD. In the PD, we asked for four comprehension questions and we automatically screened out those subjects who failed any of the comprehension questions. Comprehension questions were formulated in order to make clear the tension between maximising one's own payoff and maximising the other's payoff. In the DG, since the strategical situation is really straightforward, we decided to skip the comprehension questions and ask the subjects to describe the reason of their choice. This procedure allowed us to check whether the subjects understood the decision problem, but also to address the second major issue of AMT experiments, namely that some subjects may think that the participants they are paired with are not real. Indeed, typically, in the description of the reason of their choice, one finds a few subjects saying ‘I kept the money because I think the other person is not real’, or similar statements. Of course, we would like to exclude systematically these problematic subjects. To do so, we have manually checked all the original DataSet and we have constructed DataSetExcluded by removing those subjects belonging to one of the following categories: (i) Subjects who explicitly say that they believe that the other participant is not real; (ii) Subjects who do not provide any reason for their choice; (iii) Subjects whose reason of their choice was not consistent with their actual choice. This led us with two datasets to analyse: DataSet and DataSetExcluded. Statistics are reported in the Results section, but we anticipate that the two analyses turned out to be qualitatively equivalent.

After collecting the results, subjects were matched and bonuses were computed and paid. No deception was used. Informed consent was obtained by all participants. These experiments were approved by the Southampton University Ethics Committee on the Use of Human Subjects in Research and carried out in accordance with the approved guidelines.

Results

A total of 232 US subjects (62.9% male, mean age = 30.4) participated in our Study 1, as Person B, passing all comprehension questions. 81 subjects (64.2% male, mean age = 31.1) participated in the baseline and played a neutrally framed PD using an endowment provided by the experimenter; 75 subjects (58.7% male, mean age = 30.4) participated in Control 1 and played the PD using an endowment coming from a donation in a previous DG; 76 subjects (65.8% male, mean age = 29.7) participated in Control 2 and played the PD using an endowment coming from a benevolent act in a previous BG. The average cooperation is very similar across the three treatments (33.3% in the baseline, 33.3% in Control 1, 25.0% in Control 2). See Figure 1. To test for an effect of how the endowment is provided (baseline vs Control 1 and baseline vs Control 2) we use logistic regression, with and without control on gender, age, and level of education, predicting cooperation or defection as the dependent variable. As shown by Table 1 we find no significant effect of how the endowment was provided. Table 2 shows the effect of demographics on cooperation: none of the demographic characteristics we collected predicts cooperation significantly. As mentioned in the Methods section, we now report the statistical analysis of DataSetExcluded. In a manual screening, we excluded 9 subjects and remained with 223 US subjects (62.8% male, mean age = 30.5). 79 subjects (62.9% male, mean age = 31.3) in the baseline, 71 subjects (60.6% male, mean age = 30.4) in Control 1, and 74 subjects (64.9% male, mean age = 29.8) in Control 2. Also in this case, the average cooperation was very similar across the three treatments (33.3% in the baseline, 32.3% in Control 1, and 25.7% in Control 2) and Table 1 shows that the way the endowment was provided had no statistically significant effect on cooperative behaviour. We conclude, that a good action in the DG or in the BG does not inspire a good action in the PD, at least in our subject pool. This conclusion is also supported by the fact that none of the subjects in the control treatments declared that his or her action in the PD was somehow influenced by how they were previously treated.

Figure 1. Average cooperation in Study 1 for each of the three treatments, using DataSet.

Figure 1

Error bars represent the standard error of the mean. It is visually clear that the control treatments do not significantly differ from the baseline. Logistic regression confirms this expectation, as reported in Table 1.

Table 1. The effect of being recipient of a good action on cooperation in the Prisoner's Dilemma. We used logistic regression with and without control on sex, age, and education, using ‘treat’ as a dummy variable. We report the β-value, its standard error, and the significance level. ‘Bas’ stands for ‘Baseline’, ‘Con’ for ‘Control’, and ‘Exc’ for ‘Excluded’. So, for instance, the column ‘Bas Exc vs Con 1 Exc’ reports the results of the regression using Bas Exc = 0 and Con 1 Exc = 1 as dummy variable. We find no significant effect of the dummy variable on cooperation in the PD. Being recipient of a good action does not significantly increase the probability of cooperating in the PD.

  Bas vs Con 1 Bas vs Con 1 Bas Exc vs Con 1 Exc Bas Exc vs Con 1 Exc Bas vs Con 2 Bas vs Con 2 Bas Exc vs Con 2 Exc Bas Exc vs Con 2 Exc
dummy for decision
treat −.000 .043 −.043 .022 −.405 −.419 −.370 −.382
  (.34) (.34) (.35) (.36) (.36) (.36) (.36) (.37)
sex   .020   −.065   −.198   −.227
    (.35)   (.37)   (.38)   (.39)
age   −.012   −.017   −.004   −.004
    (.02)   (.02)   (.02)   (.02)
education   .291   .394*   .252   .308
    (.16)   (.16)   (.17)   (.18)
Constant −.693** −1.620 −.693** −1.800 −.693** −1.399 −.693** −1.595
  (.24) (.99) (.24) (1.04) (.24) (1.02) (.24) (1.03)
Pseudo R2 .000 .019 .000 .034 .007 .019 .006 .024
No. of cases 156 156 149 149 157 157 152 152

Significance level:

**: p < 0.01.

*: p < 0.05.

Table 2. Impact of demographic variables on individual decision in the DG and the PD before and after exclusion of subjects. We used logistic regression and report the β-value, its standard error, and its significance level. Females donate significantly more than males in the DG. Borderline positive effects of age on altruism in the DG and education on cooperation in the PD were also noted.

  DG DG Exc PD PD Exc
dec
sex .671*** .594** .136 .060
  (.18) (.19) (.30) (.30)
age .015* .017 −.001 −.004
  (.01) (.01) (.01) (.01)
education −.092 −.150 .209 .278*
  (.08) (.08) (.14) (.14)
Constant −1.140* −.711 −1.886* −1.994*
  (.46) (.48) (.81) (.84)
Pseudo R2 .029 .029 .010 .015
No. of cases 340 316 232 223

Significance level:

***: p < 0.001.

**: p < 0.01.

*: p < 0.05.

A total of 340 US subjects (63.9% male, mean age = 29.2) participated in our Study 2, as Person B. 112 subjects (59.8% male, mean age = 28.1) participated in the baseline and played a neutrally framed binary DG with endowment provided by the experimenter; 115 subjects (57.4% male, mean age = 28.7) participated in Control 1 and played the binary DG with endowment coming from a donation in a previous binary DG; 113 subjects (74.4% male, mean age = 30.7) participated in Control 2 and played the binary DG with endowment coming from a benevolent act in a previous BG. The average choice (Keep = 0, Split = 1) is very similar across the three treatments (0.43 in the baseline, 0.42 in Control 1, 0.48 in Control 2). See Figure 2. To test for an effect of how the endowment is provided (baseline vs Control 1 and baseline vs Control 2) we use logistic regression, with and without control on gender, age, and level of education, predicting keeping or splitting as the dependent variable. As shown by Table 3 we find no significant effect of how the endowment was provided. Table 2 shows the effect of demographics on cooperation: females donated significantly more than males and age had a borderline significant positive effect on altruism. As mentioned in the Methods section, we now report the statistical analysis of DataSetExcluded. In a manual screening, we excluded 24 subjects and remained with 316 US subjects (62.7% male, mean age = 29.3). 108 subjects (58.3% male, mean age = 28.1) in the baseline, 102 subjects (54.9% male, mean age = 29.3) in Control 1, and 106 subjects (74.5% male, mean age = 30.5) in Control 2. Also in this case, the average choice was very similar across the three treatments (0.45 in the baseline, 0.47 in Control 1, and 0.50 in Control 2) and Table 1 shows that the way the endowment was provided had no statistically significant effect. We conclude, that a good action in the DG or in the BG does not inspire a good action in the DG, at least in our subject pool. We mention that, this time, several participants declared that they were influenced by how they were previously treated. To be more precise, 15 out of 102 subjects in Control 1 Excluded declared ‘The other participant chose to split his 40 cents with me, so I elected to pass on the love and do the same’ or equivalent statements. A similar thing happened in Control 2. Thus there is a psychological effect, but it does not give rise to an economically and statistically significant effect. It is then possible that those people who reported to be positively influenced by the other's choice would split the money anyway.

Figure 2. Average giving in Study 2 for each of the three treatments, using DataSet.

Figure 2

Error bars represent the standard error of the mean. It is visually clear that the control treatments do not significantly differ from the baseline. Logistic regression confirms this expectation, as reported in Table 3.

Table 3. The effect of being recipient of a good action on altruism in the Dictator game. We used logistic regression with and without control on sex, age, and education, using ‘treat’ as a dummy variable. We report the β-value, its standard error, and the significance level. ‘Bas’ stands for ‘Baseline’, ‘Con’ for ‘Control’, and ‘Exc’ for ‘Excluded’. So, for instance, the column ‘Bas Exc vs Con 1 Exc’ reports the results of the regression using Bas Exc = 0 and Con 1 Exc = 1 as dummy variable. We find no significant effect of the dummy on donations in the DG. Being recipient of a good action does not significantly increase the probability of splitting the endowment in the DG.

  Bas vs Con 1 Bas vs Con 1 Bas Exc vs Con 1 Exc Bas Exc vs Con 1 Exc Bas vs Con 2 Bas vs Con 2 Bas Exc vs Con 2 Exc Bas Exc vs Con 2 Exc
dec
treat −.082 −.115 .068 .024 .163 .257 .186 .289
  (.27) (.27) (.28) (.28) (.27) (.28) (.27) (.29)
sex   .545   .436   .624*   .619*
    (.28)   (.29)   (.31)   (.31)
age   .030   .028   .015   .015
    (.02)   (.02)   (.02)   (.02)
education   .047   −.006   −.194   −.229
    (.11)   (.12)   (.11)   (.12)
Constant −.251 −2.078** −.186 −1.556* −.251 −.746 −.186 −.520
  (.19) (.74) (.19) (.76) (.19) (.74) (.19) (.77)
Pseudo R2 .000 .032 .000 .023 .001 .032 .002 .035
No. of cases 227 227 210 210 225 225 214 214

Significance level:

**: p < 0.01.

*: p < 0.05.

Finally, a total of 175 US subjects were recruited to play the role of Person A (90 in the DG and 85 in the BG). Note that the statistics in Table 2 do not include these participants, since they played a different DG ($0.40 at stake, instead of $0.20). Statistics on these subjects are not significant, probably due to the relatively small sample. We used these subjects only to avoid deception and match the players in the role of Person B with a real participant.

Discussion

Good actions are defined as those which maximise the other's payoff. Sharing the endowment in the binary Dictator game (DG), letting the other person take the endowment in the Benevolence game (BG), cooperating in the Prisoner's dilemma (PD), are all examples of good actions. Motivated by Plato's quote ‘Good actions give strength to ourselves and inspire good actions in others’ we have investigated whether good actions of possible different types can spread from person to person to person in the simplest possible way: does a good action of A towards B increase the probability of a good action of B towards C? We have conducted six experiments: two baseline treatments where B has to make a decision in either the DG or the PD using an endowment given by the experimenter; four control treatments where the endowment needed to play comes from either an altruistic action or a benevolent action made by someone else in a previous interaction. Across four comparisons and 572 participants we have never found a significant increase of good actions by player B when they were recipient of a good action.

Our results provide evidence that good actions do not spread from person to person to person and thus they support the theoretical prediction that upstream reciprocity alone does not lead to the evolution of good actions34. However, they challenge the experimental results reported in refs. 38 and 41, which also analyse the spread of altruistic behaviour in the DG.

In ref. 38, the authors show that altruistic behavior spreads when people interact fact-to-face. There is reason to believe that face-to-face interactions are profoundly different from anonymous interactions and this may have driven the spread observed in ref. 38. Indeed, face-to-face good actions are typically accompanied by eye-contact, small talks, smiles, and other kinds of signals, which are likely to improve the recipient's mood so that the recipient's utility is the sum of his material payoff and his non-material payoff given by the fact that his mood has been indirectly improved by other factors. It is then possible that it is not really the fact of being recipient of a good action that inspires other good actions, but the fact that the mood has been improved by other factors.

Closer to our experiment is the one reported in ref. 41, where the authors find evidence of the spread of altruistic actions in an anonymous setting. Here we can only conjecture a reason of the discrepancy between our results and theirs. In the setting of ref. 41, recipients of a good action had a larger endowment to spend and so it is a priori possible that larger givings from recipients of good actions were driven by having just more money to spend. The authors tried to exclude this possibility in their Experiment 2, but they compared only those who were recipient of a bad action with those who were recipient of a good action and it is then not clear where the recipients of a neutral action are seated. Moreover, when they analysed whether the endowment had driven their effect, they found a non-significant but rather small p-value (0.12), when compared with the sample size, that was rather small as well (100 participants, divided in four treatments). It is then possible that the same experiment, with a little larger sample, would have given negative results; or, alternatively, that comparing also the recipients of a neutral action would have shown that their effect was driven by a strong decrease on the givings from those who were recipient of a bad action, rather than an increase from those who were recipient of a good action.

Further investigation are then needed to solve this discrepancy, also in light of the fact that our experiment as well has its own limitations, the major of which is that it is virtually impossible to convince AMT workers that the people they interact with are real. To address this problem, we asked the subjects to write the reason of their choice and conducted two statistical analyses, one including all participants and one including only those whose description revealed that they were playing as they would do in reality. Although the two analyses gave qualitatively equivalent results, we cannot be completely sure that all participants in the second analysis acted as they would act in a real scenario: it is possible that they described a reason consistent with a real scenario, but behaved as the other participants were not real. On the other hand, it is extremely difficult to design an experiment where participants are made completely convinced that the other participants are real, without generating confounding factors. For instance, showing pictures, names, or TurkIDs would decrease the ‘distance’ between the participants with the consequence of increasing good actions, as shown by a number of similar studies50,51,52.

In addition to what described above, our results also contribute to the increasing body of literature regarding gender differences in the Dictator game. Alike the majority of studies53,54,55,56,57,58,59,60, but not all57,60,61, we too have found that females are significantly more generous than males in the Dictator game. Furthermore, consistent with Engel's metastudy62, we too have found that age has a positive effect on giving in the DG, though our effect is only borderline significant (P = 0.05 in DG and P = 0.092 in DG excluded).

Finally, our results add to the research concerning framing effects in the Dictator game and the Prisoner's dilemma. A number of studies57,59,63 agree that behaviour in the Dictator game is independent of the name of the game (Keep game vs Take game) and the name of the strategies (Keep vs Give). Here we have shown that it is independent of how the endowment is provided (by the experimenter vs by someone else through a good act). Similarly, a number of studies64,65,66,67,68,69,70,71,72,73,74,75, but not all76,77,78, suggest that behaviour in the Prisoner's dilemma depends on the name of the game and the name of the strategies. Here we have provided evidence that it does not depend on how the endowment is provided.

Author Contributions

V.C. designed and performed the experiment, V.C. and A.M. analysed the data and wrote the manuscript.

Supplementary Material

Supplementary Information

Supplementary Information

srep07470-s1.pdf (95.4KB, pdf)

References

  1. Trivers R. The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q Rev Biol 46, 35–57 (1971). [Google Scholar]
  2. Axelrod R. & Hamilton W. D. The evolution of cooperation. Science 211, 1390–1396 (1981). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  3. Ostrom E. Collective action and the evolution of social norms. J Econ Perspect 14, 137–158 (2000). [Google Scholar]
  4. Fehr E. & Fischbacher U. The nature of human altruism. Nature 425, 785–791 (2003). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  5. Fehr E. & Fischbacher U. Social norms and human cooperation. Trends Cogn Sci 8, 185–190 (2004). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  6. Kaplan H. & Gurven M. The natural history of human food sharing and cooperation: a review and a new multi-individual approach to the negotiation of norms. In:: Moral sentiments and material interests: The foundations of cooperation in economic life [Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R. & Fehr, E. (eds.)] [57–113] (MIT Press, Cambridge, 2005). [Google Scholar]
  7. Nowak M. A. Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science 314, 1560–1563 (2006). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  8. Rand D. G. & Nowak M. A. Human cooperation. Trends Cogn Sci 17, 413–425 (2013). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  9. Capraro V. A Model of Human Cooperation in Social Dilemmas. PLoS ONE 8, e72427; 10.1371/journal.pone.0072427 (2013). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  10. Wong R. Y. & Hong Y. Y. Dynamic Influences of Culture on Cooperation in the Prisoner's Dilemma. Psychol Sci 16, 429–434 (2005). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  11. Engel C. & Zhurakhovska L. When is the Risk of Cooperation Worth Taking? The Prisoners Dilemma as a Game of Multiple Motives. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2132501 (2012) (Date of access: 14/11/2014).
  12. Khadjavi M. & Lange A. Prisoners and their dilemma. J Econ Behav Organ 92, 163–175 (2013). [Google Scholar]
  13. Barcelo H. & Capraro V. Group size effect on cooperation in social dilemmas. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2425030 (2014) (Date of access: 14/11/2014).
  14. Capraro V., Jordan J. J. & Rand D. G. Heuristics guide the implementation of social preferences in one-shot Prisoner's Dilemma experiments. Sci Rep 4, 6790 10.1038/srep06790 (2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  15. Capraro V., Smyth C., Mylona K. & Niblo G. A. Benevolent characteristics promote cooperative behaviour among humans. PLoS ONE 9, e102881; 10.1371/journal.pone.0102881 (2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  16. Capraro V. The emergence of altruistic behaviour in conflictual situations. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2505920 (2014) (Date of access: 13/11/2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  17. Rand D. G., Arbesman S. & Christakis N. A. Dynamic social networks promote cooperation in experiments with humans. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 108, 19193–19198 (2011). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  18. Wang J., Suri S. &Watts D. J. Cooperation and assortativity with dynamic partner updating. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 109, 14363–14368 (2012). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. Pacheco J. M., Traulsen A. & Nowak M. A. Active linking in evolutionary games. J Theor Biol 243, 437–443 (2006). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  20. Kahneman D., Knetsch J. L. & Thaler R. Fairness And The Assumptions Of Economics. J Bus 59, S4:S285 (1986). [Google Scholar]
  21. Boyd R. & Richerson P. J. Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethol Sociobiol 13, 171–195 (1992). [Google Scholar]
  22. Fehr E. & Gächter S. Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90, 980–994 (2000). [Google Scholar]
  23. Fehr E. & Gächter S. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415, 137–140 (2002). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  24. Gürerk Ö., Irlenbusch B. & Rockenbach B. The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions. Science 312, 108–111 (2006). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  25. Milinski M., Semmann D. & Krambeck H. J. Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Nature 415, 424–426 (2002). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  26. Panchanathan K. & Boyd R. Indirect reciprocity can stabilize cooperation without the second-order free rider problem. Nature 432, 499–502 (2004). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  27. Milinski M., Semmann D., Krambeck H. J. & Marotzke J. Stabilizing the Earth's climate is not a losing game: supporting evidence from public goods experiments. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 103, 3994–3998 (2006). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  28. Andreoni J., Harbaugh W. & Vesterlund L. The carrot or the stick: rewards, punishments, and cooperation. Am Econ Rev 93, 893–902 (2003). [Google Scholar]
  29. Rockenbach B. & Milinski M. The efficient interaction of indirect reciprocity and costly pun- ishment. Nature 444, 718–723 (2006). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  30. Sefton M., Shupp R. & Walker J. M. The effects of rewards and sanctions in provision of public goods. Econ Inq 45, 671–690 (2007). [Google Scholar]
  31. Hilbe C. & Sigmund K. Incentives and opportunism: from the carrot to the stick. Proc R Soc B 277, 2427–2433 (2010). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  32. Nowak M. A. & Sigmund K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 437, 1291–1298 (2005). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  33. Boyd R. & Richerson P. J. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Soc Networks 11, 213–236 (1989). [Google Scholar]
  34. Nowak M. A. & Roch S. Upstream reciprocity and the evolution of gratitude. Proc Roy Soc B 207, 605–610 (2007). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  35. Sigmund K. The calculus of selfishness. Princeton University Press, Princeton, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  36. Suri S. & Watts D. J. Cooperation and Contagion in Web-Based, Networked Public Goods Experiments. PLoS ONE 6, e16836; 10.1371/journal.pone.0016836 (2011). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  37. Bartlett B. Y. & DeSteno D. Gratitude and prosocial behavior helping when it costs you. Psychol Sci 17, 319–325 (2006). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  38. Dufwenberg M., Gneezy U., Güth W. & van Damme E. Direct vs indirect reciprocity: an experiment. Homo Oecon 18, 19–30 (2001). [Google Scholar]
  39. Fowler J. H. & Christakis N. A. Cooperative behavior cascades in human social networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 107, 5334–5338 (2010). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  40. Gray K., Ward A. F. & Norton M. I. Paying it Forward: Generalized Reciprocity and the Limits of Generosity. J Exp Psychol Gen 143, 247–254 (2014). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  41. Güth W., Königstein M., Marchand N., Nehring K. T. Trust and reciprocity in the investment game with indirect reward. Homo Oecon 18, 241–262 (2001). [Google Scholar]
  42. Stanca L. Measuring Indirect Reciprocity: Whose Back Do We Scratch? J Econ Psychol 30, 190–202 (2009). [Google Scholar]
  43. Tsvetkova M. & Macy M. W. The Social Contagion of Generosity. PLoS ONE 9, e87275; 10.1371/journal.pone.0087275 (2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  44. Leimgruber K. L., Ward A. F., Widness J., Norton M. I., Olson K. R. et al. Give What You Get: Capuchin Monkeys (Cebus apella) and 4-Year-Old Children Pay Forward Positive and Negative Outcomes to Conspecifics. PLoS ONE 9, e87035; 10.1371/journal.pone.0087035 (2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  45. Watanabe T. et al. Two distinct neural mechanisms underlying indirect reciprocity. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 111, 3990–3995 (2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  46. Jordan J. J., Rand D. G., Arbesman S., Fowler J. H. & Christakis N. A. Contagion of Cooperation in Static and Fluid Social Networks. PLoS ONE 8, e66199; 10.1371/journal.pone.0066199 (2013). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  47. Paolacci G., Chandler J. & Ipeirotis P. G. Running Experiments on Amazon Mechanical Turk. Judgm Decis Mak 5, 411–419 (2010). [Google Scholar]
  48. Horton J. J., Rand D. G. & Zeckhauser R. J. The online laboratory: conducting experiments in a real labor market. Exper Econ 14, 399–425 (2011). [Google Scholar]
  49. Rand D. G. The promise of Mechanical Turk: How online labor markets can help theorists run behavioral experiments. J Theor Biol 299, 172–179 (2012). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  50. Frohlich N., Oppenheimer J. & Moore J. B. Some doubts about measuring selfinterest using dictator experiments: the costs of anonimity. J Econ Behav Organ 46, 271–290 (2001). [Google Scholar]
  51. Burnham T. C. Engineering altruism: a theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving. J Econ Behav Organ 50, 133–144 (2003). [Google Scholar]
  52. Charness G. & Gneezy U. What's in a name? Anonymity and social distance in dictator and ultimatum games. J Econ Behav Organ 68, 29–35 (2008). [Google Scholar]
  53. Eckel C. C. & Grossmann P. Are Women Less Selfish than Men? Evidence from Dictator Experiments. Econ J 107, 726–735 (1997). [Google Scholar]
  54. Andreoni J. & Vesterlund L. Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Q J Econ 116, 293–312 (2001). [Google Scholar]
  55. Dufwenberg M. & Muren A. Gender Composition in Teams. J Econ Behav Organ 61, 50–54 (2006). [Google Scholar]
  56. Houser D. & Schunk D. Fairness, competition and gender: Evidence from German schoolchildren. J Econ Psychol 30, 634–641 (2009). [Google Scholar]
  57. Dreber A., Ellingsen T., Johannesson M. & Rand D. G. Do people care about social context? Framing effects in dictator games. Exp Econ 16, 349–371 (2013). [Google Scholar]
  58. Dreber A., von Essen E. & Ranehill E. Gender and competition in adolescence: task matters. Exp Econ 17, 154–172 (2014). [Google Scholar]
  59. Kettner S. E. & Ceccato S. Framing Matters in Gender-Paired Dictator Games. Discussion paper series, University of Heidelberg, Department of Economics (2014) (Date of access: 13/11/2014). [Google Scholar]
  60. Boschini A., Dreber A., von Essen E., Muren A. & Ranehill E. Gender and economic preferences in a large random and representative sample. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2443315 (2014) (Date of access: 14/11/2014).
  61. Bolton G. E. & Katok E. An Experimental Test for Gender Differences in Beneficent Behaviour. Econ Lett 18, 287–292 (1995). [Google Scholar]
  62. Engel C. Dictator Games: A Meta Study. Exp Econ 14, 583–610 (2011). [Google Scholar]
  63. Suvoy R. The effects of give and take framing in a dictator game. Unpublished Honors Thesis available at https://scholarsbank.uoregon.edu, University of Oregon (2003) (Date of access: 14/11/2014).
  64. Liberman V., Samuels S. M. & Ross L. The name of the game: predictive power of reputations versus situational labels in determining prisoner's dilemma game moves. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 30, 1175–1185 (2004). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  65. Kay A. C. & Ross L. The perceptual push: the interplay of implicit cues and explicit situational construals on behavioral intentions in the Prisoner's dilemma. J Pers Soc Psychol 39, 634–643 (2003). [Google Scholar]
  66. Andreoni J. Warm-glow versus cold-prickle: the effects of positive and negative framing on cooperation in experiments. Q J Econ 110, 1–21 (1995). [Google Scholar]
  67. Brewer M. B. & Kramer R. M. Choice behavior in social dilemmas: effects of social identity, group size, and decision framing. J Pers Soc Psychol 50, 543–549 (1986). [Google Scholar]
  68. Cookson R. Framing effects in public goods experiments. Exp Econ 3, 55–79 (2000). [Google Scholar]
  69. Ellingsen T., Johannesson M., Mollerstrom J. & Munkhammar S. Social framing effects: preferences or beliefs? Games Econ Behav 76, 117–130 (2012). [Google Scholar]
  70. McDaniel W. C. & Sistrunk F. Management dilemmas and decisions: impact of framing and anticipated responses. J Confl Resolut 35, 21–42 (1991). [Google Scholar]
  71. McCusker C. & Carnevale P. J. Framing in resource dilemmas: loss aversion and the moderating effects on sanctions. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 61, 190–201 (1995). [Google Scholar]
  72. Pillutla M. M. & Chen X. Social norms and cooperation in social dilemmas: the effects of context and feedback. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 78, 81–103 (1999). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  73. Sell J. & Son Y. Comparing public goods and common pool resources: three experiments. Soc Psychol Q 60, 118–137 (1997). [Google Scholar]
  74. van Dijk E. & Wilke H. Decision-induced focusing in social dilemmas: Give-some, keep-some, take-some, and leave-some dilemmas. J Pers Soc Psychol 78, 92–104 (2000). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  75. Zhong C. B., Loewenstein J. & Murnighan J. K. Speaking the same language: the cooperative effects of labeling in the prisoner's dilemma. J Confl Resolut 51, 431–456 (2007). [Google Scholar]
  76. Cubitt R. P., Drouvelis M. & Gächter S. Framing and free riding: emotional responses and punishment in social dilemma games. Exp Econ 14, 254–272 (2011). [Google Scholar]
  77. Dufwenberg M., Gächter S. & Hennig-Schmidt H. The framing of games and the psychology of play. Games Econ Behav 73, 459–478 (2011). [Google Scholar]
  78. Rege M. & Telle K. The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. J Public Econ 88, 1625–1644 (2004). [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Supplementary Information

Supplementary Information

srep07470-s1.pdf (95.4KB, pdf)

Articles from Scientific Reports are provided here courtesy of Nature Publishing Group

RESOURCES