Skip to main content
Bulletin of the World Health Organization logoLink to Bulletin of the World Health Organization
. 2016 Sep 19;94(12):925–930. doi: 10.2471/BLT.15.164418

Cost–effectiveness thresholds: pros and cons

Seuils de rentabilité: avantages et inconvénients

Umbrales de rentabilidad: ventajas e inconvenientes

القيم الحدية لفعالية التكلفة: الإيجابيات والسلبيات

成本效益阈值: 利与弊

Пороговые значения экономической эффективности: за и против

Melanie Y Bertram a,, Jeremy A Lauer a, Kees De Joncheere a, Tessa Edejer a, Raymond Hutubessy a, Marie-Paule Kieny a, Suzanne R Hill a
PMCID: PMC5153921  PMID: 27994285

Abstract

Cost–effectiveness analysis is used to compare the costs and outcomes of alternative policy options. Each resulting cost–effectiveness ratio represents the magnitude of additional health gained per additional unit of resources spent. Cost–effectiveness thresholds allow cost–effectiveness ratios that represent good or very good value for money to be identified. In 2001, the World Health Organization’s Commission on Macroeconomics in Health suggested cost–effectiveness thresholds based on multiples of a country’s per-capita gross domestic product (GDP). In some contexts, in choosing which health interventions to fund and which not to fund, these thresholds have been used as decision rules. However, experience with the use of such GDP-based thresholds in decision-making processes at country level shows them to lack country specificity and this – in addition to uncertainty in the modelled cost–effectiveness ratios – can lead to the wrong decision on how to spend health-care resources. Cost–effectiveness information should be used alongside other considerations – e.g. budget impact and feasibility considerations – in a transparent decision-making process, rather than in isolation based on a single threshold value. Although cost–effectiveness ratios are undoubtedly informative in assessing value for money, countries should be encouraged to develop a context-specific process for decision-making that is supported by legislation, has stakeholder buy-in, for example the involvement of civil society organizations and patient groups, and is transparent, consistent and fair.

What are cost–effectiveness thresholds?

The main results of a cost–effectiveness analysis – in which the costs and outcomes of alternative policy options are compared – are cost–effectiveness ratios. In the field of health, a cost–effectiveness ratio usually represents the amount of additional health gained for each additional unit of resources spent. The makers of health policy initially used cost–effectiveness analyses for priority setting, in their attempts to ensure that the greatest possible health benefits were achieved given the available budget. Many countries currently use cost–effectiveness analyses and the resultant cost–effectiveness ratios to guide their decisions on resource allocation and to compare the efficiencies of alternative health interventions.

A cost–effectiveness threshold is generally set so that the interventions that appear to be relatively good or very good value for money can be identified. There are several types of threshold. In health-related analyses, a willingness-to-pay threshold represents an estimate of what a consumer of health care might be prepared to pay for the health benefit – given other competing demands on that consumer’s resources. There are also supply-side thresholds that take resource allocation into account – e.g. estimates of the health foregone because an insurance company or other provider spends some of its available budget on a new intervention and is therefore forced to reduce its funding of older interventions.

In considering the choice of the type of cost–effectiveness threshold to use, the concept of opportunity cost may be the one most relevant to providers who are primarily concerned with using the available resources to improve health. In considering the implementation of a new intervention, decision-makers need estimates of both the health that might be gained elsewhere through the alternative use of the resources needed for the new intervention and the health that is likely to be lost if the new intervention is not used.

Recent claims about the misapplication of cost–effectiveness thresholds1 are well founded. However, we feel that the implication that the World Health Organization’s (WHO’s) Commission on Macroeconomics and Health’s cost–effectiveness thresholds are intended to be used as the explicit criteria for health decisions at national level – ignoring all other policy-relevant evidence – is incorrect.

Thresholds based on gross domestic product

The most commonly cited cost–effectiveness thresholds are those based upon a country’s per-capita gross domestic product (GDP) and the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health’s corresponding estimate of the economic value of a year of healthy life.2 As ill health has a negative economic impact, investments in health can contribute to economic development. The commission, in trying to encourage investment in health, has suggested that all countries should map out a path to universal access to essential health services, increase domestic financing for health and include economic considerations in their attempts to identify health priorities.2 The commission also suggested that it was reasonable to spend the estimated value of a year of healthy life, per capita, on an intervention that led to a mean of at least one additional year of healthy life per capita.2

The commission’s GDP-related cost–effectiveness thresholds were based on assumptions about leisure time, non-health consumption, longevity and health-related quality of life. They can be compared to measures – e.g. the so-called value of a statistical life – that are based on individuals’ actual choices3 (DT Jamison, personal communication, 2015) and represent an estimate of an individual’s willingness to pay to extend their healthy life by one year. There has been criticism of the commission’s focus on GDP-based thresholds, since “people value life in dimensions that extend beyond income”.4 However, the cost thresholds published by the commission in 20012 are similar to the more detailed – and, perhaps, more reliable – estimates published over a decade later.5

In 2005, authors writing on behalf of WHO’s Choosing Interventions that are Cost–Effective project (WHO-CHOICE) suggested that “interventions that avert one DALY [disability-adjusted life-year] for less than average per capita income for a given country or region are considered very cost–effective; interventions that cost less than three times average per capita income per DALY averted are still considered cost–effective; and those that exceed this level are considered not cost–effective”.6 Although they may indicate that an intervention is cost–effective or very cost–effective, none of these thresholds should be used, alone, as a decision rule for funding or as a measure of affordability. They are simply an indication that, in a given setting, an intervention may represent poor, good or very good value for money.

As used by WHO-CHOICE, the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health’s GDP-based thresholds were only intended to be generic global norms. For example, the list of interventions given in Appendix 3 of the WHO’s Global Action Plan for the Prevention and Control of Noncommunicable Diseases 2013–20207 – i.e. the list of interventions sometimes referred to as the best buys – represents a menu of medical and public health interventions to consider in a range of settings. Although this list was partly based on value for money – in terms of GDP-based cost–effectiveness thresholds – it was also based on affordability, feasibility and other criteria. In a similar manner, in work carried out on behalf of WHO-CHOICE, GDP-based thresholds were used to categorize interventions as cost–effective or very cost–effective but the intention was only to guide policy-makers on value for money.8 It was always assumed and intended that other considerations relevant to local settings would be used in decision-making.

Interpreting WHO-CHOICE’s results

The main objective of WHO-CHOICE is to assist with priority setting across an entire benefits package – and, ultimately, achieve universal health coverage. Other related programmes for priority setting – e.g. the SMART vaccine project9 – use the results of cost–effectiveness analysis only to make incremental or marginal decisions about the addition of single interventions to an existing benefits package. Where the primary goal of a health system is the optimization of population health, it can be important to use an approach such as that followed by WHO-CHOICE – and its generalized cost–effectiveness analysis – to decide which set of interventions, out of a larger group of feasible options, offer the best value for money. The addition of single interventions one at a time, based on incremental analyses, may not result in the optimal use of resources. However, given that many systems already have an existing package of interventions, in some settings there is clearly still a role for incremental analysis.

Misuse of thresholds

Many factors influence the results of cost–effectiveness analyses – e.g. the data used to estimate costs and effects, the choice of comparator and whether or not subgroups of the target population are analysed. Variations in the inputs can have substantial effects on the estimate of a cost–effectiveness ratio. If the analyses do not reflect the policy context accurately, overreliance on cost–effectiveness ratios and a fixed cost–effectiveness threshold, to guide decision-making, may result in the wrong decisions being made.

At a technical level, it is important to note that cost–effectiveness ratios derived from economic modelling are simply estimates – generally based on several assumptions – produced to indicate the potential value for money of one or more interventions. The construction of economic models is prone to problems and errors,1015 but such models can still be a valuable input for decision-making if well-constructed and validated. However, even well-constructed models can produce a range of estimates depending on the assumptions adopted and the formulation of the policy question being evaluated. Use of a rigid cost–effectiveness threshold to determine funding decisions may simply encourage the interested parties to tailor their estimates so that they trigger funding.

Even if estimated accurately, generic GDP-based cost–effectiveness ratios – or other estimates of willingness to pay – do not provide information on affordability, budget impact or the feasibility of implementation. In Peru, a contextualised WHO-CHOICE analysis of breast cancer treatments concluded that addition of trastuzumab to a package of interventions would be cost–effective – i.e. cost less than three times the per-capita GDP per DALY averted.16 However, the costs of adding trastuzumab would exceed Peru’s entire budget for breast cancer treatment.16

Similarly, several analyses have concluded that sofosbuvir is a cost–effective treatment option for some subgroups of patients with hepatitis C.1719 For example, using a cost– effectiveness threshold of 100 000 United States dollars per DALY averted, it was estimated that 83% of hepatitis C patients in the United States of America would be eligible for treatment with the drug.17 However, treatment of all the eligible patients would require a 4% increase in national pharmaceutical spending. Such an increase is probably unaffordable and more cost–effective interventions would probably be crowded out if sofosbuvir were to be offered on such a large scale.

In the detection of tuberculosis, the use of GeneXpert (Cepheid, Sunnyvale, United States of America) – a molecular test for the deoxyribonucleic acid of Mycobacterium tuberculosis – is considered to be a cost–effective intervention that has already been implemented in South Africa.20 Widespread use of the test not only has high initial costs – in terms of laboratory space, GeneXpert machines and staff training – but also depends on a consistent electrical supply.21 In the absence of basic amenities such as regular electricity supply, any GeneXpert machines are likely to remain underused and unable to achieve their modelled levels of efficiency and cost–effectiveness.

From evidence to decision-making

The use of cost–effectiveness ratios in decision-making remains an area without consensus.15 Our view is that a fixed cost–effectiveness threshold should never be used as a stand-alone criterion for decision-making. Above all, the indiscriminate sole use of the most common threshold – of three times the per-capita GDP per DALY averted – in national funding decisions or for setting the price or reimbursement value of a new drug or other intervention must be avoided. WHO-CHOICE has never recommended this practice, which would be a distortion of the intention and meaning of the GDP-based thresholds proposed by the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health.

If a single fixed cost–effectiveness threshold is not to be used – at least, not alone – what are the alternatives? In the development of clinical guidelines, evidence-to-decision frameworks have been developed to guide decision-making.22,23 Explicit guidance on the inclusion of fairness in the decision-making needed to achieve universal health coverage has been published.24 Multi-criteria decision analysis frameworks have also been suggested.25

Based on our experience, we believe that countries should consider establishing a context-specific process for decision-making that is supported by legislation, has stakeholder buy-in and is consistent, fair and transparent. While cost–effectiveness ratios are undoubtedly informative in assessing value for money – from either the supply or demand side – they also need to be considered alongside affordability, budget impact, fairness, feasibility and any other criteria considered important in the local context. The Norwegian Committee on Priority Setting has proposed the use of three criteria – i.e. health benefit, health loss and resources – and suggested differentiating thresholds across the different categories of potential health loss.26

Decision-makers need to have sufficient confidence in the quality and reliability of cost–effectiveness estimates, which, in turn, requires sufficient local capacity for the appraisal of economic models and their outputs. In health systems that have these components in place, a more meaningful local and explicit cost–effectiveness threshold might eventually emerge (Box 1). To ensure better health outcomes and optimal value for money, decision-makers need to use all the relevant data and estimates wisely.

Box 1. Experiences with the use of explicit cost–effectiveness thresholds.

Australia

A retrospective analysis of the recommendations of the Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee found that the implied threshold for a positive recommendation was 46 400 Australian dollars – i.e. 1.35 times the per-capita gross domestic product (GDP) in 1999 – per quality-adjusted life-year (QALY) gained.27 However, it was noted that there was, in fact, no fixed threshold and that other aspects of the related evidence – e.g. confidence in the clinical data – appeared to have been just as important to the committee as estimated cost–effectiveness ratios.27,28 The committee has experts who review all submissions and has the legislative mandate to provide advice on reimbursement prices.

Poland

In 2012, for its decisions on reimbursing the costs of new pharmaceuticals, Poland legislated a cost–effectiveness threshold of three times the per-capita gross GDP per QALY gained.29 Manufacturers who submit applications for reimbursement of the costs of new products are required to provide fully-functional models that allow the evaluation of all the input parameters. Although the impact of the threshold is not yet clear, the prices paid in Poland for certain products appear to be higher than the mean values for the European Union.30

Thailand

In 2007, the subcommittee responsible for the development of Thailand’s national list of essential medicines set a threshold of 100 000 Thai baht – i.e. 0.8 of the per-capita GDP – per QALY gained.31 This threshold, which applies specifically to medicines included on the essential medicines list, has been a particularly powerful tool in price negotiations. For example, it has resulted in price decreases, in Thailand, of 72% for tenofovir and 69% for oxaliplatin.32 Health technology assessments are commissioned through the Health Intervention and Technology Assessment Programme and made independently of any pharmaceutical company. Decisions on the benefit package are made by the National Health Assembly, using societal values, and cost–effectiveness thresholds are therefore not the only aspect taken into consideration.33

United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland

Since at least 2000, the United Kingdom’s National Institute for Health and Care Excellence has used an explicit cost–effectiveness threshold of between 20 000 and 30 000 pounds sterling (£) – i.e. 1.18 and 1.76 times the per-capita GDP in 2000, respectively, but only 0.70 and 1.04 times the corresponding product for 2015, respectively – per QALY gained. If the incremental cost–effectiveness ratio for a new technology falls below £20 000 per quality-adjusted life-year gained, that technology is generally recommended for purchase by the national health system. Technologies that appear less cost–effective may still be recommended if they are for end-of-life care or for diseases associated with short life expectancies that would be extended by the technology. However, when some cancer drugs were consistently found to have cost–effectiveness ratios of more than £30 000 per QALY gained – and were therefore rejected by the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence – an alternative funding mechanism was established. The National Institute’s effective cost–effectiveness threshold – reflecting the likely impact of expenditure on both mortality and morbidity – has been estimated to be £12 936 per QALY gained. This relatively low value probably reflects the displacement of more cost–effective activities by new approvals.34,35

Competing interests:

None declared.

References

  • 1.Marseille E, Larson B, Kazi DS, Kahn JG, Rosen S. Thresholds for the cost–effectiveness of interventions: alternative approaches. Bull World Health Organ. 2015. February 1;93(2):118–24. 10.2471/BLT.14.138206 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Macroeconomics and health: investing in health for economic development. Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2001. Available from: http://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/10665/42435/1/924154550X.pdf [cited 2016 Aug 18].
  • 3.Garber AM, Phelps CE. Economic foundations of cost-effectiveness analysis. J Health Econ. 1997. February;16(1):1–31. 10.1016/S0167-6296(96)00506-1 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Shillcutt SD, Walker DG, Goodman CA, Mills AJ. Cost effectiveness in low- and middle-income countries: a review of the debates surrounding decision rules. Pharmacoeconomics. 2009;27(11):903–17. 10.2165/10899580-000000000-00000 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Jamison DT, Summers LH, Alleyne G, Arrow KJ, Berkley S, Binagwaho A, et al. Global health 2035: a world converging within a generation. Lancet. 2013. December 7;382(9908):1898–955. 10.1016/S0140-6736(13)62105-4 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Hutubessy R, Chisholm D, Edejer TT. Generalized cost-effectiveness analysis for national-level priority-setting in the health sector. Cost Eff Resour Alloc. 2003. December 19;1(1):8. 10.1186/1478-7547-1-8 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Global action plan for the prevention and control of noncommunicable diseases 2013-2020. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2013. Available from: http://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/10665/94384/1/9789241506236_eng.pdf [cited 2016 Aug 18].
  • 8.Hutubessy R, Chisholm D, Edejer TT. Generalized cost-effectiveness analysis for national-level priority-setting in the health sector. Cost Eff Resour Alloc. 2003. December 19;1(1):8. 10.1186/1478-7547-1-8 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Ranking vaccines: a prioritization framework. Phase I: demonstration of concept and a software blueprint. Washington: National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine; 2012. Available from: http://www.nationalacademies.org/hmd/Reports/2012/Ranking-Vaccines-A-Prioritization-Framework-Phase-I.aspx [cited 2016 Mar 15]. [PubMed]
  • 10.Hill SR, Mitchell AS, Henry DA. Problems with the interpretation of pharmacoeconomic analyses: a review of submissions to the Australian Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme. JAMA. 2000. April 26;283(16):2116–21. 10.1001/jama.283.16.2116 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Yong JH, Beca J, Hoch JS. The evaluation and use of economic evidence to inform cancer drug reimbursement decisions in Canada. Pharmacoeconomics. 2013. March;31(3):229–36. 10.1007/s40273-012-0022-5 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Hoomans T, Severens JL, van der Roer N, Delwel GO. Methodological quality of economic evaluations of new pharmaceuticals in the Netherlands. Pharmacoeconomics. 2012. March;30(3):219–27. 10.2165/11539850-000000000-00000 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Oostvogels AJ, De Wit GA, Jahn B, Cassini A, Colzani E, De Waure C, et al. Use of DALYs in economic analyses on interventions for infectious diseases: a systematic review. Epidemiol Infect. 2015. July;143(9):1791–802. 10.1017/S0950268814001940 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Simoens S. Assessment of methodological quality of economic evaluations in belgian drug reimbursement applications. PLoS One. 2013. December 30;8(12):e85411. 10.1371/journal.pone.0085411 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Williams I, Bryan S. Lonely at the top and stuck in the middle? The ongoing challenge of using cost-effectiveness information in priority setting. Comment on “Use of cost-effectiveness data in priority setting decisions: experiences from the national guidelines for heart diseases in Sweden”. Int J Health Policy Manag. 2015. February 15;4(3):185–7. 10.15171/ijhpm.2015.32 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Zelle SG, Vidaurre T, Abugattas JE, Manrique JE, Sarria G, Jeronimo J, et al. Cost-effectiveness analysis of breast cancer control interventions in Peru. PLoS One. 2013. December 10;8(12):e82575. 10.1371/journal.pone.0082575 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Chhatwal J, Kanwal F, Roberts MS, Dunn MA. Cost-effectiveness and budget impact of hepatitis C virus treatment with sofosbuvir and ledipasvir in the United States. Ann Intern Med. 2015. March 17;162(6):397–406. 10.7326/M14-1336 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Petta S, Cabibbo G, Enea M, Macaluso FS, Plaia A, Bruno R, et al. ; WEF Study Group. Cost-effectiveness of sofosbuvir-based triple therapy for untreated patients with genotype 1 chronic hepatitis C. Hepatology. 2014. May;59(5):1692–705. 10.1002/hep.27010 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Linas BP, Barter DM, Morgan JR, Pho MT, Leff JA, Schackman BR, et al. The cost-effectiveness of sofosbuvir-based regimens for treatment of hepatitis C virus genotype 2 or 3 infection. Ann Intern Med. 2015. May 5;162(9):619–29. 10.7326/M14-1313 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Meyer-Rath G, Schnippel K, Long L, MacLeod W, Sanne I, Stevens W, et al. The impact and cost of scaling up GeneXpert MTB/RIF in South Africa. PLoS One. 2012;7(5):e36966. 10.1371/journal.pone.0036966 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Creswell J, Codlin AJ, Andre E, Micek MA, Bedru A, Carter EJ, et al. Results from early programmatic implementation of Xpert MTB/RIF testing in nine countries. BMC Infect Dis. 2014. January 2;14(1):2. 10.1186/1471-2334-14-2 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Guyatt G, Oxman AD, Akl EA, Kunz R, Vist G, Brozek J, et al. GRADE guidelines: 1. Introduction–GRADE evidence profiles and summary of findings tables. J Clin Epidemiol. 2011. April;64(4):383–94. 10.1016/j.jclinepi.2010.04.026 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Schünemann HJ, Mustafa R, Brozek J, Santesso N, Alonso-Coello P, Guyatt G, et al. ; GRADE Working Group. GRADE Guidelines: 16. GRADE evidence to decision frameworks for tests in clinical practice and public health. J Clin Epidemiol. 2016. February 27;S0895-4356(16)00136-0. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Norheim OF, Baltussen R, Johri M, Chisholm D, Nord E, Brock D, et al. Guidance on priority setting in health care (GPS-Health): the inclusion of equity criteria not captured by cost-effectiveness analysis. Cost Eff Resour Alloc. 2014. August 29;12(1):18. 10.1186/1478-7547-12-18 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Angelis A, Kanavos P. Value-based assessment of new medical technologies: towards a robust methodological framework for the application of multiple criteria decision analysis in the context of health technology assessment. Pharmacoeconomics. 2016. May;34(5):435–46. 10.1007/s40273-015-0370-z [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Ottersen T, Førde R, Kakad M, Kjellevold A, Melberg HO, Moen A, et al. A new proposal for priority setting in Norway: open and fair. Health Policy. 2016. March;120(3):246–51. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2016.01.012 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.George B, Harris A, Mitchell A. Cost-effectiveness analysis and the consistency of decision making. Evidence from pharmaceutical reimbursement in Australia (1991 to 1996). Pharmacoeconomics. 2001;19(11):1103–9. 10.2165/00019053-200119110-00004 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Harris AH, Hill SR, Chin G, Li JJ, Walkom E. The role of value for money in public insurance coverage decisions for drugs in Australia: a retrospective analysis 1994-2004. Med Decis Making. 2008. Sep-Oct;28(5):713–22. 10.1177/0272989X08315247 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Jakubiak-Lasocka J, Jakubczyk M. Cost-effectiveness versus cost-utility analyses: what are the motives behind using each and how do their results differ?—A Polish example. Value Health Reg Issues. 2014;4C:66–74. 10.1016/j.vhri.2014.06.008 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Iyengar S, Tay-Teo K, Vogler S, Beyer P, Wiktor S, de Joncheere K, et al. Prices, costs, and affordability of new medicines for hepatitis C in 30 countries: an economic analysis. PLoS Med. 2016. May 31;13(5):e1002032. 10.1371/journal.pmed.1002032 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Thavorncharoensap M, Teerawattananon Y, Natanant S, Kulpeng W, Yothasamut J, Werayingyong P. Estimating the willingness to pay for a quality-adjusted life year in Thailand: does the context of health gain matter? Clinicoecon Outcomes Res. 2013;5:29–36. 10.2147/CEOR.S38062 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Teerawattananon Y, Tritasavit N, Suchonwanich N, Kingkaew P. The use of economic evaluation for guiding the pharmaceutical reimbursement list in Thailand. Z Evid Fortbild Qual Gesundhwes. 2014;108(7):397–404. 10.1016/j.zefq.2014.06.017 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Youngkong S, Baltussen R, Tantivess S, Mohara A, Teerawattananon Y. Multicriteria decision analysis for including health interventions in the universal health coverage benefit package in Thailand. Value Health. 2012. Sep-Oct;15(6):961–70. 10.1016/j.jval.2012.06.006 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Claxton K, Sculpher M, Palmer S, Culyer AJ. Causes for concern: is NICE failing to uphold its responsibilities to all NHS patients? Health Econ. 2015. January;24(1):1–7. 10.1002/hec.3130 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Claxton K, Martin S, Soares M, Rice N, Spackman E, Hinde S, et al. Methods for the estimation of the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence cost-effectiveness threshold. Health Technol Assess. 2015. February;19(14):i–xxxiv, 1–503. 10.3310/hta19140 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Articles from Bulletin of the World Health Organization are provided here courtesy of World Health Organization

RESOURCES