Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2017 Jul 27;12(7):e0181353. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0181353

Foregone benefits of important food crop improvements in Sub-Saharan Africa

Justus Wesseler 1,*, Richard D Smart 2,#, Jennifer Thomson 3,#, David Zilberman 4,#
Editor: Sanjay B Jadhao5
PMCID: PMC5531496  PMID: 28749984

Abstract

A number of new crops have been developed that address important traits of particular relevance for smallholder farmers in Africa. Scientists, policy makers, and other stakeholders have raised concerns that the approval process for these new crops causes delays that are often scientifically unjustified. This article develops a real option model for the optimal regulation of a risky technology that enhances economic welfare and reduces malnutrition. We consider gradual adoption of the technology and show that delaying approval reduces uncertainty about perceived risks of the technology. Optimal conditions for approval incorporate parameters of the stochastic processes governing the dynamics of risk. The model is applied to three cases of improved crops, which either are, or are expected to be, delayed by the regulatory process. The benefits and costs of the crops are presented in a partial equilibrium that considers changes in adoption over time and the foregone benefits caused by a delay in approval under irreversibility and uncertainty. We derive the equilibrium conditions where the net-benefits of the technology equal the costs that would justify a delay. The sooner information about the safety of the technology arrive, the lower the costs for justifying a delay need to be i.e. it pays more to delay. The costs of a delay can be substantial: e.g. a one year delay in approval of the pod-borer resistant cowpea in Nigeria will cost the country about 33 million USD to 46 million USD and between 100 and 3,000 lives.

Introduction

There is uncertainty and confusion in many of the African governments’ responses to a wide range of social, ethical, environmental, trade and economic issues associated with the development and application of modern genetic engineering. The absence of an African consensus and strategic approaches to address these emerging biotechnology issues has allowed different interest groups to exploit uncertainty in policymaking, regardless of what may be the objective situation for Africa.” [1]

A number of new crops have been developed that address important traits of relevance to smallholder farmers in Africa [2]. A sizeable body of literature (see survey by [3]) argues that flows in the regulatory system, partially caused by political economic considerations [4], caused scientifically unjustified delays in the approval process for these new crops. Such delays often result in the bizarre situation where technologies that both increase consumer and producer surplus also have the potential for meaningfully decreasing malnutrition, fail to reach the market. The objective of this paper is to assess the costs caused by those delays under uncertainty and irreversibility.

In this article we investigate three genetically engineered (GE) crops for Africa in more detail, namely disease resistant cooking banana (matoke), and insect resistant cowpea, and corn (maize). A yield increase for those crops can improve the dietary energy supply and have a positive impact on malnutrition [5].

The disease resistant banana [6] and herbicide resistant corn [7] have been available for field trials since the mid- to late 2000s, while the herbicide resistant cowpea has recently received approval for field trials in Nigeria [8]. Although delays for the corn and banana have already been observed, further delays can be expected, including for cowpea.

Despite the clear link between agricultural productivity and malnourishment, many countries in Africa are reluctant to approve GE crops. African governments find themselves juxtaposed between the opponents and proponents of the technology.

Here, we develop a theoretical model assessing the benefits and costs of approval processes using a real option framework calling upon the ‘Santaniello Theorem of Irreversible Benefits’ [9]. The model explicitly considers the standard welfare measures of changes in producer and consumer surplus. Many studies on GE crops have focused on the economic surplus at farm, regional, or sector levels. We contribute to the literature by also considering the effects of GE crops on malnutrition, which is an effect often acknowledged (e.g. [10]), but has received scant attention in the economic literature (notable exceptions: Vitamin A enriched rice [11,12], bio-fortified cassava [13]).

We calculate the foregone benefits caused by a delay in approval under irreversibility and uncertainty, and threshold values that would justify a delay. We consider differences in the approval time of a new crop, and derive the equilibrium conditions (where the net-benefits of the technology equal potential costs) that would justify a delay. We calibrate the model for the three crops considered to indicate the magnitude of the effects, and crucially, the economic and humanitarian consequences of delaying approvals.

The results show that about two thirds of uncertainty is sufficient to compensate for three thirds of certainty. Delays are costly and the effects on malnutrition can sometimes exceed the effects on producer and consumer surplus, and may even be much larger, especially for the case of cowpea (a protein-rich crop) as we only consider the crops’ energy content.

Approval delays of GE crops in Africa

Bt cotton was the first GE crop approved for cultivation in Africa and was introduced into South Africa in 1997, followed by yellow and white corn in 1998 and 2001, respectively [14]. The first field trials of GE crops in South Africa started in 1989. It took seed companies about nine years to identify and multiply the appropriate corn varieties, a time frame that is usual in plant breeding. If the private sector had approached Kenya or other African countries simultaneously, it is reasonable to expect that local corn varieties with insect- and herbicide resistance would have also been available shortly after the year 2000. In Kenya the first varieties for release were recommended in 1998 [15]. The National Agricultural Research Organisation of Uganda (NARO) submitted applications to the Uganda National Council for Science and Technology (UNCST) in 2000 to introduce Bt cotton and Bt corn, but their approval for confined field trials was denied [16]. One of the reasons the UNCST gave was that Uganda was unprepared to handle GE crops because it lacked a national biotechnology and biosafety policy. The progress of the Insect Resistant Maize for Africa Project (IRMA) was similarly delayed by regulatory issues [17].

In Kenya, under the IRMA (started in 1999) [18] and the Water Efficient Maize for Africa (WEMA, started in 2008) projects for insect and drought resistant corn, varieties are under development with field trials at different stages. Kenya banned the import and cultivation of GE crops in 2012 due to health concerns [19], but is currently considering removing the ban [20]. If the development of this crop under the IRMA project had proceeded as planned and approval not been delayed, the first varieties would have appeared on farmers’ fields in 2006 [18].

In Uganda, field trials with black sigatoka (also known as black leaf streak) resistant matoke (cooking banana) started in 2007 [21]. A bacterial wilt resistant matoke is under development. Field trials have been in place since 2011 [22], and its release to farmers is expected in 2020.

Research in Benin, Niger, and Nigeria (under the coordination of the African Agricultural Technology Foundation (AATF)) to develop cowpea resistant to pod borers started in 2008. Confined field trials commenced in 2010, and it is expected that seeds will be available for farmers by 2017, subject to approval from regulatory agencies [23]. An overview about the regulatory status of the three crops considered is presented in Table 1.

Table 1. Status of crops considered.

Country Benin, Niger, Nigeria[24] Kenya[17,18] Uganda[21]
Crop Cowpea (Vigna unguiculata) White Corn Matoke
Trait Insect resistance Insect resistance, stress tolerance Black sigatoka resistance, Bacterial Wilt Resistance
genetic event/ genes introduced Cry1Ab Examples: MON810, Event 176, Event 5207 Chitinase gene (Black Sigatoka), hypersensitivity response-assisting protein (Hrap) gene from sweet pepper (bacterial wilt).
Partners Involved AATF, CSIRO, IAR, IITA, INERA, Monsanto Company, NARS, NGICA, The Kirkhouse Trust AATF, KALRO (former KARI), CIMMYT, Monsanto Company, University of Ottawa, NARS, Syngenta Foundation, Rockefeller Foundation, USAID Academia Sinica, NARO, IRAZ, IITA, Public and private tissue culture laboratories in the Great Lakes region of Africa including Burundi, Democratic Republic of Congo, Kenya, Rwanda, Tanzania and Uganda
Regulatory Status confined field trials since 2011 National Performance Trials (NPT) since 2004 confined field trials since 2007
Expected releasea 2017b Since 2006c Since 2007d
2020
Country Policy Cartagena Protocol signed in 2000 Cartagena Protocol signed in 2000
National cultivation and import ban since 2012.
Cartagena Protocol signed in 2000

Sources: references mentioned and project websites: http://aatf-africa.org/.

aExpected release refers to reports. As none has been released so far early dates indicate regulator delays.

bExpected by 2017 depending on regulatory approval.

cAccording to KARI and CIMMYT, first varieties should have reached farmers field by 2006, while first recommendations for release have been submitted in 1998.

dThe status of the Black Sigatoka resistant banana is not known. Several experts involved in the research as well as the deregulation had been contacted. For the bacterial wilt resistant banana confined field trials are undertaken and release to farmers is expected for 2020.

Abbreviations: AATF: African Agricultural Technology Foundation, CIMMYT: International Maize and Wheat Improvement Center, CSIRO: Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation, IAR Institute of Agricultural Research, Zaria, Nigeria, IITA: International Institute of Tropical Agriculture, INERA: Institut de l’Environnement et de Recherches Agricoles, Burkina Faso, IRAZ: Institut de recherche agronomique et zootechnique, KALRO: Kenya Agricultural and Livestock Research Organisation, NARO: National Agricultural Research Organisation of Uganda, NGICA: Network for the Genetic Improvement of Cowpea for Africa, NARS: National Agricultural Research Systems in target countries of west Africa.

Further, Benin, Kenya, Niger, Nigeria, and Uganda signed the Cartagena Protocol in 2000 [25]. The interpretation at national level is that they must first have a biosafety law in place before approving GE crops for cultivation. The protocol does, however, provide exemptions under Article 11 in cases where countries have not yet passed a biosafety law [26]. Nevertheless, in Africa, the development of a biosafety law is often used as an instrument in the political process to delay the introduction of GE crops [4].

Benefits and costs of delay

We are interested in the minimum additional costs that policy makers implicitly perceive would justify postponing the introduction of the crops considered. The model used is explained in detail in S1 File The General Analytical Model: In particular, we assume that the policy makers know with certainty the benefits of the crops in terms of consumer and producer surplus, and malnourishment, but are uncertain about the wider impact. Those uncertainties are modelled as a random shock. Thus, to account for this uncertainty there is a threshold of the benefit from the use of the technology one period earlier that has to be exceeded at each moment in order to approve the technology for use—otherwise the regulator should delay the decision by one or more periods to gain more information. We computed that this threshold of benefits is the expected cost of earlier adoption multiplied by a coefficient that is decreasing as the variability of the cost affecting the random shock is increasing (see eq. 13 in S1 File The General Analytical Model). Our analysis shows that for a delay in approval, the increase in benefit by one dollar under reasonable assumptions requires only an increase in the cost of adoption of about 2/3 of a dollar. Thus, the tendency to overregulate the technology may be explained by the low cost of regulation relative to the benefit of adopting the technology.

The expected economic benefits of cultivating Bt corn [7], Bt cowpea [27], and disease resistant bananas [6] are expected to be substantial. The total surplus reported by studies using partial equilibrium models range from 280 to 360 million USD, 90 to 154 million USD, and 6 to 48 million USD, for bananas, cowpea, and corn, respectively (Table 2). We use this information and apply the linear supply and demand model with a logistic adoption function (see S1 File The General Analytical Model for the details) to calculate the expected average annual consumer and producer surplus. We report the results for a range of supply and demand elasticities commonly found in the literature for these crops [28, 29] (Table C in S1 Table). If not mentioned otherwise, results are reported for short-run own demand and supply elasticity of -0.3 and 0.6, respectively.

Table 2. Benefits and costs of GE crops considered.

Crop Banana Cowpea Corn
Country Uganda[6] Benin, Niger, Nigeria[27] Kenya[7]
Traits disease resistance (black sigatoka, bacterial wilt) pest resistance (maruca pod borer) pest resistance (stem borers)
Benefits reduced damage loss, better quality reduced damage loss, less mycotoxins reduced damage loss, less mycotoxins,
Δ Yield/ha 2.0t (20%) 12.5% 0.06–0.3t
Δ Rev/ha 280–450 USD 10–55 USD
Δ PS/a 280–360 Mio. USD -61–186 Mio. USD 2.0–16.1 Mio. USD
Δ CS/a -31–77 Mio. USD 4.0–32.2 Mio. USD
Δ TS/a 280–360 Mio. USD 90–154 Mio. USD 6.0–48.3 Mio. USD
K-Shift 0.16 (19.8%) 0.10 (12.5%) 0.11 (13.4%)

Note: results derived from the studies mentioned for each country in the superscript.

The Country-level cost of stunting

The changes in consumer and producer surplus exclude additional benefits that might arise due to changes in malnutrition. Assessing those benefits requires information about malnutrition and related costs. We measure effects on malnutrition by using changes in stunting, as those are well documented. Stunting reflects a failure of the human body to reach linear growth potential because of suboptimal health and/or nutritional conditions (see S2 File Calculating the Costs of Stunting for the details). Stunting at national level represents the percentage of children below the age of five years with more than minus two standard deviations below the median height-for-age of the World Health Organization (WHO) Child Growth Standards [30].

Table 3 gives an overview of malnutrition in the five countries we consider, and forms part of the data we use for calculating changes in malnutrition. More than ten percent of stunted children worldwide live in these countries. Nigeria has the worst situation with more than 11 million stunted children, followed by Kenya and Uganda. The situation is worse in rural than in urban areas, except in Niger.

Table 3. Status of malnourishment in Benin, Niger, and Nigeria, Kenya, and Uganda for the year 2011 [30].

Benin Niger Nigeria Kenya Uganda
Cowpea Corn Matoke
Children below six (thousand) 1546 3196 27195 6805 6638
Stuntinga in per cent of children below five years of age 43 (<1) 51 (1.0) 41 (6.8) 35 (1.5) 33 (1.4)
Children stunted (thousand) 572 1,585 10,029 1,839 2,318
Children stunted rural areas (thousand) 337 763 5,938 1015 1405
Consumption (kg per head and year of crop) 9[31]b 1.5[31]b 18[31]b 98[32] 300[33]
Consumption increase (kg per year) 2.25 0.375 4.5 14 60
Calories supplied by yield increase per year 2610 435 5220 51100 53400
Per cent of demand ≅ effect on stunting in per cent[34] 0.51 0.09 1.02 10.00 10.48
Current costs of stunting (Mio USD per year) 572 1,585 10,029 1,839 2,318
Current costs of stunting in rural areas (Mio USD per year) 337 763 5,938 1015 1405
Cost reduction (Mio USD/year) 1.72 0.65 60.66 101.54 146.83
Cost reduction (Mio USD/year)c[5] 0.48 0.18 16.85 10.53 15.23

Note: Current costs per country estimated by 1000 USD per stunted child.

aNumber in brackets indicate world share.

bGrams per day per household multiplied by 365 and divided by 5 members per household, providing a range between 2.99 and 14.60 kg per year. A value of 10kg per year has been chosen.

cBased on estimations by Smith and Haddad.

Calculating the costs related to stunting is not a trivial exercise. The costs include those related to early childhood death and losses in labour productivity. We use the number provided by The World Bank [35] on productivity losses caused by stunting for Africa and Asia of 1,000 USD per child below the age of five years (present value). The details of our calculations are provided in the supplement (Calculating the Costs of Stunting). The current costs of stunting in rural areas (Mio USD per year) are very much on the low side. Other estimations show much higher costs [36].

Results—The cost of regulatory policy

A delay in approval results in welfare losses due to foregone benefits. In our analysis the foregone benefits include: foregone consumer and producer surplus, and foregone reductions in malnutrition (measured as reduced stunting among children). The results shown in Fig 1 and in S1A Table, assume an immediate introduction of the GE crops and report the resultant consumer and producer surplus, plus the benefits of reduced stunting. In general, the consumer surplus is twice as large as the producer surplus for η is -0.3 and ε is 0.6. The total surplus (net present value) is the largest for GE matoke in Uganda with about 1,300 million USD, followed in descending order by: cowpea in Nigeria with about 710 million USD, corn in Kenya with about 475 million USD, and cowpea in Niger and in Benin with about 375 million USD and about 47 million USD, respectively. The average annual consumer and producer surplus is reported in brackets (Table 4).

Fig 1. Consumer and producer surplus, benefits of reduced malnutrition, minimum amount of government perceived costs for a one year delay in approval (million USD).

Fig 1

Note. Parameter values: adoption ceiling of 40% after 20 years; discount rate r = 0.04; d = 0.5; elasticity of supply ε = 0.6, elasticity of demand η = -0.3.

Table 4. Foregone benefits (consumer and producer surplus, benefits of reduced malnutrition) for a one and ten year delay in approval (million USD).

Benin Niger Nigeria Kenya Uganda
Cowpea Corn Matoke
1 year 10 year 1 year 10 year 1 year 10 year 1 year 10 year 1 year 10 year
Foregone: - consumer surplus 1.23 10.33 9.82 82.60 18.65 156.80 12.42 104.46 34.87 293.16
 - producer surplus 0.61 5.17 4.91 41.30 9.32 78.40 6.21 52.23 17.43 146.58
 - total surplus 1.84 15.50 14.74 123.91 27.97 235.19 18.64 156.69 52.30 439.74
 - reduced stunting 0.53 4.44 0.20 1.68 18.61 156.49 31.16 261.96 45.05 378.78
 - reduced stuntingSH[5] 0.15 1.23 0.06 0.47 5.17 43.47 3.23 27.17 4.67 39.28
Total 2.37 19.93 14.94 125.58 46.58 391.68 49.79 418.65 97.35 818.52
TotalSH 1.99 16.73 14.79 124.37 33.14 278.66 21.87 183.86 56.97 479.02

Note: superscript SH denotes calculation for malnutrition based on Smith and Haddad. Parameter values: adoption ceiling of 40% after 20 years; discount rate r = 0.04; d = 0.5; elasticity of supply ε = 0.6, elasticity of demand η = -0.3.

The effect of alleviating malnutrition by using GE crops can be substantial. In Kenya, the benefits from reduced malnutrition can be larger than the total economic surplus. The benefits from reduced malnutrition can be up to about 1,150 million USD for matoke in Uganda, followed by about 795 million USD for corn in Kenya. The effects are also substantial for cowpea in Nigeria with about 475 million USD, while they are smaller for Benin with about 13 million USD and Nigeria with about five million USD. The average annual benefits of reduced stunting reported in Fig 1 are lower than those in Table 3 as adoption over time has been taken into consideration (40 percent ceiling reached after 20 years) for the former.

The minimum perceived costs by national governments that would justify a delay from a welfare economic viewpoint are lower than the welfare benefits: They are about 68 percent (based on the following: discount rate of 0.04, value of d = 0.5, demand elasticity of -0.3, supply elasticity of 0.6, and an adoption ceiling of 40 percent reached after 20 years) (see Fig 1). The minimum perceived costs are the lowest for Benin (about 40 to 48 million USD), and the highest for Uganda (about 1,160 to 1,983 million USD). The perceived costs increase with an increase in the time of delay, for e.g., an increase in delay from one to ten years increases the perceived costs, c.p., by about 17 percent (see S1A Table). Placing these numbers in perspective (Fig 2) shows their importance: They are similar to Niger’s health budget and more than three times Uganda’s health budget.

Fig 2. Comparing government perceived costs with health budget of 2014 [37].

Fig 2

Note. Parameter values: adoption ceiling of 40% after 20 years; discount rate r = 0.04; d = 0.5; elasticity of supply ε = 0.6, elasticity of demand η = -0.3.

Table 4 reports the forgone benefits caused by delays in approval, which range between about 2 million USD and 97 million USD, and about 17 million USD and 818 million USD for a one and ten year delay, respectively. As with the share of benefits from reduced malnutrition, the share of foregone benefits of reduced malnutrition can be substantial. In Kenya (similar to the results reported above), these benefits can be larger than the foregone economic surplus.

Fig 3 and S1B Table report the results of changes in the adoption ceiling, as well as the speed of adoption expressed in lives lost, which illustrate the effects of the GE crops on food deficient households. We report results for 40, 80, and 100 percent adoption ceilings and two rates of adoption: Ceiling reached after 20 and 10 years, respectively. The number of lives lost by delaying the introduction range between about 200 and 5,500, depending on the speed of adoption, adoption ceiling, and the method used for calculating malnourishment. The results illustrate that a higher adoption ceiling has a much stronger effect on the death toll than a higher adoption rate (Fig 2).

Fig 3. Comparison of doubling the speed of adoption and the ceiling of adoption.

Fig 3

Note. Parameter values: discount rate r = 0.04; d = 0.5; elasticity of supply ε = 0.6, elasticity of demand η = -0.3. See Table C in S1 Table for different elasticities.

The effect of the length in delay, as well as changes in the discount rate for different levels of d on the perceived government costs, are shown in Fig 4. The share of perceived costs needed to compensate one unit of welfare benefits decreases with an increase in d at a decreasing rate. The effect of a marginal change in the discount rate is the same as a marginal change in the length of the delay (see equation 13 in S1 File The General Analytical Model). The lower the value of d, the larger the effect of marginal changes in d (i.e. a relatively high elasticity) on changes in the perceived costs of the government.

Fig 4. Effect of changes in government perceived costs (d) on cost needed to compensate for one unit of benefit for different discount rates, r, and length in delay, T.

Fig 4

The effects of delaying the introduction of a GE crop on foregone benefits also depend on the demand and supply elasticities. The results reported so far were based on a demand elasticity of −0.3 and a supply elasticity of 0.6. Foregone benefits have also been calculated for lower and higher elasticity values (see S1C Table). In general, we observe that a change in the demand elasticity has a less pronounced effect than a change in the supply elasticities. Overall, the effect of changes in the elasticities on foregone benefits are less pronounced than changes in adoption ceiling.

Discussion and conclusion

For opponents of the technology, announcing uncertainty about the GE crops shortly before decisions are to be made about them can be an effective tool for delaying their introduction. High uncertainty reduces the perceived costs needed (about two thirds) to compensate for one unit of welfare benefits. This uncertainty eases the opponents’ success in delaying approval compared to the proponents’ efforts at speeding up the approval process. This finding also applies to cases not discussed by us and to the approval process for GE crops in general. Delays in approval have been observed for countries outside of Africa too [38, 39]. The results further support the findings by Tosun et al. [40] that show opponents compared with proponents of GE crops time their activities better, have much larger networks, and are more active.

Few studies have investigated the costs of a delay. Most ex-ante studies identify the benefits and costs of the introduction of a new GE crop, which are different to those of a delay. Nevertheless, estimating producer and consumers surplus is an important step. The producer and consumer surplus we report for the three crops are somewhat lower than those reported by others [6, 7, 27]. In comparison to previous studies on the benefits and costs of GE crops, we include their effect on malnutrition, which we show can be substantial. For Kenya, the effect on malnutrition can even be larger than the effect on producer and consumer surplus. This illustrates that in countries where malnutrition is of importance the effect should be considered in the analysis of welfare effects. This further illustrates that the effect on malnutrition of GE crops and other yield increasing strategies deserve attention, so that their economic and humanitarian effects are not underestimated.

Kenya and Uganda (and many other African countries) had the chance to follow South Africa’s example of adopting GE crops. If Kenya had adopted GE corn in 2006—according to the reports of the IRMA project this was possible—between 440 and 4,000 lives could theoretically have been saved. Similarly, Uganda had the possibility in 2007 to introduce the black sigatoka resistant banana, thereby potentially saving between 500 and 5,500 lives over the past decade. The introduction of Bt cowpea is expected to be in 2017 in Benin, Niger, and Nigeria. The AATF has already indirectly expressed concerns about reaching this goal by explicitly mentioning the phrase: “depending on approvals” [41]. A one-year delay in approval would especially harm Nigeria, as malnourishment is widespread there. The consumption of cowpea per capita is higher than in both Benin and Niger. A one-year delay is estimated to cost Nigeria about 33 million USD to 46 million USD and between 100 and 3,000 lives.

Our results might have underestimated the cost of delay, especially in evaluating the benefit of adopting insect resistant cowpea, as we only consider the energy content of this crop. Further, environmental and health benefits from reduced pesticide use for pest and disease control are not explicitly included—an important area for future research.

Nevertheless, our results show that delaying the approval of GE crops not only reduces consumer and producer surplus of households (mainly in rural areas), but importantly, it also costs human lives. We have expressed the effects of a one-year delay on lives lost. The death toll can be substantial. Reducing the approval time of GE crops results in generating economic gains, potentially contributing to reducing malnutrition and saving lives, and can be an inexpensive strategy for reaching the Sustainable Development Goal of eradicating malnutrition by 2030.

Unfortunately, the use of GE crops has been very controversial. African governments are in the dilemma as they face contradicting statements from international organizations. While those organizations (e.g. the UN [42]) stress the importance of addressing malnutrition and urge countries to use modern biotechnology, they also warn about the environmental risks of using the technologies [43]. Unsurprisingly, governments are uncertain about which is the right strategy to follow. We have calculated the economic value of this uncertainty, which is substantial and costs lives. As already mentioned, about two thirds of uncertainty are sufficient to compensate for three thirds of certainty.

Supporting information

S1 File. The General Analytical Model.

(DOCX)

S2 File. Calculating the costs of stunting.

(DOCX)

S1 Table

(DOCX)

Data Availability

All relevant data are within the paper and its Supporting Information files.

Funding Statement

The authors received no specific funding for this work.

References

  • 1.African Union. An African Position on Genetically Modified Organisms in Agriculture. Conference of African Union Ministers of Agriculture, Libreville, Gabon, 27 November–1 December 2006. http://www.africaunion.org/root/au/AUC/Departments/HRST/biosafety/conference/2007/August/GMOs_paper.doc. Cited 2 May 2016.
  • 2.Qaim M. Genetically Modified Crops and Agricultural Development. Hampshire UK: Palgrave Macmillan; 2016. [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Bennett AB, Chi-Ham C, Barrows G, Sexton S, Zilberman D. Agricultural biotechnology: economics, environment, ethics, and the future. Annu Rev Environ Resour. 2013;38:19.1–19.31. [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Paarlberg R. Starved for Science: How Biotechnology is Being Kept Out of Africa. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; 2008. [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Smith LC, Haddad L. Reducing Child Undernutrition: Past Drivers and Priorities for the Post-MDG Era. World Dev. 2015;68: 180–204. [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Kikulwe E, Falck-Zepeda J, Wesseler J. Incremental Benefits of Genetically modified Bananas in Uganda In Castle D, Phillips P, Smyth S, editors. Handbook on Agriculture, Biotechnology and Development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar; 2014. pp. 793–807. [Google Scholar]
  • 7.De Groote H, Overholt WA, Ouma JO, Wanyama J. Assessing the potential economic impact of Bacillus thuringiensis (Bt) maize in Kenya. African Journal of Biotechnology 2011;10: 4741–4751. [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Addae P. The African Agricultural Technology Foundation. Pers. comm. by telephone on 15 July 2014.
  • 9.Wesseler J. The Santaniello Theorem of Irreversible Benefits. AgBioForum. 2009;12: 8–13. [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Santaniello V. Agricultural biotechnology: implications for food security. Agr Econ. 2005;32 (Issue Supplement s1): 189–197. [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Stein A, Sachdev H, Qaim M. Genetic Engineering for the Poor: Golden Rice and Public Health in India. World Dev. 2008;36:144–158. [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Wesseler J, Zilberman D. The Economic Power of the Golden Rice Opposition. Environ Dev Econ. 2014;19: 724–742. [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Nguema A, Norton GW, Fregene M, Sayre R, Manary M. Expected economic benefits of meeting nutritional needs through bio-fortified cassava in Nigeria and Kenya. AfJARE. 2011; 6(1): 70–86. [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Gouse M. Socioeconomic and Farm-Level Effects of Genetically Modified Crops: The Case of Bt Crops in South Africa In: Falck-Zepeda J, Gruere G, Sithole-Niang I, editors. Genetically Modified Crops in Africa. Washington DC: International Food Policy Research Institute; 2014. pp. 25–42. [Google Scholar]
  • 15.KARI and CIMMYT. Insect Resistant Maize for Africa (IRMA) Project Annual Report 2002. KARI/CIMMYT IRMA Project. IRMA Project Document No. 10. Mexico D.F: KARI and CIMMYT; 2003.
  • 16.Wafula D, Clark N. Science and governance of modern biotechnology in Sub-Saharan Africa—the case of Uganda. J Int Dev. 2005; 17: 679–694. [Google Scholar]
  • 17.KARI and CIMMYT. Insect Resistant Maize for Africa Annual Report 2006. KARI/CIMMYT IRMA Project. IRMA Project Document No. 27. Mexico D.F.: KARI and CIMMYT; 2007.
  • 18.KARl and CIMMYT. Insect Resistant Maize for Africa Annual Report 2003–2004.” KARI/CIMMYT IRMA Project. Project Document No. 20. Mexico D.F.: KARl and CIMMYT; 2005.
  • 19.Snipes K, Kamau C. Kenya Bans Genetically Modified Food Imports. GAIN Report Kenia November 27. Washington DC: USDA; 2012. [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Gebre S. Kenyan Authority Recommends Lifting of Ban on GM Corn Imports. Bloomberg. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-01-06/kenyan-authority-recommends-lifting-of-ban-on-gm-corn-imports. Cited 6 January 2016.
  • 21.Falck-Zepeda J, Guère G, Sithole-Niang I. 2013. What Role for Genetically Modified Crops in the African Countries South of the Sahara? Washington DC: International Food Policy Research Institute; 2013. [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Meldolesi A. GM bananas. Nat Biotechnol. 2011;29(6):472. [Google Scholar]
  • 23.AATF. Maruca-Resistant Cowpea. Progress Report 2012. Nairobi: AATF; 2012.
  • 24.AATF. Podborer Resistant Cowpea. http://cowpea.aatf-africa.org/. Cited 16 June 2016.
  • 25.Secretariat of the Convention on Biological Diversity. 2016. Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety Ratification List. https://bch.cbd.int/protocol/parties/. Cited 16 June 2016.
  • 26.Falck-Zepeda J, Wesseler J, Smyth S. The current status of the debate on socio-economic regulatory assessments: positions and policies in Canada, the USA, the EU and developing countries. World Review of Science & Technology and Sustainable Development 2013;10(4):203–227. [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Gbègbèlègbè SD, Lowenberg-DeBoer J, Adeoti R, Lusk J, Coulibaly O. The estimated ex ante economic impact of Bt cowpea in Niger, Benin and Northern Nigeria. Agric Econ. 2015;46: 563–577. [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Magrini E, Balie J, Opazo CM. Price signals and supply responses for staple food crops in SSA countries. Discussion Paper 1601. Department für Agrarökonomie und Rurale Entwicklung, Georg-August-University Göttingen; 2016.
  • 29.Kumar P., Kumar A., Parappurathu S., and Raju S.S.. Estimation of Demand Elasticity for Food Commodities in India. Agricultural Economics Research Review. 2011;24: 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  • 30.UNICEF. Improving Child Nutrition. New York: UNICEF; 2013. [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Mamiro PS, Mbwaga AM, Mamiro DP, Mwanri AW, Kinabo JL. Nutritional Quality and Utilization of Local and Improved Cowpea Varieties in Some Regions in Tanzania. AJFAND. 2011;11(1): 4490–4506. [Google Scholar]
  • 32.ACDI/VOCA. Kenya–Kenya Maize Development Program (KMDP). http://acdivoca.org/our-programs/project-profiles/kenya-kenya-maize-development-program-kmdp. Cited 2 May 2016.
  • 33.Englberger L, Darnton-Hill I, Coyne T, Fitzgerald MH, Marks GC. Carotenoid-rich bananas: A potential food source for alleviating vitamin A deficiency. Food Nutr Bull. 2003;24(4): 303–318. doi: 10.1177/156482650302400401 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Gómez C. Cowpea: Post-Harvest Operations. Rome: FAO; 2004. [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Shekar M. The Costs of Stunting. Washington DC: The World Bank; 2013. [Google Scholar]
  • 36.World Food Programme. WFP in Africa 2013 Facts, Figures, and Partners. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia: WFP Africa Office to the AU & UNECA; 2014. [Google Scholar]
  • 37.The World Bank. Health expenditure, public (% of GDP). <http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SH.XPD.PUBL.ZS>; 2017.
  • 38.Smart R, Blum M, Wesseler J. Trends in Genetically Engineered Crops’ Approval Times in the United States and the European Union. J Agr Econ. 2016; 68(1): 182–198. [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Herring R. State science, risk and agricultural biotechnology: Bt cotton to Bt Brinjal in India. J Peasant Stud. 2015;42 (1): 159–186. [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Tosun J, Schaub S, Smart RD, Wesseler J. 2016. Sympathy for the Devil? Policy Activism and Voting Behaviour of EU Member States on the Approval of Genetically Modified Organisms. Paper presented at the 20th International Conference of International Consortium of Applied Bioeconomy Research, Ravello, Italy, June 26–29.
  • 41.AATF. Maruca Resistant Cowpea. Frequently Asked Questions. http://www.aatf-africa.org/userfiles/CowpeaFAQ.pdf. Cited 4 June 2017.
  • 42.FAO. The State of Food and Agriculture: Food Systems for better Nutrition. Rome: FAO; 2013. [Google Scholar]
  • 43.Sekanjako H. FAO warns against genetically modified foods. New Vision. http://www.newvision.co.ug/new_vision/news/1315374/fao-warns-genetically-modified-foods. Cited 20 May 2016.

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

S1 File. The General Analytical Model.

(DOCX)

S2 File. Calculating the costs of stunting.

(DOCX)

S1 Table

(DOCX)

Data Availability Statement

All relevant data are within the paper and its Supporting Information files.


Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES