Susceptibility of global economic network to production loss has increased since the beginning of this century.
Keywords: Climate change, climate adaptation, climatic extremes, economics of climate change, costs of climate change, heat stress, econometrics, multi-regional input-output matrices
Abstract
Assessing global impacts of unexpected meteorological events in an increasingly connected world economy is important for estimating the costs of climate change. We show that since the beginning of the 21st century, the structural evolution of the global supply network has been such as to foster an increase of climate-related production losses. We compute first- and higher-order losses from heat stress–induced reductions in productivity under changing economic and climatic conditions between 1991 and 2011. Since 2001, the economic connectivity has augmented in such a way as to facilitate the cascading of production loss. The influence of this structural change has dominated over the effect of the comparably weak climate warming during this decade. Thus, particularly under future warming, the intensification of international trade has the potential to amplify climate losses if no adaptation measures are taken.
INTRODUCTION
An unabated increase of future greenhouse gas emissions will lead to a significant rise in global mean temperature (1) with severe impacts on natural and societal systems (2, 3). Several studies, as reviewed by Dell et al. (4), focusing on the economic implications of changing climatic conditions suggest that weather fluctuations influence agricultural (5) and industrial (6) output, and the health (7, 8) and energy (9) sectors, as well as exports of countries (10). They potentially amplify social conflicts (11, 12) and migration (13). Although physiological heat stress is influenced by a number of meteorological factors (14), it has been shown that labor productivity declines quasilinearly with temperature above a threshold that is estimated to be ≥25°C (15–22). Reductions in labor supply associated with temperature shocks are observed mainly but not exclusively (23, 24) in industries exposed to outdoor temperature, such as forestry, mining, and construction (25). In response to a global temperature rise, an increase in production losses due to heat stress can be expected if no adaptation measures are taken. At the same time, global market integration has increased economic linkages between countries. Production processes increasingly rely on (vertically integrated) supply chains spanning multiple countries and sectors (26, 27). In a globally connected economy, a production reduction due to heat stress is not necessarily locally confined but can evoke supraregional repercussions through both the supply and the demand sides (28–31). It might entail further production reductions along the supply chain. Consequently, climate-related losses may be influenced by the structural evolution of the global economic network, which is subject to numerous nonclimatic factors. Here, we focus on this structural change and analyze how it relates to the cascading of production loss throughout the supply network. By (production) loss, we refer to a reduction in output of regional sectors [measured in U.S. dollars (USD) at day level] that can be induced by either diminished labor productivity due to heat stress (first-order loss) or associated changes in demand and supply [higher-order loss; as defined in Okuyama and Chang (32)].
There is a large body of economic literature on international trade [as reviewed by Donaldson (33) and Costinot and Rodriguez (34)], and the theoretical proposition that there are substantial benefits from market integration is very fundamental (35). For instance, empirical analyses suggest that facilitated resource allocation in past decades has led to efficiency gains in the U.S. agriculture sector in the same order of magnitude as the rate of technological progress (36) and has enhanced savings in global water resources (37); yet, beneficial short-term effects of trade might come along with reduced societal resilience in the long term (38). Trade dependencies can render countries vulnerable to adverse events in other parts of the world (39, 40). For instance, it has been argued that global supply chains played a role in the 2009 global recession (41). Although, theoretically, trade has the potential to mediate the effects of supply shocks at comparably low costs (36, 42), restricting trade policies were often applied in the past to stabilize domestic supply at the expense of market supply (43–45). Particularly in the light of increasingly frequent and intense extreme weather under future warming (46), a better understanding of the complex interdependencies in the network of global supply chains is required. Here, we provide a structural analysis of the economic network with respect to production failures in response to heat stress.
RESULTS
As a probing case, we combine data on temperature, population, and the global economic network at day level for the years 1991–2011 and analyze the economic system’s susceptibility to heat stress–induced production losses and their propagation in each year. By susceptibility, we mean the magnitude of production losses that can potentially arise from heat stress throughout the network if only very basic response mechanisms and no economic adaptation are seized. These losses may be directly driven by the daily temperature (first order) or indirectly driven by the structure of economic dependencies within the network (higher order).
To this end, a population-weighted time series of daily mean temperature is computed for 186 countries using bias-corrected (47) observed temperature and population data on a 0.5° grid provided by the Inter-Sectoral Impact Model Intercomparison Project [ISI-MIP (48); see Methods for more information]. As a representation of the global supply network, multi-regional input-output tables (MRIOTs) for the years 1991–2011 provided by the Eora MRIO database (49) are used. They represent annually averaged monetary transactions between 26 industry sectors (and final demand) of these 186 countries (confer tables S1 and S2 as well as Methods for detailed information). The input and output flows are interpreted as links in a network of regional sectors and final demand (50). The sum of all output flows of a regional sector yields its daily production level.
Following a recent econometric study (16), the effect of temperature on labor supply is computed proportional to the daily temperature above 27°C. As suggested by the data, the production of the sectors of construction, agriculture and fishing, and mining and quarrying is reduced by a factor of 0.6, 0.8, and 4.2%, respectively, for each degree above this threshold (table S1). Exemplary time series for the South Korean construction and the Ecuadorian agriculture sector (fig. S1) show the shock-like daily heat stress forcing on the production. Here, the analysis is restricted to these sectors because of their potential to induce higher-order losses. Sectors with potential gain from warming are not considered. The resulting reductions in production levels (in USD) are denoted first-order losses due to heat stress. The perturbation is only applied in countries located in a belt between 30°N and 30°S around the equator (Fig. 1A and table S2) because the econometric study is restricted to tropical countries. The main conceptual result reported is altered by neither this specification nor the precise value of the temperature threshold (see fig. S2).
To estimate higher-order production losses associated with heat stress, that is, reduced production of other regional sectors due to supply and demand relations, the first-order production losses are propagated with the numerical model Acclimate (Fig. 1, B and C) (51, 52). The model attributes several basic economic features to all regional sectors in the network of economic flows and describes their dynamic interaction (see Methods for more detail). It propagates production losses from one regional sector to another through forward (supply shortages) and backward (demand reductions) linkages in the network. In case of supply shortages, the production of a regional sector is limited by the minimal relative availability of one input good across all input goods following the assumption of perfect complementarity; that is, if, for example, 10% of one input (and less of all other inputs) is missing, production is reduced by this factor. The loss propagation is buffered by the existence of storage, transport-induced time delay, and the possibility of demand redistribution.
The modeling framework used here purposefully differs from alternative approaches, such as static input-output (I-O) and computable general equilibrium (CGE) models, to capture the network-related economic response to perturbations on the same time scale as those occur. Static I-O and CGE models simulate the economic response to an exogenous shock at one specific point in time, and dynamic CGE models typically have coarse time steps of 1 to 10 years (53). By contrast, the dynamic framework applied here depicts the economic response at day level. This is central to the study because we do not analyze one major shock but small daily perturbations due to heat stress. Dynamic CGEs generally include an intertemporal optimization, thereby adapting a social planner’s perspective that implies that the representative agents in these models have strong spatial oversight and perfect temporal foresight. Accordingly, shocks can be anticipated, the welfare-optimizing path of the system is sorted out, and economic losses are mitigated more effectively compared to the situation of unexpected perturbations that is considered here (54). Another difference to most CGEs is the more heterogeneous representation of the global economic system. Such heterogeneity is also reflected in static I-O models, but they have been criticized for overestimating economic losses from shocks (31, 53). Because they assume a fixed production system, important mediating effects are ignored. Our approach attempts to find a middle ground in that it combines the heterogeneous perspective of I-O approaches with a more flexible economic system. The complex dynamics of loss propagation are modeled in a simplified framework that allows analyzing structural dependencies without neglecting some very basic buffering mechanisms such as storage, transport, and demand adjustments. The model Acclimate is designed in the spirit of an agent-based model with almost 5000 regional sectors as agents, which seek to regain their initial productivity as quickly as possible after a perturbation. They dynamically interact with their direct network neighbors to avoid production losses. However, these production losses are not expected by the regional sectors. After a perturbation, the model gradually strives back to its initial state as given by the data but is not constrained by the assumption of a general equilibrium of prices and quantities in each time step. Apart from CGEs, gravity and Ricardian models (55) are often applied in trade theory to investigate the gains of and barriers to market integration. They are also general equilibrium approaches and often focus on trade patterns between few (often just two) countries, whereas the approach presented here aims to analyze the economic system’s interaction at a global scale without the equilibrium assumption.
For each of the years 1991–2011, we compute the first-order production loss induced by heat stress, as described above. Then, we simulate the propagation of this loss with the numerical anomaly model Acclimate to account for higher-order losses throughout the network of economic flows.
The simulations indicate that total annual production losses from heat stress (that is, first- and higher-order losses in USD aggregated across sectors, regions, and days) are substantial and, in this century, increase with time (Fig. 2, A and B). A decomposition of total production loss shows that higher-order losses contribute significantly to the total loss (Fig. 2A). They vary in dependence on the size of storage, but even when very high storage capacities are assumed, higher-order losses arise (Fig. 2B). Above a saturation value, an increase in storage size does not considerably diminish higher-order losses. The results then become independent of the storage size. All analyses in this study use a storage size of 15 days well within the saturation range (as in Fig. 2A). In this case, higher-order losses are between 12 and 24% of the first-order losses (Fig. 2C).
We find that total annual production losses increase between 1991 and 2011. This trend is not as pronounced in the 1990s but becomes apparent from 2001 on. As a measure for this trend, but not to be taken as quantification of actual economic climate damages, the production loss value increases almost by an order of magnitude, that is, between 10 and 60 billion USD per year (Fig. 2A).
Because the temperature time series does not show a corresponding trend in the first decade of the 21st century (fig. S3), this difference is not climate-driven. Furthermore, it cannot solely be explained by economic growth because it is also seen in relative production losses, that is, total production losses per year as a share of the global annual production level (Fig. 3A). Relative losses grow quasilinearly with the simulation year during this decade. Moreover, the contribution of higher-order losses to the total loss rises over time, whereas the contribution of first-order losses declines (fig. S4 and Fig. 2C). Consequently, the economic structure present in the different years that are underlying the simulations dominates the system’s susceptibility to heat stress–induced production loss, and the recent evolution of the economic network has been such as to facilitate the propagation of losses; that is, the dynamic susceptibility is due to the static structure of the network.
To describe and analyze this relationship, a static network measure, the Supply Propagation Connectivity (SPC), is introduced. SPC is a globally and annually averaged network measure that determines the economic connectivity in terms of the dependence of production in different countries on supplies from other countries (see Methods for definition and Fig. 4 for a conceptual illustration). This static network measure correlates with the relative production losses caused by unexpected heat stress events in the respective years (Fig. 3B). It represents a change in the network structure that results in an increase in the economic system’s susceptibility to production loss in the 1991–2011 period and particularly during the years 2001–2011 (see Fig. 5 for an illustration).
This correlation is nontrivial especially because the SPC measure is a global average of all regional SPC values (see Methods for detail). Its value can change over time either because the number of nonzero regional SPC values is changing or because the existing regional SPC values vary. The first effect is given by the link density of the supply network measured by the number of links over the number of possible links. This density has been steadily grown over the first decade of this century (50) and is dominating the change in the network’s SPC (Fig. 6A). A smaller part of the change in global SPC is explained by quantitative changes in the strength of existing dependencies (Fig. 6B). The log-log frequency distribution of regional SPC values is shifted toward higher values over time, as represented by the mean (fig. S5), indicating that existing dependencies on supply from tropical countries have become larger.
DISCUSSION
The regional SPC is a ratio representing the dependence of production in one country on supplies from another country, which, in this study, is particularly a tropical one. We find that the global average of this ratio is a good predictor for global economic losses due to unexpected climatic events if no economic adaptation occurs, as what can be expected on the fast daily time scale considered here. This qualitative result is unlikely to depend on the specific representation of loss propagation within the model Acclimate because the characteristics of the propagation dynamics that are necessary for our results are very fundamental; that is, any other model of production loss propagation along the supply network is likely to show the same dependence on the network structure. Here, we find that global SPC was stagnant during the last decade of the previous century and that it steadily increased in the first decade of this century. We further find that this was mainly due to an increase in the number of network links. Whereas the losses found here are small in absolute terms, the increase that we find in the first decade of the century is significant. This suggests that the current evolution of the supply network might facilitate the propagation of climate-induced production losses.
As a thought experiment, we compute heat stress–induced production losses for a future scenario of unmitigated climate change without economic adaptation. To this end, we use economic data and population distribution for a fixed year between 1991 and 2011 (which we refer to as economic base year) and combine it with a time series of daily temperature data corresponding to the strongest warming scenario [Representative Concentration Pathway (RCP) 8.5 (56); see Methods for detail]. Total and relative annual production losses until 2100 vary again by an order of magnitude for the different economic base years (fig. S6). Although the specific values of the time series cannot be considered projections because they assume a fixed economic network without adaptation, the sensitivity of the losses to the economic structure is a robust feature of the simulations. It is thus likely that in a warming world, future changes in the complex global supply network will be a major factor in the evolution of the costs of climate change.
METHODS
Data
For this study, daily mean temperature data on a horizontal grid of 0.5° × 0.5° resolution from the ISI-MIP (48) climate data set were combined with coherent socioeconomic scenarios defined by population and economic data for the years 1991–2011.
Temperature data
For the analysis of the 1991–2011 period, we take data from the WFDEI (WATCH-Forcing-Data-ERA-Interim) meteorological forcing data set (57), where the WATCH Forcing Data methodology was applied to the ERA-Interim reanalysis data (58). Projections correspond to RCP 8.5 (56). They build on data by the Princeton Earth System Model of the Geophysical Fluid Dynamics Laboratory [GFDL-ESM2M (59)] of the Coupled Model Intercomparison Project Phase 5 [CMIP-5 (60)]. The application of a bias correction technique (47) ensures statistical agreement with historical observations of the WATCH database.
Population data
Population data on a 0.5° grid for the years 1991–2011 were also taken from the ISI-MIP data set. Population projections (from 2010 on) correspond to the second Shared Socioeconomic Pathway (61), and the historical information is derived from the United Nations World Population Prospects (UNWPP) national estimates.
Economic data
The economic network was constructed using data from the Eora26 World MRIO data set (49) covering annual monetary transactions between 26 industry sectors and final demand in 186 countries. For our computations, we used the MRIOTs in basic prices for the years 1991–2011 (version 199.324). Because small flows are more likely to be subjected to large balancing adjustments in the MRIOT generating process (62), each flow that contributed less than 1.6 × 10−6% (in the order of 106 USD in 2001) to the global annual flow volume was neglected in the computation. Results reported in this study became even more pronounced for a fixed cutoff value of 106 USD for all simulation years (fig. S2C). For our simulation time step of one day, we divided the annual data by 365 to yield the average daily transactions.
Population-weighted temperature time series per country
For each country covered by the Eora World MRIO, a population-weighted time series of daily mean temperature was computed. To this end, a country mask provided by the Global Administrative Areas initiative (www.gadm.org/country) assigning grid cells to countries was used. Very small tropical countries were not captured by the mask. Given their comparably small contribution to the global production level, they were not considered in our analysis.
Model Acclimate
The model Acclimate is detailed in the Supplementary Materials as well as in extensive description papers (51, 52). It builds on a network representation of the global supply network based on input-output matrices (49). The nodes in this network are production and consumption sites that are connected through input and, in case of a production site, output flows (in USD per day). The dynamics occur through decisions by these sites to avoid production losses. The model thereby operates on discrete time steps of 1-day length. It accounts for storage capacities and geographically derived transportation times. Production sites produce in accordance with the availability of inputs, the demand requests they receive, and, possibly, external perturbations (for example, as induced by meteorological events). They distribute their output among several customers and request inputs from different suppliers in dependence on their current storage level and under consideration of the recent reliability of each supplier. Inputs can either be immediately processed or be stored for later production. Production is limited by the assumption of perfect complementarity, that is, if one input is lacking by a certain percentage, the entire production is reduced by the same factor. The model adopts a Leontief production function with fixed coefficients and without substitution elasticities. The economic state, given by the annual data, serves as a baseline for the model. Its evolution over time is not modeled. Instead, the model simulates the response to an external perturbation (for example, heat stress) after which it strives back to this initial state. The external forcing is modeled as a production reduction that may be passed on from one production site to another through forward and backward linkages in the economic network. In the case of forward loss propagation, production sites experience a lack of inputs. They receive less demand requests in the case of backward loss propagation. Production sites cannot anticipate a perturbation, but respond to supply shortages or demand reductions by reverting to stored inputs by redirecting their demand to unaffected suppliers and by readjusting their production capacity. For this study, we used the following model setup: we assume that there are enough storage capacities to maintain production for 15 days without input (we also compare scenarios where storages can last for 3 to 15 days, respectively). This initial storage capacity can be surpassed by a factor of 2. If the storage level diminishes, demand is adjusted to regain half of the initial storage level within 5 days. Varying demand shares are requested from different suppliers with the aim of receiving inputs as fast as possible. Herein, past performances of suppliers, in decreasing shares, are taken into account, whereas no market forces are considered. The initial production capacity cannot be enhanced, and the network is not allowed to restructure. Although the model cannot claim to precisely depict real-world supply and demand dynamics, it represents the basic propagation of the effect of production reduction along the supply chains as required for this study.
Network measure SPC
SPC measures dependencies in the network of economic flows. It can be computed at different scales, that is, for production sites, regions, and the global network as a whole. In the context of this study, we primarily consider the global SPC value with respect to supplies from tropical countries. On the level of production sites, SPC is computed for each economic flow Zir → js from the input-output tables and expresses how dependent a production site j ∈ {1, …, NI} in an arbitrary region s ∈ {1, …, NR} is on supplies from any other production site i in a tropical region
where denotes the number of tropical regions, NR is the number of all regions, and NI is the number of sectors. It is thereby an upper limit of the dependency mainly because it assumes that the supply is not compensated by enhanced productivity of other production sites and because it postulates perfect complementarity of the production process. On the regional level, SPC describes how dependent an arbitrary region s is on direct supplies from a tropical country r. It is computed by weighing the maximal sectoral impact r imposes on each sector j it supplies in region s by the ratio to which this production site contributes to the overall production of region s and by summing up over all production sites j in region s
At the global scale, SPC is given by the mean of all regional SPC values
It describes the general economic connectivity of the network in terms of production dependencies on supplies from tropical countries.
Supplementary Material
Acknowledgments
We are grateful to S. Willner and C. Otto for their comments on the manuscript and their collaboration in the development of the model Acclimate. Map figures have been made using https://github.com/swillner/colour-map. We thank S. Hsiang for the very valuable input. Funding: This work was funded by the German Environmental Foundation and the European Union Seventh Framework Program FP7/2007-2013 under grant agreement no. 603864. The publication of this article was funded by the Open Access fund of the Leibniz Association. Author contributions: L.W. and A.L. designed the study and analyzed the results. L.W. conducted the analysis and led the writing of the paper. Competing interests: The authors declare that they have no competing interests. Data and materials availability: All data needed to evaluate the conclusions in the paper are present in the paper and/or the Supplementary Materials. Additional data related to this paper may be requested from the authors.
SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIALS
REFERENCES AND NOTES
- 1.T. F. Stocker, D. Qin, G.-K. Plattner, M. Tignor, S.K. Allen, J. Boschung, A. Nauels, Y. Xia, V. Bex, P.M. Midgley, IPCC, 2013: Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, 2013), 1535 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 2.O. Edenhofer, R. Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, IPCC, 2014: Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Working Group III Contribution to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, 2014), 1086 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 3.C. B. Field, V. R. Barros, D. J. Dokken, K. J. Mach, M. D. Mastrandrea, T. E. Bilir, M. Chatterjee, K. L. Ebi, Y. O. Estrada, R. C. Genova, B. Girma, E. S. Kissel, A. N. Levy, S. MacCracken, P. R. Mastrandrea, L. L.White, IPCC, 2014: Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, 2014), pp. 1–32. [Google Scholar]
- 4.Dell M., Jones B. F., Olken B. A., What do we learn from the weather? The new climate-economy literature. J. Econ. Lit. 52, 740–798 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 5.Lobell D. B., Schlenker W., Costa-Roberts J., Climate trends and global crop production since 1980. Science 333, 616–620 (2011). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Dell M., Jones B. F., Olken B. A., Temperature shocks and economic growth: Evidence from the last half century. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 4, 66–95 (2012). [Google Scholar]
- 7.Patz J. A., Campbell-Lendrum D., Holloway T., Foley J. A., Impact of regional climate change on human health. Nature 438, 310–317 (2005). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Bosello F., Roson R., Tol R. S. J., Economy-wide estimates of the implications of climate change: Human health. Ecol. Econ. 58, 579–591 (2006). [Google Scholar]
- 9.Auffhammer M., Mansur E. T., Measuring climatic impacts on energy consumption: A review of the empirical literature. Energy Econ. 46, 522–530 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 10.B. F. Jones, B. A. Olken, Climate Shocks and Exports (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2010), vol. 100, pp. 454–459. [Google Scholar]
- 11.Hsiang S. M., Burke M., Miguel E., Quantifying the influence of climate on human conflict. Science 341, 1235367 (2013). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Burke M. B., Miguel E., Satyanath S., Dykema J. A., Lobell D. B., Warming increases the risk of civil war in Africa. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 106, 20670–20674 (2009). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 13.McLeman R., Smit B., Migration as an adaptation to climate change. Clim. Change 76, 31–53 (2006). [Google Scholar]
- 14.Budd G. M., Wet-bulb globe temperature (WBGT)—Its history and its limitations. J. Sci. Med. Sport 11, 20–32 (2008). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Wyndham C. H., Adaptation to heat and cold. Environ. Res. 2, 442–469 (1969). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 16.Hsiang S. M., Temperatures and cyclones strongly associated with economic production in the Caribbean and Central America. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 107, 15367–15372 (2010). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Dell M., Jones B. F., Olken B. A., Temperature and income: Reconciling new cross-sectional and panel estimates. Am. Econ. Rev. 99, 198–204 (2009). [Google Scholar]
- 18.T. Deryugina, S. M. Hsiang, Does the Environment Still Matter? Daily Temperature and Income in the United States (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2014). [Google Scholar]
- 19.Ramsey J. D., Task performance in heat: A review. Ergonomics 38, 154–165 (1995). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 20.O. Seppanen, W. J. Fisk, D. Faulkner, Control of Temperature for Health and Productivity in Offices (Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, Berkeley, CA, 2004). [Google Scholar]
- 21.Pilcher J. J., Nadler E., Busch C., Effects of hot and cold temperature exposure on performance: A meta-analytic review. Ergonomics 45, 682–698 (2002). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Burke M., Hsiang S. M., Miguel E., Global non-linear effect of temperature on economic production. Nature 527, 235–239 (2015). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23.G. P. Cachon, S. Gallino, M. Olivares, Severe Weather and Automobile Assembly Productivity (Columbia Business School Research Paper, New York, NY, 2012), 31 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 24.J. S. G. Zivin, S. M. Hsiang, M. J. Neidell, Temperature and Human Capital in the Short- and Long-Run (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2015), 42 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 25.Zivin J. G., Neidell M., Temperature and the allocation of time: Implications for climate change. J. Labor Econ. 32, 1–26 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 26.Costinot A., Vogel J., Wang S., An elementary theory of global supply chains. Rev. Econ. Stud. 80, 109–144 (2012). [Google Scholar]
- 27.Hummels D., Ishii J., Yi K.-M., The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. J. Int. Econ. 54, 75–96 (2001). [Google Scholar]
- 28.Kousky C., Informing climate adaptation: A review of the economic costs of natural disasters. Energy Econ. 46, 576–592 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 29.van der Veen A., Disasters and economic damage: Macro, meso and micro approaches. Disaster Prev. Manag. 13, 274–279 (2004). [Google Scholar]
- 30.Christopher M., Peck H., Building the resilient supply chain. Int. J. Logist. Manag. 15, 1–14 (2004). [Google Scholar]
- 31.Okuyama Y., Santos J. R., Disaster impact and input–output analysis. Econ. Syst. Res. 26, 1–12 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 32.Y. Okuyama, S. E. Chang, Modeling Spatial and Economic Impacts of Disasters (Springer, Berlin Heidelberg, 2004), 323 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 33.Donaldson D., The gains from market integration. Annu. Rev. Econ. 7, 619–647 (2015). [Google Scholar]
- 34.A. Costinot, A. Rodríguez-Clare, Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2013), 67 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 35.Samuelson P. A., The gains from international trade once again. Econ. J. 72, 820–829 (1962). [Google Scholar]
- 36.A. Costinot, D. Donaldson, C. B. Smith, Evolving Comparative Advantage and the Impact of Climate Change in Agricultural Markets: Evidence from 1.7 Million Fields around the World (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2014), 45 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 37.Dalin C., Konar M., Hanasaki N., Rinaldo A., Rodriguez-Iturbe I., Evolution of the global virtual water trade network. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 109, 5989–5994 (2012). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 38.D’Odorico P., Laio F., Ridolfi L., Does globalization of water reduce societal resilience to drought? Geophys. Res. Lett. 37, L13403 (2010). [Google Scholar]
- 39.di Giovanni J., Levchenko A. A., Trade openness and volatility. Rev. Econ. Stat. 91, 558–585 (2009). [Google Scholar]
- 40.d’Amour C. Bren, Wenz L., Kalkuhl M., Steckel J. C., Creutzig F., Teleconnected food supply shocks. Environ. Res. Lett. 11, 35007 (2016). [Google Scholar]
- 41.J. Eaton, S. Kortum, B. Neiman, J. Romalis, Trade and the Global Recession (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2011), 51 pp. [Google Scholar]
- 42.Burgess R., Donaldson D., Can openness mitigate the effects of weather shocks? Evidence from India’s famine era. Am. Econ. Rev. 100, 449–453 (2010). [Google Scholar]
- 43.Fellmann T., Hélaine S., Nekhay O., Harvest failures, temporary export restrictions and global food security: The example of limited grain exports from Russia, Ukraine and Kazakhstan. Food Secur. 6, 727–742 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 44.Martin W., Anderson K., Export restrictions and price insulation during commodity price booms. Am. J. Agr. Econ. 94, 422–427 (2012). [Google Scholar]
- 45.Jensen H. G., Anderson K., Grain price spikes and beggar-thy-neighbor policy responses: A global economywide analysis. World Bank Econ. Rev. 10.1093/wber/lhv047 10.1093/wber/lhv047 (2015). [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 46.Rahmstorf S., Coumou D., Increase of extreme events in a warming world. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 108, 17905–17909 (2011). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 47.Hempel S., Frieler K., Warszawski L., Schewe J., Piontek F., A trend-preserving bias correction—The ISI-MIP approach. Earth Syst. Dynam. 4, 219–236 (2013). [Google Scholar]
- 48.Frieler K., Levermann A., Elliott J., Heinke J., Arneth A., Bierkens M. F. P., Ciais P., Clark D. B., Deryng D., Döll P., Falloon P., Fekete B., Folberth C., Friend A. D., Gellhorn C., Gosling S. N., Haddeland I., Khabarov N., Lomas M., Masaki Y., Nishina K., Neumann K., Oki T., Pavlick R., Ruane A. C., Schmid E., Schmitz C., Stacke T., Stehfest E., Tang Q., Wisser D., Huber V., Piontek F., Warszawski L., Schewe J., Lotze-Campen H., Schellnhuber H. J., A framework for the cross-sectoral integration of multi-model impact projections: Land use decisions under climate impacts uncertainties. Earth Syst. Dynam. 6, 447–460 (2015). [Google Scholar]
- 49.Lenzen M., Kanemoto K., Moran D., Geschke A., Mapping the structure of the world economy. Environ. Sci. Technol. 46, 8374–8381 (2012). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 50.Maluck J., Donner R. V., A network of networks perspective on global trade. PLOS One 10, e0133310 (2015). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 51.Bierkandt R., Wenz L., Willner S. N., Levermann A., Acclimate—A model for economic damage propagation. Part 1: Basic formulation of damage transfer within a global supply network and damage conserving dynamics. Environ. Syst. Decis. 34, 507–524 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 52.Wenz L., Willner S. N., Bierkandt R., Levermann A., Acclimate—A model for economic damage propagation. Part II: A dynamic formulation of the backward effects of disaster-induced production failures in the global supply network. Environ. Syst. Decis. 34, 525–539 (2014). [Google Scholar]
- 53.Hallegatte S., Modeling the role of inventories and heterogeneity in the assessment of the economic costs of natural disasters. Risk Anal. 34, 152–167 (2014). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 54.Farmer J. D., Hepburn C., Mealy P., Teytelboym A., A third wave in the economics of climate change. Environ. Resour. Econ. 62, 329–357 (2015). [Google Scholar]
- 55.Eaton J., Kortum S., Technology, geography, and trade. Econometrica 70, 1741–1779 (2002). [Google Scholar]
- 56.van Vuuren D. P., Edmonds J., Kainuma M., Riahi K., Thomson A., Hibbard K., Hurtt G. C., Kram T., Krey V., Lamarque J.-F., Masui T., Meinshausen M., Nakicenovic N., Smith S. J., Rose S. K., The representative concentration pathways: An overview. Clim. Change 109, 5–31 (2011). [Google Scholar]
- 57.Weedon G. P., Gomes S., Viterbo P., Shuttleworth W. J., Blyth E., Österle H., Adam J. C., Bellouin N., Boucher O., Best M., Creation of the WATCH forcing data and its use to assess global and regional reference crop evaporation over land during the twentieth century. J. Hydrometeorol. 12, 823–848 (2011). [Google Scholar]
- 58.Dee D. P., Uppala S. M., Simmons A. J., Berrisford P., Poli P., Kobayashi S., Andrae U., Balmaseda M. A., Balsamo G., Bauer P., Bechtold P., Beljaars A. C. M., van de Berg L., Bidlot J., Bormann N., Delsol C., Dragani R., Fuentes M., Geer A. J., Haimberger L., Healy S. B., Hersbach H., Hólm E. V., Isaksen L., Kållberg P., Köhler M., Matricardi M., McNally A. P., Monge-Sanz B. M., Morcrette J.-J., Park B.-K., Peubey C., de Rosnay P., Tavolato C., Thépaut J.-N., Vitart F., The ERA-Interim reanalysis: Configuration and performance of the data assimilation system. Q. J. Roy. Meteorol. Soc. 137, 553–597 (2011). [Google Scholar]
- 59.Dunne J. P., John J. G., Adcroft A. J., Griffies S. M., Hallberg R. W., Shevliakova E., Stouffer R. J., Cooke W., Dunne K. A., Harrison M. J., Krasting J. P., Malyshev S. L., Milly P. C. D., Phillipps P. J., Sentman L. T., Samuels B. L., Spelman M. J., Winton M., Wittenberg A. T., Zadeh N., GFDL’s ESM2 global coupled climate–carbon earth system models. Part I: Physical formulation and baseline simulation characteristics. J. Climate 25, 6646–6665 (2012). [Google Scholar]
- 60.Taylor K. E., Stouffer R. J., Meehl G. A., An overview of CMIP5 and the experiment design. Bull. Am. Meteorol. Soc. 93, 485–498 (2012). [Google Scholar]
- 61.Moss R. H., Edmonds J. A., Hibbard K. A., Manning M. R., Rose S. K., van Vuuren D. P., Carter T. R., Emori S., Kainuma M., Kram T., Meehl G. A., Mitchell J. F. B., Nakicenovic N., Riahi K., Smith S. J., Stouffer R. J., Thomson A. M., Weyant J. P., Wilbanks T. J., The next generation of scenarios for climate change research and assessment. Nature 463, 747–756 (2010). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 62.Lenzen M., Moran D., Kanemoto K., Geschke A., Building Eora: A global multi-region input–output database at high country and sector resolution. Econ. Syst. Res. 25, 20–49 (2013). [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.