Abstract
The expansion of higher education witnessed in many societies influences the pattern of educational assortative mating. Structural transition theory predicts growing educational homogamy due to increasing preference for highly-educated partners who become more widely available. In contrast, social closure theory suggests depressed educational homogamy because the inflation of the education elite circle fosters the openness of marriage market, reducing the preference for a highly-educated mate and increasing the penetrability across social-status boundaries. Capitalizing the survey data that are representative of the post-80s one-child generation collected in Shanghai, China, we test the hypotheses derived from the two theories. Empirical results suggest that, with increasing availability of highly educated individuals, the extent of educational homogamy by birth cohort reveals a U-shaped pattern. This U-shaped pattern demonstrates increasing levels of educational homogamy and lends support to structural transition theory.
Keywords: Educational Homogamy, Higher Education Expansion, Post-80s Generation, China
INTRODUCTION
Educational attainment is associated with many desirable outcomes, such as higher economic status, better health condition, and happiness (e.g., Hartog and Oosterbeek 1998; Hout 2012). It benefits not only the individual, but also his or her partner in a union (Lefgren and Mclntyre 2006). It is not a surprise that an individual’s educational attainment is always valued in mate selection. However, the number of highly-educated individuals is finite in a society. This structural constraint, along with the general preference for an educated partner, determines that, educated individuals tend to marry each other, leaving the less-educated either unmarried or married with someone of similar educational attainment. As a result, a pattern of “like marries like,” or educational assortative mating (EAM henceforth), would emerge (e.g., Blossfeld 2009; Blossfeld and Timm 2003; Kalmijn 1994, 1998; Qian and Preston 1993; Qian 1998; Schwartz 2013; Schwartz and Mare 2005; Smits, Ultee, and Lammers 1998; Smits and Park 2009).
The extent of EAM is intrinsically related to men’s and women’s educational compositions. Over the past decades, more men and women have received college education around the world (Carnoy et al. 2013; Schofer and Meyer 2005). This trend has fundamentally altered marriage markets and borne implications for EAM. For instance, educational expansion has been cited by scholars as one important social force in shaping the pattern of EAM in the U.S. (e.g., Mare 2016), Britain and Ireland (Halpin and Chan 2003), South Korea (Park and Smits 2005), Spain (Esteve and Cortina 2006), Norway (Birkelund and Heldal 2003), China (Han 2010), Hong Kong (Zhou 2016), Latin America (Esteve, McCaa, and Lopez 2013), and Eastern Europe (Katrnak, Kreidl, and Fonadova 2006), to name a few. Also, variation in the extent of the expansion of formal education has been serving to account for cross-national variations in EAM, as suggested by Monaghan (2015), Smits (2003), and Smits and Park (2009). Besides these studies, what is especially worth mentioning is the research into the direct relationship between education and marriage. Rauscher (2015), in this regard, illustrates how the effect of the early U.S. compulsory schooling laws on EAM varies between the North and the South. The study of Musick, Brand, and Davis (2012) shows that marital sorting based on non-educational attributes might be strengthened within educational expansion, resulting in a lesser extent of EAM for college-goers with disadvantaged background.
Despite the large volume of studies on EAM, prior literature nevertheless does not reach a consensus pertaining to the relationship between higher education expansion and EAM. Regarding this question, different theoretical arguments have been proposed. Specifically, structural transition theory (STT henceforth) posits that higher education expansion gives rise to the extent of EAM by enlarging the pool of similarly-educated individuals and cultivating the preference for a well-educated partner (e.g., Blau and Schwartz 1984; Blossfeld and Timm 2003; Sweeney 2002; Sweeney and Cancian 2004).1 In contrast, status closure theory (SCT henceforth) hypothesizes a decline in educational homogamy within educational expansion, due to the increasingly penetrable educational boundaries on the marriage market and declining preference for a highly-educated mate (Smits 2003; Smits, Ultee, and Lammers 1998; Smits and Park 2009).
It is a challenge to understand the connection between higher educational expansion and EAM because educational expansion in most societies is such a comprehensive and gradual social transformation that its social impact often takes decades to unfold. For instance, it took the U.S. 70 years to raise the percentage of tertiary educated individuals among the 25 years old and over from 5 percent to 30 percent (Ryan and Siebens 2012).2 That is why many prior studies examine the consequences of educational expansion through cross-national comparisons (e.g., Smits and Park 2009),3 where mixed results are obtained. For instance, Ultee and Luijkx (1990) have documented increases, decreases, and trendless fluctuations of educational homogamy among 18 industrial nations, which provide evidence for neither STT nor SCT.
In this paper, we focus on the post-80s generation (individuals born between 1980 and 1989) in Shanghai, the largest metropolis of China, which enables us to better understand the connection between higher educational expansion and EAM, for the following reasons. First of all, higher education expansion in China was rapid and the centralized administrative system singlehandedly increased the percentage of those with college education at a phenomenal rate within a very short period of time. For example, the original objective of China’s Ministry of Education was to raise the gross college enrollment rate to 15 percent by 2010, but this goal was accomplished eight years ahead of schedule. As a result, the gross tertiary enrollment rate rose from 7 percent in 1999 to 27 percent in 2011. The unprecedented rapid expansion of tertiary education provides us a valuable opportunity to examine the temporal variations across cohorts instead of using a proxy of regional variation.
Second, the post-80s generation is a unique group because they were in college ages during or soon after the onset of higher education expansion in 1999. That is to say, the fact that they were born in the 1980s determines their relatively high likelihood of receiving college education. Meanwhile, this generation, interviewed in 2013, was in the phase of transition from youth to adulthood, and most were already married. An examination of this generation helps us understand the impact of educational expansion on educational homogamy.
Lastly, the data were collected in Shanghai, the largest and the most modern metropolis in contemporary China. This one-city sample, although limited in generalization, alleviates the concern of strong regional heterogeneity in implementation of higher education expansion policies (Morgan and Wu 2011). Shanghai accommodates 68 higher education institutions and has always assumed a leading role in higher education expansion in China. More importantly, gender equality is stronger in Shanghai than in the other parts (Shen 2011; Shu and Zhu 2012). Thus, educational expansion should thus have a significant influence on young women – an important contributive factor for assortative mating.
All in all, this study, by taking advantage of the unique societal transition in China, i.e., the phenomenally rapid expansion of higher education driven by the state, describes a more detailed picture about the association between educational expansion and EAM. Moreover, by specifying and separating the mechanisms of EAM (marriage market structure versus marital preference), this article betters our understanding about how and why the extent of EAM changes in the post 80s generation in China.
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
As well-documented in the extant literature, a particular pattern of EAM is jointly determined by both individual preference and structural constraints of the marriage market (Blossfeld 1996; Kalmijn and Flap 2001; Zeng and Xie 2008). For example, a marriage between a college-educated man and a college-educated woman is possible only if (1) there are college-educated partners available for a college educated person to mate; and (2) there is a preference to marry someone with college education. Higher education expansion has the potential to alter the extent of EAM by changing both preference and structural constraints. In this regard, however, STT and SCT propose contrasting theoretical reasonings.
Structural Transition Theory
STT focuses on how expanding educational opportunities alter the pattern of EAM, and argues that both marriage market structure and individual marital preference are influenced by the lowered threshold for attending college.
Higher education expansion influences the structure of marriage market by increasing the availability of highly-educated partners. This change promotes EAM because college serves as a local marriage market, where less educated individuals are blocked out and college-educated individuals meet each other (Blau and Schwartz 1984; Blossfeld and Timm 2003; McPherson, Smith-Lovin, and Cook 2001). Moreover, they reach marriageable ages in college and have a smaller variation in marriage timing due to later school departures than the less educated. This likely gives rise to the likelihood of educational homogamy (Mare 1991). Hence, as more people attend college in the process of educational expansion, the overall EAM should be strengthened.
Meanwhile, within higher education expansion, college-educated individuals may prefer someone just like themselves because common educational experience bestows people with similar values and opinions. Thus, they share a common foundation for conversation and joint activities, and reveal a higher likelihood of favoring each other in the family formation process (Blossfeld and Timm 2003). This mechanism is seen evident in the social psychological literature, where cultural similarity breeds interpersonal attraction and willingness to establish a long-term relationship such as marriage (e.g., Byrne 1971).
It is especially important that the expansion of higher education raises women’s educational attainment, which promotes educational homogamy (Diprete and Buchmann 2013; Hou and Myles 2008). Disadvantaged groups, such as women, have been noted to benefit more from expanded opportunities of higher education (e.g., Attewell and Lavin 2007). This would balance the sex ratio in the pool of highly-educated individuals and promote EAM. Women’s improved educational attainment suggests that wife’s earnings are increasingly as important as husband’s in a family (Gerson 2010; Oppenheimer 1988). Moreover, the wife’s human capital further boosts her spouse’s productivity and earnings (Lefgren and Mclntyre 2006; Huang, Li, Liu, and Zhang 2009). In light of growing significance of women’s education for family life, the mating pattern is expected to gradually deviate from Becker’s traditional model (1981),4 and move toward a symmetric model in which men prefer and compete for highly-educated women the same way as women do on a marriage market (England and Farkas 1986). Educational homogamy is thus strengthened as a result (Rose 2004; Sweeney and Cancian 2004).
In summary, according to STT, expansion of college education changes the structure of the marriage market and people’s marital preference, both of which are in favor of stronger EAM.
Status Closure Theory
SCT offers a different perspective of examining the consequence of higher educational expansion on EAM. From this perspective, mate selection is viewed a measure of social openness (Glass 1954), because marriage is in nature a union between two individuals who accept each other as social equals. Who marries whom thus reveals which social boundaries are more permeable than others. In modern societies, education is a primary determinant of an individual’s social status and the pattern of educational homogamy implies the extent of status closure (or openness) in a society (Goldthorpe 1980; Parkin 1971; Weber [1921] 1972).5
Smits and colleagues (Smits 2003; Smits, Ultee, and Lammers 1998; Smits and Park 2009) argue that one key factor that affects education status closure is the group size of the education elite. The elite circle is usually small, which makes elite members more aware of their advantaged positions and helps maintain their privilege (e.g., a rewarding college degree). Hence, when higher education is accessible only to a small number of individuals, education elites tend to consolidate education status closure, maintaining a higher level of educational homogamy.
Higher education expansion inevitably increases the size of education elites. As the size of highly educated individuals grows, those with less education gradually make up a small proportion in the population, so the structural opportunity for them to mate with highly-educated individuals would rise (Feld 1982). The major implication of this structural transition for the marriage market is the increasing penetrability across educational boundaries, which opens up the overall marriage market and drives down EAM.
Reduced barriers of marriage markets by educational attainment may also alter marital preference. Since the privileged benefits of education elites are “diluted” by credential proliferation, the preference for homogamy may go down and reduce EAM. Previous studies on cross-national comparisons have provided evidence for this relationship (Smits 2003, Smits, Ultee, and Lammers 1998, and Smits and Park 2009).
As summarized in Table 1, STT and SCT propose different patterns of transition in marriage market structure and preference in mate selection. Specifically, STT assumes higher education expansion to be positively associated with the extent of EAM by increasing the pool of college educated individuals and cultivating stronger preference for a well-educated partner. This is especially embodied by the strengthened gender balance in educational attainment and the rising role of women in family life. SCT posits that higher education expansion brings about more penetrable educational barriers and reduces the relative attractiveness of highly-educated individuals, which results in weakened EAM. This study tests these hypotheses with the data collected in China. To familiarize readers with the social setting, the following subsection introduces the state of educational assortative mating in Chinese society.
Table 1.
Marriage Market Structure | Marital Preference | The Pattern of Educational Assortative Mating | |
---|---|---|---|
Structural Transition Theory | Increase in the Pool of Potential Partners with Higher Education (Gender Balance of Educational Attainment) | Cultivate the Preference for a Highly-Educated Partner (Preference for a Highly-Educated Woman in Union Formation) | Strengthened |
Status Closure Theory | Increasingly Penetrable Educational Boundaries | Decline in the Preference for a Highly-Educated Partner | Weakened |
Educational Assortative Mating in China
“Match-door marriage,” the door of one’s home in a marriage must match that of his/her suitor’s, used to be the norm in China. The match-door marriage required meticulous pairing of couples’ family background and was often fulfilled by parents through arranged marriage (Xia and Zhou 2003). This tradition, however, was gradually abandoned, especially after 1950 when the Marriage Law regulated that arranged marriage was feudalistic and illegal. Since then, the mating process gradually gravitates less toward individuals’ family background and more toward one’s achieved attributes (Croll 1981).
During the socialist regime, education was nevertheless not valued as much as individual attributes that were tied to political capital, such as work unit type (e.g., civil servants) or Communist Party membership (Croll 1981). Education emerged to be important in mate selection after the implementation of the comprehensive social reform in the late 1970s.6 As shown in Han (2010), the extent of educational assortative marriage increased substantially between 1980 and 1995 and then grew at a relatively slower pace in the late 1990s.7 Yet, few studies extend their investigation to the period of higher educational expansion (that is, after the late 1990s). One exception is Qian and Qian (2014b), who show that highly educated women have a different propensity of marriage relative to highly educated men. In short, how EAM may vary within the comprehensive and rapid credential proliferation in China is still elusive. We aim to investigate this question in this study.
DATA AND METHODOLOGY
Sample and Measures
The data used in this study are the Shanghai Post-80s Generation Survey (Post-80s hereafter), which were collected in 2013 by Fudan University in Shanghai, China. The target population includes individuals born between 1980 and 1989. The Post-80s survey covers 160 neighborhoods in all of the 18 administrative districts in Shanghai. From each neighborhood, 10,000 addresses were randomly selected and the socio-demographic information of households was collected. From each selected household, a maximum of one household member born between 1980 and 1989 was interviewed (if more than one member born in the period, one was randomly selected).
The response rate of the Post-80s is 71 percent, and the final sample size is 2,357, in which 1,249 were married. Of the 1,249 married respondents, 1,173 have non-missing information about their spouse’s educational attainment. The age interval of the respondents is between 24 and 32. Since most Chinese college students graduate at the age of 22, this age interval is sufficiently long to guarantee our respondents, if attending college, to complete their formal tertiary education.
Educational attainment is classified into five levels, 1=elementary school and below; 2=junior high school or equivalent; 3=senior high school or equivalent; 4= junior college or equivalent; and 5= regular college or equivalent. In order to reveal variation in EAM by cohort, we divide the time span between 1980 and 1989 into three cohorts: 1980–1983, 1984–1986, and 1987–1989. For each cohort, a 5×5 contingency table between the husband’s and the wife’s educational attainment is constructed. Note that the sample size of each cohort is large enough to guarantee the statistical power of a 5×5 contingency table, even for the youngest cohort (Stelzl 2000). The grouping strategy of cohorts, by trisecting the period 1980–1989, ensures the relatively same length of time span (that is, 2–3 years) for each cohort. This strategy not only serves the interest of computational convenience, but also makes practical sense because the process of higher education expansion in Shanghai almost follows a linear trend. As shown in Figure 1, the rate of college enrollment in Shanghai nearly monotonically increased from 1999 to 2008. Since most senior high school graduates attend college at around 18 or 19 years old in China, this linear tendency suggests that the extent of increase in the opportunity of attending college linearly went up from the cohort 1980 to the cohort 1989. In this regard, a grouping scheme of ensuring a same length of time span for each cohort should not bring about severe biases.
For robustness check, we used a different time span partitioning: dividing the period between 1980 and 1989 based on the cumulative percentage of population. Specifically, we set new cutting points respectively at the years where the 33 cumulative percent (that is, 1982) and the 66 cumulative percent (that is, 1984) of sample size are located. This new strategy gives us a new scheme of grouping cohorts: 1980–1982, 1983–1984, and 1985–1989. If the analytical results do not show significant change, our estimates are robust. In addition, the robust analysis serves to test the influences of the unbalanced sample size problem. The trisecting scheme we describe above, as such, inevitably results in unbalanced sample sizes across cohorts since younger cohorts have fewer individuals than older cohorts. This problem is nevertheless circumvented by the cumulative population grouping scheme because the young cohorts now covers more years to compensate for their sample size, ensuring the population sizes by cohort to be balanced.
Analytical Strategies
The log-multiplicative layer model is used to examine the variation in the extent of educational homogamy across cohorts (Xie 1992). This model identifies the shift in EAM by “a common association pattern and a table-specific parameter” (Xie 1992:380). Specifically, taking into account cohort variation, we construct a three-way table, in which husband’s education, wife’s education, and cohort interact with each other. Following previous practice, we assign a small value (0.01) for empty cells. A saturated model to describe this set of three-way interactions is
(1) |
In Equation (1), Fijk is the expected number of marriages between husbands with educational level i and wives with educational level j (i, j=1, …, 5) in cohort k (k=1, 2, and 3). The log-multiplicative layer model simplifies Equation (1) and reduces the last two terms to be exp(ψijϕk), as follows:
(2) |
In Equation (2), ψij describes the common association between the husband’s and the wife’s educational attainment, and ϕk indicates cohort-specific association strength. Based on the log-multiplicative layer model, we adopt the following strategies to separate the mechanism of marriage market structure transition from the mechanism of changing marital preference in determining the state of educational homogamy.
Effect of Marital Preference Net of Structural Availability of Partners
We first investigate the effect of marital preference net of the availability of partners, testing the competing hypotheses about the transition of marital preference by STT and SCT.
Following previous studies (e.g., Breen and Salazar 2011; Breen and Andersen 2012), we adopt a counterfactual approach. Specifically, the observed level of educational homogamy for cohort k can be viewed as a joint effect of both availability and preference, which can be expressed as:
(3) |
where Ak and Pk respectively denote availability and preference for cohort k, and f refers to a function that links Ak and Pk to ϕk. Here, the function form of f does not have to be estimated. In this formula, it is appropriate to view ϕk to be a type of observed conditional distribution, which is the combination of net association that is captured by Pk, and the marginal distribution that is captured by Ak. With the setup of formula (3), the observed transition of educational homogamy across the three cohorts can be expressed as f(A1, P1) → f(A2, P2) → f(A3, P3).
Then, to show the effect of preference net of availability, we deploy the iterative proportional fitting (IPF) algorithm (also called the Stephan-Deming standardization or the matrix raking procedure) (Deming and Stephan 1940). The IPF algorithm is a mathematical scaling procedure which has been used by demographers to standardize the marginal distribution of a contingency table to some fixed value, while retaining the net association between row and column variables (e.g., Bishop et al. 2007; Breen and Andersen 2012). Since the availability of partners is captured by the marginal distribution of the contingency tables, the IPF procedure enables us to construct counterfactual scenarios where the marginal distributions of contingency tables for cohorts 1984–1986 and 1987–1989 are fixed at that of 1980–1983, as expressed to be:
(4) |
With Equation (4), the counterfactual tendency in the extent of educational homogamy would then be f(A1, P1) → f(A1, P2) → f(A1, P3). Evidently, only the mechanism of preference is at play, so that the cross-cohort variation in educational homogamy under these counterfactual states can be attributed to the variation of marital preference.
One thing that deserves discussing is that, in equation (2), and capture the observed cross-cohort variation in the distribution of husbands and wives of different educational backgrounds, so the log-multiplicative layer model reveals change in EAM for a given observed variation in marginal counts. However, the counterfactual analysis is aimed to uncover EAM with the same marginal counts across cohorts. In this regard, the IPF is necessary for our research objectives.
Effect of Structural Availability of Partners Net of Marital Preference
The net effect of availability should be examined after controlling for the parameter of preference across cohorts. However, marital preference refers to an individual-level attitude, but the log-multiplicative layer model examines the expected frequencies of different cells of the contingency tables. The discrepancy in the unit of analysis determines that we cannot directly add a measure of preference to the log-multiplicative layer model as a control variable. In order to resolve this challenge, we use propensity score weighting (Freedman and Berk 2008).
Weighting has been a popular technique to balance attributes across groups of cases. By propensity score weighting, we refer to a process of weighting analyzed cases according to their estimated probabilities of preferring certain type of partners. Specifically, in the Post-80s data, respondents were asked about their preference for educational credentials and intellectual background when choosing a mate. The option to these two questions is from 1(not important) to 5 (very important). We add up the answers of these two questions and generate a new binary variable where people with responses above the median is coded one and otherwise coded zero. Subsequently, we use cohort to predict the probability of providing a positive answer in a logistic regression model. The predicted probability for each case is the propensity score, which is used to generate analytical weights. Suppose the predicted propensity score for individual i is denoted with pi, the new weight for those whose answer to the newly generated binary variable is one is , and that for those with answer being zero is .
The merit of propensity score weighting is that people’s marital preference, after weighting, is balanced across cohorts. To see this formally, suppose one’s marital preference probability is denoted by π. This probability is decomposed into two components: one systematical component S that is determined by some observed explanatory variables (e.g., cohort) and one random component R representing some random noise. This relationship is shown in formula (5).
(5) |
As noted earlier, the propensity score is estimated based on cohort, so weighting based on propensity score is tantamount to balancing S. As a result, the systematical component is controlled for and what is left is some random variation of marital preference across cohorts.
Two caveats are necessary. First, propensity score weighting is performed based on observed covariates, and we cannot control for unobserved factors that are related to marital preference (e.g, the random component R). In this light, propensity score weighting only tackles the systematical part of marital preference. Second, propensity score weighting does not produce a particular parameter to estimate the net availability effect. As an alternative, this analytical approach changes the weights of every respondent to generate a new balanced sample. Hence, after weights are applied, we can use the log-multiplicative layers model to analyze the weighted sample and the result of transition in EAM across cohorts would be attributed to the mechanism of availability.
Penetrability of Educational Barriers
One major hypothesis of SCT is the increasing penetrability of educational barriers within higher education expansion. To test this hypothesis, we use the crossing effect model (e.g., Qian 1998; Mare 1991). As shown in Figure 2, we configure three design matrices to denote the extents of difficulty in crossing the adjacent categories of educational attainment in union formation. Specifically, we set our focus on the three educational stages beyond the nine-year compulsory education, that is, senior high school, junior college, and regular college.
RESULTS
Descriptive Findings
Table 2 presents results of the cross classification between spouses’ educational attainment for each of the three cohorts. For the oldest cohort, 1980–1983, married couples tend to have similar educational backgrounds, as the cells on the main diagonal always have the largest percentage for each row from men’s perspective and for each column from women’s perspective (1.39 percent, 14.09 percent, 9.60 percent, 13.47 percent, and 15.02 percent), except for the least educated women, who had a higher percent being married to a man of junior-high-school education (2.94 percent) rather than to a same education partner (1.39 percent). These findings suggest that educational homogamy is generally a common norm of marriage for those born between 1980 and 1983, despite a certain extent of hypergamy for the least-educated women.
Table 2.
wife’s education
|
|||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
husband’s education | 1980–1983 | Elementary School | Junior High School | Senior High School | Junior College | Regular College | |
Elementary School | 1.39 | 1.39 | 0.15 | 0.15 | 0 | ||
Junior High School | 2.94 | 14.09 | 4.18 | 0.93 | 0 | ||
Senior High School | 1.08 | 6.04 | 9.6 | 5.57 | 1.7 | ||
Junior College | 0.15 | 0.77 | 4.8 | 13.47 | 6.35 | ||
Regular College | 0.15 | 0 | 1.24 | 8.82 | 15.02 | ||
N=646 | |||||||
1984–1986 | Elementary School | Junior High School | Senior High School | Junior College | Regular College | ||
Elementary School | 0.57 | 0.85 | 0 | 0 | 0 | ||
Junior High School | 1.42 | 12.82 | 1.99 | 1.42 | 0.28 | ||
Senior High School | 0.85 | 4.84 | 11.97 | 3.99 | 1.71 | ||
Junior College | 0.57 | 0.85 | 5.41 | 13.96 | 9.4 | ||
Regular College | 0 | 0 | 3.42 | 7.41 | 16.24 | ||
N=351 | |||||||
1987–1989 | Elementary School | Junior High School | Senior High School | Junior College | Regular College | ||
Elementary School | 1.14 | 1.7 | 0 | 0 | 0 | ||
Junior High School | 1.14 | 16.48 | 4.55 | 0.57 | 0.57 | ||
Senior High School | 0.57 | 4.55 | 12.5 | 9.66 | 0 | ||
Junior College | 0 | 1.14 | 5.68 | 12.5 | 6.25 | ||
Regular College | 0 | 0 | 0 | 6.82 | 14.2 | ||
N=176 |
Data Source: the Shanghai Post-’80 Generation Survey
The educational pairing for the 1984–1986 cohort reveals a similar pattern, since the main diagonal percentages (12.84 percent, 11.97 percent, 13.96 percent, and 16.24 percent) are the highest for each row and column among those with an educational level above elementary school. Same as the oldest cohort, the least educated women had a greater percentage marrying men with junior high school (1.42 percent) than marrying those with a same-education partner. Yet, the 1984–1986 cohort witnessed a new finding -- men with elementary school education started to marry more-educated women (0.85 percent). This may well be related to a rise in women’s education and a decline in the number of women with only elementary school education.
The youngest cohort, 1987–1989, also reveals strong EAM among those with at least junior high school education, as well as a tendency of the least educated men matching with women with a junior high school degree. Interestingly, hypergamy among the least educated women is no longer evident. Instead, the least-educated women have similar percentages marrying men with elementary school or junior high school education. This pattern is reasonably related to the general improvement in education of the population.
Results of the Log-Multiplicative Layer Models
Following Raymo and Xie (2000) and Song (2009),8 we specify five log-multiplicative layer models. Model 1 is the baseline model in which educational attainment for both husbands and wives is set to be conditionally independent (Xie 1998). It means that there is no association assumed between the husband’s and the wife’s education for each cohort. We then specify the association between spouses’ education through two design matrices (Raymo and Xie 2000). Models 2 and 3 fit a main-diagonal model, and Models 4 and 5 add the distance parameters to Models 2 and 3 (the design matrices are presented in Figure 3), respectively. Furthermore, Models 2 and 4 set the ϕ parameter to be constant across cohorts (ϕ1 = ϕ2 = ϕ3) and Models 3 and 5 allow for cross-cohort variations.
The results of these models for the observed data and the IPF-generated data are presented in Table 3.
Table 3.
Observed Data
| ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
d.f. | L2 | BIC | AIC | Δ | ϕk across Cohorts | |||
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | ||||||
|
||||||||
(1) WC, HC | 48 | 1000.86 | 661.63 | 904.86 | 0.35 | |||
(2) WC, HC, M, constant ϕk over C | 43 | 374.05 | 70.16 | 288.05 | 0.16 | |||
(3) WC, HC, M, varying ϕk over C | 41 | 372.46 | 82.70 | 290.46 | 0.16 | 1 | 1.06 | 1.15 |
(4) Model 2 + D | 40 | 47.27 | −235.42 | −32.72 | 0.05 | |||
(5) Model 3 + D | 32 | 39.51 | −186.64 | −24.49 | 0.04 | 1 | 0.56 | 2.43 |
| ||||||||
Counterfactual based on IPF
| ||||||||
d.f. | L2 | BIC | AIC | Δ | ϕk across Cohorts | |||
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | ||||||
|
||||||||
(1) WC, HC | 48 | 1779.68 | 1416.35 | 1683.68 | 0.37 | |||
(2) WC, HC, M, constant ϕk over C | 43 | 660.61 | 335.12 | 574.61 | 0.16 | |||
(3) WC, HC, M, varying ϕk over C | 41 | 656.33 | 345.99 | 574.33 | 0.16 | 1 | 1.05 | 1.16 |
(4) Model 2 + D | 40 | 94.39 | −193.65 | 29.13 | 0.05 | |||
(5) Model 3 + D | 32 | 88.79 | −153.43 | 24.79 | 0.04 | 1 | 0.81 | 2.28 |
Data Source: the Shanghai Post-’80 Generation Survey
Note: W=wife’s education; H=husband’s education; C=cohorts; M=main diagonal; D=distance from the main diagonal; d.f. = degree of freedom; L2=the log likelihood ratio chi-square statistic; BIC= Bayesian information criterion; AIC= Akaike information criterion; Δ=the dissimilarity index between observed and predicted frequencies. N=1173.
The upper panel of Table 3 reports statistics for the goodness of model fit, including the log likelihood ratio chi-square statistic, BIC, AIC, and the dissimilarity index. Model 1 does not fit the observed data well, as shown by the large values of these statistics. Allowing for the interaction of educational attainment of spouses significantly improves model fit, where L2 decreases from 1000.86 to 374.05, BIC drops from 661.63 to 70.16, and AIC is reduced from 904.86 to 288.05. Moreover, the dissimilarity index is almost halved relative to Model 1. Model fit improves when educational association between spouses is allowed to vary by cohort (Model 3). Adding the distance parameters in Model 4 further improves model fit, indicated by the smaller values of L2, BIC, AIC, and Δ. Model 5 has the best fit when ϕk is allowed to change by cohort.
In Model 5, the parameter ϕk roughly shows a U-shaped pattern, first decreasing (from 1 to 0.56) and then increasing (from 0.56 to 2.43).9 This finding indicates that educational homogamy during higher educational expansion in China declined from the 1980–1983 cohort to the 1984–1986 cohort, but then went up in the 1987–1989 cohort.
Robustness Check
The U-shape transition in educational homogamy, as discussed earlier, might be subject to how cohort is classified. In order to examine the extent of sensitivity to cohort divide, we refit the log-multiplicative layer models using a new cohort grouping scheme based on the cumulative percentage of population. The new observed pattern is presented in Table 4, which is almost the same as Table 2.
Table 4.
wife’s education
|
|||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
husband’s education | 1980–1982 | Elementary School | Junior High School | Senior High School | Junior College | Regular College | |
Elementary School | 1.53 | 1.15 | 0.19 | 0.19 | 0 | ||
Junior High School | 3.06 | 13.77 | 4.4 | 1.15 | 0 | ||
Senior High School | 1.34 | 6.12 | 10.13 | 6.12 | 2.1 | ||
Junior College | 0.19 | 0.38 | 5.54 | 12.81 | 6.88 | ||
Regular College | 0.19 | 0 | 1.34 | 8.22 | 13.19 | ||
N=523 | |||||||
1983–1984 | Elementary School | Junior High School | Senior High School | Junior College | Regular College | ||
Elementary School | 0.42 | 1.67 | 0 | 0 | 0 | ||
Junior High School | 2.09 | 16.74 | 2.93 | 0.84 | 0.42 | ||
Senior High School | 0 | 6.28 | 6.28 | 3.77 | 1.26 | ||
Junior College | 0.42 | 2.09 | 2.93 | 12.97 | 6.28 | ||
Regular College | 0 | 0 | 2.51 | 9.62 | 20.5 | ||
N=239 | |||||||
1985–1989 | Elementary School | Junior High School | Senior High School | Junior College | Regular College | ||
Elementary School | 0.97 | 1.22 | 0 | 0 | 0 | ||
Junior High School | 1.22 | 12.9 | 2.92 | 0.97 | 0.24 | ||
Senior High School | 0.97 | 4.14 | 14.11 | 6.33 | 0.73 | ||
Junior College | 0.24 | 0.73 | 5.84 | 14.6 | 8.27 | ||
Regular College | 0 | 0 | 1.7 | 7.06 | 14.84 | ||
N=411 |
Data Source: the Shanghai Post-’80 Generation Survey
The results of the log-multiplicative layer models based on data shown in Table 4 are reported in the upper panel of Table 5. As shown by the best fit model (Model 5), the extent of educational homogamy remains a U-shaped trend, changing from 1 to 0.92 and then to 1.81. This lends support to the robustness of the results presented earlier.
Table 5.
Observed Data
| ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
d.f. | L2 | BIC | AIC | Δ | ϕk across Cohorts | |||
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | ||||||
|
||||||||
(6) WC, HC | 48 | 986.88 | 647.65 | 890.88 | 0.35 | |||
(7) WC, HC, M, constant ϕk over C | 43 | 364.91 | 61.01 | 278.91 | 0.16 | |||
(8) WC, HC, M, varying ϕk over C | 41 | 360.99 | 71.23 | 278.99 | 0.15 | 1 | 1.05 | 1.20 |
(9) Model 2 + D | 40 | 38.17 | −244.52 | −41.83 | 0.05 | |||
(10) Model 3 + D | 32 | 31.97 | −194.18 | −32.03 | 0.03 | 1 | 0.92 | 1.81 |
| ||||||||
Counterfactual based on IPF
| ||||||||
d.f. | L2 | BIC | AIC | Δ | ϕk across Cohorts | |||
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | ||||||
|
||||||||
(6) WC, HC | 48 | 1337.49 | 984.30 | 1241.49 | 0.36 | |||
(7) WC, HC, M, constant ϕk over C | 43 | 525.07 | 208.67 | 439.07 | 0.16 | |||
(8) WC, HC, M, varying ϕk over C | 41 | 519.54 | 217.85 | 437.54 | 0.16 | 1 | 0.99 | 1.18 |
(9) Model 2 + D | 40 | 67.03 | −227.30 | −12.97 | 0.05 | |||
(10) Model 3 + D | 32 | 56.69 | −178.77 | −7.31 | 0.04 | 1 | 0.48 | 1.65 |
Data Source: the Shanghai Post-’80 Generation Survey
Note: W=wife’s education; H=husband’s education; C=cohorts; M=main diagonal; D=distance from the main diagonal; d.f. = degree of freedom; L2=the log likelihood ratio chi-square statistic; BIC= Bayesian information criterion; AIC= Akaike information criterion; Δ=the dissimilarity index between observed and predicted frequencies. N=1173.
Effect of Preference Net of Availability
The U-shaped pattern presented above reflects the joint effects of both availability and preference. Using the IPF algorithm, we standardize the marginal distribution of the contingency tables for cohorts 1984–1986 and 1987–1989 to be that of cohort 1980–1983. This standardization guarantees the homogeneity in the marginal distribution of all three contingency tables, enabling us to examine the net effect of preference. The results of the log-multiplicative layer models based on the IPF-generated data are presented in the lower panel of Table 3 and Table 5.10
Following the same procedure of model selection, Model 5 is the one with the best fit. The transition pattern of ϕk also reveals a U-shaped pattern, where the odds of educational homogamy, under the condition of homogenous marginal counts, declined first (from 1 to 0.81) and then went up (from 0.81 to 2.28). Since this U-shaped pattern is obtained with the marginal distribution “controlled for”, it can be viewed to indicate the effect of marriage preference. That is to say, the extent of EAM was not driven down by the transition of marital preference.
Then, the question at issue is, how people’s marital preference changes across cohorts. For this question, Figure 4 presents some descriptive information. As shown, both men and women increasingly emphasize the importance of educational credential when looking for a partner. Especially, men’s preference for highly educated women increased notably from the 1984–1986 cohort to the 1987–1989 cohort. As for women, the preference for a highly-educated man reveals a roughly linear increase by cohort.
In summary, the cross-cohort comparison generally portrays a picture of increasing preference for a highly-educated partner across cohorts. This finding, in addition to the net effect of preference shown earlier, implies that marital preference has been strengthened within the concerted educational expansion in China, and such variation in marital preference does not drive down the extent of EAM as hypothesized by SCT.
Effect of Availability Net of Preference
As noted in the methodological section, we examine the net effect of availability by fitting the log-multiplicative layer model based on the propensity-score weighted sample. For robustness check, we fit the models using two cohort classification schemes. Table 6 presents the results.
Table 6.
Data based on cohort grouping scheme 1*
| ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
d.f. | L2 | BIC | AIC | Δ | ϕk across Cohorts | |||
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | ||||||
|
||||||||
(11) WC, HC | 48 | 1002.81 | 663.58 | 906.81 | 0.35 | |||
(12) WC, HC, M, constant ϕk over C | 43 | 374.76 | 70.86 | 288.76 | 0.16 | |||
(13) WC, HC, M, varying ϕk over C | 41 | 373.09 | 83.33 | 291.09 | 0.16 | 1 | 1.06 | 1.16 |
(14) Model 2 + D | 40 | 46.33 | −236.37 | −33.67 | 0.05 | |||
(15) Model 3 + D | 32 | 38.94 | −187.21 | −25.06 | 0.04 | 1 | 0.55 | 2.40 |
| ||||||||
Data based on cohort grouping scheme 2**
| ||||||||
d.f. | L2 | BIC | AIC | Δ | ϕk across Cohorts | |||
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | ||||||
|
||||||||
(16) WC, HC | 48 | 989.66 | 650.43 | 893.66 | 0.35 | |||
(17) WC, HC, M, constant ϕk over C | 43 | 366.35 | 62.45 | 280.35 | 0.16 | |||
(18) WC, HC, M, varying ϕk over C | 41 | 362.48 | 72.72 | 280.48 | 0.15 | 1 | 1.05 | 1.20 |
(19) Model 2 + D | 40 | 37.92 | −244.77 | −42.08 | 0.05 | |||
(20) Model 3 + D | 32 | 31.80 | −194.36 | −32.20 | 0.03 | 1 | 0.99 | 1.80 |
Data Source: the Shanghai Post-’80 Generation Survey
cohorts 1980–1983, 1984–1986, and 1987–1989
cohorts 1980–1982, 1983–1984, and 1985–1989
The extent of educational homogamy based on the weighted data continues to follow a U-shaped pattern, for both cohort grouping strategies. This pattern suggests that EAM, after controlling for mate selection preference, does not significantly deviate from the observed pattern shown earlier. The increased supply of highly-educated individuals and the concomitant decline in the number of less educated individuals lead to an increase in educational homogamy for the youngest cohort, thus lending support to STT.
To better understand the net effect of availability, we depict the educational spectrum by cohort, as presented in Figure 5.
In Figure 5, both husband’s and wife’s educational attainment exhibit a cross-cohort growth, for both cohort grouping schemes. The percentage of college educated men declined slightly for the youngest cohort but it was not statistically significant. In addition, the percentage of junior college educated men remarkably increased. For women, the percentage of the college educated steadily increased by cohort. Lastly, the percentage of the lowest educated declined for both men and women across cohorts.
Penetrability of Educational Barriers
To test the hypothesis about the increasing penetrability of educational barriers, we fitted the crossing effect model, with the major findings presented in Table 7.
Table 7.
1980–1983 | 1984–1986 | 1987–1989 | z value | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Cohort1 | Cohort2 | Cohort3 | Cohort1–Cohort2 | Cohort1–Cohort3 | Cohort2–Cohort3 | |
v1 | −0.96 (0.34)** | −0.76 (0.52) | −1.86(1.03)# | 0.32 | 0.83 | 0.95 |
v2 | −2.50 (0.28)*** | −2.17 (0.32)*** | −2.34 (0.52)*** | 0.78 | 0.27 | 0.27 |
v3 | −1.79 (0.24)*** | −1.20 (0.26)*** | −3.47 (1.02)*** | 1.67# | 1.60 | 2.16* |
| ||||||
AIC | 8.44 | 6.86 | 4.78 | |||
BIC | 46.67 | 22.55 | −5.37 |
p<0.1
p<0.5
p<0.01
p<0.001
Note: loglinear regression coefficients with standard error in parentheses.
As shown in Table 7, no evidence for increasing penetrability is detected across cohorts. Specifically, the boundary of mating between senior-high-school graduates and non-senior-high-school graduates is kind of stable by cohort, which is also the case for the educational category of junior college. As for the marital barrier pertaining to the category of regular college, despite a marginal decline from cohort 1980–1983 to cohort 1984–1986, such boundary becomes more rigid as we move to cohort 1987–1989. Hence, the barriers of mating across educational categories do not relax within higher education expansion as predicted by SCT.
CONCLUSION AND DISCUSSIONS
The expansion of higher education witnessed in many societies has influenced the pattern of EAM. Structural transition theory predicts a growing tendency of EAM due to strengthened availability of and preference for a highly-educated partner amid educational expansion. In contrast, social closure theory suggests that increasingly penetrable educational boundaries driven by the expanding size of the education elite circle would promote the openness of the marriage market and reduce the preference for a highly-educated spouse, which accordingly drive down educational homogamy. Using survey data collected in Shanghai, we examine the relationship between higher education expansion and educational homogamy with a focus on a sample of youth born in 1980–1989, many of whom go through courting and marriage during a period of rapid proliferation of college credential in China.
Applying the log-multiplicative layer model, we show that the likelihood of educational homogamy was lower in cohort 1984–1986 than in cohort 1980–1983, but rebounded in cohort 1987–1989. In order to pinpoint social forces behind this observed pattern, we adopt the iterative proportional fitting algorithm and propensity score weighting to reveal the net effects of partner preference and partner availability. Our analyses show that preference for a highly-educated mate has been intensified during higher education expansion in China and EAM under the influences of such transition in marital preference does not show a downtrend. As for partner availability, a continuous increase in the supply of highly-educated persons in the marriage market has given rise to EAM. Lastly, no evidence is documented to indicate a tendency of increasing penetrability of educational barriers in mate selection across cohorts.
Indeed, Shanghai is not representative of urban China and the pattern of EAM found here is likely to overestimate the extent of EAM in Chinese urban areas, at least in part due to greater prevalence of college graduates in Shanghai than in other cities of China. For instance, the latest census ranked Shanghai the second after Beijing in percentage of college-educated residents among all major cities. That being said, this study still bears a general implication for change in EAM in Chinese society. Shanghai, as a vanguard in social transitions in the Reform Era of China, is leading the process of higher educational expansion due to its abundant educational resources (e.g., the number of educational institutions, the quality of faculty, etc.). As a result, our findings can be witnessed on a larger scale for the rest of China as more senior high school graduates are able to attend college in the future.
Another implication of this study concerns the alarming income inequality in contemporary China (e.g., Xie and Zhou 2014). As noted above, the barrier between highly-educated and less-educated groups does not become more penetrable within higher education expansion. Prior studies have shown a strong link between educational attainment and income in the Reform Era of China (e.g., Wang 2012). Hence, educational homogamy might serve as a demographic process to exacerbate income inequality because people with stronger earning capacities marry each other (Hu and Qian 2015). In this light, higher education institutions in contemporary China may fail to serve as a social equalizer (Hu and Hibel 2014).
The documented extent of EAM relates to the one-child policy in China since those born in the 1980s are exactly the one-child generation. For them, two mechanisms might be at play to strengthen EAM. First, the one-child policy and the concomitant rigid limitation on the number of children encourage parents to raise the “perfect child” (Evans 2010). This may help promote educational attainment of post 80s women. Second, the birth control partly results in a skewed sex ratio among the post 80s (Guilmoto 2010). In this case, men have to confront fiercer competition for highly-educated women on the marriage market. These two factors highlight the potential role of the one-child policy and the uniqueness of the Chinese context.
Lastly, the transition in the extent of EAM in large supports more STT than SCT, since marital preference for a highly-educated partner does not go down and no evidence suggests an increasing penetrability of educational barriers. However, the only three cohorts that are in analysis cannot rule out the possibility that the transition in the likelihood of EAM is driven by some latent cyclical fluctuations. In addition, the U-shaped pattern is not fully aligned with the predicted continuous trend of EAM by STT. We speculate that the slight drop in the extent of EAM from the oldest to the middle cohort might be driven by the mechanism of SCT, while the transition from the middle to the youngest cohort suggests more the effects of STT. Specifically, one possible factor in this vein is the preference for Shanghai household registration status in union formation in Shanghai. Other things being equal, a partner with a Shanghai household registration status is more attractive. As more people outside Shanghai attended college and lived in Shanghai and college graduates educated elsewhere migrated to Shanghai within higher education expansion, the preference for a Shanghai household registration status might drive down EAM. However, for the youngest cohort, this household registration status preference may become less influential, or overridden by the preference for education, especially in the gloomy economic climate.
In this study, we examine the extent of educational homogamy among the married respondents, so the standardization based on IPF can only ensure that the marginal counts of married respondents for both men and women are fixed across cohorts. For our purpose, we control for neither availability of unmarried nor “the force of attraction” between couples with different educational backgrounds (Qian and Preston 1993). Thus, the changing extent of EAM, as well as the potential role played by the mechanisms of availability and preference, is conditional on marriage and only apply to married individuals.
This leads us to a major limitation of this study – there are more unmarried people in the youngest cohort than in the older cohorts. To examine this concern, our supplemental sensitivity analysis (not shown here) excluded people who were married at an older age among the older cohorts in order to achieve a similar age of marriage across the three cohorts. Specifically, we restricted the median duration of marriage for all three cohorts to be no more than two years (the median length of marriage for the youngest cohort) and refit the log-multiplicative layer models. The results again return a U-shaped probability of educational homogamy by cohort. This finding partly alleviates the concern of focusing on the married sample.
The concern of varying ages of marriage by cohort can be also seen from the perspective of age-period-cohort (APC) analysis, which is de facto tantamount to the problem of separating age, period, and cohort effects in a cross-sectional study. Cohort variation, when serving as a proxy to period transition in this study, potentially carries the information of life course effect (aging). Without longitudinal or repeated cross sectional data, we cannot investigate cohort variation and simultaneously control for age.
Fortunately, the APC identification problem is likely not a severe concern for our study. First, the age range of our sample is between 24 and 32, so the majority of our respondents are in the 20s, the prime ages for marriage in China. Second, the potential age effect, if exists, should roughly shows a downward trend of educational homogamy because the older an individual is, the longer the departure from school, and the more likely to meet people with a different level of education (Mare 1991). Yet, our analysis suggests that this age effect, if any, is overwhelmed by the increasing trend in educational homogamy. Third, the mean age at first marriage for both men and women in Shanghai declined monotonically from the 1980 cohort to the 1989 cohort (Cai and Wang 2012). Thus, the marriage postponing effect of aging, at least in Shanghai, has been shrinking.
Highlights.
The sample of the post-80s generation collected in Shanghai is analyzed.
A U-shaped pattern of educational homogamy by cohort is detected.
Structural transition theory is supported.
Footnotes
Indeed, whether improvement in women’s education facilitates EAM is related to contextual gender role differences. In societies with a more gender-symmetric division of labor within households, women’s improved education could be positively related to EAM (Sweeney 2002).
Previous studies based on cross-sectional data over a long period of time in the U.S. document a lesser extent of intermarriage among groups of highly-educated persons (e.g., Mare 1991; Schwartz and Mare 2005). Such longitudinal data are rare in many other societies.
Despite the merits inherent to this “regional variation as proxy for temporal variation” approach, institutional differences across societies have always been a real concern (Raymo and Xie 2000). For instance, the basic classification of educational stages substantially differs from one society to another (Wong 2003).
According to Becker (1981), family gains are optimized when couples form division of labor, with specialty in either market or household work, which leads to a pattern of mating between high-wage men (or women) and low-wage women (or men).
However, this does not rule out the other mechanism of status closure. Besides education, people might adopt other criteria in mate selection, such as occupation or political status.
In the past, the pattern of educational matching often follows a pattern of hypergamy, in which wife’s education is lower than husband’s. This type of educational pairing is largely due to the traditional gender-role. That is, women are homemakers while men are bread winners (Attane 2012).
The traditional gender role is still at play in contemporary China (Qian and Qian 2014a; Zuo 2003).
Raymo and Xie (2000) illustrate the log-multiplicative layer model in a methodological commentary. Song (2009) applies this method to analyze the effect of the Cultural Revolution on the extent of EAM in China, but this study, due to its focus on a different cohort, is not directly related to the current article.
This could also be called a V shaped pattern since only three groups are involved. We follow prior literature and describe it to be a U shaped pattern.
Contributor Information
Anning Hu, Department of Sociology, Fudan University, 831, Liberal Arts Building, Handan Road, Shanghai 200433, China.
Zhenchao Qian, Population Studies and Training Center and Department of Sociology, Brown University Maxcy Hall, Box 1916 108 George Street Providence, RI 02912, USA.
References
- Attane Isabelle. Being a Woman in China Today: A Demography of Gender. China Perspectives. 2012;4:5–15. [Google Scholar]
- Attewell Paul, Lavin David. Passing the Torch: Does Higher Education for the Disadvantaged Pay Off Across the Generations? New York: Russell Sage Foundation; 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Birkelund Gunn, Heldal Johan. Who Marries Whom? Educational Homogamy in Norway. Demographic Research. 2003;8(1):1–30. [Google Scholar]
- Bishop Yvonne, Fienberg Stephen, Holland Paul. Discrete Multivariate Analysis: Theory and Practice. New York: Springer; 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Blau Peter M. Structural Contexts of Opportunities. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1994. [Google Scholar]
- Blau Peter M, Schwartz Joseph. Crosscutting Social Circles: Testing A Macrostructural Theory of Intergroup Relations. FL, Orlando: Academic; 1984. [Google Scholar]
- Blossfeld Hans-Peter. Educational Assortative Marriage in Comparative Perspective. Annual Review of Sociology. 2009;35:513–530. [Google Scholar]
- Blossfeld Hans-Peter, Timm Andreas. Who Marries Whom? Educational Systems as Marriage Markets in Modern Societies. Dordrecht: Kluwer Acad; 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Blossfeld Hans-Peter. Macro-Sociology, Rational Choice Theory, and Time: A Theoretical Perspective on the Empirical Analysis of Social Processes. European Sociological Review. 1996;12:181–206. [Google Scholar]
- Breen Richard, Salazar Leire. Educational Assortative Mating and Earnings Inequality in the United States. American Journal of Sociology. 2011;117(3):808–843. [Google Scholar]
- Breen Richard, Andersen Signe Hald. Educational Assortative Mating and Income Inequality in Denmark. Demography. 2012;49:867–887. doi: 10.1007/s13524-012-0111-2. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Buchmann Claudia, Hannum Emily. Education and Stratification in Developing Countries: A Review of Theories and Research. Annual Review of Sociology. 2001;27:77–102. [Google Scholar]
- Byrne Donn Erwin. The Attraction Paradigm. Vol. 11. New York: Academic Press; 1971. [Google Scholar]
- Cai Yong, Wang Feng. From Collective Synchronization to Individual Liberalization: (Re)emergence of Late Marriage in New Shanghai. 2012 Retrieved at http://paa2012.princeton.edu/papers/120544 on 12-3-2014.
- Carneiro Pedro, Heckman James J, Vytlacil Edward. Estimating Marginal and Average Returns to Education. Department of Economics, University College London; 2007. Unpublished manuscript. [Google Scholar]
- Carnoy Martin, Loyalka Prashant, Dobryakova Maria, Dossani Rafiq. University Expansion in a Changing Global Economy Triumph of the BRICs? Stanford: Stanford University; 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Croll Elisabeth. The Politics of Marriage in Contemporary China. UK: Cambridge University Press; 1981. [Google Scholar]
- Deming Edward, Stephan Frederick F. On a Least Squares Adjustment of a Sampled Frequency Table When the Expected Marginal Total Are Known. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics. 1940;11:427–444. [Google Scholar]
- England Paula, Farkas George. Households, Employment, and Gender: A Social, Economic, and Demographic View. New York: Aldine; 1986. [Google Scholar]
- Esteve Albert, Cortina Clara. Changes in educational assortative mating in contemporary Spain. Demographic Research. 2006;14(17):405–428. [Google Scholar]
- Esteve Albert, McCaa Robert, Lopez Luis. The Educational Homogamy Gap between Married and Cohabiting Couples in Latin America. Population Research and Policy Review. 2013;32:81–102. doi: 10.1007/s11113-012-9263-4. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Evans H. The Gender of Communication: Changing Expectations of Mothers and Daughters in Urban China. China Quarterly. 2010;204:980–1000. [Google Scholar]
- Featherman David, Hogan Dennis, Sorensen Aage. Entry into Adulthood. Profiles of Young Men in the 1950s. In: Baltes Paul B, Brim Orville G., editors. Life-Span Development and Behavior. FL, Orlando: Academic; 1984. pp. 159–202. [Google Scholar]
- Feld Scott. Social structural determinants of similarity among associates. American Sociological Review. 1982;47(6):797–801. [Google Scholar]
- Freedman David, Berk Richard. Weighting Regressions by Propensity Scores. Evaluation Review. 2008;32:392–409. doi: 10.1177/0193841X08317586. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Gerson Kathleen. The Unfinished Revolution: Coming of Age in a New Era of Gender, Work, and Family. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Goldthorpe John. Social Mobility and Class Structure in Modern Britain. Clarendon Press; 1980. [Google Scholar]
- Guilmoto Christophe Z. Skewed Sex Ratios at Birth and Future Marriage Squeeze in China and India, 2005–2100. Demography. 2012;49(1):77–100. doi: 10.1007/s13524-011-0083-7. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Halpin Brendan, Chan Tak Wing. Educational homogamy in Ireland and Britain: trends and patterns. British Journal of Sociology. 2003;54(4):473–495. doi: 10.1080/0007131032000143546. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Han Hongyun. Trends in Educational Assortative Marriage in China from 1970 to 2000. Demographic Research. 2010;22:733–770. [Google Scholar]
- Hannum Emily, Park Albert F. Education and Reform in China. New York, NY: Routledge; 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Hartog Joop, Oosterbeek Hessel. Health, Wealth and Happiness: Why Pursue a Higher Education? Economics of Education Review. 1998;17(3):245–256. [Google Scholar]
- Hou Feng, Myles John. The Changing Role of Education in the Marriage Market: Assortative Marriage in Canada and the United States since the 1970s. Canadian Journal of Sociology. 2008;33:337–366. [Google Scholar]
- Michael Hout. Social and Economic Returns to College Education in the United States. Annual Review of Sociology. 2012;38:379–400. [Google Scholar]
- Hu Anning, Hibel Jacob. Changes in College Attainment and the Economic Returns to a College Degree in Urban China, 2003–2010: Implications for Social Equality. Social Science Research. 2014;44:173–186. doi: 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2013.12.001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Hu Anning, Qian Zhenchao. Educational Homogamy and Earnings Inequality of Married Couples: Urban China, 1988–2007. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility. 2015;40:1–15. [Google Scholar]
- Kalmijn Matthijs. Assortative Mating by Cultural and Economic Occupational Status. American Journal of Sociology. 1994;100(2):422–52. [Google Scholar]
- Kalmijn Matthijs. Assortative Mating by Cultural and Economic Occupational Status. American Journal of Sociology. 1994;100(2):422–52. [Google Scholar]
- Kalmijn Matthijs. Intermarriage and Homogamy: Causes, Patterns, Trends. Annual Review of Sociology. 1998;24:395–421. doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.24.1.395. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Katrnak Tomas, Kreidl Martin, Fonadova Laura. Trends in Educational Assortative Mating in Central Europe: the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland, and Hungary, 1988–2000. European Sociological Review. 2006;22(3):309–322. [Google Scholar]
- Lefgren Lars, Mclntyre Frank. The Relationship between Women’s Education and Marriage Outcomes. Journal of Labor Economics. 2006;24(4):787–830. [Google Scholar]
- Lewis Susan K, Oppenheimer Valerie K. Educational Assortative Mating across Marriage Markets: Nonhispanic Whites in the United States. Demography. 2000;37(1):29–40. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Li Fengliang, John Morgan W, Ding Xiaohao. The Expansion of Higher Education, Employment and Over-Education in China. International Journal of Educational Development. 2008;28:687–697. [Google Scholar]
- Li Tao, Zhang Juyan. What Determines Employment Opportunity for College Graduates in China after Higher Education Reform? China Economic Review. 2010;21:38–50. [Google Scholar]
- Lichter Daniel T, Leclere Felicia B, Mclaughlin Diane K. Local Marriage Markets and the Marital Behavior of Black and White Women. American Journal of Sociology. 1991;96(4):843–867. [Google Scholar]
- Lichter Daniel, Anderson Robert N, Hayward Mark D. Marriage Market and Marital Choice. Journal of Family Issues. 1995;16:412–431. [Google Scholar]
- Lloyd Kim M, South Scott J. Contextual Influences on Young Men’s Transition to First Marriage. Social Forces. 1996;74(3):1097–1119. [Google Scholar]
- Mare Robert. Five Decades of Educational Assortative Mating. American Sociological Review. 1991;46:72–87. [Google Scholar]
- Mare Robert. Educational Homogamy in Two Glided Ages: Evidence from Inter-generational Social Mobility Data. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 2016;663(1):117–139. [Google Scholar]
- McPherson Miller, Smith-Lovin Lynn, Cook James M. Birds of a Feather: Homophily in Social Networks. Annual Review of Sociology. 2001;27:415–444. [Google Scholar]
- Monaghan David. Income inequality and educational assortative mating: Evidence from the Luxembourg Income Study. Social Science Research. 2015;52:253–269. doi: 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2015.02.001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- John Morgan, Wu Bin. Higher Education Reform in China: Beyond the Expansion. New York: Routledge; 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Musick Kelly, Brand Jennie, Davis Dwight. Variation in the Relationship between Education and Marriage: Marriage Market Mismatch? Journal of Marriage and Family. 2012;74:53–69. doi: 10.1111/j.1741-3737.2011.00879.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Oppenheimer Valerie Kincade. A Theory of Marriage Timing: Assortative Mating under Varying Degrees of Uncertainty. American Journal of Sociology. 1988;94:563–591. [Google Scholar]
- Park Hyunjoon, Smits Jeroen. Educational Assortative Mating in South Korea: Trends 1930–1998. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility. 2005;23:103–127. [Google Scholar]
- Parkin Frank. Strategies of Social Closure in Class Formation. In: Parkin Frank., editor. The Social Analysis of the Class Structure. London, England: Tavistock; 1974. pp. 1–18. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Yue, Qian Zhenchao. Work, Family, and Gendered Happiness among Married People in Urban China. Social Indicators Research. 2014a doi: 10.1007/s11205-014-0623-9. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- Qian Yue, Qian Zhenchao. The Gender Divide in Urban China: Singlehood and Assortative Mating by Age and Education. Demographic Research. 2014b;31:1337–1364. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Zhenchao, Preston Samuel H. Changes in American Marriage, 1972 to 1987: Availability and Forces of Attraction by Age and Education. American Sociological Review. 1993;58(4):482–495. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Zhenchao. Changes in Assortative Mating: The Impact of Age and Education, 1970–1890. Demography. 1998;35(3):279–292. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Rauscher Emily. Effects of Early U.S. Compulsory Schooling Laws on Educational Assortative Mating: The Importance of Context. Demography. 2015;52:1219–1242. doi: 10.1007/s13524-015-0402-5. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Raymo James, Xie Yu. Temporal and Regional Variation in the Strength of Educational Homogamy: Comment on Smits, Ultee and Lammers. American Sociological Review. 2000;65(4):773–781. [Google Scholar]
- Rose Elaina. CSDE Working Paper No. 04-03. Center for Studies in Demography and Ecology, University of Washington; 2004. Education and Hypergamy in Marriage Markets. [Google Scholar]
- Ryan Camille L, Siebens Julie. Educational Attainment in the United States: 2009. 2012 Retrieved at www.census.gov/prod/2012pubs/p20-566.pdf.
- Schofer Evan, Meyer John. The Worldwide Expansion of Higher Education in the Twentieth Century. American Sociological Review. 2005;70:898–920. [Google Scholar]
- Schwartz Christine R. Trends and Variation in Assortative Mating: Causes and Consequences. Annual Review of Sociology. 2013;39:451–470. [Google Scholar]
- Schwartz Christine R, Mare Robert. Trends in Educational Assortative Marriage from 1940 to 2003. Demography. 2005;42:621–646. doi: 10.1353/dem.2005.0036. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Seidman Robert H. The Logic and Behavioral Principles of Educational Systems: Social Independence or Dependence? In: Archer Margaret., editor. The Sociology of Educational Expansion: Take-off, Growth and Inflation in Educational Systems. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage; 1982. pp. 267–292. [Google Scholar]
- Seidman Robert H. National Education ‘Goals 2000’: Some Disastrous Unintended Consequences. Education Policy Analysis Archives. 1996;4 Available at: www.eric.ed.gov/ERICWebPortal/search/detailmini.jsp?_nfpb=true&_&ERICExtSearch_SearchValue_0=ED388673&ERICExtSearch_SearchType_0=no&accno=ED388673. [Google Scholar]
- Shen Yifei. China in the “Post-Patriarchal Era. Chinese Sociology and Anthropology. 2011;43(4):5–23. [Google Scholar]
- Shu Xiaoling, Zhu Yifei. Uneven Transitions: Period- and Cohort-Related Changes in Gender Attitudes in China, 1995–2007. Social Science Research. 2012;41:1100–1115. doi: 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2012.05.004. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Simon Herbert A. Rational Choice and the Structure of Environments. Psychological Review. 1956;63(2):129–138. doi: 10.1037/h0042769. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Smits Jeroen, Park Hyunjoon. Five Decades of Educational Assortative Mating in 10 East Asian Societies. Social Forces. 2009;88(1):227–255. [Google Scholar]
- Smits Jeroen, Wout Ultee, Lammers Jan. Educational Homogamy in 65 Countries: An Explanation of Differences in Openness Using Country-Level Explanatory Variables. American Sociological Review. 1998;63:264–285. [Google Scholar]
- Smits Jeroen. Social Closure among the Higher Educated: Trends in Educational Homogamy in 55 Countries. Social Science Research. 2003;32:251–277. [Google Scholar]
- Song Lijun. The Effect of the Cultural Revolution on Educational Homogamy in Urban China. Social Forces. 2009;88(1):257–270. [Google Scholar]
- Stelzl Ingeborg. What sample sizes are needed to get correct significance levels for log-linear models? - A Monte Carlo Study using the SPSS-procedure “Hiloglinear. Methods of Psychological Research Online. 2000;5(2):1–22. [Google Scholar]
- Sweeney Megan M. Two Decades of Family Change: the Shifting Economic Foundations of Marriage. American Sociological Review. 2002;67:132–147. [Google Scholar]
- Sweeney Megan M, Cancian Maria. The Changing Importance of White Women’s Economic Prospects for Assortative Mating. Journal of Marriage and Family. 2004;66:1015–1028. [Google Scholar]
- Ultee Wout C, Luijkx Ruud. Educational Heterogamy and Father–to–Son Occupational Mobility in 23 Industrial Nations: General Societal Openness or Compensatory Strategies of Reproduction? European Sociological Review. 1990;6(2):125–149. [Google Scholar]
- Wang Le. Economic transition and college premium in urban China. China Economic Review. 2012;23:238–252. [Google Scholar]
- Weber Max. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Mohr; [1921] 1972. [Google Scholar]
- Willis Robert J, Rosen Sherwin. Education and Self-Selection. Journal of Political Economy. 1979;87:S7–36. [Google Scholar]
- Wong Raymond. To See or not To See: Another Look at Research on Temporal trends and Cross-National Differences in Educational Homogamy. Taiwanese Journal of Sociology. 2003;31:48–91. [Google Scholar]
- Xia Yan R, Zhou Zhi G. The Transition of Courtship, Mate Selection, and Marriage in China. In: Hamon Raeann R, Ingoldsby Bron B., editors. Mate Selection across Cultures. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage; 2003. pp. 231–246. [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu, Zhou Xiang. Income inequality in today’s China. PNAS. 2014;111(19):6928–6933. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1403158111. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu. The Log-Multiplicative Layer Effect Model for Comparing Mobility Tables. American Sociological Review. 1992;57(3):380–395. [Google Scholar]
- Xie Yu. The Essential Tension between Parsimony and Accuracy. Sociological Methodology. 1998;28:231–246. [Google Scholar]
- Zeng Zhen, Xie Yu. A Preference-Opportunity-Choice Framework with Applications to Intergroup Friendship. American Journal of Sociology. 2008;114(3):615–648. doi: 10.1086/592863. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Zhou Muzhi. Educational Assortative Mating in Hong Kong: 1981–2011. Chinese Sociological Review. 2016;48(1):33–63. [Google Scholar]
- Zuo Jiping. From Revolutionary Comrades to Gendered Partners: Marital Construction of Breadwinning in post-Mao Urban China. Journal of Family Issues. 2003;24(3):314–447. [Google Scholar]