Skip to main content
Scientific Reports logoLink to Scientific Reports
. 2017 Nov 10;7:15242. doi: 10.1038/s41598-017-15555-7

Intermediate Levels of Network Heterogeneity Provide the Best Evolutionary Outcomes

Flávio L Pinheiro 1,, Dominik Hartmann 2,3,
PMCID: PMC5681591  PMID: 29127336

Abstract

Complex networks impact the diffusion of ideas and innovations, the formation of opinions, and the evolution of cooperative behavior. In this context, heterogeneous structures have been shown to generate a coordination-like dynamics that drives a population towards a monomorphic state. In contrast, homogeneous networks tend to result in a stable co-existence of multiple traits in the population. These conclusions have been reached through the analysis of networks with either very high or very low levels of degree heterogeneity. In this paper, we use methods from Evolutionary Game Theory to explore how different levels of degree heterogeneity impact the fate of cooperation in structured populations whose individuals face the Prisoner’s Dilemma. Our results suggest that in large networks a minimum level of heterogeneity is necessary for a society to become evolutionary viable. Moreover, there is an optimal range of heterogeneity levels that maximize the resilience of the society facing an increasing number of social dilemmas. Finally, as the level of degree heterogeneity increases, the evolutionary dominance of either cooperators or defectors in a society increasingly depends on the initial state of a few influential individuals. Our findings imply that neither very unequal nor very equal societies offer the best evolutionary outcome.

Introduction

It is well known that the structure of complex networks affects the outcomes of dynamical processes1,2, such as epidemic outbreaks35, diffusion of innovations6,7, opinion formation810 and behavioral evolution11,12. In that context, network heterogeneity is a topological feature of complex networks that is of particular importance1317. The network heterogeneity refers to the heterogeneity among the number of ties maintained by each individual in a network; it is often measured by the variance of the degree distribution18 and called degree heterogeneity. Until now most works have, however, dealt with structures that exhibit opposite levels of degree heterogeneity, such as networks where all individuals have a similar number of network ties or networks with a power law distribution of the individuals’ ties. In this paper, we explore the gap between these two extremes in the context of evolutionary game theory19,20 and the problem of the evolution of cooperation21,22. Our goal is to understand if (1) there is a minimum threshold of heterogeneity necessary for the evolution of cooperation, and (2) if is there an optimal level of heterogeneity?

Previous theoretical works have extensively explored the role of the population structure in the evolution of cooperation. Yet, they have mainly dealt with structures that exhibit opposite levels of degree heterogeneity2334. In this regard, regular and highly symmetric structures with low levels of heterogeneity–such as lattices11,2527–have been shown to promote a stable co-existence dynamics between different competing behaviors, such as cooperators and defectors35. This co-existence dynamics stems from the formation of compact clusters that constrain the evolution of cooperation to the boundaries between regions dominated by individuals of a single type. In contrast, structures with high levels of degree heterogeneity (e.g. scale-free networks) prompt a coordination-like dynamics36,37 that result in the population being quickly driven to a monomorphic state which is dominated by one of the existing behaviors (i.e. either only cooperators or defectors). In these heterogeneous networks, the observed coordination dynamics results from the existence of higher degree nodes (i.e. hubs) that act as role models and lead to effective dynamics of competition between hubs. Thus, while both low and high heterogeneous networks promote cooperation, heterogeneous networks are able to promote cooperation in a wider range of social dilemmas.

Few works, though, have explored how a gradual interpolation between extreme levels of topological features in complex networks impact the outcome of dynamical processes. For instance, Santos et al.38 explored how the randomization of the connectivity patterns of a network–interpolating from a regular to a randomized homogeneous network–impacts the evolution of cooperative behavior and epidemic spreading. Following this line of research, we explore in this paper how the level of degree heterogeneity impacts the evolution of cooperation. For this purpose we analyze a wide range of networks with different levels of degree heterogeneity to show to which extent degree heterogeneity facilitates the dominance or co-existence of cooperators and/or defectors in a society.

Previous works have linked degree heterogeneity and degree variance also with social diversity, in the sense that it captures diversity among individual’s degrees of popularity and influence18. Social diversity is, however, not limited to popularity and influence, nor is it only able to be modeled through to the interaction structure of the population. Indeed, recent works have explored how diversity among interactions weights39, individuals’ aspirations40, wealth distribution4143, age distribution44, and the type of social dilemmas faced by individuals45 play an important role in dictating the fate of cooperative behavior in social systems. Central for the positive impact of diversity in promoting cooperation is the heterogeneous distribution of wealth and influence it generates46. Thus our work also contributes to a better understanding of how social diversity drives the evolution of cooperation in complex networks.

To explore how different levels of degree heterogeneity impact the evolution of cooperation, we make extensive Monte Carlo simulations of the evolutionary dynamics. Moreover, we consider a wide range of populations whose structures smoothly interpolate between low and high levels of heterogeneity (see Model Section). Our findings show that many situations require a minimum threshold level of heterogeneity for cooperation to be sustainable. Moreover, there is an optimal range of heterogeneity that maximizes the population’s resilience across a wide range of social dilemmas. This is the case because an increasingly heterogeneous network structure becomes increasingly correlated with the initial state of a few highly influential individuals (see Discussion section). The findings imply that neither very equal nor extremely unequal societies, in terms of their level of degree heterogeneity, tend to offer the best evolutionary outcome.

Model

Let us consider a population with Z individuals. The structure of interaction between the Z individuals of the population is modeled by means of a complex network, where nodes represent individuals, and the links between the nodes represent social relationships between the individuals. The total number of links of an individual i corresponds to his/her degree z i. The degree distribution, D(z), describes the fraction of individuals with degree z. To generate networks with different levels of degree heterogeneity D(z), we use an algorithm of network growth and biased preferential attachment by Fortunato et al.47. The algorithm proceeds as follows: it starts from a clique of three connected nodes and then sequentially Z − 3 other nodes are added; each of the newly added nodes gets attached to two pre-existing ones sampled proportionally to t α (α ≥ 0.0) where t corresponds to the age of the nodes. In the limiting case of Z → ∞, the networks exhibit a degree distribution of the form D(z) ≈ z γ with γ = (1 + α)/α 47,48. Here α takes the role of the degree heterogeneity parameter exhibiting a one-to-one relationship with var(z), so that a low (large) α is associated with a low (large) level of degree variance or heterogeneity.

Let us also consider that individuals behave unconditionally either as Cooperators (C) or Defectors (D). At each moment, there are k Cs and Zk Ds in the population. The evolutionary process follows the fermi update rule 49,50, thus at each time step a random individual (A) imitates the strategy of a random neighbor, B, with the probability

pAB=11+eβ(fBfA) 1

where β regulates the selection pressure (i.e. the level of randomness of the individuals’ decision to be a cooperator or a defector), while f i corresponds to the fitness of the individual i. When β ≪ 1, the population evolves under weak selection pressure; when β ≫ 1 the population evolves under strong selection pressure. In the limit of strong selection (large β), the results obtained under the fermi update rule become qualitatively similar to the replicator dynamics51.

Individuals obtain a payoff from each interaction with their neighbors. The value of the payoff depends only on the strategies of both. The four possible outcomes can be summarized in the following payoff matrix:

graphic file with name 41598_2017_15555_Equ1_HTML.gif

where R represents the Reward payoff resulting from mutual cooperation; P is the Punishment payoff from mutual defection; S is the Sucker’s payoff obtained by a Cooperator that faced a Defector; and T represents the Temptation payoff that a Defector obtains when facing a Cooperator. Here, we consider a simplified parameter space in which R = 1, P = 0, T = λ and S = 1 − λ with 1 ≤ λ ≤ 2. Hence, λ represents both the temptation for defection and the fear of being cheated, encapsulating the harshness of the dilemma faced by individuals.

The fitness of an individual corresponds to the accumulated payoff over all interactions in which he/she participates and can be computed as

fi=niC(1+λ)siλ(niD+niC) 2

where niC (niD) is the number of Cs (Ds) in the neighborhood of i (niC+niD=zi) and s i = 1 (0) if i is a C (D). Moreover, λ defines the strength of the dilemma faced by individuals. When λ > 0, individuals engage in the Prisoner’s Dilemma (PD) and λ captures both the temptation to defect towards a C and the fear of being cheated by a D.

In order to measure the impact of different network structures on the evolution of cooperation, we measure the level of cooperation (η x0). More details on how the level of cooperation (η x0) is computed can be found in the Methods section. We estimate η x0 starting from a fraction x 0 of cooperators and for different levels of selection pressure β, degree heterogeneity α, and harshness of the social dilemma λ. The level of cooperation (η x0) can thus be understood as the expected number of cooperators in the equilibrium. In order to explore the role that different individuals play in the evolutionary dynamics, we classify the individuals according to their network degree18. Hence let us denote nodes as low degree (LDN) if their degree is bounded by 3z im α; medium degree (MDN) when m α < 3z i ≤ 2m α; and high degree (HDN) for 3z i > 2m α, where m α corresponds to the observed maximum degree of an individual in a network with a level of degree heterogeneity of α.

Results and Discussion

We start by analyzing how the level of degree heterogeneity (α) and the selection pressure (β) impact the level of cooperation (ηx0) under different values of dilemma strength (λ). In the panels A, B and C of Fig. 1, three different regions can be highlighted according to their evolutionary outcome: (i) the domain of parameters strictly dominated by Ds (blue region); (ii) the domain of parameters strictly dominated by Cs (red region) and (iii) the domain of parameters where neither Cs or Ds are strictly dominant. The results in Fig. 1 suggest that cooperation requires a minimum level of degree heterogeneity (α) to be evolutionary viable – i.e. to achieve a state of C dominance with a non-zero likelihood. This result is particularly evident under weaker selection regimes (β < 1). Moreover, there is a region in the α × β domain under which the viability of cooperation is more resilient to variations in the harshness of the social dilemma faced by individuals (λ).

Figure 1.

Figure 1

The impact of degree heterogeneity (0.0 ≤ α ≤ 1.25) and intensity of selection (10−2β ≤ 102) on the level of cooperation (ηx0=0.5) under different values of the harshness of the social dilemmas that the individuals face: λ = 1.15 (left), 1.25 (center) and 1.35 (right). Blue areas indicate the parameters that lead to a full dominance of Defector and Red regions denote areas of Cooperator dominance. White areas correspond to scenarios in which it is equally likely for the population to reach either a state fully dominated by Cooperators or Defectors. The horizontal line marks β = 0.3. All simulations have been conducted in populations with Z = 103 individuals and start from a configuration with equal composition of strategies.

It must be noted that optimal levels of selection pressure have been identified in previous works26,27,52. Here, though, we show that this effect is restricted to a certain interval of network heterogeneity, in our case for α > 0.6. Figure 2A shows how the level of cooperation is affected by degree heterogeneity for different levels of the dilemma strength. While a sharp transition in the levels of cooperation characterizes the evolution under small values of degree heterogeneity, increasing values of degree heterogeneity lead to a slower decay of cooperation with rising levels of dilemma strengths.

Figure 2.

Figure 2

Population-wide dynamics for a wide range of levels of heterogeneity. (Panel A) shows how the level of cooperation changes for variation of λ and α with β = 0.3. Although the level of cooperation ηx0 increases with increasing α the range of λ strictly dominated by cooperators decreases. (Panel B) shows the Average Gradient of Selection (Γg(k)) after 150 generations for λ = 1.25 and β = 0.3 for a wide range of α values. The red line shows how the respective levels of cooperation change under the parameters as used to compute Γg(k). Panels C and D show how Average Gradient of Selection changes over time until the 150th generation. In (panels B, C and D), λ = 1.25 and β = 0.3. The dark areas denote regions in which Γg(k) < 0 and white areas in which Γg(k) > 0.

Previous works have shown that heterogeneous networks facilitate a coordination-like dynamics at the population-wide level36. Hence, next we compute the Average Gradient of Selection (Γg(k)) in order to inspect of the nature of the population-wide dynamics with different levels of degree heterogeneity. Details on how to compute Γg(k) can be found in the methods section. In a nutshell, negative (positive) values of Γg(k) indicate that a population with k Cooperators and Zk Defectors population is more likely to see an decrease (increase) in the number of cooperators. For instance, in a well-mixed population (i.e. a complete graph, where all individuals are connected with each other) and when individuals engage in the Prisoner’s Dilemma, we observe Γg(k) to be always negative within the interval 0 < k < Z. Moreover, Γg(k) has two trivial solutions, one at k * = 0 and another at k * = Z. Hence, we inspect the existence of internal solutions (k *) that lie inside the domain 0 < k * < Z.

Figure 2B shows the internal fixed points of the Average Gradient of Selection (Γg(k)) at the 150th generation. Gray areas represent regions in which Γg(k) < 0 and white areas regions in which Γg(k) > 0. Arrows point towards the direction of selection. White circles represent coordination points. These are unstable fixed points, because when the population is close to one of this points it will evolve away from such state. Conversely, black circles represent co-existence points. These are stable fixed points, because the population will converge to such a state. We see that for the interval of heterogeneity under analysis the Γg(k) is mostly dominated by a single coordination point (x L), which implies that the population will be driven to a monomorphic state, depending on the initial fraction of cooperators (x 0). Hence, these results reassure us that measuring the level of cooperation (ηx0) equates to finding the likelihood with which a population reaches a state of full cooperation.

Figure 2C and D shows the internal fixed points of Γg(k) during the first 150 generations when α = 0.35 and α = 1.00, respectively. Although at the beginning the Γg(k) is mostly a negative, the evolutionary dynamics will lead to the emergence of an internal coordination point, which shapes the outcome of the population.

Next, we show the level of cooperation (ηx0=0.5) as a function of the temptation to defect (λ) and of the level of degree heterogeneity (α) in the case of a weak (β = 0.3) and a strong (β = 3.0) selection pressure (see Fig. 3A and B). The level of heterogeneity largely defines the domain of social dilemmas under which cooperation is evolutionary viable. Although increasing levels of degree heterogeneity diminishes the range of λ that are strictly dominated by Ds, the degree heterogeneity also does not increase the region strictly dominated by Cs. In fact, for low selection pressures there is an optimal level of heterogeneity that maximizes the range of social dilemmas strictly dominated by Cs. For β = 0.3 this is between 0.6 ≤ α ≤ 0.9. This implies that if a population structure evolves to become increasingly heterogeneous, the population will eventually reach a level under which cooperation becomes less viable. Moreover, Fig. 3A and B show that for increasing levels of degree heterogeneity there is an increase in the region in which neither strategy is strictly dominant (white area), a result that is also suggested from the analysis of the α × β domain in Fig. 1A,B and C.

Figure 3.

Figure 3

Panels A and B show the level of cooperation (η) while panels C, D, E and F show the correlations between the initial state of Low Degree Nodes (LDN), Medium Degree Nodes (MDN) and High Degree Nodes (HDN). All panels explore these quantities as a function of the harshness of the social dilemmas λ the individuals face and the degree heterogeneity α of the population structure. The left column shows results for β = 0.3 while the right column considers β = 3.0. All results have been computed for a population size of Z = 103 and an average degree of 〈k〉 = 4.

We scrutinize the mechanisms that lead to the prevalence of balanced levels of cooperation (white regions) for such a wide range of parameters. Our hypothesis is that the evolutionary outcome of the population becomes correlated with the initial state of the most well-connected individuals. With increasing levels of degree heterogeneity, the higher connected individuals (hubs) also receive more and more connections during the network growth. In consequence, the network becomes increasingly more unequal in terms of the distribution of influence and wealth. In other words, the fact that a small number of individuals in the population can participate in the majority of the available social interactions, thus accumulating a proportionally large fitness, results in these individuals dictating the outcome of the population according to their initial state.

To explore this hypothesis, we compute the phi correlation (ϕ M) between the initial strategy of individuals in a degree class (LDN, MDN or HDG) and the final state of the population. This quantity is formally defined as

φM=nM(C,C)nM(D,D)nM(D,C)nM(D,C)nM(C,)nM(,C)nM(D,)nM(,D) 3

where n M(X, Y) is the number of times we observe an individual in the degree class M with initial strategy X in a simulation where the population ended in a state dominated by strategy Y, n M(X, •) = n M(X, Y) + n M(X, X) and n M(•, X) = n M(X, X) + n M(Y, X). Hence, when ϕ M = 0, the initial state of the nodes in degree class M are not correlated with the final state of the population, however when ϕ M = 1, the population always ends up in a state dominated by the initial strategy of the nodes of degree class M. Conversely, when ϕ M = −1, the population always ends up in the opposite state of the initial strategy of the nodes of degree class M.

Figure 3C to H show the correlation between the initial state of individuals from different degree classes and the final state of the population. We draw three main conclusions from these results: (i) in the region dominated by a single strategy (blue and red areas in Fig. 4A and B) the final state is not predicted by the elements of any of the degree classes; (ii) Medium degree (MDN) and Low degree (LDN) nodes are weak predictors of the final level of cooperation; and (iii) the most connected, high degree, individuals (HDN) play a fundamental role in the region associated with a balanced levels of cooperation. In this region, we observe a strong correlation between their initial state and the fate of the population, meaning that the evolutionary outcome of the society depends on the probability (set by the initial fraction of cooperators parameter) of the highly connected individuals starting as cooperators or defectors. This confirms the hypothesis that the evolutionary outcome is driven by the initial state of the most influential individuals in the population. Moreover, HDN nodes play a central role in determining the final level of cooperation of the population in domains associated with the phase transition between the two strictly dominance regimes. Indeed, at this point the evolution of cooperation is dictated by the initial state of the most influential and wealthiest individuals.

Figure 4.

Figure 4

Level of Cooperation (ηx0) as a function of the initial fraction of Cooperators, and for different levels of degree heterogeneity, α. The red areas correspond to areas that are strictly dominated by Cooperators, the blue areas are dominated by Defectors. The horizontal line indicates x 0 = 0.5. All simulations have been conducted with populations of Z = 103 individuals, an average degree of 〈z〉 = 4 and a selection pressure of β = 0.3.

However, the initial state of the most influential individuals (HDN) does not suffice in explaining what determines the final evolutionary outcome of the society. Without the existence of other Cs in the population, the odds of cooperation being sustainable are very slim. Figure 4 shows how the evolutionary outcome (ηx0) depends on the initial abundance of cooperators (x 0 in the Y-axis) under different heterogeneity levels (α in the X-axis) and the temptation to defect (λ). Again, it is clear that the evolution of cooperation requires a minimum level of degree heterogeneity and, moreover, a minimum number of cooperators to be evolutionary viable. For increasingly difficult social dilemmas, i.e. larger λ, cooperation viability requires a larger level of degree heterogeneity, hence a more unequal population.

Figure 5 shows the correlation between the initial state of the most influential individuals (HDN) and the final state of the population under similar conditions as considered in Fig. 4. The obtained results suggest, once again, a strong correlation in the domain characterized by a balanced levels of cooperation (non-blue or non-red areas in Fig. 4).

Figure 5.

Figure 5

Correlation between initial state of high degree nodes and the final state of the population (ϕ HDN) as a function of the initial fraction of Cooperators and for different levels of degree heterogeneity (α). Red (Yellow) areas correspond to regions in which the initial state of higher degree nodes is highly correlated (uncorrelated) with the final state of the population. All simulations have been conducted with populations of Z = 103 individuals, average degree of 〈z〉 = 4 and selection pressure of β = 0.3.

Conclusions

In this work we have explored how different levels of degree heterogeneity impact the evolution of cooperation in the Prisoner’s Dilemma. To that end, we made use of an algorithm of network growth and biased preferential attachment to generate a large set of network structures that interpolate between low and high levels of heterogeneity.

We find evidence of a threshold level of degree heterogeneity above which there is a substantial increase in the range of dilemmas where cooperation is evolutionary dominant. More importantly, we show that increasing levels of degree heterogeneity lead to an evolutionary trade off for populations: although the range of dilemmas in which cooperation can evolve increases, the range of dilemmas under which cooperation is strictly dominant decreases. Indeed, we observe that the evolution of cooperation becomes coupled with the initial state of the most well connected individuals. Hence, the ability of populations to overcome the underlying social dilemmas individuals engage becomes tied to the ability of a few individuals do so. Our findings imply that neither equal nor very unequal societies (in terms of degree heterogeneity) tend to offer the best evolutionary outcome, but instead suggest that there is an optimal level of equality. Although here we have explored static structures, recent works have shown how co-evolution of population structure often leads to an increase in degree heterogeneity5356. Whenever the degree heterogeneity of a population increases, it also increases the dependence of the population on the decisions of a handful of influential individuals.

Open questions, though, are whether competition between societies can explain the preferential selection of heterogeneous social structures and whether a particular level of heterogeneity is favored under such a competitive environment. Finally, we explored the role of degree heterogeneity in the context of the evolution of cooperation. Our results suggest that there is a need to pay attention to the role that different levels of network heterogeneity play in the context of opinion dynamics and epidemic outbreaks.

Methods

Level of cooperation

(ηx0) is estimated by averaging the number of cooperators in the population after a large transient period of up to 105 generations from 104 independent simulations. Each simulation lasts for 5 × 103 generations and starts from a fraction x 0 of Cs that are randomly distributed across the network. Given the coordination nature of the population-wide dynamics in heterogeneous networks36, ηx0 provides a good approximation of the likelihood of a population reaching a monomorphic state dominated by Cs. Along the manuscript we compute under ηx0 different scenarios of degree heterogeneity (α), selection pressure (β) and the temptation to defect (λ).

Average Gradient of Selection

(AGoS) captures the population-wide dynamics on structured populations. This quantity is the numerical counterpart of the drift term in a Birth-Death stochastic processes on finite and well-mixed populations57. We can estimate this quantity conveniently by computing the difference between the probability to increase (ξg+(k)) and the probability to decrease (ξg(k)) the number of Cooperators by one when the population is in a state with k Cooperators and Zk Defectors. The AGoS is, thus, formally defined as

Γg(k)=ξg+(k)ξg(k) 4

where ξg±(k) is numerically computed according to

ξg±(k)=1Λg(k)ω=1Ωt=1tmaxδ(k,kt)Θ(tZ,g))ξω±(k,t) 5

where Λg(k) accounts for the total number of times the population was observed in a state with k Cooperators at generation g over all Ω simulations and Θ(a,b) is a square discrete function that is equal to 1 if b − 1 ≤ a < b, being 0 otherwise. Finally ξω±(k,t) is the transition probability at time t of time-series ω, that is

ξω±(k,t)=1Zi=1Z1zijζi1δ(sj,si)1+eβ(fjfi) 6

where ζ j is the set of closest neighbours of j and k t is the number of Cs at time t. In this expression, the first sum is calculated over each individual in the population and the second sum is calculated over each individual’s neighbourhood. In order to estimate Γ(k) we let a population evolve for 150 generations. Each simulation of the evolutionary process starts from a possible random state (i.e. starting from a random number of Cooperators k randomly selected from the interval 1 < k < Z). We repeat this for a total of Ω = 2.5 × 107 times. For each iteration we estimate the ξω±(k,t) as described above.

Acknowledgements

This work was funded by the Cooperative Agreement between the Masdar Institute of Science and Technology and the MIT Media Lab Consortia. The authors would like to thank Pedro Neves, Fernando P. Santos, Vítor V. Vasconcelos, Cristian Candia-Castro-Vallejos, Francisco C. Santos and Jorge M. Pacheco for helpful discussions and insights and the two anonymous referees for the helpful feedback.

Author Contributions

F.L.P. and D.H. conceived the experiment(s), conducted the experiment(s) and analyzed the results.

Competing Interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Footnotes

Publisher's note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Contributor Information

Flávio L. Pinheiro, Email: flaviopp@mit.edu

Dominik Hartmann, Email: dominik.hartmann@uni-leipzig.de.

References

  • 1.Nowak MA, May RM. Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature. 1992;359:826–829. doi: 10.1038/359826a0. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Barrat, A., Barthelemy, M. & Vespignani, A. Dynamical processes on complex networks (Cambridge university press, 2008).
  • 3.Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A. Epidemic spreading in scale-free networks. Physical Review Letters. 2001;86:3200. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.86.3200. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Moreno Y, Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A. Epidemic outbreaks in complex heterogeneous networks. The European Physical Journal B-Condensed Matter and Complex Systems. 2002;26:521–529. [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Newman ME. Spread of epidemic disease on networks. Physical review E. 2002;66:016128. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.66.016128. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Kocsis G, Kun F. The effect of network topologies on the spreading of technological developments. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment. 2008;2008:P10014. doi: 10.1088/1742-5468/2008/10/P10014. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Castellano C, Fortunato S, Loreto V. Statistical physics of social dynamics. Reviews of Modern Physics. 2009;81:591. doi: 10.1103/RevModPhys.81.591. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Fortunato S. Damage spreading and opinion dynamics on scale-free networks. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications. 2005;348:683–690. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2004.09.007. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A. Opinion dynamics and learning in social networks. Dynamic Games and Applications. 2011;1:3–49. doi: 10.1007/s13235-010-0004-1. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Sood V, Redner S. Voter model on heterogeneous graphs. Physical Review Letters. 2005;94:178701. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.94.178701. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Szabó G, Fath G. Evolutionary games on graphs. Physics Reports. 2007;446:97–216. doi: 10.1016/j.physrep.2007.04.004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Rand DG, Nowak MA, Fowler JH, Christakis NA. Static network structure can stabilize human cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 2014;111:17093–17098. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1400406111. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Liljeros F, Edling CR, Amaral LAN, Stanley HE, Åberg Y. The web of human sexual contacts. Nature. 2001;411:907–908. doi: 10.1038/35082140. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Dorogovtsev, S. N. & Mendes, J. F. Evolution of networks: From biological nets to the Internet and WWW (OUP Oxford, 2013).
  • 15.Csányi G, Szendröi B. Structure of a large social network. Physical Review E. 2004;69:036131. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.69.036131. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Mislove, A., Marcon, M., Gummadi, K. P., Druschel, P. & Bhattacharjee, B. Measurement and analysis of online social networks. In Proceedings of the 7th ACM SIGCOMM conference on Internet measurement, 29–42 (ACM, 2007).
  • 17.Gjoka, M., Kurant, M., Butts, C. T. & Markopoulou, A. Walking in facebook: A case study of unbiased sampling of osns. In Infocom, 2010 Proceedings IEEE, 1–9 (IEEE, 2010).
  • 18.Santos FC, Pinheiro FL, Lenaerts T, Pacheco JM. The role of diversity in the evolution of cooperation. Journal of Theoretical Biology. 2012;299:88–96. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2011.09.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Perc, M. et al. Statistical physics of human cooperation. Physics Reports (2017).
  • 20.Nowak, M. A. Evolutionary Dynamics (Harvard University Press, 2006).
  • 21.Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. Evolutionary games and population dynamics (Cambridge university press, 1998).
  • 22.Nowak MA. Evolving cooperation. Journal of Theoretical Biology. 2012;299:1–8. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2012.01.014. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Nakamaru M, Matsuda H, Iwasa Y. The evolution of cooperation in a lattice-structured population. Journal of Theoretical Biology. 1997;184:65–81. doi: 10.1006/jtbi.1996.0243. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Szolnoki A, Szabó G. Cooperation enhanced by inhomogeneous activity of teaching for evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma games. Europhysics Letters. 2007;77:30004. doi: 10.1209/0295-5075/77/30004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Szabó G, Töke C. Evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma game on a square lattice. Physical Review E. 1998;58:69. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.58.69. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Szabó G, Vukov J, Szolnoki A. Phase diagrams for an evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma game on two-dimensional lattices. Physical Review E. 2005;72:047107. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.72.047107. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Vukov J, Szabó G, Szolnoki A. Cooperation in the noisy case: Prisoner’s dilemma game on two types of regular random graphs. Physical Review E. 2006;73:067103. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.73.067103. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Santos FC, Pacheco JM. Scale-free networks provide a unifying framework for the emergence of cooperation. Physical Review Letters. 2005;95:098104. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.95.098104. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Santos FC, Santos MD, Pacheco JM. Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games. Nature. 2008;454:213–216. doi: 10.1038/nature06940. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Assenza S, Gómez-Gardeñes J, Latora V. Enhancement of cooperation in highly clustered scale-free networks. Physical Review E. 2008;78:017101. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.78.017101. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Poncela J, Gómez-Gardenes J, Flora L, Moreno Y. Robustness of cooperation in the evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma on complex networks. New Journal of Physics. 2007;9:184. doi: 10.1088/1367-2630/9/6/184. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Poncela J, Gómez-Gardenes J, Moreno Y. Cooperation in scale-free networks with limited associative capacities. Physical Review E. 2011;83:057101. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.83.057101. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Xia C-Y, Meng X-K, Wang Z. Heterogeneous coupling between interdependent lattices promotes the cooperation in the prisoner’s dilemma game. PLoS ONE. 2015;10:e0129542. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0129542. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Jin, Q., Wang, L., Xia, C.-Y. & Wang, Z. Spontaneous symmetry breaking in interdependent networked game. Scientific reports4 (2014). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 35.Hauert C, Doebeli M. Spatial structure often inhibits the evolution of cooperation in the snowdrift game. Nature. 2004;428:643–646. doi: 10.1038/nature02360. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Pinheiro FL, Pacheco JM, Santos FC. From local to global dilemmas in social networks. PLoS ONE. 2012;7:e32114. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0032114. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Skyrms, B. The stag hunt and the evolution of social structure (Cambridge University Press, 2004).
  • 38.Santos FC, Rodrigues J, Pacheco JM. Epidemic spreading and cooperation dynamics on homogeneous small-world networks. Physical Review E. 2005;72:056128. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.72.056128. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Ma Z-Q, et al. Heterogeneous link weight promotes the cooperation in spatial prisoner’s dilemma. International Journal of Modern physics C. 2011;22:1257–1268. doi: 10.1142/S0129183111016877. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Perc M, Wang Z. Heterogeneous aspirations promote cooperation in the prisoner’s dilemma game. PLoS ONE. 2010;5:e15117. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0015117. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 41.Wang J, Fu F, Wang L. Effects of heterogeneous wealth distribution on public cooperation with collective risk. Physical Review E. 2010;82:016102. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.82.016102. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Xu B, Lan Y. The distribution of wealth and the effect of extortion in structured populations. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals. 2016;87:276–280. doi: 10.1016/j.chaos.2016.03.036. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 43.Hartmann, D. Economic complexity and human development: how economic diversification and social networks affect human agency and welfare, vol. 110 (Routledge, 2014).
  • 44.Wang Z, Zhu X, Arenzon JJ. Cooperation and age structure in spatial games. Physical Review E. 2012;85:011149. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.85.011149. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 45.Amaral MA, Wardil L, Perc M, da Silva JK. Evolutionary mixed games in structured populations: Cooperation and the benefits of heterogeneity. Physical Review E. 2016;93:042304. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.93.042304. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Perc M, Szolnoki A. Social diversity and promotion of cooperation in the spatial prisoner’s dilemma game. Physical Review E. 2008;77:011904. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.77.011904. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 47.Fortunato S, Flammini A, Menczer F. Scale-free network growth by ranking. Physical Review Letters. 2006;96:218701. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.96.218701. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 48.Goh K-I, Kahng B, Kim D. Universal behavior of load distribution in scale-free networks. Physical Review Letters. 2001;87:278701. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.87.278701. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Traulsen A, Nowak MA, Pacheco JM. Stochastic dynamics of invasion and fixation. Physical Review E. 2006;74:011909. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.74.011909. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.Traulsen A, Pacheco JM, Nowak MA. Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics. Journal of theoretical biology. 2007;246:522–529. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2007.01.002. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 51.Xia C-Y, Meloni S, Perc M, Moreno Y. Dynamic instability of cooperation due to diverse activity patterns in evolutionary social dilemmas. EPL (Europhysics letters) 2015;109:58002. doi: 10.1209/0295-5075/109/58002. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 52.Pinheiro FL, Santos FC, Pacheco JM. How selection pressure changes the nature of social dilemmas in structured populations. New Journal of Physics. 2012;14:073035. doi: 10.1088/1367-2630/14/7/073035. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 53.Santos FC, Pacheco JM, Lenaerts T. Cooperation prevails when individuals adjust their social ties. PLoS Comput Biol. 2006;2:e140. doi: 10.1371/journal.pcbi.0020140. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 54.Pinheiro FL, Santos FC, Pacheco JM. Linking individual and collective behavior in adaptive social networks. Physical Review Letters. 2016;116:128702. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.116.128702. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 55.Poncela J, Gómez-Gardenes J, Flora LM, Sánchez A, Moreno Y. Complex cooperative networks from evolutionary preferential attachment. PLoS ONE. 2008;3:e2449. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0002449. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 56.Poncela J, Gómez-Gardeñes J, Traulsen A, Moreno Y. Evolutionary game dynamics in a growing structured population. New Journal of Physics. 2009;11:083031. doi: 10.1088/1367-2630/11/8/083031. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 57.Traulsen A, Claussen JC, Hauert C. Coevolutionary dynamics in large, but finite populations. Physical Review E. 2006;74:011901. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.74.011901. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Articles from Scientific Reports are provided here courtesy of Nature Publishing Group

RESOURCES