Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2016 May 9.
Published in final edited form as: J Labor Econ. 2015 Jun 29;33(Suppl 1):S187–S223. doi: 10.1086/679020

Recruitment of Foreigners in the Market for Computer Scientists in the United States

John Bound 1, Breno Braga 1, Joseph M Golden 1, Gaurav Khanna 1,
PMCID: PMC4860810  NIHMSID: NIHMS756563  PMID: 27170827

Abstract

We present and calibrate a dynamic model that characterizes the labor market for computer scientists. In our model, firms can recruit computer scientists from recently graduated college students, from STEM workers working in other occupations or from a pool of foreign talent. Counterfactual simulations suggest that wages for computer scientists would have been 2.8–3.8% higher, and the number of Americans employed as computers scientists would have been 7.0–13.6% higher in 2004 if firms could not hire more foreigners than they could in 1994. In contrast, total CS employment would have been 3.8–9.0% lower, and consequently output smaller.

1 Introduction

An increasingly high proportion of the scientists and engineers in the US were born abroad. At a very general level, the issues that come up in the discussion of high skilled immigration mirror the discussion of low skilled immigration. The most basic economic arguments suggest that both high-skill and low-skill immigrants: (1) impart benefits to employers, to owners of other inputs used in production such as capital, and to consumers, and (2) potentially, impose some costs on workers who are close substitutes (Borjas (1999)). On the other hand, the magnitude of these costs may be substantially mitigated if US high skilled workers have good alternatives to working in sectors most impacted by immigrants (Peri & Sparber (2011), Peri et al. (2013)). Additionally, unlike low skilled immigrants, high skilled immigrants contribute to the generation of knowledge and productivity through patenting and innovation. Doing so both serves to shift out the production possibility frontier in the US and may also slow the erosion of the US comparative advantage in high tech (Freeman (2006); Krugman (1979)).

In this paper we study the impact of high skilled immigration on the labor market for computer scientists (CS) in the US, during the Internet boom of the 1990s, and the subsequent slump in the early 2000s. During this period, we observe a substantial increase in the number of temporary non-immigrant visas awarded to high skilled workers, and individuals with computer-related occupations becoming the largest share of H-1B visa holders (US General Accounting Office, 2000). Given these circumstances, it is of considerable interest to investigate how the influx of foreigners affected the labor market outcomes for US computer scientists during this period.

In order to evaluate the impact of immigration on CS domestic workers, we construct a dynamic model that characterizes the labor supply and demand for CS workers during this period. We build into the model the key assumption that labor demand shocks, such as the one created by the dissemination of the Internet, can be accommodated by three sources of CS workers: recent college graduates with CS degrees, US residents in different occupations who switch to CS jobs, and skilled foreigners. Furthermore, firms face a trade-off when deciding to employ immigrants: foreigners are potentially either more productive or less costly than US workers, but there are extra recruitment costs associated with hiring them.

The approach we take in this paper is distinctly partial equilibrium in nature – we focus on the market for computer scientists and ignore any wider impacts that high skilled immigration might have on the U.S. economy (Nathan (2013)). While we believe this approach can potentially be used to understand the impact that the availability of high skilled foreign labor might have had for this market, this approach precludes any analysis of the overall welfare impact of the H-1B program in particular or high skilled immigration more generally.

The predictions of the model on the impacts of immigration on wages depend on the elasticity of labor demand for computer scientists. As long as the demand curve slopes downwards, the increased availability of foreign computer scientists will put downward pressure on the wages for computer scientists in the US. However, as we discuss further in Section 4.4, there are a number of considerations that might lead us to think otherwise in the case of computer scientists. First, even in a closed economy, the fact that computer scientists contribute to innovation reduces the negative effects foreign computer scientists might have on the labor market opportunities for skilled domestic workers. In addition, in an increasingly global world, we might expect that restrictions on the hiring of foreign skilled workers in the US would lead employers to increase the extent to which they outsource work. Indeed, if computer scientists are a sufficient spur to innovation, or if it is easy for domestic employers to offshore work, any negative effects that an increase in the number of foreign computer scientists working in the US might have on the domestic skilled workforce would be completely offset by increases in the domestic demand for computer scientists. In the end this issue comes down to the slope of the demand curve for computer scientists. 1

We use data on wages, domestic and foreign employment, and undergraduate degree completions by major, during the late 1990s and early 2000s to calibrate the parameters of our model such that it reproduces the stylized facts of the CS market during the period. Next, we use the calibrated model to simulate counterfactuals on how the economy would behave if firms had a restriction on the number of foreigners they could hire. Conditional on our assumptions about the slope of the demand curve for computer scientists, our simulation suggests that had US firms not been able to increase their employment of foreign computer scientists above its 1994 level, CS wages would be 2.8–3.8% higher in 2004. Furthermore, the number of Americans working in the CS industry would be 7.0–13.6% higher, the total number of CS workers would be 3.8–9.0% lower and the enrollment levels in computer science would be 19.9–25.5% higher than the observed levels in 2004.

Within the confines of the model, the predictions of our model do not depend on the specific choice we made for non-calibrated parameters, with one important exception. The exception: crowd out in the market for computer scientists depends crucially on the elasticity of demand for their services. Ideally, we would be able to use exogenous supply shifts to identify the slope of the demand curve for computer scientists, while we use exogenous shifts in demand to identify supply curves. We believe that largely exogenous technological breakthroughs in the 1990s increased the demand for computer scientists, allowing us to identify supply curves.2 In other contexts, researchers have treated the increase in foreign born workers in the US economy as exogenous. However, in the current context, immigration law in the US implies that most of the foreign born and trained individuals who migrate to the US to work as computer scientists do so because they are sponsored by US based firms. Thus, it seems implausible to treat the number of foreign born computer scientists in the US as an exogenous increase in supply. In the end, without credible sources of identifying information, we resort to parametrically varying the elasticity of the demand for computer scientists through, what we will argue is a plausible range, from −1.3 to −4.0.

This paper constitutes a contribution to two different dimensions of the research literature. First, our study can be seen as an extension of the models of the market for scientists and engineers developed by Freeman (1975, 1976) in the 1970s and refined by Ryoo & Rosen (2004) more recently. In Ryoo and Rosen’s model, employers are restricted to hiring recent graduates from US engineering programs. In our model, employers can also hire both foreigners and US based individuals not trained as computer scientists. As a result, the supply of CS workers implied by our model is substantially more elastic than implied by the Ryoo and Rosen model, especially in the short term. More importantly, the substantial number of skilled foreign workers affects how the labor and education markets adjusts to an increase in the demand for skilled labor. Second, our paper relates to the recent literature on the potential impact that the hiring of high skilled immigrants might have on the wages and employment prospects of US natives.

We review this literature in detail, and describe the market for CS workers in section 2. Section 3 presents the dynamic model we build to characterize the market for CS workers when firms can recruit foreigners. In section 4, we describe how we calibrate the parameters of the model and the counterfactual simulations where firms have restrictions on the number of foreigners they can hire. We conclude with section 5 which presents a discussion based on the results of the paper.

2 The Market for Computer Scientists in the 1990s

2.1 The Information Technology Boom of the Late 1990s

During the mid 1990s, we observe the beginning of the utilization of the Internet for commercial purposes in the United States3 and a substantial increase in the number of Internet users. One indicator of a contemporaneous change in demand for IT workers is the rise of R&D expenditure of firms in both the computer programming services, and the computer related equipment sector. Specifically, the share of total private R&D of the firms of these two industries increased from 19.5% to 22.1% between 1991 and 1998 (author’s computations using Compustat data). The entry and then extraordinary appreciation of tech firms like Yahoo, Amazon and eBay provides a further testament to the “boom” in the IT sector prior to 2001.

These technological innovations had a dramatic effect on the labor market for computer scientists. According to the Census, the number of employed individuals working either as computer scientists or computer software developers (CS) increased by 161% between the years 1990 and 2000. As a comparison, during the same period, the total number of employed workers with at least a bachelor degree increased by 27%, while the number of workers in other STEM occupations increased by 14%.4 Table 1 shows computer scientists as a share of the college educated workforce and the college educated STEM workforce. In each case, the share was rising before 1990, but rises dramatically during the 1990s. Indeed, by 2000 more than half of all STEM workers are computer scientists. In Figure 1a, we use the CPS to show a similar pattern, additionally showing that the growth of CS employment started in the second half of the decade - the same period as the dissemination of the Internet. There is no doubt this was a period of employment expansion of the CS workforce.

Table 1.

Fraction of Computer Scientists and Immigrants in the US Workforce by Occupation

Year 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Computer Scientists:
as a fraction of workers with a Bachelor’s/Master’s 1.68% 1.83% 3.30% 5.66% 5.28%
as a fraction of STEM college graduates 16.86% 23.60% 35.99% 53.31% 54.90%

Immigrants:
as a fraction of Bachelor’s/Master’s 2.10% 5.43% 6.86% 8.41% 12.77%
as a fraction of Computer Scientists 2.37% 7.09% 11.06% 18.59% 27.82%
as a fraction of Other STEM workers 3.63% 9.72% 10.71% 12.69% 18.21%

Note: Sample restricted to employed workers with a Bachelors or a Masters degree. Definition of Computer Scientists and STEM workers determined by occupational coding (for details see Data Appendix online). Immigrant is defined as one born abroad, and migrated to the US after the age of 18.

Source: US Census (years 1970 to 2000); ACS (2010)

Figure 1.

Figure 1

Major Trends (1990 to 2012)

Note: Sample restricted to employed workers with a Bachelors or a Masters degree. Definition of Computer Scientists and STEM workers determined by occupational coding (for details see Data Appendix online). STEM majors are defined as engineering, computer and math sciences and natural science. Earning are median weekly earnings. Imputed values excluded, and values are lagged by one year due to retrospective nature of the survey. Immigrant defined as one born abroad, and migrated to the US after the age of 18. Immigration status is not available in the CPS before 1994.

Sources: March CPS (for employment, earnings, and immigrants); IPEDS Completions Survey (for degrees)

On top of employment decisions, there is evidence that Internet innovation also affected educational choices of students. We show in Figure 1b that the number of bachelor degrees awarded in computer science as a fraction of both the total number of bachelor degrees and the number of STEM major degrees increased dramatically during this period. The CS share of total bachelor degrees increased from about 2% in 1995 to more than 4% in 2002. Even when compared to other STEM majors, it is clear from the figure that for college students, the decision to study computer science also responded to the Internet boom.

In addition to affecting employment and enrollment decisions, there is also empirical evidence that computer scientist wages responded to expanding Internet use. From the Census, we observe a 18% increase in the median real weekly wages of CS workers between 1990 and 2000. The CPS presents similar patterns: starting in the year 1994 we observe in Figure 1c that wages of computer scientists increased considerably when compared to both workers with other STEM occupations and all workers with a bachelor degree. In fact, while during the beginning of the 1990s, the earnings of CS workers were systematically lower than other STEM occupations, the wage differential tends to disappear after 1998.5

2.2 The Immigrant Contribution to the Growth of the High Tech Work-force

Employment adjustments in the market for computer scientists happened disproportionately among foreigners during the Internet boom. Evidence for this claim is found in Table 1 and Figure 1d, where we use the Census and CPS to compare the share of foreign computer scientists to the share of foreign workers in other occupations.6 In the second half of 1990s, the foreign fraction of CS workers increased considerably more than both the foreign fraction of all workers with a bachelor degree and the foreign fraction of all workers in a STEM occupation. In particular, foreigners were less represented among individuals working as computer scientists than in other STEM occupations in 1994. However, with the dissemination of the Internet in the later years of the decade, foreigners became a more important part of the pool of CS workers, as foreigners comprised 29.6% of the increase in CS workers.

The growth in the representation of the foreign born among the US computer scientist workforce was fueled by two developments. First, there was a truly dramatic increase in the foreign supply of men and women with college educations in science and engineering fields (Freeman (2009)). To take one important example, in India, the number of first degrees conferred in science and engineering rose from 176 thousand in 1990 to 455 thousand in 2000. Second, the Immigration Act of 1990 established the H-1B visa program for temporary workers in “specialty occupations.”7 The regulations define a “specialty occupation” as requiring theoretical and practical application of a body of highly specialized knowledge in a field of human endeavor including, but not limited to, architecture, engineering, mathematics, physical sciences, social sciences, medicine and health, education, law, accounting, business specialties, theology, and the arts. In addition, applicants are required to have attained a bachelor’s degree or its equivalent as a minimum.

Firms that wish to hire foreigners on H-1B visas must first file a Labor Condition Application (LCA). In LCA’s for H-1B workers, the employer must attest that the firm will pay the non-immigrant the greater of the actual compensation paid to other employees in the same job or the prevailing compensation for that occupation, and the firm will provide working conditions for the non-immigrant that do not cause the working conditions of the other employees to be adversely affected. At that point, prospective H-1B non-immigrants must demonstrate to the US Citizenship and Immigration Services Bureau (USCIS) in the Department of Homeland Security (DHS) that they have the requisite education and work experience for the posted positions. USCIS then may approve the petition for the H-1B non-immigrant for a period up to three years. The visa may be extended for an additional three years, thus a foreigner can stay a maximum of six years on an H-1B visa, though firms can sponsor H-1B visa holders for a permanent resident visa. An important feature of the H-1B visa is that the visa is for work at the specific firm. As a result, workers are effectively tied to their sponsoring firm.

Since 1990 there has been a cap in the number of H-1B visas that can be issued. Initially this cap was set at 65,000 visas per year. In the initial years of the program, the cap was never reached, By the mid-1990s, however, the allocation tended to fill each year on a first come, first served basis, resulting in frequent denials or delays on H-1Bs because the annual cap had been reached. After lobbying by the industry, at the end of the decade, Congress acted to raise the cap first to 115,000 for FY1999 and to 195,000 for FY2000–2003. The cap then reverted to 65,000.8 Figure 2 shows the growth in the number of H-1 visas issued over the last three decades, estimates of the stock of H-1 visas in the economy each year, and the changes in the H-1B visa cap.

Figure 2.

Figure 2

H-1 and H-1B Visa Population

Note: Population stock is constructed using estimations of in flow (visas granted) and out flow (deaths, permanent residency, or emigration) of H-1 workers. In later years, the number of visas granted could exceed the visa cap due to exemptions for foreigners who work at universities and non-profit research facilities.

Through the decade of the 1990s, H-1B visas became an important source of labor for the technology sector. The National Survey of College Graduates shows that 55% of foreigners working in CS fields in 2003 arrived in the US on a temporary working (H-1B) or a student type visa (F-1, J-1). Furthermore, institutional information indicates a significant increase in the number of visas awarded to computer related occupations during the 1990s. Numbers from the U.S. General Accounting Office (1992) report show that “computers, programming, and related occupations” corresponded only to 11% of the total number of H-1 visas in 1989. However, with concurrent to the Internet boom, computer scientists became a more significant fraction of individuals that received these type of working visas: according to the U.S. Immigration and Naturalization Service (2000), the number of H-1B visas awarded to computer-related occupation in 1999 jumped to close to two-thirds of the visas, and the Department of Commerce (2000) estimated that during the late 1990s, 28% of programmer jobs went to H-1B visa holders.

While H-1B visas holders represent an important source of computer scientists, they do not represent all foreigners in the country working as computer scientists. A significant number of such foreigners are permanent immigrants, some of whom may have come either as children or as students. Other foreigners enter the US to work as computer scientists in the US on L-1B visas, which permit companies with offices both in the US and overseas to move skilled employees from overseas to the US. While we know of no data showing the fraction of computer scientists working in the US on L-1B visas, substantially fewer L-1(A&B) visas are issued than are H-1Bs.

2.3 The Previous Literature on the Impact of Immigrants on the High Tech Workforce in the US

Critiques of the H-1B program (e.g. Matloff (2003)) argue that firms are using cheap foreign labor to undercut and replace skilled US workers. Even the fiercest critiques of the program do not claim that employers are technically evading the law (Kirkegaard (2005)). Rather, these authors argue that the requirement that firms pay visa holders the prevailing wage is close to meaningless. They claim that firms can describe positions using minimal qualifications for the job, thereby establishing a low “prevailing” wage, and then hire overqualified foreigners into the position. These authors conclude that given the excess supply of highly qualified foreigners willing to take the jobs, and given the lack of portability of the H-1B visa, workers on an H-1B visa are not in a position to search for higher wages.

One way to get a handle on the extent to which H-1B visa holders are being under-paid relative to their US counterparts is to compare foreigners on H-1B visas to those with “green cards,” which are portable. Available evidence suggests that computer scientists holding green cards are paid more than observationally equivalent H-1B visa holders. Using difference-in-difference propensity score matching, Mukhopadhyay & Oxborrow (2012) find that green card holders earn 25.4 percent more than observably comparable temporary foreign workers. Additionally, based on an internet survey, Mithas & Lucas (2010), found that IT professionals with green cards earn roughly 5 percent more than observationally equivalent H-1B visa holders using log earnings regressions. Comparisons between green card and H-1B holders are far from perfect, because green cards are not randomly assigned. Many high skilled workers obtain green cards by being sponsored by their employers after they have been working on an H-1B for a number of years. It seems reasonable to assume that those being sponsored are those that both want to stay in the US and are also amongst those the employer wants to hold onto. These kind of considerations lead us to suspect that, conditional on observables, green card holders are positively selected. Given these considerations, it is somewhat surprising that the observed green card premium is not larger than it is.

While there may be no incontrovertible estimate of the productivity (conditional on earnings) advantage of foreign high skilled labor, simple economic reasons suggests this advantage must exist. US employers face both pecuniary and non-pecuniary costs associated with hiring foreigners. A small GAO survey (U.S. General Accounting Office, 2011) estimated the legal and administrative costs associated with each H-1B hire to range from 2.3 to 7.5 thousand dollars. It seems reasonable to assume that employers must expect some cost or productivity advantage when hiring foreigners. This does not mean that foreign hires are always super stars. The productivity advantage could be quite small, and could involve effort, not ability. However, without some productivity advantage, it is hard to see why employers go through the effort and expense to hire foreigners.

H-1B critics are arguing that, for the reasons discussed above, employers find hiring foreign high skilled labor an attractive alternative and that such hiring either “crowds out” natives from jobs or put downward pressure on their wages. However, as far as we know, critics of the H-1B program have not tried to estimate the magnitude of either of these effects. Recent work by economists have started to fill this void. Kerr & Lincoln (2010) and Hunt & Gauthier-Loiselle (2010) provide original empirical evidence on the link between variation in immigrant flows and innovation measured by patenting - finding evidence suggesting that the net impact of immigration is positive rather than simply substituting for native employment. Kerr & Lincoln (2010) also show that variation in immigrant flows at the local level related to changes in H-1B flows do not appear to adversely impact native employment and have a small, statistically insignificant effect on their wages.

A potential issue with Kerr and Lincoln’s analysis is that the observed, reduced-form outcomes may capture concurrent changes in area specific demand for computer scientists. Kerr and Lincoln fully understand this endogeneity issue. To circumvent the problem, they construct a variable that interacts an estimate for the total number of individuals working on H-1B visas in a city with local area dependencies on H-1Bs. Their hope is that the variation in this variable is driven largely by changes in the cap on new H-1B visas that occurred over the last 20 years. That said, it is unclear the extent to which the variation Kerr and Lincoln use is being driven by variation in the visa cap. Because of the dot com bubble bust in 2000 and 2001, the variation in the H-1B cap is only loosely related to actual number of H-1Bs issued. In addition, it is hard to imagine that the cap was exogenous to the demand for IT workers. Finally, if because of local agglomeration effects, the IT boom was concentrated in areas of the country that were already IT intensive (such as Silicon Valley), then the measure of local dependency would be endogenous.

In the context of an economic model, it is difficult to generate a situation in which there is little crowd out unless labor demand is very elastic. While there are models of the labor market which could rationalize such large elasticities,9 this paper proposes an alternative interpretation to Kerr and Lincoln’s results, even when the labor demand is not close to perfectly elastic. If employers face costs to hire immigrant labor and are bound to pay the going wage, firms might disproportionately hire immigrants only when the demand for workers is increasing. In this case, immigrants would not replace incumbent workers or depress wages, but rather have a negative impact on the growth of wages and employment for natives. Under these circumstances, one might very well see a positive association between an increase in the utilization of foreign computer scientists and the increased utilization of their US counterparts, even though the availability of skilled foreigners is putting downward pressure on the growth in earnings and employment of native computer scientists.

3 A Dynamic Model of Supply and Demand of Computer Scientists

To gauge the impact that the availability of foreign high skilled labor has had on US workers, we construct a simple model of the labor market for computer scientists. While our model is quite stylized, we intend to capture the most salient features of the market.

In our model there are three potential sources for computers scientists. First, there are those who earn computer science bachelor’s degrees from US institutions. These individuals must complete college before they are ready to work. Second, there are US residents working in other occupations who can switch into computer science, but must pay costs to switch occupations. Third, there are foreigners who are being recruited on temporary work visas.10 There is also the group who immigrated with their parents as children, but these individuals are typically either citizens or green card holders and we assume employers do not distinguish between these individuals and the US born. We also ignore the fact that some immigrants are coming in on permanent visas. As the GAO and Department of Commerce reports cited earlier suggest, at least in the 1990s, the majority of foreigners working as computer scientists within the US who have finished their undergraduate degrees abroad, arrived on temporary work visas. In addition, the data we will use does not allow us to distinguish visa types.

In terms of the demand side of the model, we assume that firms observe the technological progress level and make decisions about whether to hire foreigners or domestic workers. We assume that foreigners are somewhat more productive than US workers but are paid the same wage due to institutional restrictions. Alternatively, we could have equally well assumed employers experience a cost advantage associated with hiring foreigners. Furthermore, firms face increasing costs for recruiting foreigners, making it non-optimal for firms to only hire foreign workers.

3.1 Labor Supply of American Computer Scientists

We model U.S computer scientists as making two types of decisions along their career in order to maximize the expected present value of their life time utility. At age 20, individuals in college choose the field of study that influences their initial occupation after graduation, and from age 22 to 65, workers choose between working as a computer scientist or in another occupation. Individuals have rational, forward looking behavior and make studying and working decisions based on the information available at each period.

3.1.1 Studying decision

We assume that students make their major decisions when they are juniors in college. At age 20, an individual i draws idiosyncratic taste shocks for studying computer science or another field: ηic and ηio, respectively. This student also has expectations about the prospects of starting a career in each occupation after graduation (age 22), which have a values V22c and V22o respectively. With this information, an individual chooses between pursuing computer sciences or a different choice of major at the undergraduate level.11

We model the utility of a student as a linear function of the taste shocks and career prospects in each sector. There is also a taste attractiveness parameter αo for studying a different field from computer science and individuals discount their future with an annual discount factor β. With these assumptions, the field of study decision is represented by:

max{β2EtV22c+ηic,β2EtV22o+αo+ηio}

We assume that ηic and ηio are independently and identically distributed and for s = {c, o}, can be defined as ηis=σ0vis, where σ0 is a scale parameter and vis is distributed as a standard Type I Extreme Value distribution. This distributional assumption is common to dynamic discrete choice models (Rust (1987), Kline (2008)) and it is convenient because it allows the decisions of agents to be smoothed out, a desired property that will be used in the characterization of the equilibrium of the model.

Given the distributional assumption of idiosyncratic taste shocks, it follows that the probability of a worker graduating with a computer science degree can be written in logistic form:

ptc=[1+exp(-(β2Et-2[V22c-V22o]-αo)/σ0)]-1

Note that the important parameter for how studying choices of workers are sensitive to different career prospects is the standard deviation of taste shocks. Small values of σ0 imply that small changes in career prospects can produce big variations in the number of students graduating with a computer science degree.

The next step to characterize the supply of young computer scientists is to map the graduating probability described above to employment. Defining Mta as the exogenous number of college graduates with age a in time period t,12 the number of recent graduates with a computer science degree in year t is represented by Ct=ptcMt22.

3.1.2 Working Decision

The field of study determines if an individual enters the labor market as either a computer scientist or with a different occupation. However, individuals can choose to switch occupations along their careers. Specifically, at the beginning of each period, individuals between ages 22 and 65 choose to work in CS or another type of job in order to maximize the expected present value of their lifetime utility.

A feature of the model is that switching occupations is costly for the worker. A justification for this assumption is that workers have occupational-specific human capital that cannot be transferred (Kambourov & Manovskii (2009)). We assume the cost to switch occupations is a quadratic function of a worker’s age. Note that this assumption implies that it becomes increasingly harder for workers to switch occupations as they get older. Additionally, there is no general human capital accumulation and wages do not vary with the age of a worker.13

Finally, we assume that workers have linear utility from wages, taste shocks and career prospects. Furthermore, wages must be totally consumed in that same year and workers cannot save or borrow. The Bellman equations of worker i at age a between 22 and 64 at time t if he starts the period as a computer scientist or other occupation are respectively:

Vt,ac=max{wtc+βEtVt+1,a+1c+εitc,wto-c(a)+βEtVt+1,a+1o+εito+α1}Vt,ao=max{wtc-c(a)+βEtVt+1,a+1c+εitc,wto+βEtVt+1,a+1o+εito+α1}

where c(a) = λ0 + λ1a + λ2a2, is the monetary cost of switching occupation for an age a worker, and α1 is the taste attractiveness parameter for not working as a computer scientist. For simplicity, we assume that the current wage in the other occupation wto is exogenous and perfectly anticipated by the workers.14 In the model, all workers retire at age 65 and their retirement benefits do not depend on their career choices. As a consequence, workers at age 65 face the same decision problem but, without consideration for the future.

As in the college-major decision problem, idiosyncratic taste shocks play an important role in working decisions of an individual. Once more, we will assume that taste shocks are independently15 and identically distributed and for s = {c, o} can be defined as εits=σ1vits where σ1 is a scale parameter and vis is distributed as a standard Type I Extreme Value distribution.

Defining pt,asS as the probability that a worker at age a between 22 and 64 moves from occupation s to occupation S, it follows from the error distribution assumption that the migration probabilities can be represented as:

pt,aoc=[1+exp(-(wtc-wto-c(a)-α1+βEt[Vt+1,a+1c-Vt+1,a+1o])/σ1)]-1pt,aco=[1+exp(-(wto-wtc-c(a)+α1+βEt[Vt+1,a+1o-Vt+1,a+1c])/σ1)]-1

and the migration probabilities of workers at age 65 are the same without discounting future career prospects. Note that the switching probabilities depend upon both the current wage differential and expected future career prospects at each occupation. The standard deviation of the taste shocks, the sector attractiveness constant and the cost of switching occupations will effect the extent to which changes in relative career prospects affect the movement of US residents across fields.

A feature of dynamic models with forward looking individuals is that working decisions depend upon the equilibrium distribution of career prospects. As in the dynamic choice literature with extreme value errors (Rust (1987) and Kline (2008)), we use the properties of the idiosyncratic taste shocks distribution to simplify the expressions for the expected values of career prospects. As a result, the expected value function for an individual at age a between 22 and 64 working as a computer scientists or in another occupation are respectively:

EtVt+1,a+1c=σ1Et[γ+ln{exp((wt+1c+βEt+1Vt+2,a+2c)/σ1)+exp(((wt+1o-c(a)+α1+βEt+1Vt+2,a+2o)/σ1)}]EtVt+1,a+1o=σ1Et[γ+ln{exp((wt+1o+α1+βEt+1Vt+2,a+2o)/σ1)+exp(((wt+1s-c(a)+βEt+1Vt+2,a+2c)/σ1)}] (1)

where gamma γ ≅ 0.577 is the Euler’s constant and the expectations are taken with respect to future taste shocks. Workers at age 65 face the same expected values but don’t discount the future.

Now we turn to transforming migration probabilities to employment. The first step is to determine the CS supply of recent college graduates. After leaving college, individuals can start their careers in the occupation correspondent to their field of study with no cost. However, we also allow workers at age 22 to pay the switching costs and get their first job in an occupation different from their field of study. As a consequence, the number of computer scientists at age 22 is a function of the number of recent graduates with a computer science degree and the migration probabilities:

Lt22=(1-pt,22co)Ct+pt,22oc[Mt22-Ct]

where Mt22 is the number of recent college graduates, Ct is the number of recent graduates with a computer science degree, and Mt22-Ct is the number of college graduates with any other degree.

In the same way, the supply of computer scientists at age a from 23–65 is a function of past employment in each occupation and the migration probabilities:

Lta=(1-pt,aco)Lt-1a-1+pt,aoc[Mt-1a-1-Lt-1a-1]

where Mta is the exogenous total number of workers in the economy at age a in time period t. Mta-Lta is the number of workers at age a working in the residual sector. For simplicity, we assume that the number of workers in the economy at age Mta is exogenous and constant over time.16

The aggregate domestic labor supply of computer scientists is the sum of labor supply at all ages:

Lt=a=22a=65Lta (2)

Note that the labor supply of computer scientists depends on past employment, new college graduates with a computer science degree and on wages through the migration probabilities.

3.2 Labor Supply of Foreign Computer Scientists

An important characteristic of our model is that firms can recruit foreigners to work as computer scientists. As it will become clear throughout the section, this possibility has implications on how the market for CS workers responds to technological shocks, such as Internet innovation, in terms of enrollment decisions, wages and employment.

We model foreign computer scientists as having a perfectly elastic labor supply. The wage that a computer scientist could obtain in India, for example, is so much lower than it is in the US that the wage premium creates a large queue of individuals ready to take jobs in the US (Clemens (2013) provides direct evidence on this point).17 Additionally, we assume that foreigners cannot switch their occupation once hired to work as computer scientists and they continue to work in the US until their visa expires.18

A simplified way to model the framework describe above is to define Rt as the number of foreigners recruited as CS in period t. Next, we assume that all CS foreigners stay in the US for 6 years, that is the maximum length of a H-1B visa contract.19 In this framework, the number of foreigners currently working as CS in the US is defined as the sum of current and the recruitment in the past 5 years:

Ft=j=05Rt-j (3)

3.3 Labor Demand for Computer Scientists

We model the labor demand as resulting from the decisions made by a standard representative firm in a perfectly competitive framework. In the model, firms observe both the wage and technological progress levels and choose US and foreign employment in order to maximize their intertemporal profits. While firms do not assume that their US employees will necessarily stay with them from one period to the next, given the institutional setting, firms do assume that foreign workers will continue with the firm until the workers’ visa expires six years after he or she is hired.

We assume there is only one type of firm that hires computer scientists. CS labor is the only input used in the production function and we ignore the firm’s decision about capital or other types of labor adjustments.20 We further assume that computer scientists at different ages are perfect substitutes in the production function. As a consequence, firms do not distinguish workers by age when making their hiring decision, precluding the kind of issues addressed by Kerr et al. (2013).21 In addition, we assume that foreigners and US workers are close substitutes in the production function, but foreigners have higher marginal productivity than US workers.

A restriction we impose in the model is that all computer scientists in the market are paid the same wage independently of their age or citizenship. This assumption is in accordance with the H-1B visa regulation that requires that wages paid to foreigners must be at least the prevailing wage rate for the occupational classification in their area of employment. Finally, there are no adjustment costs for American workers but firms incur extra costs to recruit foreigners.22 This expenditure is justified by the fees and expenses directly related to the visa application process, and also the extra cost that a firm typically has for searching for workers overseas.

As it will become clear throughout the section, this framework implies that firms face a trade-off when making the decision of hiring foreigners. On one hand, foreigners have a higher marginal productivity than US workers and are paid the same wage. As a consequence, firms are willing to substitute foreign workers for their US workers. On the other hand, there are extra recruitment costs to bring foreigners to the US. This restriction implies that firms never completely substitute foreign for US workers.

3.3.1 Firm’s Decision

The forward looking firm makes decisions about the recruitment of US and foreign workers in order to maximize intertemporal profits, as represented by the Bellman equation:23

πt=maxLt,RtAtY(Lt+θFt)-wt(Lt+Ft)-CR(Rt)+βEt[πt+1]

subject to foreign labor supply:

Ft=j=05Rt-j

where AtY (.) is the production function, θ is a constant greater than 1 that represents marginal productivity differences between foreigners and US workers, and CR(.) is the recruitment cost function of foreigners.

We represent the production function as Cobb-Douglas, such that Y (Lt + θFt) = (Lt + θFt)γ, for some γ between zero and one, implying a downward sloping labor demand curve for computer scientists. This set-up can be made consistent with the Romer (1986) model of knowledge accumulation as a by-product of capital accumulation; or the Arrow (1962) learning-by-doing model, where we allow increases in employment to lead to increases in productivity. To see this, we can reformulate the production function to be Yt = [Bt(Lt + θFt)]δ. If we let the technology parameter exhibit learning-by-doing, then Bt = ψt(Lt + θFt)α, giving us a production function of the form Yt=ψtδ(Lt+θFt)δα. If we define, At=ψtδ and γ = αδ, then we recover the simple Cobb-Douglas production function: At(Lt + θFt)γ. The parameter, γ, should then be thought of as a reduced-form parameter that captures not just the effective labor share in output, but also the productivity gains from hiring more effective workers. As long as γ lies between 0 and 1, this parametrization guarantees a decreasing marginal return to labor and thus an interior solution for the employment decision of the firm. Furthermore, the parameter γ has a direct mapping to the long-run elasticity of labor demand with respect to effective labor (Le = L + θF):

εLe,w=11-γ

Additionally, we assume that recruitment costs of foreigners include both linear and quadratic components CR(Rt)=c1Rt+c2Rt2. The linear term in the foreign recruitment cost represents expenditures that are required for hiring each foreign worker, such as application fees. The quadratic term has been widely used in dynamic labor demand literature (Sargent (1978) and Shapiro (1986)). As will become clear from the first order condition of the firm, convex hiring costs, because increasing marginal recruitment costs of foreigners, prevents firms from completely substituting foreigners for domestic workers.24

As in a typical dynamic labor demand problem the solution to the firm’s decision can be characterized by both the first order and envelope conditions with respect to the employment level. The first order condition of the firm’s maximization problem with respect to US employment is represented by the following equation:

Atγ(Lt+θFt)γ-1=wt (4)

Note that because there is no adjustment costs for US workers, the first order condition with respect to US employment is the same as in a static maximization problem. It is simply characterized by firms equalizing the marginal product of US workers to their wage level.

In addition to choosing US worker employment, the firm also decides the number of foreign workers recruited at each period. The first order condition of the firm’s problem with respect to Rt is given by:

θAtγ(Lt+θFt)γ-1-wt-c1-2c2Rt+j=15βjEt[πt+jRt]=0

where πt+jRt is defined as how profits in t+j are affected by changes in the recruitment in t. Finally, we use envelope condition to derive the shadow price of past foreign recruitment on current profits, such that:

πtRt-j=θAtγ(Lt+θFt)γ-1-wtforj=1,,5

Rearranging the first order and envelope conditions of foreigner recruitment leads us to the useful alternative representation to the demand for foreign workers:

j=o5βjEt[θAt+jγ(Lt+j+θFt+j)γ-1-wt+j]=c1+2c2Rt (5)

Equation (5) shows the trade-off faced by firms when hiring foreigners. The left hand side can be interpreted as the present value of the expected marginal benefit of recruiting a foreigner, defined as the difference between the marginal productivity of a foreigner and wage level during the 6 years duration of his contract. Note that firms benefit from hiring foreigners because they are more productive than US workers by a constant θ but are paid the same wage. The right hand side represents the marginal cost of recruiting a foreigner. Since the marginal cost of recruiting a foreigner is increasing with Rt, firms will never completely substitute foreigners for US workers in the model.

3.4 Equilibrium

A dynamic general equilibrium can be characterized by the system of equations that represent those choice functions and the stochastic process of technological progress At. In particular, equation (1) characterizes the expectations of workers with respect to future career prospects, equations (2) and (3) are the dynamic labor supply of American and foreigner computer scientists respectively, and equations (4) and (5) describe the dynamic labor demand for American and foreign CS.

The last piece to characterize the equilibrium of the model is to define a stochastic process of technological progress. Note that At is the only source of exogenous variation to the system. We choose to specify At as a close to random walk process, 25 such that:

At=0.999At-1+0.001A¯+ξt (6)

where Ā is the steady state level of progress, and ξt is the i.i.d. random idiosyncratic productivity shock with mean zero that is assumed to be independent of other variables of the model.26

The equilibrium of the model can be expressed by a mapping from the state variables: s={Ct,Lt-122,,Lt-164,Rt-1,,Rt-5,At-1} and exogenous productivity shock ξt to the values of Lt, wt, Rt, and Vt, the vector of career prospects at different occupations for different ages, that satisfies the system of equations (1) to (6). We solve the system by numerically simulating the model in Dynare (a widely used software) via perturbation methods (Juillard (1996)). The policy functions are calculated using a second order polynomial approximation to the decision rules implied by the equations of the model Collard & Juillard (2001a,b).

4 Calibration and Simulation

4.1 Identification and Calibration Method

There are twelve parameters in the model {σ0, α0, σ1, α1, λ0, λ1, λ2, β, γ, θ, cR1, cR2}. We set the foreign worker productivity27 parameter θ = 1.12 based on estimations from the 2003 National Survey of College Graduates data.28 This value of the wage premium earned by foreign green card holders is broadly consistent with other estimates in the literature (Mithas & Lucas (2010), Mukhopadhyay & Oxborrow (2012)). Furthermore, we set the annual discount rate of workers and firms β = 0.9. Our results are not sensitive to plausible variations of this parameter.

In our modeling we are treating the wage, employment and enrollment shifts as a response to an exogenous shift in the demand for computer scientists due to the technological developments that occurred during the period of analysis. We use this demand shift to identify the enrollment and labor supply response of natives, and the parameters affecting the hiring decision of foreigners: {σ0, α0, λ0, λ1, λ2, σ1, α1, cR1, cR2}. At the same time, demand shifts will not identify the slope of the labor demand curve. As a result, we present the results of the paper using different assumptions about the values of γ.

To calibrate {σ0, α0, λ0, λ1, λ2, σ1, α1, cR1, cR2}, we use observations of US and foreign employment, wages, and enrollment29 between 1994 and 2004. We define other STEM occupations as the career alternative to CS jobs. The data we are using on employment and earnings is derived from the March Current Population Survey. This survey contains no indication as to the visa status of the foreign born. To approximate the population of interest, we identify the foreign born who immigrated to the US after they turned 18 as our foreign workers. We also normalize employment variables to use units of American STEM workers, and wages to use units of wages30 of other STEM jobs, and thus define our key data series as:31

  1. Lt=UScomputerscientistsUSworkerswithSTEMoccupations

  2. Ft=ForeigncomputerscientistsUSworkerswithSTEMoccupations

  3. wt=MedianweeklywagesforcomputerscientistsMedianweeklywagesforotherSTEMjobs

  4. pt+2c=UScomputerscienceBachelorsdegressawarded(lagged2years)USSTEMBachelorsdegressawarded(lagged2years)

  5. sta1,a2=UScomputerscientistswithagebetweena1anda2UScomputerscientists For a1and a2 defined as the age ranges {22 to 34; 35 to 44; 45 to 65}.

Conditional on γ and θ and observations of {wt, Lt, Ft} we are able to recover values of At implied by our model during the period of 1994 to 2004:

At=wtγ(Lt+θFt)γ-1

We assume that the economy is in steady state in 1994, such that Ā = A1994, and that it is hit by the series of shocks. In terms of expectations, we assume that both firms and individuals are surprised by changes in At.32 Note that following equation (6), firms and workers have essentially static expectations about future technology progress, such that 𝔼t[At+j] = ≅ At for any j.

The remaining parameters {σ0, α0, λ0, λ1, λ2, σ1, α1, cR1, cR2} are calibrated such that the model matches the observations of Lt, Ft, wt, in two periods of time: 1994 and 2004, and the changes in the age structure sta1,a2 in 2004.33 We use a Nelder-Mead simplex method to find parameter values which yield solutions to the model under these data restrictions.34 The intuition for the identification of the parameters comes straight from the data. For the given series of exogenous technological shocks and wages, variations of enrollment between 1994 and 2004 identify the parameters σ0 and α0, changes in native employment identify the parameters σ1 and α1, variations in foreign employment identify the recruitment cost parameters cR1 and cR2, and changes in the age structure of computer scientists identify the quadratic costs of switching occupations: parameters λ0, λ1, and λ2.

4.2 Calibration results

We use the procedure described above to calibrate the model using three different values of γ: {0.25, 0.5, 0.75}.35 We present the calibrated parameters for these different values of γ in Table 2 and a comparison of the data with the model’s output in Figures 34. We consider the demand elasticities derived from our γ’s to span a reasonable range of plausible values of this parameter, which as we describe in Section 4.4, is challenging to identify.

Table 2.

Calibrated Parameters

Parameter Description γ
Calibrated Parameters 0.25 0.50 0.75
Calibrated Value
α0 Mean taste for not studying CS 0.0940 0.0943 0.0836
σ0 Std. dev. of study area taste shocks 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002
α1 Mean taste for not working in CS 0.3715 0.3486 0.3673
σ1 Std. dev. of occupation taste shocks 0.1385 0.1364 0.1439
cR1 Foreign linear recruitment cost 0.5247 0.5228 0.5221
cR2 Foreign quadratic recruitment cost 0.0102 0.0109 0.0124
λ0 Sector switching constant cost 0.1159 0.1164 0.1031
λ1 Sector switching linear cost 0.0138 0.0119 0.0151
λ2 Sector switching quadratic cost 0.0006 0.0004 0.0003
Economic Results
εLd,w Long run effective labor demand elasticity 1.33 2.00 4.00
εLs,w Long run US occupational labor supply elasticity 5.4612 5.5743 5.3404
εp,w Long run US CS enrollment elasticity 11.6954 11.2624 11.7071
εLs,ws
Short run US occupational labor supply elasticity 0.5591 0.6745 0.6642
εp,ws
Short run US CS enrollment elasticity 10.2834 11.3758 11.3386
ACF Average cost of recruiting foreign worker 0.5312 0.5299 0.53

Note: The average cost of recruiting a foreign worker is measured in units of average annual US non-CS STEM worker wages. The parameter determines the labor demand elasticity to wages.

Figure 3.

Figure 3

Model and Counterfactual (1/2)

Note: The full model is the simulation of the economy using the calibrated parameters. The restricted model simulates the same calibrated model, but restricting firms to keep their foreign temporary worker CS employment to its 1994 value. Wages are relative to other STEM occupations. Employment and enrollment are shares of STEM workers and undergrad STEM enrollment, respectively, and are multiplied by 100. The parameter gamma determines the labor demand elasticity to wages. See Section 4 for details.

Figure 4.

Figure 4

Model and Counterfactual (2/2)

Note: The full model is the simulation of the economy using the calibrated parameters. The restricted model simulates the same calibrated model, but restricting firms to keep their foreign temporary worker CS employment to its 1994 value. Wages are relative to other STEM occupations. Employment and enrollment are shares of STEM workers and undergrad STEM enrollment, respectively, and are multiplied by 100. The parameter gamma determines the labor demand elasticity to wages. See Section 4 for details.

The calibrated model allows us to calculate several additional economically meaningful statistics, which we also include in the bottom segment of Table 2. We calculate the long-run occupation and enrollment elasticities with respect to wages, by replacing the demand side of the model with an exogenous wage, which we set to be permanently 1% higher than its 1994 value, and in each case, we allow the supply side to come to a new equilibrium based on the calibrated parameters. We similarly calculate the short-run occupation and enrollment elasticities, but instead of allowing the supply side to come to a new steady-state, we calculate the elasticities based off of changes in occupation and enrollment after 1 year.

In the bottom section of Table 2, we show how each of these long-run elasticities varies with γ. The long-run occupational labor supply elasticity for Americans is around 5.4. The enrollment in CS is even more elastic, with a long-run elasticity that lies around 11.6.36 This result reflects the large enrollment response we witness in the data. The short-run occupation elasticity is much lower than the corresponding long-run elasticity. We expect this result, due to the supply frictions and lags in our model. In contrast, the short-run and long-run enrollment elasticities are almost exactly the same. Pre-enrollment students respond immediately to a wage shock. A fuller model which includes capacity constraints on the supply side of the higher education market, would work to slow such adjustments. Finally, the average cost of recruiting a foreign worker is about 0.53 times the average annual earnings of a non-CS STEM job.

In Figures 34, we report both the path predicted by our calibrated model (Full model) and the path observed in the data (Smooth data) during 1994–2009. Note that by the construction of our calibration procedure, the full model fits the data perfectly in 1994 and 2004. We use the transition period between 1995 to 2003 to evaluate how well the model fits the data, and the years 2005–2009 for out of sample prediction. These years include observed changes to relevant immigration laws, and potentially unobserved structural changes which would map to changes in our parameters, so our model has trouble fitting the data in this period for some series. Figure 3 shows that for different γ’s, the model is a fairly close fit for CS wages and American employment during the evaluation period, although CS wages in the model grow faster at first and American employment in CS grows more slowly in the model than the data. The fit of these two series is still relatively good in the out of sample prediction period, with wages slightly higher and American employment slightly lower in the model compared to the data.

Figure 4 shows that the enrollment output of the model is particularly sensitive to the choice of γ, where lower values somewhat under-predict the enrollment boom surrounding 2001. At odds with the predictions of our model, enrollment does not increase starting in 2006. Given the rising wages of computer scientists at the time, this pattern seems a bit surprising and we confess to not having a good understanding as to why enrollments do not seem to be responding to market signals. The figure also shows that foreign employment grows more slowly at first in the model than the data. In the out of sample period, foreign employment shrinks in the model instead of growing slightly, as in the data. This could be because our model assumes that after a 6-year period, foreigners return to their home country. In the Online Appendix, we calibrate a model that allows a certain fraction of H-1B workers to become permanent residents. This extension of the model does a better job of fitting the share of foreign employment in the last few years (and overall does a good job of fitting the different calibrated series).

4.3 Simulation of Fixed Foreign Worker Population Counterfactual

We use our calibrated model to simulate a counterfactual Internet boom from 1994–2004, as if firms had restrictions on the number of foreigners that they can hire. The exercise consists of hitting the calibrated model with the same technological shocks we derived before but imposing that firms cannot increase Ft above its 1994 level. The results of this simulation are also presented in Figures 34 (Restricted Model). There we can compare the counterfactual for different values of γ with the smoothed data.

Overall, our calibrated model implies an increase in the demand for domestic workers when firms cannot increase foreign employment above its 1994 level. As a result, we observe higher wages, US employment and computer science enrollment in the counterfactual economy. We simulate significant differences in the labor market for computer scientists during the Internet boom if firms had restrictions on the number of foreigners they could hire. While the data shows that the relative wages for CS workers increased by 3.2% between 1994 and 2004, in the simulated economy wages would have increased between 5.9% to 6.9% (decreasing with γ) during the same period. In terms of employment, we observe an increase of 41% of total CS employment during the Internet boom, while in the economy where we restrict foreign workers we find an increase of only 29.1% to 36.1% (decreasing with γ) during the same period. This change in employment results from the more inelastic labor supply curve that firms face when extra foreigners are not available.

In Table 3 we compare the 2004 levels of the variables of interest between the data and the simulated economy where firms could not increase foreign employment above its 1994 levels. We find that in 2004, CS workers wages would be 2.8% to 3.8% higher if firms had restrictions in the number of foreigners they could hire. Furthermore, the number of Americans working in the CS sector would be 7.0% to 13.6% higher in 2004, but the total employment level would be lower by 3.8% to 9.0%. Finally we find a significant difference in the number of students enrolling in computer science in the simulated counterfactual economy. Relative to other STEM fields, enrollment in CS would be 19.9% – 25.5% higher in 2004 if firms could not increase foreign employment during the Internet boom. These numbers reflect the fact that, according to our calibrations, students’ major choices are very sensitive to changes in wages.

Table 3.

Summary of Results from Counterfactual Simulation

% Differences between Simulated Economy Holding F Constant and Actual Outcomes in 2004
Variable γ
0.25 0.5 0.75
CS Wages 3.8% 3.2% 2.8%
CS US Native Employment 13.6% 12.5% 7.0%
CS Enrollment 25.5% 20.2% 19.9%
Total Employment −3.8% −4.6% −9.0%

Note: The counterfactual simulates an economy from 1994–2009 in which the level of foreign CS workers is not allowed to increase from its 1994 value. The parameter determines the labor demand elasticity to wages. See section 4 for details.

To sum up, even when assuming a very elastic labor demand curve (high γ values) we find significant effects of foreign recruitment on wages and employment of domestic CS workers during the Internet boom. Additionally, firms would not replace all foreigners with domestic workers during this period if they were restricted to keeping the same foreign employment level of 1994, implying that industry output would be reduced.

4.4 Identification of Labor Demand

As shown previously, the labor market outcomes of the counterfactual simulations holding Ft fixed can vary with values of γ. In particular, we observe that when using a more elastic labor demand (higher γ), our simulated counterfactual economy (where we restrict foreigner workers) from section 4.3 has smaller increases in wages and US employment. The natural question is which, if any, of the 3 different γ’s yields results that are closest to what we would observe if firms had not been able to recruit foreigners during the Internet boom?

In a closed, constant returns to scale economy, the elasticity of demand for computer scientists would depend on both the substitutability between consumption of goods produced in sectors of the economy intensive in computer scientists and other goods, and on the substitutability between production of computers scientists and other factors of production. Given the fact that the share of computer scientists working in any one sector is not large,37 the demand elasticity will be determined largely by the elasticity of substitution between computer scientists and other factors of production. In the relatively small window of time we are talking about, it is hard to believe these elasticities are that large.

There are two factors that mitigate this basic conclusion. First, to the extent that computer scientists contribute to innovation in the sectors of the economy intensive in computer scientist labor, the derived elasticity of demand for computer scientists in those sectors is likely to be higher than it would otherwise have been. In addition, the potential for off-shoring would drive up the derived elasticity of demand for computer scientists. However, even if, for these reasons, the derived demand for computer sciences in computer manufacturing and computer services was quite high, a small enough share of computer scientists work in these industries, that it is hard to believe either agglomeration effects or off-shoring can drive up the derived demand elasticity for computer scientists that much. Additionally, if it would have been easy for employers to outsource, CEOs like Microsoft’s Bill Gates would not have been lobbying to increase the H-1B visa cap. It is hard to reconcile the fact that the computer industry is lobbying so hard for easier access to foreigners, if it did not matter where their workforce was located.

Traditionally, exogenous shifts in supply are used to identify demand curves. In our case, while there is a plausibly exogenous component to the increased representation of the foreign born amongst the US Science and Engineering workforce, our visa system ensures that there is a large endogenous component. In theory, it might be possible to get some leverage on identifying the labor demand curve for CS workers by comparing the results of the counterfactual simulation for the different γ’s to the observations of what happened in the Information Technology (IT) sector in the the mid 1970s. Specifically, as described in Bound et al. (2013), during this earlier period, the IT sector experienced a significant transformation due to the introduction of the microprocessor, which generated an increase in the demand for IT workers. However, firms had substantially less access to foreign labor during that earlier boom than they did during the 1990s. This happened because there was a sharp increase in the supply of college graduates from overseas in the past decades, but also due to the change in the US visa system in the early 1990s that facilitated a greater inflow of high skilled foreigners via employer-sponsored visas.

Our strategy would be to use our calibrated model to simulate what would happen if firms had less access to foreign high-skilled labor in the 1990s boom and compare these simulations to the earlier boom. Comparisons between simulation results with different values of γ and what actually happened earlier would help narrow plausible values for γ. Intuitively, if demand is relatively elastic, the loss of access to foreigners would have relatively little impact on wages, but a large impact on total CS employment. Whereas a less elastic demand curve would have a large effect on wages and less of an effect on total CS employment. This kind of exercise is valid only under the strong assumptions that our economic model accurately reflects that labor market for IT workers, and that the demand and supply elasticities were the same during the two periods and that the two shocks generated shifts in the labor demand of roughly the same magnitude. However heroic such assumptions might be, the strategy fails for a simpler reason. The strategy requires comparing wage and employment changes for a small segment of the workforce across periods. Our estimates were simply not reliable enough for such exercises to be meaningful.

Given the data limitations and other complications discussed in this section, we cannot provide an estimate for the value of γ, but our discussion suggests that the elasticity of demand for computer scientists should not be too large and that the values presented in this paper cover a plausible range.

5 Discussion

The model we have developed in this paper suggests an intermediate position as the most reasonable one in the debate over the effects of high-skilled immigration, on US workers. Focusing on the tech boom of the 1990s, we develop a model that allows us to answer the counterfactual question: what would have happened to overall employment, to the employment of US residents, and to wages in the IT sector had the immigration of computer scientists been restricted to its level as of the early 1990s before the tech boom? Our results suggest a middle ground between the two sides of this debate.

First, our estimates suggest that even without foreign trained computer scientists, the supply of computer scientists to the US market is quite elastic, especially in the medium run, as the students induced to study computer science by the increased opportunities in the field begin to enter the market. For elasticities of demand that lie between −1.3 and −4.0, we show that had firms not been able to hire immigrants through the late 1990s, the wages of US trained computer scientists would have been 2.8% to 3.8% higher than they were, and there would have been 7% to 13.6% more Americans working as computer scientists.

At the same time our estimates suggest that were it not for the immigrant computer scientists that firms were able to hire, the growth in the number of computer scientists in the economy would have been significantly slowed. Our estimates suggest that total employment in the CS sector would have been 3.8–9% lower if firms were not able to hire additional immigrants during the late 1990s, thus implying that the fact that firms could hire immigrants during the 1990s increased output and lowered both input and output prices in the computer scientist intensive sectors of the economy. How much these developments benefited stock holders and consumers depends on the nature of the output market, which we have not tried to model. The increased employment of computer scientists would also have increased the demand for complementary production inputs, such as software marketing and sales workers. Furthermore, the availability of foreign CS workers made the CS labor supply curve more elastic, further enhancing this demand increase for complements.

Under the assumption that the tech boom of the 1990s exogenously increased the demand for computer scientists, we have been able to reliably estimate supply curves. Estimating the slope of the labor demand curve was substantially more difficult. In other contexts, labor economists have been willing to assume some degree of exogeneity to immigrant supplies. In the current framework, the institutional context implies that immigrant CS labor is completely endogenous to labor demand.

While we cannot reliably estimate the slope of the demand curve for computer scientists, we believe that we can reject any notion that the demand curve for computer scientists is close to perfectly elastic. Perfectly elastic demand curves are inconsistent with the rising wages for computer scientists that we observe during the 1990s. As long as the demand curve for computer scientists is downward sloping, the increased access employers had to foreign-trained, skilled immigrants during the 1990s works to lower both the wages and employment opportunities for US trained computer scientists.

Our paper should be viewed as a first-step towards modeling the US labor market for computer-scientists. In the model we incorporate features that were ignored in earlier models developed by Freeman (1976) and Ryoo & Rosen (2004). Specifically we model both the possibility that individuals might switch occupations, and the possibility that firms might hire immigrants from abroad. In the context of computer scientists both are clearly important. We focused on the market for computer scientists. In the context of other scientific fields where a masters or PhD are essential, it would also be important to model foreign participation in US graduate programs as well. Such an effort would need to model both the demand for and supply of higher education. While we believe that such an effort would be of considerable value, we leave it for future research.

Acknowledgments

We would like to acknowledge the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation for generous research support. Motivation and evidence for this analysis draws from work by Bound and Sarah Turner under the title “Pathways to Adjustment in Science and Engineering Labor Markets.” We would also like to thank Charlie Brown, Chris House, Peter Hudomiet, Bill Kerr, Pat Kline, Pawel Krolikowski, Paul Oyer, Isaac Sorkin, Sarah Turner, two anonymous referees and seminar participants at the University of Michigan and NBER for comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank Thomas Lemieux and Chris Bollinger for help identifying imputations in the Current Population Survey data we use.

Footnotes

1

In this discussion we are assuming that foreign trained computer scientists are close substitutes for domestically trained ones. If foreign and domestically trained computer scientists are imperfect substitutes for each other, then the impact that the increased immigration will have on domestically trained computer scientists will also depend on the degree of substitutability between computer scientists trained domestically and abroad.

2

These include the introduction of the World Wide Web, web browsers, and of search engines. During this time, Microsoft developed popular user-friendly operating systems, and Linux and other free and open-source software packages grew to power much of the Internet’s server infrastructure. Sun Microsystems introduced the Java programming language and various service providers made e-mail available to a wider base of consumers. These types of software innovation, along with steady, rapid improvements to computer hardware and reductions in its cost permanently changed the structure and nature of the industry.

3

The decommissioning of the National Science Foundation Network in April of 1995 is considered the milestone for introducing nationwide commercial traffic on the Internet. (Leiner et al. (1997)).

4

Here and elsewhere our tabulations restrict the analysis to workers with at least a bachelor degree and use the IPUMS suggested occupational crosswalk. Other STEM occupations are defined as engineers, mathematical and natural scientists.

5

It seems likely to us that wages increased as well for complementary jobs to computer scientists, such as marketing and sales staff at software companies. But we leave such spillovers for later research.

6

Here and elsewhere, we define foreigners as who immigrated to the US after the age of 18. We believe that this definition is a proxy for workers who arrived to the US with non-immigrant visa status.

7

The Immigration and Nationality Act of 1952 established the precursor to the H-1B visa, the H-1. The H-1 non-immigrant visa was targeted at aliens of “distinguished merit and ability” who were filling positions that were temporary. Nonimmigrants on H-1 visas had to maintain a foreign residence. The Immigration Act of 1990 established the main features of H-1B visa as it is known today, replacing “distinguished merit and ability” with the “specialty occupation” definition. It also dropped the foreign residence requirement and also added a dual intent provision, allowing workers to potentially transfer from an H-1B visa to immigrant status.

8

The 2000 legislation that raised the cap also excluded Universities and non-profit research facilities from it, and a 2004 change added an extra 20,000 visas for foreigners who received a masters degree in the US

9

If computer scientists have large effects on firm productivity, then demand curves for them would be very elastic. Alternatively, one could imagine that, absent the foreign computer scientists, production would shift overseas either because of domestic firms outsourcing production or because of Heckscher-Ohlin effects.

10

Here we are aggregating foreign students getting degrees in the US with their domestic counterparts. During the 1990s, foreigners represented a small (10%) share of new CS graduates each year (IPEDS completion survey).

11

Essentially, we are assuming that students decide their major after the end of their second year in school. This presumes that the relative pool of potential applicants would have sufficient background to potentially major in computer science. A four year time horizon is more standard. We experimented with such a horizon and doing so made little qualitative difference to our conclusions.

12

We are implicitly assuming that anyone who majors in computer science would have completed college even had they not majored in computer science and that computer science majors are infra marginal college finishers. A similar assumption was made by Ryoo and Rosen (2004) in their work on Engineers

13

The implications of the model will still hold if there is general human capital accumulation and individuals expect similar wage growth profiles working as computer scientists or in the alternative occupation.

14

As a matter of fact, in the simulations of the paper we will set wto=1 and measure wages of computer scientists as an occupational premium.

15

In the working decision problem, the independence assumption might be less plausible because taste shocks could be serially correlated. However, identifying parameters of the model with serially correlated errors is infeasible without longitudinal data (Kline (2008)).

16

In the simulation of the paper we set Mta to be constant for all ages and a=22a=65Mta=100. We measure employment of computer scientists as percentage points of the employed population of interest.

17

As it will become clear later, the reason why in our model foreigners do not swamp the U.S. labor markets is because firms must pay, in addition to prevailing wages, increasing recruitment costs to employ foreigners.

18

In fact, during the period we are studying roughly half of those on H-1B visas eventually became permanent residences. In our online appendix, we present a modification of the model that allows a constant fraction of H-1B visa holders to become permanent residents. Our results are consistent across modeling specifications.

19

The initial duration of the H-1B contract is 3 years, but it is extendable for an additional 3 years. Extensions do not count toward the H-1B cap, and are generally granted. As it will become clear in the labor demand side, in our model firms have incentive to keep foreigners for the maximum length of their contract.

20

The assumption that labor adjustment decisions are independent of capital is standard in the dynamic labor demand literature when data on capital stock is not available (Hamermesh (1989)). Including capital in the production function generally does not qualitatively change the results (Kline (2008)).

21

While we suspect is would make sense to allow workers of different ages to be imperfect substitutes in production for each other, CPS sample sized are too small to support this kind of analysis.

22

In our online appendix we set-up and calibrate a model where the quadratic cost term for hiring foreigners also applies to Americans. Our results are not sensitive to this modeling change.

23

For simplicity, we assume that firms and individuals have the same annual discount factor β. For expositional purposes, we now omit the the superscript c for wages and employment of computer scientists.

24

Our formulation implies the foreign share of new hires will rise as demand increases. There are alternative models that would imply something similar. For example, if firms had some local monopsony power, and if foreign labor were supplied elastically, firms would accommodate demand increases by shifting recruitment toward foreign labor so as to avoid paying increased wages associated with the increased hiring of US trained labor.

25

We model the technology progress as a close to random walk since we will interpret the Internet boom as a series of very persistent technological shocks that hit the information technology sector during the late 1990s. We also interpret the 2000 to 2004 to be a dot com bust. We found little evidence that workers, students or employers expected the increase in the demand for computer scientists during the 1990s to be temporary (and subject to a post-Y2K bug slump). First, the BLS projected a steady increase in CS employment after the year 2000, and claimed that it expected the top two fastest growing occupations to be computer scientists, and computer engineers respectively. Furthermore, there is a substantial increase in CS degrees started during the dot-com boom, indicating that students perceived the demand for computer scientists to be increasing permanently during the period. We therefore believe that a more realistic assumption is that agents perceived the increase in demand during the late 1990s to be permanent - and that the World Wide Web generated opportunities for new businesses that demanded computer scientists. However, at some period in the beginning of the year 2000, presumably for a variety of reasons, the boom turned around and NASDAQ crashed.

26

Note that both workers and firms are risk neutral in our model. For this reason, the certainty equivalence property holds and the solution of the model does not depend on higher moments of the idiosyncratic productivity shock.

27

In an Online Appendix we re-do all our results for different values of this parameter, and find that our results are not sensitive to the choice of this parameter.

28

Specifically, we estimate the wage premium for foreign born computer scientists who are naturalized or permanent residents, compared to US born CS workers. This estimation comes from a logarithmic of annual earnings regression controlling for gender and a cubic age polynomial. We interpret this wage premium as the average marginal productivity difference between foreign and US computer scientists.

29

Uses data from 1996 to 2006, representing enrollment decisions from 1994 to 2004. See the Online Appendix for more details.

30

We exclude imputed values of wages, and multiply top-coded values by a factor of 1.4. Bollinger & Hirsch (2007) show that not excluding imputations can lead to biased results. Whereas the top-coding adjustment is standard in the literature (Lemieux (2006)). See the Online Appendix for more details.

31

See the data appendix online for more information on occupational classifications. We smooth the raw data as follows: Xt,smooth=13(Xt-1,raw+Xt,raw+Xt+1,raw), except for the American and foreigner employment data in 1994, which citizenship information is unavailable prior to 1994 for which we use: X1994,smooth=23Xt,raw+13Xt+1,raw).

32

We also considered the alternative assumption that all agents fully or partially anticipated the future path of technological process. This assumption yields time paths for wages and employment that are quite similar to the ones we observe under our static expectations assumption. In contrast, with this alternative assumption, enrollment jumps almost immediately, which is inconsistent with the time path of enrollment we observe. At the same time, our counterfactual simulations presented later with the alternative anticipation assumption are similar to the ones we present with static expectations. Presumably a model that allowed expectations to evolve would be more realistic. However, given the robustness of our central results to the static versus foresight assumption, we did not explore such an alternative.

33

The decision to match changes in the age structure of CS rather then levels is to assure that our calibrated model reflects movements that occurred in the market for CS during the period rather than the age structure of the entire population.

34

Note that we have a perfectly identified system: we find the values of 9 independent parameters and 2 implied values of At such that the model matches 11 data observations: Lt, Ft, wt and pt-2c in two years and the observation of changes in st22,34,st35,44, and st45,65 in 2004.

35

γ in the 0.25 to 0.75 range imply labor demand elasticities between −1.33 and −4.0. Ryoo & Rosen (2004), estimate demand elasticities for engineers that lie between −1.2 and −2.2, while Borjas (2009), studying the effect the immigration of foreign born PhD scientists on the wages of competing workers, estimates demand elasticities of approximately −3.0. This do suggest that we have varied γ through a sensible range.

36

Ryoo and Rosen estimate substantially smaller enrollment elasticities of between 2.5 and 4.5, but are modeling the decision to enroll in a broader field than we are.

37

According to the Census, roughly 30% of computer scientists worked in either the computer manufacturing or the computer services three-digit industries during 1990 and 2000.

Contributor Information

John Bound, Email: jbound@umich.edu.

Breno Braga, Email: bgbraga@umich.edu.

Joseph M. Golden, Email: goldenjm@umich.edu.

Gaurav Khanna, Email: gkhanna@umich.edu.

References

  1. Arrow Kenneth J. The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing. The Review of Economic Studies. 1962;29(3):155–173. [Google Scholar]
  2. Bollinger Christopher, Hirsch Barry. How Well are Earnings Measured in the Current Population Survey? Bias from Nonresponse and Proxy respondents. North American Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society; Duke University; 2007. [Google Scholar]
  3. Borjas George. The Economic Analysis of Immigration. In: Ashenfelter Orley, Card David., editors. Handbook of Labor Economics. 3A. North-Holland; 1999. [Google Scholar]
  4. Borjas George. Immigration in High-Skill Labor Markets: The Impact of Foreign Students on the Earnings of Doctorates. In: Freeman Richard B, Goroff Daniel L., editors. Science and Engineering Careers in the United States: An Analysis of Markets and Employment. 2009. pp. 131–161. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bound John, Braga Breno, Golden Joseph, Turner Sarah. Pathways to Adjustment: The Case of Information Technology Workers. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 2013 [Google Scholar]
  6. Clemens Michael A. Why Do Programmers Earn More in Houston Than Hyderabad? Evidence from Randomized Processing of US Visas. American Economic Review, Papers & Proceedings. 2013;103(3):198–202. [Google Scholar]
  7. Collard Fabrice, Juillard Michel. A Higher-Order Taylor Expansion Approach to Simulation of Stochastic Forward-Looking Models with an Application to a Non-Linear Phillips Curve. Computational Economics. 2001a;17(2):125–139. [Google Scholar]
  8. Collard Fabrice, Juillard Michel. Accuracy of Stochastic Perturbation Methods: The Case of Asset Pricing Models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 2001b;25(7):979–999. [Google Scholar]
  9. Freeman Richard B. Supply and Salary Adjustments to the Changing Science Manpower Market: Physics, 1948–1973. American Economic Review. 1975;65(1):27–39. [Google Scholar]
  10. Freeman Richard B. A Cobweb Model of the Supply and Starting Salary of New Engineers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 1976;29(2):236–248. [Google Scholar]
  11. Freeman Richard B. Does Globalization of the Scientific/Engineering Workforce Threaten U.S. Economic Leadership? In: Jaffe Adam B, Lerner Josh, Stern Scott., editors. Innovation Policy and the Economy. Vol. 6. 2006. [Google Scholar]
  12. Freeman Richard B. Working Paper 14962. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2009. May, What Does Global Expansion of Higher Education Mean for the US? [Google Scholar]
  13. Hamermesh Daniel S. Labor Demand and the Structure of Adjustment Costs. The American Economic Review. 1989;79(4):674–689. [Google Scholar]
  14. Hunt Jennifer, Gauthier-Loiselle Marjolaine. How Much Does Immigration Boost Innovation? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 2010;2(2):31–56. [Google Scholar]
  15. Juillard Michel. DYNARE: A Program for the Resolution and Simulation of Dynamic Models with Forward Variables through the Use of a Relaxation Algorithm. CEPREMAP. 1996;9602 [Google Scholar]
  16. Kambourov Gueorgui, Manovskii Iourii. Occupational Specificity Of Human Capital. International Economic Review. 2009;50(1):63–115. [Google Scholar]
  17. Kerr Sari Pekkala, Kerr William R, Lincoln William F. Skilled Immigration and the Employment Structures of U.S. Firms. Working Paper 2013 [Google Scholar]
  18. Kerr William, Lincoln William. The Supply Side of Innovation: H-1B Visa Reforms and U.S. Ethnic Invention. Journal of Labor Economics. 2010;28(3):473–508. [Google Scholar]
  19. Kirkegaard Jacob. Working Paper no 05–15. Peterson Institute for International Economics; Washington, DC: 2005. Outsourcing and Skill Imports: Foreign High-Skilled Workers on H-1B and L-1 Visas in the United States. [Google Scholar]
  20. Kline Patrick. Understanding Sectoral Labor Market Dynamics: An Equilibrium Analysis of the Oil and Gas Field Services Industry. Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University; 2008. Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers 1645. [Google Scholar]
  21. Krugman Paul. A Model of Innovation, Technology Transfer, and the World Distribution of Income. Journal of Political Economy. 1979;87(2):253–266. [Google Scholar]
  22. Leiner Barry M, Cerf Vinton G, Clark David D, Kahn Robert E, Kleinrock Leonard, Lynch Daniel C, Postel Jon, Roberts Lawrence G, Wolff Stephen S. The past and future history of the Internet. Commun ACM. 1997;40(2):102–108. [Google Scholar]
  23. Lemieux Thomas. Increasing Residual Wage Inequality: Composition Effects, Noisy Data, or Rising Demand for Skill? The American Economic Review. 2006;96:461–498. [Google Scholar]
  24. Matloff Norman. On the Need for Reform of the H-1B Non-Immigrant Work Visa in Computer-Related Occupations. University of Michigan Journal of Law Reform. 2003;36(4):815–914. [Google Scholar]
  25. Mithas Sunil, Lucas Henry C. Are Foreign IT Workers Cheaper? U.S. Visa Policies and Compensation of Information Technology Professionals. Management Science. 2010;56(5):745–765. [Google Scholar]
  26. Mukhopadhyay Sankar, Oxborrow David. The Value of an Employment-Based Green Card. Demography. 2012;49:219–237. doi: 10.1007/s13524-011-0079-3. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  27. Nathan Max. IZA Working Papers. 2013. The Wider Economic Impacts of High-Skilled Migrants: A Survey of the Literature. Discussion Paper No. 7653. [Google Scholar]
  28. Peri Giovanni, Sparber Chad. Highly-Educated Immigrants and Native Occupational Choice. Industrial Relations. 2011;50(3):385–411. [Google Scholar]
  29. Peri Giovanni, Shih Kevin, Sparber Chad. STEM Workers, H1B Visas and Productivity in US Cities 2013 [Google Scholar]
  30. Romer Paul M. Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy. 1986;94(5):1002–1037. [Google Scholar]
  31. Rust John. Optimal Replacement of GMC Bus Engines: An Empirical Model of Harold Zurcher. Econometrica. 1987;55(5):999–1033. [Google Scholar]
  32. Ryoo Jaewoo, Rosen Sherwin. The Engineering Labor Market. Journal of Political Economy. 2004;112(S1):S110–S140. [Google Scholar]
  33. Sargent Thomas J. Estimation of Dynamic Labor Demand Schedules under Rational Expectations. Journal of Political Economy. 1978;86(6):1009–1044. [Google Scholar]
  34. Shapiro Matthew D. The Dynamic Demand for Capital and Labor. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1986;101(3):513–542. [Google Scholar]
  35. U.S. Department of Commerce. Digital Economy 2000. U.S. Department of Commerce; 2000. Tech. rept. [Google Scholar]
  36. U.S. General Accounting Office. Immigration and the Labor Market: Nonimmigrant Alien Workers in the United States. U.S. General Accounting Office; Washington, D.C: 1992. Tech. rept. GAO/PEMD-92-17. [Google Scholar]
  37. U.S. General Accounting Office. H-1B Foreign Workers: Better Controls Needed to Help Employers and Protect Workers. U.S. General Accounting Office; Washington, D.C: 2000. Tech. rept. GAO/HEHS 00-157. [Google Scholar]
  38. U.S. General Accounting Office. H-1B Visa Program: Reforms Are Needed to Minimize the Risks and Costs of Current Program. U.S. General Accounting Office; Washington, D.C: 2011. Tech. rept. GAO/HEHS 00-157. [Google Scholar]
  39. U.S. Immigration and Naturalization Service. Characteristics of Specialty Occupation Workers (H 1B) U.S. Immigration and Naturalization Service; Washington, D.C: 2000. Feb, Tech. rept. [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES