Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2015 Aug 1.
Published in final edited form as: J Dev Stud. 2014 Aug 1;50(8):1172–1196. doi: 10.1080/00220388.2014.919383

Cash transfer programme, productive activities and labour supply: Evidence from randomized experiment in Kenya

Solomon Asfaw 1,*, Benjamin Davis 1, Josh Dewbre 1, Sudhanshu Handa 2, Paul Winters 3
PMCID: PMC4316733  NIHMSID: NIHMS653960  PMID: 25663712

Abstract

This paper reports analysis of the impact of Kenya’s Cash Transfer for Orphans and Vulnerable Children Programme on the household decisions on productive activities using data from a randomized experimental design. Results show that the programme had a positive and significant impact on food consumption coming from home production, accumulation of productive assets, especially on the ownership of small livestock and on formation of nonfarm enterprise, especially for females. The programme has provided more flexibility to families in terms of labour allocation decisions, particularly for those who are geographically isolated. The programme was also found to have reduced child labour, an important objective of the programme. However we find very little impact of the programme on direct indicators of crop production.

Keywords: cash transfers, impact evaluation, productive impact, difference in difference, propensity score, Kenya

1. Introduction

Over the past 15 years, a growing number of African governments have launched safety net programmes to provide assistance to the elderly and children, as well as households that are ultra-poor, labour-constrained, and/or caring for orphan and vulnerable children. Cash transfer programmes in African countries have tended to be unconditional (where regular and predictable transfers of money are given directly to beneficiary households without conditions or labour requirements) rather than conditional (more common in Latin America), which require recipients to meet certain conditions such as using basic health services or sending their children to school. Most of these programmes seek to reduce poverty and vulnerability by improving food consumption, nutritional and health status and school attendance.

The Kenya Cash Transfer Programme for Orphans and Vulnerable Children (CT-OVC) is the government’s flagship social protection programme, reaching over 150,000 households across the country as of December, 2012, with the ultimate goal of providing coverage to 300,000 households. A flat monthly transfer of Ksh 1500 (approximately US$21; increased in the 2011/12 budget from Ksh 1500 to Ksh 2000) is given to those households who are ultra-poor and contain OVC (Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team, 2012). OVC are defined as household residents between zero and 17 years old with at least one deceased parent, or a parent who is chronically ill, or whose main caregiver is chronically ill. The value of the transfer represented an average of 14 percent of the expenditures of the beneficiary households in 2011. Given the fixed transfer amount regardless of household size, in per capita terms the transfer is larger for smaller-sized households. Due to inflation, the real value of the transfer declined by 40 percent between 2007 and 2009, and by an additional 15 percent between 2009 and 2011. The Government of Kenya began implementing the CT-OVC as a pilot in 2004. After a three-year demonstration period, the programme was formally approved by Cabinet, integrated into the national budget and began expanding rapidly in 2007. Further details on the programme and the targeting procedure can be found in Handa et al. (2012).

Although the primary goal of the programme is to build human capital and to improve the care of OVC, there are good reasons to believe that cash transfer programmes, and the CT-OVC programme in particular, can have impacts on household decision making including labour supply, accumulation of productive assets and productive activities. Most beneficiaries of cash transfer programmes in Sub Saharan Africa live in rural areas, depend on subsistence agriculture and live in places where markets for financial services (such as credit and insurance), labour, goods and inputs are lacking or do not function well. Cash transfers often represent a significant share of household income, and when provided in a regular and predicable fashion, may help households in overcoming the obstacles that block their access to credit or cash.

There is robust evidence from numerous countries (especially Latin America and increasingly Sub Saharan Africa) that cash transfers have leveraged sizeable gains in access to health and education services, as measured by increases in school enrolment (particularly for girls) and use of health services (particularly preventative health, and health monitoring for children and pregnant women) (e.g., Fiszbein and Schady, 2009; Barrientos and DeJong, 2004; Davis et al., 2012). However, there is relatively limited empirical evidence on the productive impact of cash transfer programmes, particularly in the African context. Todd et al. (2010) and Gertler et al. (2012) find that the Mexican PROGRESA programme led to increased land use, livestock ownership, crop production and agricultural expenditures and a greater likelihood of operating a microenterprise. Soares et al. (2010) find from their analysis of a conditional cash transfer (CCT) programme in Paraguay that beneficiary households invested between 45–50 percent more in agricultural production and that the programme also increased the probability that households would acquire livestock by 6 percent. Martinez (2004) found that the BONOSOL pension programme in Bolivia had a positive impact on animal ownership, expenditures on farm inputs, and crop output, although the specific choice of investment differs according to the gender of the beneficiary.

In contrast, Maluccio (2010) finds that the Red de Proteccion Social (RPS) programme in Nicaragua had muted impacts on the acquisition of farm implements and no impact on livestock or land ownership (Maluccio, 2010). The results in Nicaragua may stem from the implementation of the RPS pilot, in particular the low levels of transfers (as share of total income) combined with a stronger programme emphasis and pressure on how the transfers should be spent (Davis et al., 2010).

On the other hand, CCTs in Latin America have been shown to have little impact on work incentives and adult labour supply. Studies of Bolsa Familia in Brazil (Ribas and Soares, 2111; Foguel and Paes de Barrios, 2010; Teixeira, 2010), PROGRESA in Mexico (Parker and Skoufias, 2000; Skoufias and di Maro, 2008; Alzua et al., 2010), the Red de Proteccion Social in Nicaragua (Maluccio and Flores, 2005; Maluccio, 2010; Alzua et al., 2010), the BDH programme in Ecuador (Edmonds and Schady, 2008) and PRAF in Honduras (Alzua et al., 2010; Galiani and McEwan, 2012), using a variety of approaches, have not found significant impact on participation in wage employment by adults, female or male, nor reallocation between agricultural and non agricultural sectors. There is some evidence, however, that CCTs have modestly reduced time spent working, for males in Nicaragua (Maluccio and Flores, 2005) and females in Brazil (Teixeira, 2010), and substitution between wage and domestic home work in Brazil (Ribas and Soares, 2011). And Handa et al. (2010) find that agricultural households benefiting from PROGRESA were less likely to comply with conditionality due to time conflicts with agricultural work on their own farms. Finally, a number of programmes have been found to lead to reduced child labour (see the review in Fiszbein and Shady, 2009).

With respect to Sub-Saharan Africa, Covarrubias et al. (2012) and Boone et al. (2013) found that the Malawi SCT programme led to increased investment in agricultural assets, including crop implements and livestock and increased satisfaction of household consumption by own production. Gilligan et al. (2009) found that Ethiopian households with access to both the Productive Safety Net Programme (PSNP) as well as complementary packages of agricultural support were more likely to be food secure, to borrow for productive purposes, use improved agricultural technologies, and operate their own nonfarm business activities. In a later study, Berhane et al. (2011) found that the PSNP led to a significant improvement in food security status for those that had participated in the programme for 5 years versus those who only received one year of benefits. Moreover, those households that participated in PNSP as well as the complementary programmes had significantly higher grain production and fertilizer use. However, beneficiaries did not experience faster asset growth (livestock, land or farm implements) as a result of the programmes (Gilligan et al., 2009; Gilligan and Hoddinott, 2007).

Early evidence from cash transfers in SSA shows a mixed picture in terms of labour supply. Gilligan et al. (2009) in Ethiopia found that households with access to both the PSNP and a complementary package of agricultural support showed no indication of disincentive effects on labour supply, while Ardington et al. (2008) find that the South African Old Age Pension had a positive effect on adult labour supply arguing that the OAP relieved financial and child care constraints. On the other hand, Covarrubias et al. (2012) found that the Malawi cash transfer programme led to shift from agricultural wage labour and child work off farm to increased labour allocation to on farm activities by both adults and children.

Building on the existing literature, we analyze the productive impact of the Kenya CT-OVC programme on the accumulation of productive assets, food consumption by source, resource allocation among productive activities and changes in the labour supply of household members. The impact evaluation strategy was based on a randomized cluster longitudinal design, and the framework for empirical analysis is based on a comparison of programme beneficiaries with a group of non-beneficiaries serving as controls, all interviewed before the programme began and again four years later.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a conceptual framework on the link between cash transfers, productivity activities and labour supply. Survey design and data collection methods are discussed in Section 3. The fourth section presents the analytical methods, with emphasis on empirical models and hypothesized relationships. The main analytical results are presented and discussed in Section 5, followed by the conclusions in Section 6.

2. Cash transfer and productive activities – conceptual framework

The concept of cash transfer programmes leading to economic and productive impacts is built around the hypothesis that the provision of regular and predictable cash transfers to very poor households in the context of missing or malfunctioning markets has the potential to generate economic and productive impacts at the household level and to stimulate the local economy through the networks that link individuals, households, businesses and institutions.

To understand the influence of transfers on agricultural production, we start by considering how agricultural households make decisions. A common approach toward investigating household decision-making in these contexts is to employ an agricultural household model where households are both utility-maximizing consumers of agricultural goods and profit-maximizing producers of those goods, and potentially face market constraints (Singh et al., 1986). In this model, when markets function perfectly, production and consumption decisions can be viewed as “separable”—profit maximization and utility maximization are solved recursively. First, the agricultural household maximizes profit from agricultural production based on standard economic theory. Second, given that profit, they seek to maximize utility. All prices are determined exogenously through market mechanisms and households are price takers. If markets are perfect, spending and investment in agriculture are optimal and the effect of the transfer should only be on consumption.

In contrast to the assumptions underlying this model, agricultural households in developing countries often face significant barriers in multiple markets. For example, high transaction costs in staple markets can often make self-sufficiency the optimal choice (Key et al., 2000). Labour transaction costs, such as monitoring worker effort, can prevent households from hiring labour and to prefer the use of family labour, making family and hired labour imperfect substitutes. Poor households often face difficulties in accessing credit due to lack of assets to use as collateral or credit rationing that might occur due to factors such as adverse selection, asymmetric information, or government policies (Feder et al., 1990). Liquidity and credit constraints are two of the main factors limiting poor agricultural households from investing optimally (Rosenzweig and Wolpin, 1993; Fenwick and Lyne, 1999; Lopez and Romano, 2000; Barrett et al., 2001; Winter-Nelson and Temu, 2005). Without access to adequate credit markets or insurance, agricultural households may adopt low-risk, low-return strategies, either in production or the diversification of income sources. Agricultural households will often sell more than the optimal amount of labour off farm in order to provide a variety of sources of income.

When faced with multiple market failures agricultural households may then make decisions to ensure that they have enough food to eat, but not necessarily what would be the most profitable. For example, to minimize the risk of high prices for staple foods they may produce more of these foods to ensure food security even if they could make more money from a cash crop. In the face of such constraints, the production and consumption decisions of agricultural households can be viewed as “non-separable”, in the sense they are jointly determined (Singh et al., 1986).

If household production and consumption decisions are non-separable, cash transfers may be able to help overcome several of these constraints. First, if correctly implemented, transfers provide a guaranteed steady source of income at regular (e.g. monthly or bimonthly) intervals. This assurance, especially for agricultural households which are less likely to have regular sources of income, might allow households to adopt riskier strategies with a higher rate of return. This guaranteed flow of income can help make up for failures in the insurance market. Secondly, the cash can be used for productive investment by providing liquidity. This liquidity can help farmers move closer to the optimal level of inputs when credit markets have failed. Such investments can be complemented by household labour and lead to increased agricultural production by the household.

Alternative theoretical models can also help understand the potential impact of a cash transfer programme on labour supply decisions. Becker’s Time and Household Production theory (1965) suggests that time allocation decisions involve a trade-off between time devoted to domestic activities such as domestic production or leisure, which generate utility, and time devoted to paid labour, which yields income. An increase in household income unrelated to work enhances the value of time dedicated to housework activities, relative to the time dedicated to paid work. Cash transfer programmes can potentially create negative incentives for time allocated to paid work—i.e., the income effect discussed by Parker and Skoufias (2000)—while at the same time providing incentives for housework activities which promote well-being. This impact may vary by gender: given cultural norms and the constraints of caring for children, income effects may lead women to withdraw from the labour market while men increase their leisure. On the other hand, a substitution effect might also occur when there is an increase in adult labour supply in order to compensate for a reduction in child labour in response to a conditionality related to school attendance which is the case for most CCTs. Further, meeting conditions, e.g., health clinic requirements, may conflict with time spent working—and this may well vary by gender (Kabeer, 2009). While the Kenya CT-OVC is unconditional, the programme does involve social messaging (i.e., the money is suggested to be used on children, health, and improved nutrition).

The specific hypotheses we wish to test in this paper are the following: does the Kenya CT-OVC (i) lead to an increase in investment in agricultural and non agricultural productive assets and activities, (ii) increase food consumption obtained from own production, and (iii) result in a shift in adult labour towards own agricultural and non agricultural activities and away from casual labour and (iv) result in heterogeneous impact by gender (v) reduce the time children spend at work.

3. Programme evaluation design and data

3.1 Programme targeting and data type

Prior to programme expansion of the CT-OVC in 2007, UNICEF designed a social experiment to track the impact of the programme on a range of household welfare indicators including child health and schooling and economic productivity. The evaluation was contracted to a private consulting firm, Oxford Policy Management (OPM), and entailed a cluster randomized longitudinal design, with a baseline household survey (and related community survey) conducted in mid 2007 and a 24 month follow-up in 2009.

The design of the impact evaluation followed the programme’s targeting process, which involved three stages. In stage one, seven districts were chosen for inclusion into the programme based on overall poverty levels and the prevalence of HIV/AIDS (directly related to OVC). The ethical rationale for the design was that the programme could not expand to all eligible locations at the same time, so locations whose entry would occur later in the expansion cycle were used as control sites to measure impact. Thus in the second stage, within each of 7 districts that were scheduled to be included in this expansion phase, four locations were identified as eligible, two of which were subsequently randomized out of the initial expansion phase and served as control locations (Figure 1). Targeting of households was carried out in the intervention locations according to standard programme operation guidelines in the third stage. Each location formed a committee of citizens charged with identifying potentially eligible households based on criteria of ultra-poverty and containing at least one OVC as defined above. The list of eligible households was sent to the programme’s central office (located within the Ministry of Gender, Children and Social Development), which then administered a detailed socioeconomic questionnaire to confirm eligibility. The final number of households that entered the programme in each district depended on funding to that district but approximately 20 percent of the poorest households in each location were enrolled in the programme. The criteria for ultimate inclusion was based on age—child headed households received highest priority, followed by age of head of household (with oldest getting priority). Since the programme was not scheduled to be implemented during this phase in the control locations, programme targeting was ‘simulated’ in order to identify a sample of households that were comparable to those in identified as eligible in treatment locations. The simulation meant that the first stage of targeting was replicated in control locations but not the second stage, since a final eligibility list was not required. Households in both the treatment and control arms were surveyed prior to their knowledge that they were selected into the programme. The targeting performance of the programme is reported in Handa et al. (2012).

Figure 1.

Figure 1

Map of the evaluation sites

A second follow up study of the evaluation sample (this time under the leadership of the University of North Carolina) was conducted four years after baseline between May and July, 2011. Both the baseline and first follow up surveys had collected only limited data on production activities and labour supply, thus in order to measure the economic impacts of CT interventions at the individual and household level, additional data were collected in the 2011 follow-up. First, to measure the investment impacts of the programme, data were collected on livestock, agricultural asset non-agricultural asset and durable goods ownership. Respondents also provided information on land ownership and acquisition. Crop level information obtained included harvest, sales, own consumption and in kind gifts, as well as by-products obtained, sold and consumed. A livestock production module captured animal stocks, revenues from sales of live and slaughtered animals, as well as of animal by-products. Additional detailed information on changes in the labour allocation of household members to off-farm and on-farm activities was also collected. The survey also included a small module on non agricultural business operated by the household.

For this paper, we rely on data collected at baseline (2007) and the second round follow up in 2011. Not having data on some variables for the 2007 survey means that for many of the outcome variables of interest we have only one data point (no baseline). This limits our ability to control for time-invariant unobservables in the impact estimation for some of the outcome variables with no baseline information.

3.2 Characteristics of evaluation sample, attrition and balance

The original OPM evaluation sample includes four groups of households: treatment and control households, and non-eligible OVC households in intervention and control localities. The latter two groups were included in the baseline survey in order to assess the targeting effectiveness of the programme but these households were not surveyed in the 2009 or 2011 rounds.

Table 1 report the sample sizes for each survey round for eligible intervention and control households only. Approximately one-third of the sample is control households and the sample size at the 2007 baseline is 2294. Attrition was fairly substantial between 2007 and 2009 at 18 percent, but was reduced considerably to only 5 percent in the 2011 round. All three rounds of field work were conducted by Research Solutions Africa, a private research firm based in Nairobi; the field work report for the 2011 survey is provided by Otienoh (2011).

Table 1.

Sample sizes by wave (eligible households only)

Treatment Control Total
1542 Round12007755 2294
1311 + 15 (new) Round22009571+13(new) 1910
1280 Round32011531 1811

A number of variables are used in the analysis in order to set the context and establish the validity of the counterfactual for assessing impact. Two sets of variables are used: (i) those linked to programme eligibility criteria, and (ii) general variables that provide information on basic characteristics of the household and adults in the household. Table 2 shows baseline summary statistics for these variables. Statistical tests of difference are performed comparing baseline control and treatment groups to determine if the experimental procedure used to create the treatment and control groups created a valid counterfactual and, if not, to help determine what characteristics are of concern. Table 2 indicates that the first stage targeting (based on OVC and poverty) was accurate in control households. Both treatment and control households are comparable across poverty indicators. However there are significant differences in baseline characteristics across the treatment and control groups for a number of variables related to household demographic structure and individual characteristics; treatment households have heads who are about nine years older than control households (due to the priority ranking of the programme), are more likely to be male and have less education. Control households have more prime-age adults (age greater than 18) in the household relative to treatment households.

Table 2.

Summary of baseline characteristics, 2007 (household and individual level)

Total
(N=1783)
Treatment
(N=1265)
Control
(N=518)
Difference
Household characteristics
Age of the head (years) 55.97 58.53 49.73 8.81***
Female headed household (1=yes) 0.64 0.65 0.60 0.06**
Household size 5.62 5.55 5.79 0.23*
Total non-active labour force in household 3.19 3.17 3.24 0.06
Elderly headed household (1=yes) 0.42 0.48 0.27 0.20***
Education of household head (years) 3.37 2.99 4.30 1.30***
Education of the spouse (years) 1.25 1.10 1.63 0.53***
Dependency ratio 1.49 1.49 1.50 0.01
Sex ratio 1.24 1.25 1.22 0.03
Number of household members
Under 11 years 2.04 1.97 2.20 0.23***
12-17 years 1.31 1.31 1.32 0.1
18-34 years 1.02 0.97 1.15 0.18***
35-49 years 0.37 0.33 0.48 0.16***
50-64 years 0.50 0.57 0.35 0.21***
Over 65 years 0.36 0.39 0.25 0.14***
Head was sick (1=yes) 0.02 0.01 0.04 0.03***
Number of OVC in the household 2.47 2.50 2.38 0.13
Poverty Indicators
Number of adult member with over 8 years of educ. 0.63 0.62 0.66 0.04
Drinking water from unprotected sources (1=yes) 0.63 0.61 0.70 0.09***
Agriculture is the main source of income (1=yes) 0.43 0.44 0.39 0.05*
Main source of income is salaried employment (1=yes) 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.03***
Main source of income is casual labour (1=yes) 0.57 0.56 0.58 0.02
Main source of income is self-employment (1=yes) 0.32 0.32 0.30 0.02
Main source of income is transfers (1=yes) 0.07 0.07 0.05 0.02
Household asset
Own bicycle (1=yes) 0.17 0.15 0.21 0.05***
Proportion of household who owns blankets 0.86 0.86 0.86 0.00
Proportion of household who owns mosquito net 0.62 0.59 0.69 0.11***
Total cultivable land owned by household (acres) 1.95 1.70 2.56 0.85***
Proportion of livestock owner 0.76 0.75 0.79 3.21***
Monthly consumption per capita (Ksh) 1285.98 1298.09 1256.40 41.69
Community level indicators
Access to road to the village (1=yes) 0.76 0.77 0.72 0.05**
Distance to local market (1=far) 0.23 0.21 0.27 0.07***
Share of household who can make telephone calls (1=high) 0.12 0.11 0.15 0.04**
Individual characteristics (N=7191) (N=5114) (N=2077)
Age of the individual (years) 27.23 27.91 25.56 2.35***
Gender of the individual (1=female) 0.52 0.52 0.52 0.00
Marital status (1=married) 0.2 0.19 0.23 0.04***
Marital status (1=single) 0.62 0.62 0.61 0.01
Education of the individual (years) 2.52 2.42 2.75 0.33**
Individual is disabled (1=yes) 0.04 0.05 0.03 0.02***
Unemployed 0.63 0.64 0.62 0.02**
in Wage labour 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00
in Causal work 0.09 0.09 0.07 0.02**
in Off farm work 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.01

Note: Statistical significance at the 99% (***), 95% (**) and 90% (*) confidence levels. Note also that the number of observations are different for household versus individual level variables

These differences are not surprising given the simulation of targeting in control locations and the small number of communities (only 28 locations) included in the treatment and control groups. With a sufficiently large number of communities, the expectation would be that treatment and control groups would, on average, prioritize different types of poor in similar ways. With a relatively small number of communities, however, differences emerge even with randomization. Of course, these differences suggest a need to make adjustments to data to ensure unbiased estimates of impact and these adjustments are discussed in the methods section below.

We have also looked at selected characteristics at baseline for households from each of the three survey rounds for treatment and control households. This helps us understand the degree of non-random attrition as well as the comparability of households in the two arms. Results show that the differences observed between the different arms are essentially the same across households in each of the three waves of the study. In other words, there is no significant change in the composition of households across the two arms over time, which supports the idea that attrition is random and not systematic across the survey rounds. For more details on the sample and a discussion of attrition, see Handa et al. (2012).

3.2 Summary statistics

Table 3 presents summary of ownership of productive assets and participation in productive activities. A large majority of beneficiaries in the evaluation sample are agricultural producers; over 80 percent of beneficiaries grow crops, and three quarters have livestock. Agriculture households in the sample, as would be expected, have modest levels of assets—around 2.6 acres of agricultural land (Table 3), an assortment of animals and low levels of education. Agricultural producers also own a variety of tools and implements. Only 16 percent of households used credit in 2011, and of these, less than half used credit for investment in productive activities. Of those who did not use credit, the vast majority felt they had no means to repay loans. Approximately one/third of households had some small business activity in 2011. Both male and female-headed households reported that own savings were the principal first source of capital for their nonfarm enterprise, followed by gifts, loans and sales of assets. Nevertheless, the CT-OVC transfer was reported as the most important second source of capital for female-headed households (over 30 percent) and second most important for male-headed households (just under 20 percent). Averaged over beneficiary households, the percentage rises to almost 50 percent, indicating that the transfer is perceived as a factor in investment in nonfarm enterprises.

Table 3.

Descriptive summary of productive asset and activities (2011) – household level

All HH
size<5
HH
size>4
Female
head
Male head
Owns non-farm enterprise (1=yes) 0.35 0.31 0.37 0.34 0.37
Share of households that operate land 0.80 0.83 0.79 0.79 0.82
For those that operate, land size in acres 2.67 2.20 2.96 2.52 2.90
Share of households that own land 0.76 0.82 0.72 0.75 0.76
For those that own, size in acres 2.58 2.15 2.86 2.45 2.79
Owns livestock (1=yes) 0.75 0.75 0.76 0.73 0.78
Access to credit (1=yes) 0.16 0.20 0.14 0.16 0.17
Share of households that own agricultural assets 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97

N 1783 698 1085 1137 646

The importance of agriculture is also seen in the allocation of household labour supply (Table 4). Over half of all adults work on their own farm, with a somewhat higher percent of women (59 versus 52 percent). A quarter of all adults work for wages (31 percent men and 23 percent women); almost all of this work is casual and approximately two thirds are non-agricultural.

Table 4.

Descriptive summary of labour participation and intensity (2011) – individual level

All
(18+)
Female
(18+)
Male
(18+)
Children
(10-15)
Female
(10-15)
Male
(10-15)
Labour participation
Works in casual wage labour (1=yes) 0.26 0.23 0.31 0.01 0.01 0.02
Works in agriculture wage labour (1=yes) 0.09 0.09 0.08 0.01 0.01 0.01
Works in non-agriculture wage labour (1=yes) 0.18 0.14 0.23 0.00 0.00 0.01
Works in own agriculture (1=yes) 0.56 0.59 0.52 0.42 0.39 0.45
Labour intensity
Days per year in wage labour (man-days) 38.21 29.60 50.07 0.76 0.25 1.21
Days per year in agricultural wage (man-days) 10.28 9.79 10.97 0.65 0.19 1.04
Days per year in non-agricultural wage (man-days) 27.93 19.81 39.10 0.12 0.06 0.17
Days per month in own agriculture (man-days) 6.78 7.29 6.07 1.61 1.26 1.91

N 3965 2297 1668 2133 995 1138

4. Methods

4.1 Empirical approach

In this paper we seek to answer the question: “How would cash transfer beneficiaries have fared in absence of the programme?” As it is impossible to observe a household both participating in the programme and not participating, the goal is to compare participants with non-participants who are as similar as possible except for the fact that they are not beneficiaries. Creating a valid counterfactual is crucial to producing reliable estimates of programme effects. By comparing outcomes between these two groups the average impacts of the cash transfer programme can be estimated. Although on average the targeting emphasis of the treatment and control communities may have differed, the random assignment of eligible communities into treatment and control groups suggests similarities between the groups—that is, the groups are not radically different and tend to be poor with limited assets. These imply a need to adjust the baseline data to create a more reasonable counterfactual.

Towards this end, we use two approaches: a difference-in-difference estimator and a single difference approach combined with inverse probability weighting. When baseline data are not available, as is the case for some of our outcome variables (i.e. those that are observed only after the implementation of programme), single difference method can be applied. When panel data are available with pre and post intervention information, which is the case with some of our outcome variables, we use a difference-in-difference approach. Since baseline differences between treatment and control are primarily linked to observable demographic characteristics, for both approaches an emphasis is placed on these variables in ensuring an adequate estimate of impact.

For all variables with adequate baseline data, a difference-in-difference, or double difference (DD) estimator can be specified as follows:

ATT=E[(τtτt1)D=1]=E[(Y(1)tY(0)t)(Y(1)t1Y(0)t1)D=1],=E(Y(1)tY(1)t1)D=1)E(Y(0)tY(0)t1D=1) (1)

where t − 1 and t represent time periods before and after the introduction of the cash transfer programme and the binary indicator D refers to programme assignment at the baseline. The panel nature of the data provides the option of using a before-after comparison of control and treatment because it compares the difference between control and treatment as well as before and after.

By taking the difference in outcomes for the treatment group before and after receiving the cash transfer, and subtracting the difference in outcomes for the control group before and after the cash transfer was disbursed, DD is able to control for pre-treatment differences between the two groups, and in particular the time invariant unobservable factors that cannot be accounted for otherwise (Woodridge, 2002). The key assumption is that differences between treated and control households remain constant throughout the duration of the project. If prior outcomes incorporate transitory shocks that differ for treatment and comparison households, DD estimation interprets such shocks as representing a stable difference, and estimates will contain a transitory component that does not represent the true programme effect.

When differences between treatment and control groups at the baseline exist, the DD estimator with conditioning variables has the advantage of minimizing the standard errors as long as the effects are unrelated to the treatment and are constant over time (Wooldridge, 2002). Control variables are most easily introduced by turning to a regression framework which is convenient for the DD or by combining DD with propensity score matching or DD with inverse probability weighting (DD-IPW). Equation 2 presents the regression equivalent of DD with covariates and/or IPW;

Yit=β0+β1Dit+β2Rt+β3(RtDit)+ΣβiXi+μit (2)

where Yit is the outcome indicator of interest; Dit is a dummy equal to 1 if household i received the treatment; Rt is a time dummy equal to 0 for the baseline and to 1 for the follow up round; Rt * Dit is the interaction between the intervention and time dummies and, μit is an error term. To control for household and community characteristics that may influence the outcome of interest beyond the treatment effect alone, we add in X i, a vector of household and community characteristics to control for observable differences across households at the baseline which could have an effect on Yit. These factors are not only those for which some differences may be observed across treatment and control at the baseline, but also ones which could have some explanatory role in the estimation of Yit. As for coefficients, β0 is a constant term; β1 controls for the time invariant differences between the treatment and control; β2 represents the effect of going from the baseline to the follow-up period, and β3 is the double difference estimator, which captures the treatment effect.

We employed single difference combined with IPW (SD-IPW) approach when baseline data are not available. It is important to point out that unlike the DD, SD-IPW estimation procedure is not robust against time-invariant unobservables therefore results from the SD should be interpreted with these caveats in mind. The regression equivalent of SD-IPW can be expressed as follows:

Yi=β0+β1D+ΣφiZi+γi(DZi)+μi (3)

We use the method of inverse probability weighting by specifying a propensity score model. Inverse probability weighting derives weights from the propensity score, where these are defined by the inverse of the propensity score if the subject receives treatment and the inverse of 1 minus the propensity score if the subject receives the control. Propensity score is defined as the probability of receiving treatment given the measured covariates (P^(Z)=Pr(D=1Z) where Z is a vector of control variables). In the case of DD-IPW or SD-IPW, control observations are assigned weights equal to the inverse of their propensity score; i.e., w=P^(Z)(1P^(Z)), and treatment observations receive a weight equal to one. Applying these weights1 to control households effectively reweights the distribution of observable characteristics included in P^(Z) to be like that of the treatment group. Said differently, control observations that are dissimilar to the treatment group will have a P^(Z) near zero and a weight near zero; conversely, control observations who are similar to the treatment group will receive a higher weight. One advantage of the weighting approach is that it is considered to be “doubly robust”: if either the propensity model or the outcome equation is correctly specified the estimator will be consistent. Therefore for this paper following Rubin (1977) as suggested by Hirano and Imbens (2001), we combine the IPW estimator with the regression adjustment in the analysis of individual and household level outcomes as presented above.

Any method that uses the propensity score requires that all relevant confounders are included in the model and that this model is specified correctly to validate the conditional exchangeability assumption. As with all observational studies, inference is only valid under the strong assumption of there being no unmeasured confounders. This is crucial to allowing the causal interpretation placed on the parameters but is, unfortunately, untestable. Ensuring that a region of common support exists is necessary in the weighting approach to avoid observations with extremely large weights, which can yield estimates with high variance and undue influence on results (Imbens and Wooldridge, 2009). For both DD-IPW and SD-IPW, we calculate clustered standard errors at the community level (location level which is also unit of randomization for this study) for household level outcomes, and we cluster the standard errors at the household level for individual level outcomes. In the subsequent section we will discuss in detail the estimation procedure of the propensity scores and the overall results of the common support and balance.

4.2 Estimation of propensity scores

We estimate three sets of propensity scores—for household level outcomes we estimate propensity score at the household level, while for individual level outcomes we generate propensity score at the individual level, overall and by gender. Alternatively we could have estimated household level weights and then disaggregated the analysis at the individual level. However, given the importance of individual level variables in the labour allocation decision, and the existence of at least some limited information at baseline on individual labour market participation, we decided to use propensity scores generated at individual level.

The baseline data provide a rich set of variables to help identify programme participation. In the baseline survey implemented in 2007, the criteria used to target programme beneficiaries are documented. This enables us to identify the targeting component of the participation decision by including the specific eligibility criteria as control variables in the participation regression which is estimated using a logit model (Annex 1 and 2). At the household level the set of observable variables includes household characteristics such as age, gender, education of the household head, household size, dependency ratio, sex ratio, number of OVC in the household; poverty indicators such as income sources, access to drinking water; household assets such as ownership of bicycles, blankets, mosquito nets, land and livestock holding, consumption expenditure; community level indicators such as access to roads, distance to daily market, access to telephone and finally district fixed effects. Individuals’ characteristics at baseline were used in addition to the above variables when estimating the participation equation for individuals. Specifically these included participation and type of labour activity, age, education, marital status, and health.

Evidence on the result of re-weighting can be seen in Figure 2, which shows the distribution of the estimated propensity scores. As shown in Figure 2 on the left side, the unweighted distribution of the propensity score for the control groups is more negatively skewed to the right. However on the right side, with weighting the distribution of the propensity score of the control groups is similar to the distribution of the treatment group. A similar picture is seen in Figure 3 for the distribution of propensity score generated at individual level.

Figure 2.

Figure 2

Kernel density of the propensity score for the treated and control groups, household level weighting

Figure 3.

Figure 3

Kernel density of the propensity score for the treated and control groups, individual level weighting

Given that the analysis does not condition on all covariates, but on the propensity score, there is a need to check if the weighting procedure is able to balance the distribution of the variables used in the construction of the propensity score. After some experimentation we have settled on a preferred specification of the participation model for which we cannot reject the null of mean equality of baseline characteristics between (reweighted) treatment and control households. Also reported in Annex 3a and 3b are weighted means of the baseline characteristics, where the weights are constructed from estimated propensity scores. Testing for differences in these weighted means across the treatment and control groups reveals no significant differences. The fact that the weights can balance the beeline characteristics across the two groups provides motivations for their use and as a result results presented in this paper for both SD and DD rely solely on the weighted regressions. Following Imbens and Wooldridge (2009), we use IPW by combining the propensity score with regression analysis rather than PSM. Just over 4 percent of observations are outside of common support in the household level IPW, while the original and (post IPW) final number of observations for the individual level analysis (including by gender) can be found in Annex4.

4.3. Heterogeneity of programme impacts

The average treatment effect of participation in the CT-OVC may mask differential impacts of the programme on subgroups of households, for example, among female and male headed households. We use two approaches to determine the existence of these differential effects. For all household level equations, we divide the sample of households into female and male headed households and by household size. Since the transfer is a fixed amount per household regardless of household size, the per capita transfer amount is larger for smaller households, and we would expect the impact of the programme to be different for households with a smaller number of members compared to a household with a larger number of members. For the labour allocation equations at the individual level, we divide the sample into males and females and perform separate analysis on each group. For these individual level equations we interact treatment (in separate equations) with individual age and chronic illness status, as well as with household distance to market, adult household members and regional dummies.

5. Results

In this section we discuss our findings for the average treatment effects of the Kenya CT-OVC programme over four broad groups of outcome variables— food consumption, productive assets, non agricultural business activities and labour supply. When the baseline information is available for a given outcome variable, we employ a DD-IPW estimator in a multivariate framework. Otherwise, we use the SD-IPW estimator as described above.

5.1. Impact on food consumption

One of the most consistent findings regarding the impact of cash transfer programmes is their contribution to reducing hunger and food insecurity. Often the most immediate impact of cash transfer programmes for the very poor relates to basic consumption needs, particularly nutrition and food security through a direct increase in purchasing power (Devereux and Coll-Black, 2007). Table 5 presents the average difference between the control and treated groups in components of food consumption expenditure2. Results from the DD estimator with IPW show a positive and significant impact on consumption of animal products such as dairy and eggs, meat and fish, cooking oil and in consumption of fruits across household size and gender line. The results show no significant impact on consumption expenditure of cereals and legumes. The average treatment effect for food spending on dairy and eggs is 0.123, which is equivalent to a 12.3 percentage point increase as a result of the programme.

Table 5.

Impact on consumption of food groups in proportion - DD-IPW estimator (2007-2011)

All HH size <5 HH size 5
& above
Female head Male head
Cereals (1=yes) −0.004
(0.54)
−0.010
(0.63)
0.001
(0.63)
−0.005
(0.52)
−0.000
(0.20)
Legumes (1=yes) 0.004
(0.04)
0.109
(1.48)
−0.069
(0.64)
0.067
(0.65)
−0.117
(1.25)
Dairy and eggs (1=yes) 0.123
(2.52)**
0.297
(5.03)***
−0.001
(0.02)
0.163
(3.08)***
0.045
(0.63)
Meat and fish (1=yes) 0.053
(1.22)
0.135
(2.96)***
−0.007
(0.12)
0.072
(1.83)*
0.015
(0.22)
Vegetables (1=yes) −0.022
(0.69)
−0.043
(0.73)
−0.007
(0.17)
−0.033
(0.79)
−0.003
(0.06)
Fruit (1=yes) 0.043
(1.08)
0.104
(1.80)*
−0.000
(0.02)
0.047
(0.98)
0.036
(0.93)
Cooking oil (1=yes) 0.021
(0.77)
0.023
(0.50)
0.019
(0.53)
−0.004
(0.11)
0.069
(4.80)***
Other food (1=yes) −0.009
(0.66)
−0.009
(0.46)
−0.009
(0.50)
−0.007
(0.41)
−0.012
(1.04)

N 1783 698 1085 1137 646

Note: Robust standard errors are clustered at community level. Statistical significance at the 99% (***), 95% (**) and 90% (*) confidence levels. T-statistics in parentheses.

As expected, the results of the disaggregated analysis show considerable variation in the impact of the programme across gender and household size. The analysis shows no effect of the programme on spending on most of the food consumption categories for households with larger number of members but shows large, positive, and significant effects on three of the outcomes (dairy and eggs, meat and fish and fruit) for households with smaller number of members. The programme tends to have larger and positive impact on female-headed compared to male-headed households. For instance, the programme results in a statistically significant 16 percentage point increase in consumption of animal products for female headed households but only a 4.5 percentage point increase for male headed households. The only one exception where the impact is positive and significant for male-headed households is in the consumption of cooking oil.

Information was collected on the primary source of specific types of food consumption, with own production, purchases and gifts as the possible sources. We have used proportion of food consumption from own production as an indirect proxy to measure the linkages between diet diversity and food security (see Todd et al., 2010). Table 6 shows the DD with IPW results of the programme impact on the proportion of food consumption that comes from own production. The treated households appear to consume more animal products, as well as other foods, from their own production compared to control households. The estimated treatment effect for change in dairy and eggs consumption from own production is about 13 percentage points, and the impact on other types of foods is about 4 percentage points. For most of the outcomes, the differential impact again appears to be bigger for households with smaller size and for female-headed households. The average treatment effect for the share of consumption from home produced dairy and eggs is 20 percentage points for smaller households and 15 percentage points for female headed households.

Table 6.

Impact on proportion of food consumption from own production - DD-IPW estimator (2007-2011)

All HH size <5 HH size 5
& above
Female head Male head
Cereals 0.06
(1.10)
0.13
(1.72)*
0.01
(0.18)
0.05
(0.73)
0.08
(0.93)
Legumes −0.001
(0.02)
0.02
(0.32)
−0.02
(0.44)
0.04
(0.72)
−0.08
(1.66)
Dairy and eggs 0.13
(3.09)***
0.20
(3.40)***
0.09
(1.66)
0.15
(3.03)***
0.11
(1.32
Meat and fish 0.04
(0.89)
0.11
(3.64)***
−0.003
(0.05)
0.03
(1.01)
0.07
(0.62)
Vegetables 0.004
(0.06)
−0.006
(0.09)
0.02
(0.25)
−0.05
(0.72)
0.10
(1.12)
Fruit 0.04
(1.02)
0.09
(1.93)*
0.01
(0.12)
0.06
(1.31)
0.003
(0.07)
Cooking oil 0.003
(0.46)
0.01
(0.97)
−0.003
(1.02)
0.003
(0.42)
0.002
(0.39)
Other foods 0.04
(4.20)***
0.04
(2.92)***
0.04
(3.38)***
0.04
(3.60)***
0.05
(2.52)**

N 1706 680 1026 1087 619

Note: Robust standard errors are clustered at community level. Statistical significance at the 99% (***), 95% (**) and 90% (*) confidence levels. T-statistics in parentheses.

5.2. Investment in productive assets, input use and nonfarm activities

We look at investment in two types of productive assets: livestock ownership and agricultural implements. We also look at dimensions of the productive process to ascertain whether households have increased spending in agricultural activities. These include crop production, input use and credit use. Table 7 presents the impact of the CT-OVC on ownership of livestock assets estimated using the DD estimator with IPW. We used two indicators to measure the impact on livestock assets – the proportion of households owning each type of livestock and the total quantity owned (aggregated using tropical livestock unit or TLU). The results show a positive and significant impact only on the ownership of small livestock such as sheep and goats, for both smaller and female-household households. For smaller households, the estimated average treatment effect of 0.154 is equivalent to a 15.4 percentage point increase in ownership of small livestock compared to control households, while female-household households receiving the transfer experienced a 6 percentage point increase in ownership of small livestock. Overall no impact is found on the number of livestock owned by households; however for smaller households, the total number of livestock (aggregated in Tropical Livestock Units) increased by 0.7 compared to control households. Given the relatively small amount of the transfer the lack of impact on cattle is not surprising; however, we would have expected some kind of positive impact on poultry ownership.3

Table 7.

Impact on livestock ownership- DD-IPW estimator (2007-2011)

All HH size <5 HH size 5
& above
Female
head
Male
head
Proportion of household owning
Large livestock (cattle, donkey etc)
(1=yes)
0.038
(0.91)
0.033
(0.58)
0.041
(0.88)
0.051
(1.06)
0.010
(0.21)
Small livestock (sheep, goat etc) (1=yes) 0.054
(1.65)
0.154
(2.85)***
−0.022
(0.48)
0.06
(1.74)*
0.043
(0.74)
Poultry (1=yes) −0.001
(0.02)
0.053
(0.84)
−0.038
(0.58)
0.005
(0.12)
−0.013
(0.13)
Total quantity owned (measured in TLU) 0.593
(0.62)
0.671
(1.72)*
0.500
(0.34)
0.570
(1.16)
0.660
(0.31)

N 1706 680 1026 1087 619

Note: Robust standard errors are clustered at community level. Statistical significance at the 99% (***), 95% (**) and 90% (*) confidence levels. T-statistics in parentheses.

Overall, as can be seen in Table 8, we find very little impact of the programme on direct indicators of crop production. This includes no impact over the share of households growing crops (and specifically improved maize), nor the share of crop producing households using different inputs (seeds, pesticides and organic and inorganic fertilizer). In fact, we find some small, but significant, negative impacts on the use of pesticides by large households and by female headed households. Similarly, we find no impact on input expenditures, with the exception of a negative impact on seed expenditure. It’s however important to point out that these results are based on SD-IPW estimation procedure which is not robust against time-invariant unobservables therefore it should be interpreted with these caveats in mind.

Table 8.

Impact on crop production - SD-IPW estimator (2011)

All HH size <5 HH size 5
& above
Female head Male head
Proportion of households:
growing crops −0.024
(−0.44)
−0.036
(−1.16)
−0.008
(−0.13)
−0.016
−(0.31)
−0.054
(−0.96)
Improved maize −0.009
(−0.45)
0.018
(0.83)
−0.013
(−0.43)
0.003
(0.10)
−0.028
(−0.99)
Using seed −0.015
(−0.25)
−0.005
(−0.09)
−0.011
(−0.17)
0.001
(0.04)
−0.067
(−1.07)
Using pesticide −0.031
(−1.65)
−0.021
(−0.80)
−0.035*
(−1.74)
−0.053*
(−1.95)
0.008
(0.35)
Using organic fertilizer −0.005
(−0.11)
0.038
(0.67)
−0.036
(−0.71)
0.015
(0.31)
−0.039
(−0.63)
Using inorganic fertilizer −0.028
(−0.45)
0.014
(0.20)
−0.048
(−0.81)
−0.007
(−0.12)
−0.079
(−1.05)
Expenditure (Ksh) per acre on
:
Seeds −104.8**
(−2.19)
−76.59
(−1.28)
−110.4**
(−2.25)
−95.94
(−1.58)
−157.1**
(−2.35)
Pesticide 7.428
(1.03)
−9.393
(−1.20)
16.37
(1.61)
−5.635
(−0.78)
27.51
(1.28)
Organic fertilizer 10.69
(0.61)
21.13
(0.88)
15.17
(0.66)
3.357
(.015)
29.07
(1.02)
Inorganic fertilizer −72.45
(−1.16)
−14.10
(−0.22)
−107.1
(−1.38)
−81.15
(−1.32)
−68.99
(−0.86)

N 1706 680 1026 1087 619

Note: Statistical significance at the 99% (***), 95% (**) and 90% (*) confidence levels. T-statistics in parentheses.

Why are the results for the Kenya CT-OVC modest as compared to those of other programmes, such as the Malawi SCT (Covarrubias, et al, 2012; Boone, et al, 2013). Three possible reasons emerge. First, the Kenya transfer was about half the size of the Malawi transfer at the time of their respective impact evaluations. Second, the value of the transfer was severely eroded over the period of the impact evaluation. And third, the Malawi SCT programme was also a pilot only implemented in one district (Mchinji) which is a relatively homogenous and vibrant agricultural economy while the Kenya SCT is implemented in four regions over seven districts which are heterogeneous both in terms of geography and economic activities.

As reported in table 3 approximately one third of households had some small business activity in 2011. Households reported that own savings were the principal first source of capital for their nonfarm enterprise while the CT-OVC transfer was reported as the most important second source of capital for female-headed households. This perception is confirmed in the econometric analysis, at least for women (Table 9); we find that the CT-OVC transfer is associated with a 7 percentage point increase in household participation in a nonfarm enterprise, for female headed households, and an 11 percentage point decrease for male headed households (though statistically significant only at the 10 percent level). These findings are consistent with some other findings in the literature. For instance in Latin America, the Mexican PROGRESA programme increases the probability of operating a non-farm microenterprise (Gertler et al., 2012; Todd et al., 2010). In South Africa, pension beneficiaries started or strengthened their own microenterprises (Du Toit and Neves, 2006). Lichand (2010) also finds that Brazil’s Bolsa Familia (CCT) programme was positively associated with entrepreneurial investments.

Table 9.

Impact on household participation in nonfarm enterprises and access to credit - SD-IPW estimator (2011)

All HH size
<5
HH size 5
& above
Female
head
Male
head
Household participation in nonfarm enterprise
(1=yes)
0.016
(0.47)
0.019
(0.53)
0.001
(0.04)
0.072**
(2.09)
−0.112*
(−1.94)
Received loan (1=yes) 0.007
(0.31)
−0.006
(−0.18)
0.015
(0.57)
0.031
(1.31)
−0.044
(−1.13)
Sought credit (1=yes) 0.010
(0.44)
0.007
(.20)
0.010
(0.39)
0.036
(1.18)
−0.046
−1.10)

N 1706 680 1026 1087 619

Note: Robust standard errors are clustered at community level. Statistical significance at the 99% (***), 95% (**) and 90% (*) confidence levels. T-statistics in parentheses

5.3. Impact on household labour allocation

As is common in the labour literature, we model labour supply as an individual decision, though we include a series of household and context variables as this decision takes place within the decision making process of the household and within a given economic context. We look at the two main types of labour supply: wage labour supply4, and labour used on own farm. For both types, we look at both the decision to participate, and then, conditional on participation, the intensity of participation. Note that since almost all wage employment in this sample is casual, whether agricultural or non agricultural, we make no distinction between casual and permanent labour. For both wage and own farm labour, we look at all individuals as well as disaggregated by gender, and we make a distinction between adults (older than 18 years in 2011) and children (between 10 and 15 years of age, inclusive). We further look at heterogeneity of impact by running four different specifications by interacting programme participation with different explanatory variables. In the first specification, no interaction variable is introduced while in the consecutive three specifications we have interacted programme participation with the family’s distance to local market, individual age and physical health (chronic illness) for adults.

An important element missing from the analysis is the impact related to time devoted to housework activities, as receipt of the programme may permit substitution between casual wage activities and pressing housework, including care of children (one of the objectives of the programme). Unfortunately data were not collected on adult time use, and thus we leave this question for future research.

5.3.1 Adult labour allocation

Table 10 reports the estimation results of the programme impact on adult wage labour supply. Overall, in terms of the propensity to participate in wage labour, we find no significant impact of the CT-OVC programme. For all individuals, but for women in particular, however, we find a positive and large impact (13 percentage points) of the programme for those who live farther from the local markets (more isolated). The programme thus appears to facilitate labour market participation for those who face higher transaction costs, in terms of distance to local market.

Table 10.

Impact on wage labour supply by adults (age >18) - SD-IPW estimator (2011)

All adults Female Male

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Wage labour participation
Treatment −0.026 −0.053* −0.138 0.017 −0.009 −0.007 −0.091* −0.108* −0.527**
Treatment * distance to local market 0.129** 0.132* 0.072
Treatment * age 0.005 0.002 0.021*
Treatment * age squared −0.000 −0.000 −0.000
District fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Number of observations 3,643 3, 643 3, 643 1,743 1,743 1,743 1,276 1,276 1,276
Adjusted R2 0.098 0.101 0. 098 0.117 0.119 0.116 0.12 0.12 0.126
F-test of joint significance 2.17* 16.20*** 2.51* 7.83*** 1.77 12.13***

Days worked per year
Treatment −20.41** −22.162* 39.603 −13.912 −17.357 58.556 −18.582 −27.71 46.016
Treatment * distance to local market 26.047 19.903 46.944
Treatment * age −2.539 −3.377 −3.017
Treatment * age squared 0.024 0.035 0.024
District fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Number of observations 1,028 1,028 1,028 457 457 457 420 420 420
Adjusted R2 0.059 0.079 0.078 0.064 0.063 0.061 0.09 0.092 0.088
F-test of joint significance 1.7 3.31*** 0.60 0.52 1.46 1.55

Notes: The sample excludes Garissa district. Control variables used in the regression include individual level indicators (gender, age, education, health), household level proxies (gender, age, education, household size, dependency ratio, education), community level indictors (distance to market, access to road) and district level fixed effect.

***

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

**

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

*

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

From the separate male equation, for all types of wage labour, we do find a negative and significant impact on participation. However, this negative impact decreases with increasing age, eventually becoming positive (Figure 4)5; indeed, for most relevant ages the impact on male participation on non agricultural wage labour is positive. Thus from this same figure, the positive impact of the programme on males is much stronger for non agricultural wage labour, while the negative impact is more relevant for agricultural wage labour, though even here the impact of the programme becomes less negative and eventually positive with increasing age. In terms of the participation of females in non agricultural wage labour, the trend is similar, though more muted. In terms of agricultural wage labour, however, the pattern is reversed; the programme has a positive impact on younger women, and this decreases with age, eventually becoming negative.

Figure 4.

Figure 4

Impact of the programme on labour supply (participation) by age and sex of adult individuals, 2011.

We also looked at the intensity of wage labour participation (days worked per year). Overall, the programme appears to have a negative impact on labour intensity (Table 10); participation in the CT-OVC programme is associated with a reduction in 20 days per year of all types of wage labour. No significant impact is found for the separate male and female estimations; however, in the male equation for all types of wage labour and for non-agricultural wage labour, the interaction variable between gender of the head and treatment is significant. So the negative impact on labour supply among males is mostly concentrated among the male headed households. Among females, the heterogeneity impact of the programme by gender of the head is not significant in any of the equations6. The underlying story with regard to wage labour supply is that the CT-OVC programme overall tends to affect negatively the labour supply although the impact on the propensity to participate in wage labour is insignificant. However, the negative impact of the programme on labour supply is more pronounced in adult male individuals compared to females.

Table 11 reports the estimation results of the programme impact on adult labour supply on own farm activities. A major hypothesis we would like to test with this analysis is to see if there are some sort of substitution between wage labour supply and labour used for own farm as a result of the programme. Unfortunately the results do not provide a conclusive narrative. Overall the programme does not have a significant impact on the decision to participate and labour supply on own farm. Also looking at the disaggregated analysis by gender and age, a similar story (initially negative, increasingly positive with age) is found for men in terms of their participation in own farm labour (Figure 4). Again, a similar trend is found for female participation in own farm labour - with older women, the programme impact eventually becomes positive. However for both males and females, participation in the programme leads to increasing intensity of own farm labour with increasing age7. Overall these findings of ours are not unique given the fact that the evidence so far shows mixed impacts on adult labour allocation as reported in the introduction section. Again it’s important to point out that these results are based on SD-IPW estimation procedure which is not robust against time-invariant unobservables therefore it should be interpreted with these caveats in mind.

Table11.

Impact on participation in own farm labour by adults (age >18) - SD-IPW estimator (2011)

All adults Female Male

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Participation in own farm labour
Treatment −0.047 −0.063* −0.107 0.007 −0.021 0.356* −0.055 −0.043 −0.115
Treatment * distance to market 0.077 0.143* −0.052
Treatment * age 0.001 −0.019** −0.002
Treatment * age squared −0.000 0.000** −0.000
District fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Number of observations 3,643 3,643 3,643 1,743 1,743 1,743 1,276 1,276 1,276
Adjusted R2 0.243 0.243 0.243 0.340 0.342 0.342 0.222 0.222 0.230
F-test of joint significance 1.55 4.58*** 2.01 9.23*** 0.70 2.31**

Days worked per month
Treatment −0.042 0.058 −6.521 0.406 0.671 −12.198*** −0.622 −1.012 −0.233
Treatment * distance to market −0.491 −1.481 1.886
Treatment * age 0.330 0.503** −0.081
Treatment * age squared −0.003 −0.004* 0.002
District fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES
Number of observations 2,184 2,184 2,184 1,084 1,084 1,084 671 671 671
Adjusted R2 0.133 0.133 0.136 0.235 0.235 0.247 0.223 0.223 0.224
F-test of joint significance 0.42** 5.75*** 1.86 7.25*** 0.18 5.00***

Notes: The sample excludes Garissa district. Control variables used in the regression include individual level indicators (gender, age, education, health), household level proxies (gender, age, education, household size, dependency ratio, education), community level indictors (distance to market, access to road) and district level fixed effect.

***

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

**

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

*

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

5.3.2 Children labour allocation

Table 12 reports the impact of the programme on children participation in own farm labour. A significant percentage of children work on the family farm (42 percent), particularly boys (45 percent). We find that the programme results in a significant (12 percent) reduction in child labour on farm (Table 12)8. This impact appears to be concentrated among boys, as no significant impact is found on for girls. When the interaction term with distance to local markets is added, the results vary by gender. While we find that in the equation for all children the child labour reducing impact of the programme increases with increased isolation, with similar results for girls (though not statistically significant), for boys the impact of the programme is muted (by approximately 5 percentage points) by increased geographic isolation. Parallel results also show that there is meaningful overall school enrolment impact at the primary and secondary level (age 12-18). While we can’t necessarily attribute the decrease in child labour to increase in school attendance, the two seem to go in the right direction. Our findings are consistent with overwhelming evidence that shows that several social protection programmes reduce child labour supply. In Latin America two major reviews find that most CCTs significantly lower child labour participation (Fiszbein and Shady, 2009). In South Africa, children residing in pension eligible households reduce their hours of work by 33% (Edmond 2006). In Malawi, the social cash transfer scheme decreases off farm child labour but increases child labour on the family farm (Covarrubias et al., 2012).

Table 12.

Impact on participation in own farm labour by children (10-15 years) - SD-IPW estimator (2011)

All Boys Girls

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Treatment −0.124*** −0.120*** −0.120** −0.131** −0.072 −0.056
Treatment * distance to market −0.119 0.048 −0.085
District fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES
Number of observations 1,909 1,909 998 998 901 901
Adjusted R2 0.139 0.138 0.142 0.141 0.109 0.109
F-test of joint significance 4.28*** 3.13** 1.14

Notes: The sample excludes Garissa district. Control variables used in the regression include individual level indicators (gender, age, education, health), household level proxies (gender, age, education, household size, dependency ratio, education), community level indictors (distance to market, access to road) and district level fixed effect.

***

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

**

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

*

denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. Robust standard errors clustered at the household level.

6. Conclusions

This paper used data collected from a four-year randomized experimental design impact evaluation (2007 and 2011) to analyze the productive impact of the Kenya CT-OVC including food consumption, accumulation of productive assets and labour allocation. Kenya’s CT-OVC is a national child-protection programme that provides a flat monthly transfer of Ksh 1500 to ultra-poor families with orphans and vulnerable children aged 17 years and younger. Although the programme is designed to encourage care of OVC and human capital development, we find that this programme also has an impact on the productive activities of beneficiaries, who are primarily agricultural producers, but also diversified into casual wage labour and nonfarm enterprises.

Three main conclusions can be drawn from the results of this study. First, we find robust evidence of a positive impact of the programme on consumption. Taking advantage of comparable baseline information, we find that treated households consumed significantly more cereals, animal products (meat and dairy) and other foods out of own production, as compared to control households. This is particularly true for both smaller size, and female headed, households. This indirect evidence is worth highlighting because underreporting of consumption is much less likely than underreporting or measurement error in income generating activities such as agricultural and non agricultural businesses.

Second, the programme has a significant impact on the accumulation of productive assets, particularly on certain subgroups within the evaluation sample. Large and significant effects on the share of households owning small animals are found for smaller households and female headed households. We also find that the CT-OVC transfer is associated with a 7 percentage point increase in household participation in a nonfarm enterprise, for female headed households.

The final piece of evidence comes from labour allocation. The programme has a variety of impacts on labour supply, varying by gender and by type of labour. Overall, when grouping all types of labour and for all adults, we find no significant impact of the programme on participation in wage labour. For all individuals, however, and particularly for women, the programme facilitates labour force participation for those living farther from local markets. In addition, the programme is associated with a generally positive impact on participation in non agricultural wage labour (particularly for males), compared to generally negative impact on participation in agricultural wage. In both cases, however, the probability of participation increases with the age of programme beneficiaries. On the other hand, the programme appears to have a negative impact on wage labour intensity. Nevertheless for both males and females, participation in the programme leads to increasing intensity of own farm labour with increasing age. Unlike other studies which found a substitution between casual wage labour and own farm labour, this is not a pattern observed in our findings. At the same time, the programme leads to a significant reduction in child labour on farm, particularly for boys.

Overall, the study has provided evidence, direct and indirect, that the CT-OVC programme influences the livelihood strategies of the poor which is also differentiated across gender and household size. It seems clear that the programme has helped families increase food consumption and productive assets, as well as provide more flexibility to families in terms of labour allocation, particularly for those individuals who are geographically isolated, and children, an important objective of the programme. From impact evaluation point of view, while we are somewhat constrained by incomplete data at base line, forcing us to rely on non-experimental measures for some indicators, together they point to the importance of considering impacts on household decision making on productive activities in the design and implementation of the programme.

The key findings from the overall analysis is that the positive productive impact of the programme either in terms of consumption or productive asset or even to some degree in labour allocation is more modest compared to other social cash transfer programme like the Malawi SCT programme. It is however important to point out that in separate analysis, the CT-OVC programme significantly increases secondary school enrolment and helps households avert meet transport costs and the cost of school supplies (The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team, 2012). The programme alsosignificantly increases food expenditures and decreases spending on alcohol and tobacco (The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team 2012). The programme has increased the real household consumption levels of recipient households substantially – by some 274 KSh per adult equivalent. The benefit of increased consumption is concentrated in smaller households, since the value of the transfer (per capita) is diluted in larger households, reinforcing the case for indexing the payments in some way to household size. Romeo et al. (2013) also found a positive impact of the programme on child health measured in chronic malnutrition or stunting. Taylor et al. (2012) simulated the local economy impact and revealed a minimal inflationary impact and real production value-added multipliers of 1.58 Ksh per shilling transferred which suggests that that the programme may have lead to spillovers. Hence, the results discussed in the paper are underestimates of the actual impact of the programme. Therefore, it is important to frame our findings within the overall programme impact evaluation which goes beyond productive and economic activities and that in most of the human capital indicators the programme has a robust positive impact. We would have liked to also analyze heterogeneous effects for households that are credit constrained and households that are not credit constrained however we do not have sufficient data to analyze credit constraints in more detail. Thus future research should focus on heterogeneous effects for credit constrained and non-credit-constrained households (Blattman et al., 2013).

Finally, studies have shown the programme to be cost effective. Ward et al. (2010) reported that in the three financial years from July 2006 to June 2009 the OVC-CT programme spent some $9.96 million in the seven pilot districts. The total expenditure per annum per household supported during 2007-9 was about $474, including the transfer and other transaction costs. About half of the total cost reached the beneficiary in the form of the cash transfer, at a time when the government was investing considerable sums in setting up the programme, reaching 15,000 households. At the current scale of the programme, the unit cost of the programme is most likely much reduced, but data are not available to provide exact figures. Expanding the programme to cover the poorest 25 percent of OVCs in Kenya at this unit cost was estimated to imply a total programme cost of around KSh 8.7 billion per annum. This represented around 0.3% of total GDP or about 1% of government expenditure, which suggests that it ought to be financially sustainable (Ward et al., 2010).

We believe that these results are relevant for other unconditional cash transfer programmes in SSAs. First, the results reported here are based on a rigorous and credible research design and thus can be taken as causal impacts of the programme. The only caveats for our analysis are related to the absence of baseline data for some outcome variables which in turn required the use of a SD estimator instead of a DD estimation strategy. Second, the institutional, market and economic context in Kenya is similar to other SSA countries currently initiating such programmes. Finally, the design features of the CT-OVC are also typical of other programmes in the region which include unconditional transfers, community involvement in beneficiary selection and targeting based on vulnerability and poverty rather than just poverty.

Supplementary Material

Appendix

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank participants at two workshops at the Department of Child Services in Nairobi and the Transfer Project workshop in Aberdares for comments and suggestions. Errors are the responsibility only of the authors, and this paper reflects the opinions of the authors, and not the institutions which they represent or with which they are affiliated. This research forms part of the From Protection to Production Project (http://www.fao.org/economic/ptop/en/), supported financially by DFID. The 2011 survey round was funded through grant number 1R01MH093241-01 from the National Institute of Mental Health to the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

Footnotes

1

Note that propensity weights are also multiplied by survey sampling weights.

2

For each outcome variable we estimated an unweighted comparison, DD-IPW without controls and DD-IPW with controls, reporting only the latter in the included tables. The results are broadly consistent across all three estimates. Full results are available upon request.

3

We also looked at the purchase of different kinds of animals using IPW with controls; no significant impacts were found, with the exception of a positive impact (but tiny magnitude) on sheep purchases for male-headed households. Results are available upon request.

4

We also conducted analysis separately for agricultural wage labour and non agricultural wage labour. For each of these two types of wage labour types, we look at both the decision to participate in wage labour, and then, conditional on participation, the intensity of participation. Some of the results reported in Figure 4 are partly based on this disaggregated analysis. Detailed results are presented in the annex.

5

Some of the results reported in Figure 4 are partly based on this disaggregated analysis undertaken for agricultural and non-agricultural wage labour. Figure 4 is plotted based on results from the third specification. Detailed estimation results are presented in the annex.

6

Although results are not reported in this paper, we have also examined whether the programme impact is heterogeneous along a few dimensions including adult household size, gender of the head and also with regional dummies. The results seems to suggest a differentiated impact across region – treated individuals in the central province participate more in wage labor compared to individuals in the coastal areas and the same appears to be true for intensity of participation. Looking the differentiated impact across the size of households, we have not found differentiated impact in terms of the participation decision, though individuals in treated households with more adult household members tend to participate less intensively. Results of these interactions are not reported in this paper; however the full results can be available from the authors upon request.

7

We have also looked at the heterogeneous impact on own farm labour across different regions and the results show the same pattern like wage labour. Treated Individuals in the central and western province tend to participate more in own farm labour vis-à-vis treated individuals in the coastal province. However there seem to be no differentiated impact by adult household members in terms of participation in own farm labour. In contrary to the wage labour however we find a significant reduction of male labour use for own farm in female headed households. Again full results can be available upon request.

8

Although results not reported, we find no impact of the CT-OVC programme on wage labour participation by children, which is not surprising given the fact that less than 2 percent of children aged 10-15 worked in wage labour.

JEL Classification: I38, Q01, Q18

References

  1. Alzúa ML, Cruces G, Ripani L. Welfare Programs and Labor Supply in Developing Countries: Experimental Evidence from Latin America. Centro de Estudios Distributivos, Laborales y Sociales, Universidad Nacional de La Plata; 2010. Documento de Trabajo No. 95. [Google Scholar]
  2. Ardington C, Case A, Hosegood V. Labor Supply Responses to Large Social Transfers: Longitudinal Evidence from South Africa. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 2009;1(1):22–48. doi: 10.1257/app.1.1.22. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  3. Barrientos A, DeJong J. Child Poverty and Cash Transfers. Report 4. Childhood Poverty Research and Policy Centre; London: 2004. [Google Scholar]
  4. Becker G. A Theory of the Allocation of Time. The Economic Journal. 1965;299(75):493–517. [Google Scholar]
  5. Berhane G, Hoddinott J, Kumar N, Taffesse AS. The impact of Ethiopia’s productive safety nets and household asset building programme: 2006-2010. IFPRI; Washington DC., USA: 2011. [Google Scholar]
  6. Blattman C, Fiala N, Martinez S. The economic and social returns to cash transfers: evidence from a Ugandan aid program. Columbia University, Departments of Political Science and International & Public Affairs; NY, USA: 2013. [Google Scholar]
  7. Boone R, Covarrubias K, Davis B, Winters P. Cash Transfer Programs and Agricultural Production: The Case of Malawi. Agricultural Economics. 2013;44:365–378. [Google Scholar]
  8. Chetty R, Looney A. Consumption Smoothing and the Welfare Consequences of Social Insurance in Developing Economies. Journal of Public Economics. 2006;90:2351–2356. [Google Scholar]
  9. Chirwa EW, McCord A, Mvula P, Pinder C. The Evaluation of the Improving Livelihoods Through Public Works Programme (ILTPWP) Wadonda Consult/MASAF/CARE Malawi; 2004. [Google Scholar]
  10. Covarrubias K, Davis B, Winters P. From Protection to Production: Productive Impacts of the Malawi Social Cash Transfer Scheme. Journal of Development Effectiveness. 2012;4(1):50–77. [Google Scholar]
  11. Davis B, Carletto G, Winters P. Migration, transfers and economic decision making among agricultural households. Introduction to Special Issue. Journal of Development Studies. 2010;46(1):1–13. [Google Scholar]
  12. Davis B, Gaarder M, Handa S, Yablonski J. Evaluating the impact of cash transfer programs in Sub Saharan Africa: an introduction to the special issue. Journal of Development Effectiveness. 2012;4(1):1–8. [Google Scholar]
  13. Devereux S, Marshall J, MacAskill J, Pelham L. Making Cash Count: Lessons from Cash Transfer Schemes in East and Southern Africa for Supporting the Most Vulnerable Children and Households. Save the Children UK, HelpAge International and Institute of Development Studies; London and Sussex: 2005. [Google Scholar]
  14. Devereux S, Coll-Black S. Review of Evidence and Evidence Gaps on the Effectiveness and Impacts of DFID-supported Pilot Social Transfer Schemes. 2007. DFID Evaluation Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
  15. Duflo E. Grandmothers and Granddaughters: Old-Age Pensions and Intrahousehold Allocation in South Africa. World Bank Economic Review. 2003;17(1):1–25. [Google Scholar]
  16. Edmonds EV, Schady N. Poverty Alleviation and Child Labour. World Bank; 2008. Policy Research Working Paper No. 4702. [Google Scholar]
  17. Elbers C, Gunning JW, Kinsey B. Growth and Risk: Methodology and Micro-evidence. World Bank Economic Review. 2007;21(1):1–20. [Google Scholar]
  18. Feder G, Lau L, Lin J, Luo X. The Relationship between Credit and Productivity in Chinese Agriculture: A Microeconomic Model of Disequilibrium. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 1990;72(5):1151–1157. [Google Scholar]
  19. Fenwick L, Lyne M. The relative importance of liquidity and other constraints inhibiting the growth of small-scale farming in KwaZulu-Natal. Development Southern Africa. 1999;16(1):141–155. [Google Scholar]
  20. Filmer D, Schady N. Getting Girls into School: Evidence from a Scholarship Programme in Cambodia. World Bank; 2006. Policy Research Working Paper No. 3910. [Google Scholar]
  21. Fiszbein A, Schady N. The World Bank Policy Research Report. 2009. Conditional Cash Transfers for Attacking Present and Future Poverty, with Ferreira, F.H.G., Grosh, M., Kelleher, N., Olinto, P., and Skoufias, E. 2009. Chapters 2, 5. [Google Scholar]
  22. Foguel M, Paes de Barrios R. The Effects of Conditional Cash Transfer Programmes on Adult Labour Supply: An Empirical Analysis Using a Time-Series-Cross-Section Sample of Brazilian Municipalities. Estudos economicos. 2010;40(2):259–293. [Google Scholar]
  23. Galiani S, McEwan P. The heterogeneous impact of conditional cash transfers. Mimeo; Wellesley College: 2012. [Google Scholar]
  24. Gertler P, Martinez S, Rubio-Codina M. Investing Cash Transfers to Raise Long Term Living Standards. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 2012;4(1):164–92. [Google Scholar]
  25. Gilligan D, Hoddinott J, Taffesse A. The Impact of Ethiopia’s Productive Safety Net Program and Its Linkages. Journal of Development Studies. 2009;45(10):1684–1706. [Google Scholar]
  26. Gilligan DO, Hoddinott J. Is there persistence in the impact of emergency food aid? Evidence on consumption, food security, and assets in rural Ethiopia. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 2007;89(2):225–242. [Google Scholar]
  27. Gronau R. The Intrafamily Allocation of Goods - How to Separate the Men From the Boys. National Bureau of Economic Research; 1986. NBER Working Papers 1956. [Google Scholar]
  28. Handa S, Davis B, Stampini M, Winters P. Heterogeneous Treatment Effects in Conditional Cash Transfer Programs: Assessing the impact of Progresa on Agricultural Households. Journal of Development Effectiveness. 2010;2(3):320–335. [Google Scholar]
  29. Handa S, Huang C, Hypher N, Teixeira C, Soares F, Davis B. Targeting Performance in Three African Cash Transfer Programs. Journal of Development Effectiveness. 2012;4(1):78–108. [Google Scholar]
  30. Hirano K, Imbens J. Estimation of Causal Effects using Propensity Score Weighting: An Application to Data on Right Heart Catherization. Health Services and Outcomes Research Methodology. 2001;2:259–278. [Google Scholar]
  31. Imbens G, Wooldridge J. Recent Developments in the Econometrics of Program Evaluation. Journal of Economic Literature. 2009;47(1):5–86. [Google Scholar]
  32. Kabeer N. Scoping Study on Social Protection – Evidence on Impacts and Future Research Directions. DFID Research and Evidence; 2009. [Google Scholar]
  33. Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation team The impact of Kenya’s Cash Transfer for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on human capital. Journal of Development Effectiveness. 2012;4(1):38–49. [Google Scholar]
  34. Key N, Sadoulet E, de Janvry A. Transaction Costs and Agricultural Household Supply Response. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 2000;82(2):245–59. [Google Scholar]
  35. Khandker RK, Koolwal GB, Samad HA. Handbook on impact evaluation: quantitative methods and practices. The World Bank; Washington DC., USA: 2010. [Google Scholar]
  36. López R, Romano C. Rural poverty in Honduras: Asset Distribution and Liquidity Constraints. In: López R, Valdés A, editors. Rural Poverty in Latin America. MacMillan Press, Ltd; New York: 2000. [Google Scholar]
  37. Maluccio J. The Impact of Conditional Cash Transfers in Nicaragua on Consumption, Productive Investments and Labor Allocation. Journal of Development Studies. 2010;46(1):14–38. [Google Scholar]
  38. Maluccio J, Flores R. Impact Evaluation of a Conditional Cash Transfer Program: The Nicaraguan Red de Protección Social. IFPRI; Washington DC: 2005. Research Report 141. [Google Scholar]
  39. Martinez S. Doctoral dissertation. University of California; USA: 2004. Pensions, Poverty and Household Investments in Bolivia. [Google Scholar]
  40. Miller C, Tsoka M, Reichert K. Manual of Operations for the Malawi Social Cash Transfer Scheme. Third Edition Center for International Health and Development, Boston University, Boston and Centre for Social Research, University of Malawi; Zomba: 2008. [Google Scholar]
  41. Osei R, Handa S, Park M. Livelihood Empowerment Against Poverty: Predicted Impacts; Paper presented at the workshop Evaluating the Impact of Cash Transfer Programs in Sub Saharan Africa; Nyeri, Kenya. February 5-8, 2012.2012. [Google Scholar]
  42. Otienoh P. Fieldwork Report for Health, Economic, Demographic and Social Survey of Families with OVC 2011. Research Solutions Africa; Nairobi, Kenya: 2011. [Google Scholar]
  43. Parker S, Skoufias E. Final Report. IFPRI; Washington DC: 2000. The Impact of PROGRESA on Work, Leisure and Allocation. [Google Scholar]
  44. Posel D, Fairburn JA, Lund F. Labour migration and households: a reconsideration of the effects of the social pension on labour supply in South Africa. 2004. DPRU/TIPS Forum Paper. [Google Scholar]
  45. Quisumbing AR, Maluccio JA. Intrahousehold allocation and gender relations: new empirical evidence from four developing countries. International Food Policy Research Institute; Washington, DC, USA: 2000. FCND Discussion Paper 84. [Google Scholar]
  46. Ribas R, Soares F. Is the effect of conditional transfers on labor supply negligible everywhere? University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Mimeo; 2111. [Google Scholar]
  47. Rosenzweig M, Wolpin K. Credit market constraints, consumption smoothing, and the accumulation of durable production assets in low-income countries: investments in bullocks in India. The Journal of Political Economy. 1993;101(2):223–244. [Google Scholar]
  48. Singh I, Squire L, Strauss J, editors. Agricultural household models: Extension, application and policy. Johns Hopkins University Press; Baltimore, MD: 1986. [Google Scholar]
  49. Skoufias E, di Maro V. Conditional Cash Transfers, Work Incentives and Poverty. Journal of Development Studies. 2008;44(7):935–960. [Google Scholar]
  50. Soares FV, Ribas RP, Hirata GI. The impact evaluation of a rural CCT programme on outcomes beyond health and education. Journal of Development Effectiveness. 2010;2(1):138–157. [Google Scholar]
  51. Teixeira CG. A Heterogeneity Analysis of the Bolsa Familia Programme Effect on Men and Women’s Work Supply. UNDP International Policy Center for Inclusive Growth; Brasília, Brazil: 2010. Working Paper 61. [Google Scholar]
  52. Todd J, Winters P, Hertz T. Conditional Cash Transfers and Agricultural Production: Lessons from the Oportunidades Experience in Mexico. Journal of Development Studies. 2010;46(1):39–67. [Google Scholar]
  53. Ward P, Hurrell A, Visram A, et al. Kenya OVC-CT programme operational and impact evaluation: 2007-2009. Oxford Policy Management; UK: 2010. [Google Scholar]
  54. Winter-Nelson A, Temu AA. Liquidity constraints, access to credit and pro-poor growth in rural Tanzania. Journal of International Development. 2005;17(7):867–882. [Google Scholar]
  55. Wooldridge JM. Econometric analysis of cross-section and panel data. The MIT Press; Cambridge, MA: 2002. [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

Appendix

RESOURCES