Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2016 Nov 21.
Published in final edited form as: J Benefit Cost Anal. 2015 Dec 29;6(3):628–653. doi: 10.1017/bca.2015.54

Using Benefit-Cost Analysis to Scale Up Early Childhood Programs through Pay-for-Success Financing

Judy A Temple 1, Arthur J Reynolds 1,1
PMCID: PMC5116808  NIHMSID: NIHMS810119  PMID: 27882288

Abstract

Increasing access to high-quality preschool programs is a high priority at local, state, and federal levels. Recently, two initiatives to expand preschool programming in Illinois and Utah have used funds from private investors to scale up existing programs. Private-sector social impact investors provide funding to nonprofit or public preschool providers to increase the number of children served. If the measured outcomes from preschool participation meet pre-determined goals, then the estimated government cost savings arising from these preschool interventions are used to repay the investors. Social impact investing with a “Pay for Success” contract can help budget-constrained governments expand proven or promising preventive interventions without the need to increase taxes. Cost-benefit analysis plays a crucial role in helping to identify which social, educational or health interventions are suitable for this type of innovative financing. Cost-benefit analysts are needed to design the structure of the success payments that the government will make to the private investors. This paper describes social impact borrowing as a new method for financing public services, outlines the contribution of cost-benefit analysis, and discusses the innovative use of social impact financing to promote scaling up of the evidence-based Child Parent Centers and other early childhood programs.


The method of cost-benefit analysis (CBA) has been used to study the effectiveness of preschool programs and other early childhood interventions. These results have been widely reported in the academic literature. Findings from several notable longitudinal studies that have followed children into adulthood have demonstrated that benefits of high-quality well-targeted preschool programs far exceed costs, often by a factor of 7 or even 10 (Belfield et al., 2006; Temple and Reynolds, 2007; Barnett and Masse, 2007). Economists have estimated the internal rates of return of these programs to be between 5% and 18% (Heckman et al. 2010; Reynolds et al. 2011b).

Combined with academic interest in James Heckman’s (2006) theoretical work on skill formation and a growing awareness from neuroscience about the importance of early environments, the high rates of return from CBAs of early childhood programs have been cited as rationale for actual or proposed spending increases for public preschool programs over the last decade or more at all levels of government (e.g., Mervis, 2011; White House, 2013; Council of Economic Advisors, 2014) and have contributed to policy development and program expansion. Currently, 40 states offer state-funded preschool serving 1.4 million children at an annual cost of $5.6 billion. Combined with Head Start, 42% of 4-year-olds now attend public programs (Barnett et al., 2015). Early childhood programs offered on a broader scale including Head Start and some state-funded universal preschool programs have been subjected to cost-benefit analysis with studies also suggesting that the benefits may exceed costs but by a smaller margin (Kline and Walters, 2015; Bartik et al., 2012; Ludwig and Phillips, 2007). These findings are supported by extensive longitudinal studies since the 1960s showing that early gains in school readiness and achievement translate to enhanced adult well-being (Campbell et al., 2002; Consortium for Longitudinal Studies, 1983; Reynolds et al., 2001; Schweinhart et al., 2005).

As a systematic approach to evaluating the benefits and costs of a program or policy with a focus on promoting efficiency in resource allocation, CBA can be undertaken from various perspectives depending on which stakeholders preferences are assumed to matter. The standard approach to conducting a cost-benefit analysis is to use the societal perspective to assess benefits and costs. Discussion of the use of CBA in social policy and early childhood programs more specifically can be found in Vining and Weimer (2010) and Karoly (2012). The societal perspective of early childhood programs involves making a careful accounting of all benefits and costs including those to participants and to the public at large. Disaggregating the various components of benefits allows the analyst to identify which benefits accrue to the participant (and his or her family) and which benefits accrue to the rest of society including the various levels of government. Importantly, the existence of these public or spillover benefits to non-participants that can be quantified in cost-benefit analysis helps motivate the economic rationale for government involvement in this program area. Karoly et al. (1998, 2005) offer a detailed assessment of several well-studied early interventions separating out the private benefits to the participant and the participant’s family and well as providing separate reports of the governmental benefits realized by taxpayers. A close focus on identifying benefits accruing specifically to the taxpayer is part of the guardian approach as described by Boardman et al. (2011). From the perspective of the taxpayer or government sector, what matters is the effects of an intervention or policy on government expenditures and tax revenues.

Scaling Through Pay for Success Financing

Beginning in 2011, a number of state and local governments in the U.S. have been using the results of cost-benefit analyses as the foundation for a new type of private-public partnership that uses private investments to expand cost-effective public services. Social impact bonds, also called “Pay for Success” (PFS) or human capital bonds, are a new innovative financing mechanism that allows for state and local governments to expand cost-effective social services (Liebman and Sellman, 2013). The specific goal of Pay for Success is to expand an existing program for which political or economic barriers are perceived prevent the direct raising of additional tax revenues. The private sector funds the service expansion but the government only repays the investors if desired outcomes are achieved. Importantly, the desired outcomes are defined based on the expected government cost savings. The only benefits considered are government cost savings arising from the successful preventive interventions that lead to a reduction in need for later public spending to address problems that occur later on. Higher tax revenues resulting from higher private earnings may also be considered as a benefit. Social impact borrowing is based entirely on the governmental or guardian perspective in cost-benefit analysis. Under this perspective, benefits to participants and to non-participants other than taxpayers are not considered.

This paper highlights the crucial role of CBA in motivating this innovative financing mechanism and specifically examines the use PFS to expand public or nonprofit services for preschool education. We summarize the contributions of PFS as an example of social impact investing in expanding programs with a focus on the Child-Parent Center (CPC) education program currently being scaled in the Chicago and other Midwest cities. Strengths and limitations of PFS financing are described, including the use of single metrics such as special education to define success. Future directions are offered for the role of evaluation and CBA in social impact investing.

CBA principles and methods are well established in federal policy making. Executive Order 12866 (White House, 1993), which was reaffirmed in 2011, called for regulatory review in federal agencies that emphasize analysis of costs and benefits for interpreting laws and improving health and well-being. The Office of Management and Budget (OMB) requires the use of CBA in the annual budget review of individual agencies (OMB, 2008). In 2014, the President’s Council of Economic Advisors (CEA) released an analysis highlighting the economic returns of early education programs as part of the White House Conference on Early Childhood Development (CEA, 2014). Based on the increased influence of CBA perspectives, federal funding for Pay for Success initiatives began in 2012 for projects in the Departments of Labor and Justice. More recently other departments including Education, Housing and Urban Development, and the Treasury have become involved (Greenblatt and Donovan, 2013).

While the benefits of high-quality preschool education targeted towards disadvantaged children are multi-faceted and may extend for decades, proponents of social impact borrowing typically seek to identify projects in which all or most of the government cost savings exceed program costs within a fairly short time window of anywhere between two to a dozen years. Recent reports suggest that some preschool programs may generate significant early cost savings due to reductions in special education placement rates. These findings have motivated both of the U.S. preschool Pay for Success initiatives currently in operation.

Historically, CBA adopts a societal perspective to valuing benefits, which places a premium on estimating all benefits of a social program (Boardman et al., 2011). In contrast, social impact financing initiatives with a Pay for Success contract are more narrowly focused on government savings for a particular service expenditure (e.g., special education, corrections) that would likely result from increased social, health or education service investments. For practicality and to reduce the cost of contracting, the focus of the current social impact financing initiatives tends to be on a single or small set of benefits accruing to one level of government or one agency within a government. Consideration of all government benefits accruing to various agencies and levels of government, while theoretically possible, is impractical. In early childhood programs, government savings are likely to accrue for school districts, county, state and federal corrections departments, state and federal welfare agencies and revenue departments. Current initiatives, which are considered “proof of concept” endeavors, tend to focus on estimating the cost savings to a single level of government arising from a single outcome or a small set of outcomes. Challenges and opportunities for reliance on private funding to expand cost-effective preschool programs are discussed in the next section.

Governmental Savings in the Child-Parent Centers

In the area of early childhood education, cost-benefit analysts focus on identifying categories of benefits that are measurable and monetizable. Karoly et al. (1998, chapter 3) provides a useful framework in listing possible benefits and disaggregating them according to who receives the benefits. Table 1 contains similar information for the Child-Parent Center preschool program in Chicago as reported in the CBA by Reynolds et al. (2011b). Findings are based on a longitudinal study that follows a cohort of students who entered kindergarten in 1985 and are now in their 30s. The matched comparison group enrolled in the usual early childhood programs available in the district. In Table 1, the program cost for the typical preschool participant is reported as $9,519 in 2014 dollars. This is the present value evaluated at the child’s age of 3 assuming that all children participated at age 4 and 55% at age 3. More detail about the estimation of program costs is found in Reynolds et al. (2002).

Table 1.

Government savings from Child-Parent Center preschool participation in 2014 dollars reported as the present value at child’s age 3

Dollars per child
Program cost (for 1.55 years of preschool) $9,519
Savings to government $27,455
 Reductions in special education and remediation $6,711
 Reduction in child abuse/ neglect system costs $3,456
 Reduction in criminal justice system costs $10,132
 Taxes from higher earnings $7,156
 Reductions in welfare costs --

Note. From Reynolds et al. (2011b) adjusted using CPI-U price index. Welfare costs were not estimated due to no observed differences between groups. Table 4 in Reynolds et al. (2011b) reports the total social benefits per participant to be $92,220 in 2007 dollars, which is $103,130 in 2014 dollars.

As an established school-based program routinely implemented since the 1960s, the CPC program is a particularly good candidate for expansion through borrowing based on social impact with a pay for success contract. Along with the well-known Perry Preschool program which has followed into adulthood children in low-income families in Ypsilanti Michigan who were randomly assigned to a high-quality preschool program (Heckman et al. 2010), CPC has a strong base of peer-reviewed evidence of effectiveness. Unlike the Perry program, CPCs have continued to operate in public school sites in Chicago’s poorest neighborhoods. A federally-funded expansion of the CPC program called the Midwest CPC Expansion began in the fall of 2012 under an Investing in Innovation (i3) Grant from the U. S. Department of Education to the University of Minnesota. In the first year, the Chicago Public Schools and four other districts in Illinois and Minnesota served over 2,500 preschool children (Reynolds et al., 2014). Implementation of the CPC intervention has been established as a school reform model. The Chicago PFS expands the number of preschool sites and student slots offered by the program.

The Child-Parent Center program is designed to enhance early childhood development in multiple domains of health and well-being. Located within or near elementary schools, the program provides educational and family-support services between the ages of 3 and 9 (preschool to third grade). Within a structure of comprehensive services (education, family, health, and social services), 6 major components are included: (a) collaborative leadership team led by the Head Teacher, (b) effective learning experiences (e.g., small classes and a literacy-rich instruction), (c) parent involvement and engagement, (d) aligned curriculum across grades, (e) continuity and stability, and a (f) professional development system of teacher coaching and site support (Human Capital Research Collaborative, 2012).

The effectiveness of the Child-Parent Center program in Chicago has been evaluated as part of the Chicago Longitudinal Study (CLS; Reynolds et al. 2001 and 2001a, Temple and Reynolds, 2007), a prospective quasi-experimental study that follows 1,539 children who participated in Child-Parent Center educational intervention beginning at ages 3 or 4 in the mid-1980s. While the Child-Parent Center continues today the CLS focuses on a single-aged cohort of participants who are now in adulthood. Impact evaluations using the CLS indicate that high-quality early intervention targeted toward economically disadvantaged children and their parents affects school success especially in terms of reduced special education placement and grade retention, higher rates of high school graduation, reductions in juvenile and adult crime, and a number of other outcomes.

In Table 1, results from the Chicago Longitudinal Study are shown focusing on the Child-Parent Center’s effects on public savings to various levels of government estimated through age 65. These cost savings are reported in the categories of reductions in government (district, state, and federal) expenditures due to special education placement and grade retention (school district only), as well as the present value of the lifetime flow of higher tax revenues to state and the federal governments that are estimated to accrue due to higher educational attainment of program participants. Also included is the estimated criminal justice cost savings due to preschool’s estimated effect on juvenile and adult crime using actual data observed up to the participant’s age 26 and lifetime projections beyond that. The juvenile criminal justice cost savings, which accrues primarily to the county and state, constituted 63% of the total in this category in large part due to the smaller weight placed on adult crime due to discounting.

While an earlier CBA of the CPCs found evidence that participation in welfare receipt such as food stamps and AFDC/TANF were reduced (Reynolds et al. 2002), the subsequent analysis based on more years of data including the recession of the late 2000’s found no statistically significant difference in program participation between the preschool and comparison groups (Reynolds et al. 2011b). Unlike a typical preschool program, the CPC program has a strong focus on promoting parent involvement and devotes significant amount of resources toward parent involvement and support. Using administrative data obtained from Cook County in Illinois, researchers have found that parent participation in this education intervention is associated with a reduction in substantiated cases of child abuse and neglect (Reynolds and Robertson, 2003). The cost savings reported in Table 1 accrue mostly to the state and county and represent a weighted average of the costs of in-home and foster care services.

While total social benefits of $103,130 per participant (or $92,220 in 2007 dollars) from CPC preschool participation reported in Reynolds et al. (2011b) are 10.83 times greater than costs, restricting the benefits to include only government savings and added government revenues generates an estimate of the present value of benefits to be $27,455 indicating a benefit-cost ratio of $2.88 to $1. Hence an additional dollar devoted to expand preschool programming offering in the CPCs could be expected to generate $2.88 in government savings alone. The estimated government savings account for 27% of the total social benefit. As a preventive program that more than pays for itself, the benefit-cost ratio of $2.88 to $1 in terms of government savings makes the CPC program a viable candidate for social impact financing with a Pay for Success contract.

The benefits for preschool and for preventive interventions more generally have been estimated to extend for decades often through the participants’ expected time of retirement or beyond. Investors and other parties involved in social impact borrowing may prefer investments that have shorter pay-off windows. Information is needed on the length of time required for potential cost savings to cover the initial costs of the program. Investors, intermediaries and government policymakers may not want to commit their organizations to these projects for decades at a time, especially given the newness of this type of financing. Moreover, interest rates might need to be higher to cover the risks associated with longer-term investments.

While Table 1 reports the present value of estimated government savings arising from CPC preschool participation up to age 65, Table 2 highlights the differences in the timing of various benefits of CPC. Because social impact investors generally are interested in projects in which repayment could be expected within a short-to medium length time horizon, we focus solely on benefits to governments that arise during childhood and adolescence. These government benefits include a reduction in special education placement, reductions in substantiated claims of child abuse and neglect to the county welfare office, reductions in juvenile justice system costs, and a decrease in schooling costs due to a reduction in grade retention. For each category of benefits, information is provided about the assumed timing of the benefit for the purposes of discounting back to the child’s age 3. The third column provides a monetary estimate of the government cost of a single unit of the benefit. This amount is then discounted back to age 3 as shown in column 4. The last column represents the effect of preschool participation from an impact evaluation multiplied by the cost of a unit of the outcome. The information in Table 2 reflects the procedure by which the cost-benefit analysis in Reynolds et al. (2011b) was conducted. The estimated treatment effects are first translated into dollar terms. In cost-benefit analysis, the timing of the benefits and costs then need to be precisely specified because the timing affects the calculation of the present value of benefits and costs.

Table 2.

Timing of early government cost savings from preschool participation in the Child-Parent Centers

Benefit Valued at age Benefit at age occurred PV of benefit Preschool effect on outcome PV of preschool effect in dollars
Special education in years 12 $11,082 per year $8,495 0.7 reduction in years of services $5,946
Substantiated claims of child abuse and neglect 10 $56,663 per claim $46,073 7.5 percentage point reduction $3,456
Juvenile criminal justice system expenditures per petition 14 $26,956 per petition $19,474 0.33 reduction in number of petitions $6,427
Grade retention in years 19 $10,258 per year $6,392 15.4 percentage point reduction $984

Note. Estimates are in 2014 dollars. Present values are calculated at the child’s age 3 using a 3% discount rate. More information is provided in Appendix C in Reynolds et al. (2011b). By age 18, 14.4% of the program group received special education vs. 24.6 % of the comparison group.

In the Chicago study, the most common year for identification for special education was at the age of 7. Once identified, the typical special education student received services for 5 years. Hence the estimated reduction in special education of 0.7 academic years was assumed to occur at the child’s age 12. A less conservative assumption was that the CPC program delayed entry into special education; if so, then this benefit might have occurred at age 6 or 7 instead.

For child abuse and neglect, the reductions in substantiated claims occurred at various times between age 4 and 17. We assumed that the estimated reduction occurred at age 10, but in Reynolds and Robertson (2003) a significant portion of the benefits were observed in the years between 10 and 17. Juvenile crime occurred at various years before age 18 and the assumption was that the program-induced reduction occurred at the midpoint between ages 11 and 17.

Finally, because grade retention adds an additional year to K-12 schooling, it makes sense that the timing of this benefit is at the child’s age 19. Note that none of these individual categories of benefits are large enough by themselves to cover the cost of participation in the CPC program. Special education savings, however, cover 62% of the costs of preschool and some other more recent studies have led observers to believe that the special education cost savings likely to be observed today are much greater than those reported in Reynolds et al. (2011b).

The timing of the early benefits of early education for the disadvantaged population served by the CPCs presented in Table 2 makes clear that the time at which benefits cover or exceed costs is somewhere in adolescence, perhaps around age 14. Given that students may have started preschool at age 3, the payback period for this early childhood program is about 10 or 11 years long.

Despite the fact that special education cost savings by themselves do not appear large enough to cover preschool costs, some policymakers and policy analysts consider it likely that the estimated cost savings from high-quality preschool programs may be higher that what Reynolds et al. (2011b) have reported based on information from students who attended school in the 1980s and 1990s. Given a higher real cost of special education combined with an increase in the number of students nationwide identified in the category of specific learning disability, programs that reduce special education placements or reduce their duration have the promise of lowering government costs to school districts, states, and the federal government.

Evidence from Other Preschool Studies

The evidence on the effects of preschool programs targeted toward children from low-income neighborhoods on the probability that a child will be assigned to special education as well as information about the duration of special education enrollment for students in general comes from a variety of sources. Researchers studying the High/Scope Perry Preschool program, a small randomized experiment in which 123 children from low-income families in Ypsilanti Michigan were assigned to preschool versus control, report that preschool participation leads to a 1.3 year reduction in the duration of special education. This estimated treatment effect is almost twice as large as is reported in the Chicago study. A more recent study by Muschkin et al. (2015) followed students in North Carolina before and after the rollout of two state-funded early childhood programs. One program provided funding for preschool for disadvantaged 4 year olds while the other funded improvements in the quality of child care from ages 0 to 5. Using county-level data on state expenditures for these programs, Muschkin et al. find that the two programs together lead to a 39% reduction in the odds of special education placement as of 3rd grade.

Two additional studies on the effects of preschool participation on special education have been cited by social impact bond advocates as demonstrating that preschool programs can have significant effects on special education placement decisions in kindergarten. As described in Duggar and Litan (2011) and Dubno et al. (2013), children who participation in publicly-funded preschool programs (the Utah High Quality Preschool and Pennsylvania’s PreK-Counts programs) had a 2 or 3% probability of being placed in special education in kindergarten compared to an 18% rate for children who did not participate in preschool. Dubno et al. (2013) use the estimates from Utah as the foundation for a detailed set of estimates of potential state government special education cost savings from preschool participation under varying assumptions of kindergarten placement rates.

Although preschool education may lead to a reduction in special education placement in kindergarten, most students are not identified for services until a couple of years later (e.g., Hibel et al. 2010, Holt et al. 2007; Reynolds et al. 2011b). Various estimates from different sources indicate that the duration of special education services may vary by state or school district, disability category, and data source. Several studies including Holt et al. (2007) and Hibel et al. (2010) have analyzed nationally-representative data on U.S. school children from the U.S. Department’s Early Childhood Longitudinal Study-Kindergarten cohort, which follows a single cohort of children who were enrolled in kindergartens in 1998–99. Hanushek et al. (2002) use data from all public school students in Texas to show the variation in special education placement rates by disability type and grade. Evidence specifically on the duration of placement for students in a special education preschool program is reported by Jenkins et al. (2006) for a small sample of students in Washington State. By age 19, 60% of the students were still receiving services as of the end of high school.

Understanding the effect of early childhood programs also requires knowledge of which categories of special education are not likely to be affected by early intervention (e.g., physical disability) and which types might be (e.g., specific learning disability, speech impairments or perhaps emotional and behavior disturbances). The Utah study assumes that 80% of the classification decisions of special education students will be affected by preschool participation. The fastest category of special education, specific learning disabilities, is described by some education researchers as being entirely preventable and also is the category with the most subjective classification decisions (Muschkin et al. 2015; Greene, 2007). The duration of placement in special education may vary across disability type, with students in the speech impairment category typically only needing a couple of years of services.

Previous comparisons of the cost reductions in special education to the cost of preschool

A few studies have reported explicitly on the magnitude of the benefits of special education expenditure reductions compared to the costs of preschool. Belfield’s (2005) simulations of the effects and costs of targeted versus universal preschool in Pennsylvania predicted that the savings from reduced special education arising from an expansion of publicly-funded preschool will cover approximately 16–31% of the cost of preschool. On the other hand, Chase et al. (2008) estimate that the special education savings arising from a two year preschool program in Minnesota might cover only 6% of the preschool costs. A newer study of the effects of preschool and early childhood programming on placement in special education is by Muschkin et al. (2015). Regarding the state-funded slots for preschool for low-income 4 year olds, in a rigorous panel data study that made use of differential rollout of early childhood funding across counties and overtime, Muschkin et al. reported that a preschool program serving low-income students that cost an average of $1,100 per child in each county (not per preschool participant) was associated with a reduction in special education services saving $200 in third grade year per each child in the county.

While Muschkin et al. (2015) did not report special education placement in the years before third grade, speculative evidence assuming that each child observed in special education in third grade has also been enrolled in kindergarten through second grade suggests that the potential cost savings of the 4-year old preschool program may be enough to cover the preschool costs. The program offering improvements to child care quality for ages 0–5 also cost $1,100 on a per-child in the county basis (not per child served) on average over the five years of services but had a significantly smaller effect on third grade special education placement.

Social Impact Financing Through Pay for Success

Since 2011, eight U.S. states or localities have launched PFS initiatives with active discussions taking place to implement many more. In each of these projects, private sector investors have loaned anywhere from $4 million to over $20 million to social service providers to expand services in areas including recidivism, homelessness, adult education, maternal and infant health, and preschool education. If program participants meet certain pre-established outcome targets, then states, cities, school districts or counties promise to pay back the private investors. Although this new financing mechanism is referred to as a social impact bond, the initiatives to date all take the forms of loans in which investors are scheduled to be paid back on various dates if outside evaluators are able to confirm program success. Social impact borrowing is described in greater detail by Liebman (2011), Leibman and Sellman (2013), Warner (2013). A website maintained by the Nonprofits Assistance Fund at payforsuccess.org contains up to date information on ongoing and planned initiatives.

For the purpose of illustration, Table 3 describes the details associated with the first PFS initiative in the U.S. as well as the two ongoing projects in the area of early childhood. Following the lead of the first PFS that was created to fund programs in Peterborough prison in the UK, the first U.S. PFS financed the expansion of an existing program for youthful offenders at New York City’s Riker’s Island (Rudd et al., 2013; Olson and Phillips, 2013).

Table 3.

Description of three social impact borrowing initiatives 2011–2014

Borrowing initiative NYC Rikers Island ABLE intervention Utah High Quality preschool program Chicago Child-Parent Centers
Service area Recidivism Early childhood Early childhood
Projected number served 12, 320 incarcerated teens 3,500 children 2,620 children
Amount invested $9.2 million $7 million $16.9 million
Investors Goldman Sachs Goldman Sachs, Pritzker Foundation Goldman Sachs, Northern Trust Pritzker Foundation
Intermediary MDRC United Way of Salt Lake City IFF and Metropolitan Family Services
Risk-sharing arrangements among private investors Bloomberg Philanthropies contributes additional $7.2 million grant to guarantee payments to Goldman Sachs Pritzker Foundation is subordinate lender. Pritzker Foundation is subordinate lender
Success payments For each day of jail prevented within 2 years of release.
For each participant served.
For each high-risk child not assigned to special education in each year K-6th grade. For each child not placed in special education each year K-12th grade.
For each child deemed ready for kindergarten. For each child achieving proficiency in reading in third grade.
Payback window 2 years 7 or 8 years 13 years
Comparison group Similar inmates released before program was started None For special education payment only: children without preschool participation in matched Chicago public school sites.
Results as of 2015 Terminated due to first-year results showing no reduction in jail days for treatment group. First year results triggered success payments. Out of 110 students predicted to need special education, 109 avoided placement in kindergarten. Not available.

Recognizing that 50% of youthful offenders return to prison within 2 years of release, a social impact borrowing arrangement with a PFS contract was set up with the City of New York and the Goldman Sachs investment bank. The social and emotional skills ABLE intervention offered by a nonprofit service provider serves teen offenders between 16 and 19 years old. Once released, the hope is that these adolescences will not return to jail. Goldman Sachs loaned an intermediary $9.2 million dollars to contract with the service provider. An external evaluator obtains information for each participant on how many subsequent days are spent in jail within two years of release. The reports by Rudd et al. (2013) and Olson and Phillips (2013) contain detailed information about how the success payments are structured based on the number of jail days avoided for the participants relative to a control group. A second type of payment is based on participation only and is made regardless of the recidivism outcomes. As the first U.S. example of social impact investing with a Pay for Success contract, the Riker’s Island initiative inspired other states and localities to consider expanding recidivism services as part of a social impact bond. However, when the first year evaluation by the Vera Institute of Justice (2015) found that the social and emotional skills intervention failed to reduce recidivism among the participants as compared to a matched comparison group, the Riker’s Island social impact initiative was terminated.

Utah and Chicago Preschool Pay for Success Initiatives

The second social impact financing initiative with a Pay for Success contract in the U.S. was created to expand preschool and again involved Goldman Sachs along with a philanthropic foundation. Local and state policymakers were motivated to expand the Utah High Quality Preschool program offered by school districts and nonprofit organizations in Salt Lake and Granite Counties. Given the research evidence suggesting that the averted costs of special education may equal or exceed the costs of preschool, the private investors contributed $7 million to expand preschool slots. Success payments in Utah were based entirely on the state share of the cost savings for special education. Because the state government had not agreed to make these success payments as the project was being launched, Salt Lake County agreed to make the payments in the first year. Believing that the probability of placement in special education was extremely high for children who scored below a 70 on the Peabody Picture Vocabulary Test (PPVT), the success payment are to be made by the County (first year only) and then the state equal to $2470 for each child in this low range of the PPVT who later avoids special education placement during each year in kindergarten through 6th grade. If the loan is not repaid by the end of the participating student’s sixth grade year, then smaller additional success payments will continue to be made each year based on avoidance of special education among the high-risk subgroup of preschool participants. In October of 2015 results from the Utah High Quality Preschool social impact bond indicated that success payments of well over $200,000 to the investors were made as a result of success of the preschool program in reducing special education placement rates. Of the 110 high-risk preschoolers predicted to need special education services in absence of the preschool program, only 1 student was placed in special education in the kindergarten year (United Way of Salt Lake; 2015).

Expanding the Chicago CPCs is the objective of the fifth social impact borrowing initiative in the U.S. Given the research by Reynolds et al. (2011a, and 2011b) and recent U.S. Department of Education-funded efforts to expand a revised and more comprehensive CPC program in various Midwest locations (Human Capital Research Collaborative, 2012) as well as research on high-quality preschool programs in general, Goldman Sachs, the Northern Trust and the Pritzker Foundation contributed $16.9 million dollars to expand the number of CPC centers and preschool slots for children for children living in low-income neighborhoods. While Tables 1 and 2 indicated that the CPC preschool program costs in an earlier decade were not entirely paid for by the cost savings associated with special education placement reductions, private investors were still willing to expand funding based on indications by education policymakers and researchers that the benefits of preschool participation may be higher in the current climate. Note that modest changes in the estimates of the CPC program could lead to the special education savings entirely covering the preschool costs. In Table 1, for example, an increase in the program effect on special education duration by 30% combined with a 30% increase in real savings would lead to preschool covering its own costs in special education savings.

For each child in the CPC program who avoids special education in kindergarten through 12th grade relative to a comparison group of children who did not participate in preschool, the school district will make a success payment of $9,100 per child per year representing the district share of special education costs. This estimate represents a weighted average based on different types of special education services delivered. The Chicago social impact bond involves two additional indicators that will trigger success payments. For each CPC participant who is deemed kindergarten ready at the start of elementary school, the City of Chicago will pay the investors $2,900. Moreover, for each child meeting the standards for proficiency in reading in third grade, the City of Chicago will pay $750.

It is possible that projects funded by these Pay for Success social impact initiatives will not meet their success targets. If so, in the current social impact initiatives, only the investors lose as governments only pay if success targets are reached. The risk-sharing arrangements vary across the PFSs currently in operation. Table 3 describes an arrangement in the Riker’s Island contract in which a philanthropist contributes a sizeable amount to guarantee the private investment. In the preschool social impact bonds, no philanthropist guarantees the investments but the Priztker Family Foundation has agreed to be the subordinate lender meaning that they will be the last to be paid back and hence will bear most of the performance risk.

Limitations of Special Education as a Success Metric

Using special education placement as the trigger for success payments potentially is problematic due to the subjective nature of identification decisions. As Liebman (2011) explains, the participants in the social or educational services being funded should not be harmed by social impact investing. Will children in need of special education services not be served due to the incentives inherent in pay-for-success contracting? Cullen (1999) finds special education identification decisions to be highly sensitive to changes in funding formulas. About the category of specific learning disability that is the fastest growing category of special education as well as the category (along with speech impairments) that may be the most amenable to early intervention, Hanuschek et al. (2002) writes “This category encompasses a continuum of learning conditions where it is difficult to describe and to apply precise cutoffs in evaluation and assessment. This discretion also leads to considerable variation in classification rates across states, districts, and time.” Others have expressed concern about the timing of the identification of learning disabilities for dual language learners. Hibel and Jasper (2012) express concern that special education placement may be improperly delayed for dual language learners.

In Utah, concerns about causing harm by failing to place needy students in special education is believed to be mitigated by the fact that the decision to identify a student for special education services at the school level seems to be fairly removed from the financial incentive that the state government might have to not identify a student for services. Moreover, the teachers in elementary school may not know which students are participating in the study. In Chicago, including kindergarten readiness and success in third grade reading as additional success indicators and payment triggers means that these important outcomes also will be tracked and publicly reported. Hopefully this help mitigate any incentive the district might have to informally alter the subjective thresholds for special education identification.

Another limitation of using special education placement as the primary cost savings metric is that it is likely to underestimate the true cost savings from the program. In the CPC study, for example, special education savings are only one-quarter of the government savings (see Table 1). Unmeasured savings in child welfare, crime prevention as well as increased economic well-being through higher educational attainment are expected to be other major sources of benefits. The inclusion of these other sources of savings, however, requires agreements with county and state agencies who have jurisdiction over these funding sources. Cross-jurisdiction agreements are more challenging to complete and increase the amount of time and transaction costs. The CPC initiative only includes success payments made by the school district and by the City of Chicago. The Utah initiative is with the State, and only includes this portion of special education savings in the success payments made to repay the private investors.

We note, however, that significant efforts were made in Chicago on a cross-jurisdiction initiative. For example, during the planning, efforts were made to partner with the State of Illinois to include the state portion of special education costs in the transaction. Cook County also was approached, since it is the jurisdiction for child welfare and juvenile justice system savings that were documented in the CBA. There was not sufficient interest to develop either collaboration further. Governor Quinn had prioritized youth foster care for his own PFS initiative. Even if there was interest however, the extra time and complexity needed to complete the project would have dramatically multiplied. There also was consideration to include the K-3 component of the program in the transaction but the added costs made this infeasible. Thus, the constraints of time and divergent priorities across jurisdictions create barriers to implementing comprehensive PFS initiatives. If the sole purpose is to expand services that would otherwise be impossible, however, the narrow scope of PFS serves an important end.

These three examples of PFS highlight the heterogeneous nature of the contractual arrangements made by the relevant government entities. In the Riker’s Island case, New York City makes the payments to the private investors. In Utah, Salt Lake County originally agreed to make the success payments for reductions in special education placements even though the county is not involved in special education finance and so technically experiences no direct cost savings when the number of special education students falls. Instead, Salt Lake County agreed to be the payer after being convinced that special education placement rates were an indicator of future benefits that the city would experience in terms of reductions in crime and related county expenditures. By the start of the year of the Utah social impact bond, legislation was passed allowing the state government to make success payments. Finally, in Chicago the main success payment based on reductions in special education placement are based on the estimate of the cost to the school district and not the state. The City of Chicago agreed to make success payments based on the two additional outcomes of school readiness at the end of preschool and 3rd grade reading proficiency. As with the Salt Lake County’s willingness to pay for reductions in special education, the City of Chicago is willing to pay for these education-related outcomes even though there is not a sizable academic literature linking changes in these outcomes to direct savings in city, county, or state budgets. However, in the Chicago study school readiness and achievement are good predictors of the need for school remediation and special education (Reynolds and Ou, 2011; Conyers, Reynolds, and Ou, 2003).

Opportunities and Challenges in Pay for Success Social Impact Financing

The method of CBA underlies the great current interest in social impact borrowing among private investors, policymakers, and service providers. Analysts’ ability to separate out government cost savings from the rest of the benefits accruing to program participants and the public provides valuable information to all of the involved parties regarding the feasibility of this funding mechanism. In the area of early childhood education, existing studies such as Karoly et al. (1998, 2005), Heckman et al. (2010), Reynolds et al. (2011b) and Belfield et al. (2006), while based on interventions offered 30, 40 or 50 years ago and observed outcomes measured through adulthood, provide a useful framework for considering the various types of governmental cost savings or benefits, their timing, and the issue of which level of government receives each type of government savings. Benefit-cost analyses that have contributed knowledge regarding the types of governmental benefits that can be expected and to which levels of government these cost savings accrue are now being used as the foundation for private sector investments in services offered by school districts, cities, counties, and states.

There are several notable opportunities presented by this new funding mechanism. Given difficulties in raising taxes, social impact investing with a Pay for Success contract allows private investors to provide the working capital to finance the expansion in proven or promising social and educational services. As currently constructed, the social impact borrowing deals present no financial risks to governments as they only pay when success targets have been reached. A second benefit associated with Pay for Success investing is the greater and more explicit focus on evidence-based public service contracting decisions. As on-going initiatives are evaluated, these evaluations will add to the knowledge base about “what works.” There is likely to be an increase in demand for analysts trained in cost-benefit analysis. More detail about the promise of social impact borrowing more broadly is provided by Liebman (2011), Liebman and Sellman (2013), and Temple and Reynolds (forthcoming).

PFS financing is not without its critics as several challenges to its sustainability have been noted. A few of these challenges are discussed below and Duggar and Litan (2012) have a lengthier discussion. Several of the on-going PFS programs are described as intending to provide “proof of concept,” which means that they are intended to demonstrate feasibility of the contracting form rather than high levels of profitability. A major strength of the Chicago PFS initiative is that the CPC program has an evidence base demonstrating effects on outcomes in both the shorter- and longer- term and is the only program among the current PFS initiatives backed by peer-reviewed cost–benefit analyses based on longitudinal follow-up of participants that demonstrates sizeable government savings. The Chicago PFS supplements a federally-funded initial expansion of the program (Human Capital Research Collaborative, 2012) that provides additional funding from 2012–2016.

An important problem with PFS projects is that they entail high administrative costs. Issues regarding service provider selection criteria, the role of the intermediaries, fidelity of program implementation, the guidelines for the evaluation, the nature of risk sharing and the means of addressing conflicts must be discussed and decided upon by various parties. As the leader of several of the early social impact bond initiatives, Goldman Sachs has provided large amounts of investment and contracting expertise. Fortunately, a number of the negotiated contracts are available online, which will reduce contracting costs for various parties involved in future social impact arrangements.

A third concern is about private investors’ willingness to assume risk. In the PFS initiatives described in Table 3, the primary investor is shielded from much of the performance risk by a private foundation either providing a grant to help guarantee the investment or agreeing to be second in line for eventual repayment. If states or local governments wanted to securitize the future flow of cost savings and create an actual social impact appropriations bond, then government’s preference for keeping bond payments low might lead to only risk-free, high return services being chosen for financing. For example, if both the private investors and the evaluator expect to be paid a 5% rate of return and the intermediary requires 10%, then the chosen social or educational service would have to be one that could not only pay for itself in the form of government savings but generate an additional 20% return. This limits the ability of PFS to scale up innovative and promising interventions as only proven projects could be financed at low interest rates and scaling up smaller-scale projects might be considered too risky. Risk sharing could expand to include the service providers themselves although Warner (2013) expresses concern as these organizations serve the most “fragile” clients including disadvantaged children, prisoners, and the homeless and making service providers pay if success targets are not met may reduce their ability to provide services in the future. Leibman and Sellman (2013) point out that some determinants of measured program success such as the macroeconomy are not under the control of service providers.

A final challenge concerns the establishment of a comparison group. Ideally, the counterfactual is the PFS outcome (e.g., special education placement) for a comparison group that is equally eligible for the program and similar on socioeconomic characteristics that affect school success but does not participate or participates in an alternative program. In the preschool field this is typically another center-based program, since roughly 80% of 4-year-olds enroll in out of home care or preschool education at least part of the day. PFS initiatives use a variety of evaluation approaches, which will depend on the interests of the investors. In the Utah PFS, no comparison group was identified since a history of positive effects had been documented. Instead, preschool children defined at high risk of receiving special education services--those scoring two standard deviations below the mean on the Peabody Picture Vocabulary Test---served as their own controls. Each high-risk child that avoided special education generates an annual success payment to the investors for the life of the contract. In the Chicago PFS, a comparison group was identified—demographically similar children entering the public schools as kindergartners without preschool experience in the district. Success payments for special education placement reductions are triggered by a comparison of the CPC children with entering kindergartners in similar public school settings in low-income neighborhoods. The use of comparison groups and precise metrics of evaluating success are important parts of social impact financing with a Pay for Success contract.

The future of social impact investing with Pay for Success contracts both in general and for early childhood programs may move in several directions. First, there could be more across-government and across-agency cooperation. In the illustration of the governmental savings associated with the preschool program offered by the CPCs, some of the government savings accrue to the school district in the form of special education and reductions in grade retention. Some of the cost savings are accrued by the county, especially some of the criminal justice costs and the governmental costs associated with child abuse and neglect. The state also benefits by reductions in special education, crime, higher tax revenues, and lower need for welfare services. The federal government benefits also from the same categories as the state but in differing amounts. The first social impact bonds involved estimating savings to one level of government. As the understanding of this financing mechanism has evolved, the early childhood initiatives went from including the state only in Utah to including the city and school district in Chicago.

A benefit of the current popularity of Pay for Success investing is that policymakers and voters may develop a greater recognition of the importance of preventive interventions. Many government services are offered to help address social issues after they have occurred rather than prevent them from occurring. In some cases, prevention may be more cost-effective than intervention. The current interest in social impact investing may lead to a reconsideration of legislative or constitutional restrictions on borrowing. If the feasibility of social impact borrowing is established, a possible successful outcome for PFS is that these types of financial arrangements might not exist in the future as governments change their own budget priorities from intervention to prevention and restrictions are eased that limit the use of state or local debt to finance physical capital rather than human capital investments.

Conclusion and Future Directions

Cost-benefit analysis increasingly is being applied to the study of social programs (Vining and Weimer, 2010). CBA models are useful for predicting and valuing the effects of a variety of social and educational services that not only generate benefits to the program participants but to the rest of society as well. Cost benefit analyses help promote efficiency in public-sector decision making by identifying programs and policies that generate benefits to society that are greater than the costs.

Recent innovations in private funding of certain social service programs by social impact investors using Pay for Success contracts represent a new use of cost-benefit analysis. While estimation of benefits and costs to society as a whole is a main objective in CBA, a closer focus on the subset of benefits arising from government cost savings and higher government revenues reveals that there are a significant number of social programs in existence that not only generate high social returns but also have the potential to pay for themselves in terms of these government cost savings. Expansion of social services (especially those considered to be preventive interventions) through the use of Pay for Success financing requires policy analysts not only to identify interventions that generate net social benefits, but to pay close attention to the predicted magnitude and timing of the government savings arising from the interventions.

In this article, we described social impact financing with a Pay for Success contract as a promising approach for scaling high-quality early childhood programs. The frameworks and perspectives implemented in the existing CBAs of early childhood programs help inform the implementation and evaluation of PFS initiatives. The major contribution of PFS financing in early childhood and for social programs more generally is the provision of a new avenue to scale up evidence-based preventive programs. In a number of states around the U.S., private investors have provided up to $20 million to finance the expansion of social and education services. The public services that are candidates for PFS financing are preventive programs that both generate social benefits in excess of costs AND have governmental cost savings that are enough by themselves to cover program costs. Early childhood and other preventive public services that can save governments money over a shorter period are preferred to those that may take decades to generate sufficient cost savings.

In the U.S., the types of government programs that have funded by private investments with a PFS contract include services offered to youthful offenders to prevent recidivism, early childhood education programs that may reduce later placement in special education services, homeless prevention programs, and a myriad of other preventive services. This paper has focused on the use of social impact borrowing to expand preschool programming to economically-disadvantaged children, but the discussion here equally applies to other forms of early intervention such as home nurse visiting programs (Zaveri et al, 2014) for new mothers in low-income communities. The promise of high returns (both to society and to the taxpayers) is likely to be greatest when financial or political barriers are preventing tax-funded expansions of services for those most at risk of social, health or educational problems.

While the details involved in PFS initiatives are complex, a number of the legal contracts describing these financial arrangements are publicly available. Policy-led social impact initiatives are starting to be offered without the help of Goldman Sachs. Knowledge of cost-benefit analysis is useful for informing the contract language that specifies the magnitude of the success payments. Policy analysts help specify the evaluation scheme for identifying whether the providers have met pre-determined targets that generate the success payments from the government to the investors. As discussed, two aspects of CBA are central to the feasibility of this funding mechanism. First, the existence and magnitude of government savings generated by the project must be identified and accurately estimated. Second, the timing of the government benefits needs to be understood so that a payback schedule can be specified that aligns realized government cost savings with the payments that the government needs to make to repay the private investors.

Many studies have suggested that high-quality well-targeted early childhood programs generate social benefits well in excess of costs. A significant portion of these benefits are averted future government costs and higher future taxes. From these studies, there is reason to believe that programs that reduce special education placement in the early grades may not only be cost-effective but are capable of generating government savings that may cover or exceed their costs. PFS contracts allow governments and nonprofit organizations to expand education services without any increase in taxes. The current contractual arrangements place the performance risk on the private investors and philanthropists.

At this time in the U.S., external evaluations are just starting to be reported for the Riker’s Island and the Utah preschool social impact bond initiatives. The first social impact bond outside of the U.S., which expanded services to recently-released former inmates of the Petersborough Prison in the U.K., was terminated prematurely due to national changes in probation policies that would have affected the comparison group. As previously mentioned, the Riker’s Island evaluation found no evidence that the social and emotional skills training offered to teen offenders led to a reduction in recidivism. Successful results generating success payments to the investors have been reported for the first year of the Utah High Quality Preschool program, although the results have stimulated debate about the role of a control group in evaluating program success (Popper, 2015). Although social benefits are not estimated by the evaluators in these initiatives, the existence of government savings in excess of program costs is an indicator that the overall benefits to society may be even larger.

While the evaluations of the current PFS initiatives focus on how well the preschool participants fare in avoiding special education placement and, in the Chicago project, how school-ready and reading proficient they are, future research may expand to a broader examination of outcomes including avoidance of juvenile delinquency, high school completion and other indicators of economic success. Expanding the perspective to include benefits accruing to multiple jurisdictions or agencies would be a step toward broadening the narrow perspective in which benefits are conceptualized in the current social impact borrowing initiatives.

References

  1. Barnett W Steven, et al. The 2014 State Preschool Yearbook. New Brunswick, NJ: National Institute of Early Education Research, Rutgers University; 2015. [Google Scholar]
  2. Barnett W Steven, Masse Leonard N. Comparative benefit-cost analysis of the Abecedarian program and its policy implications. Economics of Education Review. 2007;26:113–125. [Google Scholar]
  3. Bartik Timothy, Gormley William, Adelstein Shirley. Earnings benefits of Tulsa’s pre-K program for different income groups. Economics of Education Review. 2012;31:1143–1161. [Google Scholar]
  4. Belfield Clive. The cost savings to special education from pre-schooling in Pennsylvania. Harrisburg, PA: Pennsylvania Build Initiative; 2005. [Google Scholar]
  5. Belfield Clive, Nores Milagros, Barnett W Steven, Schweinhart Lawrence J. The High/Scope Perry Preschool program: cost-benefit analysis using data from age 40 using data from the age 40 follow up. Journal of Human Resources. 2006;XLI:162–190. [Google Scholar]
  6. Boardman Anthony E, Greenberg David H, Vining Aidan R, Weimer David L. Cost-benefit analysis: Concepts and practice. 4. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall; 2011. [Google Scholar]
  7. Campbell Frances A, Ramey Craig T, Pungello Elizabeth, Sparling Joseph, Miller-Johnson Shari. Early childhood education: Young adult outcomes from the Abecedarian project. Applied Development Science. 2002;6(1):42–57. [Google Scholar]
  8. Chase Richard, Coffee-Borden Brandon, Anton Paul, Moore Christopher, Valorese Jennifer. The cost burden to Minnesota K-12 when children are unprepared for kindergarten. Wilder Research; Saint Paul MN: 2008. [Google Scholar]
  9. Consortium for Longitudinal Studies. As the twig is bent...lasting effects of preschool programs. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum; 1983. [Google Scholar]
  10. Conyers Liza M, Reynolds Arthur J, Ou Suh-Ruu. The effects of early childhood intervention and subsequent special education services: Findings from the Chicago Child-Parent Centers. Educational Evaluation & Policy Analysis. 2003;25:75–95. [Google Scholar]
  11. Council of Economic Advisors. The economics of early childhood investments. Washington, DC: Executive Office of the President of the United States; 2014. Dec, [Google Scholar]
  12. Cullen Julie Berry. The impact of fiscal incentives on student disability rates. Journal of Public Economics. 2003;87:1557–1589. [Google Scholar]
  13. Dubno Janis A, Dugger Robert H, Smith Michele R. Financing human capital development for economically-disadvantaged children: applying pay for success social impact finance to early childhood development. ReadyNation working paper 2013 [Google Scholar]
  14. Duggar Robert, Litan Robert. Report of Kauffman Foundation - Ready Nation Working Group on Early Childhood Finance Innovation. 2011. Early Childhood “Pay For Success” Social Impact Finance: A PFS Bond Example to Increase School Readiness and Reduce Special Education Costs. April 2012. [Google Scholar]
  15. Greenblatt Jonathan, Donovan Annie. The promise of pay for success. Community Development Investment Review. 2013;9(1):19–22. [Google Scholar]
  16. Greene Jay P. Fixing special education. Peabody Journal of Education. 2007;82:703–723. [Google Scholar]
  17. Hanushek Eric A, Kain John F, Rivkin Steven G. Inferring program effects for special populations: Does special education raise achievement for students with disabilities? Review of Economics and Statistics. 2002;84:584–599. [Google Scholar]
  18. Heckman James J, Moon Seong Hyeok, Pinto Rodrigo, Savelyev Peter A, Yavitz Adam. The rate of return to the High/Scope Perry Preschool program. Journal of Public Economics. 2010;94:114–128. doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.001. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. Heckman James J, et al. Skill formation and the economics of investments in disadvantaged children. Science. 2006 Jun;312:1900–1902. doi: 10.1126/science.1128898. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  20. Holt Emily W, McGrath Daniel J, Herring William L. Timing and duration of student participation in special education in the primary grades. 2007 NCES 2007-043 issue brief. [Google Scholar]
  21. Hibel Jacob, Farkas George, Morgan Paul L. Who is placed into special education? Sociology of Education. 2010;83:312–32. doi: 10.1177/0038040710383518. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  22. Hibel Jacob, Jasper Andrea J. Delayed special education placement for learning disabilities among immigrants. Social Forces. 2012;91:503–530. [Google Scholar]
  23. Human Capital Research Collaborative. Program requirement and guidelines, Midwest Expansion of the Child-Parent Center Program, Preschool to Third Grade. Minneapolis: Human Capital Research Collaborative; 2012. http://humancapitalrc.org/midwestcpc. [Google Scholar]
  24. Jenkins Joseph R, Dale Philip S, Mills Paulette E, Cole Kevin N, Pious Constance, Ronk Joan. How special education preschool students finish: status at 19 years of age. American Journal of Educational Research. 2006;43:737–781. [Google Scholar]
  25. Karoly Lynn A, Greenwood Peter W, Everingham SS, et al. Investing in our children: What we know and don’t know about the costs and benefits of early childhood interventions. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation; 1998. [Google Scholar]
  26. Karoly Lynn A, Kilburn MR, Cannon JS. Early childhood intervention: Proven results, future promise. Santa Monica, CA: RAND; 2005. [Google Scholar]
  27. Karoly Lynn A. Toward standardization of benefit-cost analysis of early childhood interventions. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis. 2012;3:1–45. [Google Scholar]
  28. Kline Patrick, Walters Christopher. Evaluating public programs with close substitutes: the case of Head Start. 2015 Unpublished paper. [Google Scholar]
  29. Liebman Jeffrey, Sellman Alina. Social Impact Bonds: A Guide for state and local governments. Harvard Kennedy School Social Impact Bond Technical Assistance Lab; 2013. [Google Scholar]
  30. Liebman Jeffrey. Social impact bonds: A promising new financing model to accelerate social innovation and improve government performance. Center for American Progress; 2011. [Google Scholar]
  31. Ludwig J, Phillips D. The benefits and costs of Head Start. Society for Research on Child Development Social Policy Report. 2007;XXI(3) [Google Scholar]
  32. Mervis Jeffrey. Past successes shape effort to expand early intervention. Science. 2011 Aug 19;333:952–956. doi: 10.1126/science.333.6045.952. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  33. Muschkin Clara G, Ladd Helen F, Dodge Kenneth A. Impact of North Carolina’s early childhood initiatives on special education placements in third grade. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis 2015 [Google Scholar]
  34. Office of Management and Budget. Circular A-11: Preparation, Submission, and Execution of the Budget. Washington, DC: 2008. [Google Scholar]
  35. Olson John, Phillips Andrea. Rikers Island: The first social impact bond in the US. Community Development Investment Review. 2013;9(1):97–101. [Google Scholar]
  36. Popper Nathaniel. Success metrics questioned in school program funded by Goldman. New York Times. 2015 Nov 3; [Google Scholar]
  37. Reynolds Arthur J, Ou Su-Ruu. Paths of effects from preschool to adult well-being: A confirmatory analysis of the Child-Parent Center program. Child Development. 2011;82:555–581. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8624.2010.01562.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  38. Reynolds Arthur J, Robertson Dylan L. School-based intervention and later child maltreatment in the Chicago Longitudinal Study. Child Development. 2003;74:3–26. doi: 10.1111/1467-8624.00518. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  39. Reynolds Arthur J, Temple Judy A, Robertson Dylan L, Mann Emily A. Long-term effects of an early childhood intervention on educational achievement and juvenile arrest: A 15-year follow-up of low-income children in public schools. Journal of the American Medical Association. 2001;285:2339–2346. doi: 10.1001/jama.285.18.2339. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  40. Reynolds Arthur J, Richardson Brandt A, Momo Hayakawa, et al. Association of a full-day versus part-day preschool intervention with school readiness, attendance, and parent involvement. Journal of the American Medical Association. 2014;312:2126–34. doi: 10.1001/jama.2014.15376. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  41. Reynolds Arthur J, Temple Judy A, Ou Suh-Ruu, Arteaga Irma A, White Barry AB. School-based early childhood education and age-28 well-being: effects by timing, dosage, and subgroups. Science. 2011a Jul 15;333:360–364. doi: 10.1126/science.1203618. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  42. Reynolds Arthur J, Temple Judy A, White Barry A, Ou Suh-Ruu, Robertson Dylan L. Age 26 cost benefit analysis of the Chicago Child Parent Center early education program. Child Development. 2011b;82:379–404. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8624.2010.01563.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  43. Reynolds Arthur J, Temple Judy A, Robertson Dylan L, Mann Emily A. Age 21 cost-benefit analysis of the Title I Chicago Child Parent Centers. Education Evaluation and Policy Analysis. 2002;24:267–303. [Google Scholar]
  44. Rudd Timothy, Nicoletti Elisa, Misner Kristin, Bonsu Janae. Financing promising evidence-based programs: early lessons from the New York City social impact bond. New York: MDRC; 2013. [Google Scholar]
  45. Temple Judy A, Reynolds Arthur J. The benefits and costs of investments in preschool. Economics of Education Review. 2007;26:126–144. [Google Scholar]
  46. Temple Judy A, Reynolds Arthur J. In: New developments in the economics of prevention: social impact borrowing to finance cost-effective interventions. Israelashvili Moshe, Romano John., editors. Cambridge Handbook of International Prevention Science; forthcoming. [Google Scholar]
  47. Schweinhart Lawrence J, Montie Joanne, Xiang Zongping, Barnett W Steven, Belfield Clive R, Nores Milagros. Lifetime effects: The High/Scope Perry Preschool study through age 40. Ypsilanti, MI: High/Scope Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
  48. United Way of Salt Lake. Initial results released for first social impact bond for early childhood education show success. Salt Lake City, UT: 2015. http://www.uw.org/our-work/cradle-to-kindergarten/sibfactsheet10-1-2015finaledits-4.pdf. [Google Scholar]
  49. Vera Institute of Justice. Impact evaluation of the Adolescent Behavioral Learning Experience (ABLE) program at Rikers Island: Summary. New York City, New York: 2015. [Google Scholar]
  50. Vining Aidan, Weimer David L. An assessment of important issues concerning the application of benefit-cost analysis to social policy. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis. 2010;1:1–40. [Google Scholar]
  51. Warner Mildred. Private finance for public goods. Journal of Economic Policy Reform. 2013;16:303–319. [Google Scholar]
  52. White House. Executive Order 12866: Regulatory Planning and Review. Washington, DC: 1993. [Google Scholar]
  53. White House. State of the Union Address. 2013 https://www.whitehouse.gov/state-of-the-union-2013.
  54. Zaveri Heather, Burwick Andrew, Maher Erin. The potential for cost savings from home visiting due to reductions in child maltreatment. Washington DC: Casey Family Programs; 2014. [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES