Abstract
The decoy effect is a cognitive bias documented in behavioural economics by which the presence of a third, (partly) inferior choice causes a significant shift in people’s preference for other items. Here, we performed an experiment with human volunteers who played a variant of the repeated prisoner’s dilemma game in which the standard options of “cooperate” and “defect” are supplemented with a new, decoy option, “reward”. We show that although volunteers rarely chose the decoy option, its availability sparks a significant increase in overall cooperativeness and improves the likelihood of success for cooperative individuals in this game. The presence of the decoy increased willingness of volunteers to cooperate in the first step of each game, leading to subsequent propagation of such willingness by (noisy) tit-for-tat. Our study thus points to decoys as a means to elicit voluntary prosocial action across a spectrum of collective endeavours.
The decoy effect refers to the fact that the presence of a third option can shift people’s preferences between two other options even though the third option is inferior to both. Here, the authors show how the decoy effect can enhance cooperation in a social dilemma, the repeated prisoner’s dilemma.
Introduction
Neoclassical economics has ascribed human actions to a relentless rational drive to maximise the (expected) utility1–5, even as the economic models struggled to account for the full range of displayed behaviours6–8. The apparent discrepancy between theory and reality ultimately gave birth to the field of behavioural economics, which has since amassed indisputable evidence to the effect that various cognitive biases stand in the way of the completely rational behaviour of economic agents9–12. Our focus is on the decoy effect, also known as the asymmetric dominance effect13 or the attraction effect14, which appears in multiple-choice situations in which a particular choice called “decoy” shares some defining characteristics with another choice called “target”, but is inferior to the target in one defining characteristic15. Because we apply the concept of decoy in the novel context of evolutionary game theory, it is crucial to establish which defining (shared and inferior) characteristics are relevant to this context, as will be done in a moment. We emphasise for now that while decoys should be inconsequential to decision-making, they have been found to increase the attractiveness of the target, even in real-world political elections16. The effect’s strength, however, seems to diminish in the presence of more meaningful stimulus descriptions17. Motivated by this finding, multiple recent studies questioned the limits of validity of the decoy effect18–21.
Apart from behavioural economics, evolutionary game theory is another research field in which considerable attention has been devoted to the study of human behaviour, offering, for instance, an updated view on cognitive biases22–24. The work on the evolution of human cooperation in particular boasts a rich mathematical modelling legacy25,26 complemented by a more recent track of social dilemma experimentation27–32, as well as somewhat rarer attempts to reconcile theoretical and empirical perspectives33–35. While the basic concepts are shared with economics (cf., fitness vs. utility), evolutionary game theory introduces an extra explanatory dimension behind fitness maximisation via the process of selection. Specifically, selection describes temporal evolution towards maximum fitness during which human reasoning faculties eliminate suboptimal behaviours in a trial-and-error manner. It is largely unknown, however, if the process of selection can be manipulated by means of cognitive biases.
We set up an experimental attempt within the bounds of evolutionary game theory designed to observe the decoy effect at work. Specifically, we organised a repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma (rPD) game which, based on both theory and previous experience32, should cause defection to considerably exceed cooperation. We then enriched this game with a third, decoy option to “throw off” players and get them to cooperate with one another early in the game. Finally, we asked whether such an initial burst of cooperation can be stabilised or whether players recognise that from a purely rational perspective the decoy option is irrelevant, leading to a gradual replacement of cooperation with mutual defection.
We recruited 388 undergraduate volunteers (mean age = 19.8, 67.8% women) to engage in the rPD game consisting of random pairwise encounters. Each encounter lasted, on average, four rounds because after any given round, a computer system could signal the end of the encounter with 25% probability. We allowed experimental sessions to run for about 75 min, leading to approximately 20 encounters per session. The purpose of these sessions was to contrast a control treatment, wherein the only actions available were cooperation (C) and defection (D), with a decoy treatment, wherein an additional action to “reward” one another (R) was also available. We presented the basic rules of the rPD game to volunteers in a neutrally framed manner using the following unilateral and bilateral payoff matrices:
1 |
In particular, action 1 (i.e., C) meant giving up one unit for the opponent to receive two units. Action 2 (i.e., D) meant earning one unit at the opponent’s expense of one unit. Finally, action 3 (i.e., R) was qualitatively the same as action 1 with the distinction that one would give up two units for the opponent to receive three units in return. Further details on the experimental methods are given in the Methods section and the Supplementary Methods (see also Supplementary Figs. 1–3 and Supplementary Table 1). A picture emerging from this experimental setup is that reward is effective in promoting cooperation, but this effectiveness is a consequence of a cognitive bias known as the decoy effect. We therefore conclude that decoys possess an untapped potential to elicit voluntary prosocial action.
Results
Reward ignites cooperativeness
The presence of reward R in the rPD game ignites cooperativeness (Fig. 1). Compared to the control treatment, the frequency of cooperation C (defection D) in the decoy treatment is significantly higher (lower). The frequency of C is furthermore stable in time (Fig. 2). An immediate implication is that reward plays an instrumental role in promoting cooperation, yet opponents seldom use the opportunity to reward one another. Because C and R share the property of being cooperative actions, this kind of behaviour is consistent with the decoy effect as described by behavioural economists12,15, provided that R is also an inferior alternative to C.
How do we generally determine which action choice is worse and which is better? If our interest was solely in single-shot games, then Eq. (1) would indicate that—in a game-theoretic sense—defection D dominates over cooperation C, and both D and C dominate over reward R. This is seen from the bilateral payoff matrix in which payoffs associated with D (C) are higher than the corresponding payoffs associated with C (R). Unfortunately, game repetitions complicate matters, forcing us to consider (i) the nature of the social dilemma and (ii) the effect of repetitions. The nature of the dilemma is distilled in the concept of dilemma strength25,36. For example, by taking a difference between payoffs obtained for successful defection and mutual cooperation, and then normalising by the difference in payoffs obtained for mutual cooperation and mutual defection, we quantify how “lucrative” defection is relative to cooperation. Accordingly, the stronger the dilemma, the easier it gets for defectors to exploit cooperators (Supplementary Note 1; Supplementary Fig. 4). The effect of repetitions, by contrast, is to potentially change the nature of the dilemma37, at least in a probabilistic sense (Supplementary Note 2; Supplementary Fig. 5). This means that instead of having defection D as the only evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS), cooperation C may also become an ESS. For cooperators to prevail, their initial fraction must be sufficiently high to provide protection against excessive exploitation by defectors. This initial fraction is given by the dilemma strength parameter, DS, such that , where q is the game termination probability. The higher the value of DS, the higher the initial fraction of cooperators must be for them to prevail.
To apply the concept of dilemma strength for our purpose, we recognise from Eq. (1) that R is another form of cooperation, more costly than C, but also more beneficial for the opponent, and we look at which of the two actions better protects cooperators from excessive exploitation by defectors. Rationality dictates ignoring the form of cooperation that offers less protection, meaning that rational opponents should end up playing a 2 × 2 game consisting of either the (C, D) pair or the (D, R) pair. We find from Eq. (1) that for these pairs DS = 2 and DS = 3, respectively. A higher value of DS for pair (D, R) points to a less favourable dilemma and forces a conclusion that R is inferior to C. We thus learn that C and R share the defining characteristic of being cooperative actions, but R is inferior to C in another defining characteristic, i.e., resilience to exploitation by defectors. In the context of evolutionary game theory, therefore, R as defined in Eq. (1) is a valid decoy for C.
Reward’s effectiveness and a cognitive bias
Searching for mechanisms that explain improved cooperativeness in the decoy treatment, we find that reward is an effective cooperation promoter even before it can be used. Compared to the control treatment, the odds of an encounter starting with cooperation C (defection D) are significantly improved (suppressed) (Fig. 3a). Past the first round, response to C (D) in the previous round is overwhelmingly C (D) irrespective of the treatment (Fig. 3b, c). Reward R is mostly met with C or an occasional R (Fig. 3d). These results suggest that volunteers in our experiment play what can be characterised as noisy tit-for-tat (TFT) (Fig. 4).
In evolutionary game theory, cooperativeness prevails if it leads to success in terms of fitness or payoff. We find that in the control treatment, the average payoff per-round correlates negatively (positively) with cooperation C (defection D). This situation improves significantly in the decoy treatment, but the improvement is insufficient to make the average payoff per-round positively (negatively) correlated with C (D) (Fig. 5a, b). Our failure to clearly show that cooperativeness leads to success in the decoy treatment is puzzling and raises questions about the mechanisms underlying selection, which we address below. Interestingly, the average payoff per-round shows no correlation with R either (Fig. 5c). This should be compared with punishment in previous experiments29,30,32, wherein the performance of frequent punishers was dismal. Furthermore, the cooperation-promoting effect of punishment in these experiments was unreliable30,32 (but also see Ref. 38).
Our interpretation of the effectiveness of reward R is predicated on the correct perception of how valuable R is relative to cooperation C. We tested this perception in additional treatments in which the payoff matrix from Eq. (1) was generalised with reward parameter α (Fig. 6a), whose value was increased from α = 3 to α = 4 to α = 5. These increased values of α bring the dilemma strength of the (D, R) pair first to DS = 1.5 and then DS = 1, thus making R increasingly superior to C. Volunteers respond to changes in the relation between R and C as expected from the calculated dilemma strengths (Fig. 6b). The former option becomes more frequent than the latter as the distinction between the two becomes clearer. Increased cooperativeness in the decoy treatment is therefore truly attributable to a cognitive bias, specifically, the decoy effect. To account for all eventualities, we also examined how the results between treatments change due to two common confounding factors (Supplementary Note 3): gender (Supplementary Table 2) and academic background (Supplementary Table 3).
Discussion
Returning to the question on the mechanisms underlying selection, we attempt to provide an answer by connecting several pieces of evidence. First, the results here, as well as that of a similarly structured experiment32, were successfully recreated in computer simulations using the data on how opponents respond to each other’s most recent actions (Supplementary Note 4; Supplementary Fig. 6). That most recent actions are the only ones that are truly relevant is consistent with noisy TFT described in Fig. 3. To the extent that noise cancels out, which is a first-order effect, TFT should propagate initial frequencies of cooperation C and defection D through time because C is met with C and D is met with D. We find, however, that noise fails to cancel out completely, but rather exhibits a second-order effect in the form of a bias toward defection (Supplementary Note 5; Supplementary Fig. 7). This second-order effect acts as if the decoy’s effectiveness wears off through the course of an encounter. Fortunately, at the beginning of the very next encounter, the decoy’s effectiveness is restored, causing volunteers to be more cooperative again. The overall result is that, despite the fact that volunteers correctly perceive reward R as an inferior option, the initial burst of cooperativeness caused by the decoy effect is stabilised across more than 80 rounds of the game (Fig. 2).
Our study thus points to decoys as a means to elicit voluntary prosocial action across a spectrum of collective endeavours. A hypothetical example would be a small business team in which a member has fallen behind schedule. Although others may be reluctant to put extra hours to help their distressed colleague even if there is adequate overtime pay (the cooperative option), preferences may change by setting this overtime pay to decrease considerably some weeks before the deadline (the decoy option). Explained from such a psychological perspective, our results run the risk of appearing somewhat unsurprising. We therefore invite readers to contrast this explanation with an attempt at explaining why reward is a cooperation promoter solely within the bounds of evolutionary game theory. The latter explanation is unlikely to invoke cognitive biases as particularly relevant and would struggle with reward’s effectiveness before anyone can actually reward anyone. Deeper implications of the results for the evolution of human cooperation are admittedly less obvious (Supplementary Discussion), but with promising research directions crystallised, we believe that maintaining an optimistic perspective is warranted.
Methods
Experimental Protocol and Execution
We executed a total of 11 experimental sessions from May 2015 to April 2016 at the Behavioural Economics Lab of Yunnan University of Finance and Economics in Kunming City, China. Two sessions were dedicated to the control treatment, three to the decoy treatment, and additional six to testing whether volunteers correctly value reward R relative to cooperation C. An average of 35.3 volunteers per session participated in approximately 82.0 rounds of the game over the course of 22.9 encounters. No volunteer was allowed to participate in more than one session. The experiment was coded using the z-Tree software39.
We split each experimental session into three stages: preparatory, main and payout. During preparations, incoming volunteers were randomly assigned to isolated computer cubicles, where they would find instructions displayed on their computer screens, followed by a pre-game test to check the basic understanding of the rPD game. Thereafter, randomised pairing of volunteers preceded a practice pairwise encounter consisting of several rounds. In each round, paired volunteers were given 30 s to select one of the available options, and then another 30 s to examine the consequences of their selections.
The main stage of the experiment entailed a continuing sequence of randomised pairing and pairwise encounters for about 75 min. To keep track of individual success, each volunteer was endowed with an initial balance of 50 units, which changed from round to round based on decisions made and the rules in Eq. (1). Final balance, if positive, was converted into a monetary payout at a rate of ¥0.2 for 1 unit. This was supplemented with a show-up fee of ¥15, for an average payout of ¥43.3, ranging between ¥15 and ¥75.2.
In designing the experimental protocol, particular attention was paid to minimise framing effects. Terms such as “cooperation”, “defection” and “reward” invariably carry positive or negative connotations which may affect behaviour during the experiment. Seeing oneself as a cooperator may boost one’s self-image, whereas seeing oneself as a defector may affront this self-image. Therefore, options available to volunteers during the experimental sessions were labelled simply “1”, “2” and “3” and described in terms of the effect on one’s own payoff, i.e., the unilateral payoff matrix in Eq. (1).
Ethics statement
The experiment was approved by the Yunnan University of Finance and Economics Ethics Committee on the use of human participants in research, and carried out in accordance with all relevant guidelines. We obtained informed consent from all volunteers.
Data availability
The datasets generated and analysed during the current study are available in the Open Science Framework repository, 10.17605/OSF.IO/EHJS340.
Electronic supplementary material
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Prof. Petter Holme, Prof. Xuelong Li, Dr. Yuichi Iwasaki, Dr. Peican Zhu, Dr. Jinzhuo Liu and Dr. Chen Chu for useful discussions and Chen Shen, Yini Geng, Hao Guo, Yongjuan Ma, Danyang Jia and Yuan Li for technical help. We acknowledge support from (i) the Research Grant Programme of Inamori Foundation to M.J., (ii) the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant nos. 31700393 and 11671348) to L.S., (iii) the National 1000 Young Talent Plan (No. W099102), the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (no. G2017KY0001), and China Computer Federation–Tencent Open Fund (No. IAGR20170119) to Z.W. and (iv) the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS), Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research B to Y.I. (No. 15H04423).
Author contributions
Z.W., M.J., J.-H.L. Y.I. and S.B. designed the experiment. Z.W. and L.S. performed the experiment. Z.W. and M.J. analysed the data. M.J. and J.-H.L. performed mathematical and numerical analyses. All authors discussed the results and wrote the manuscript.
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing interests.
Footnotes
These authors contributed equally: Zhen Wang, Marko Jusup.
Electronic supplementary material
Supplementary Information accompanies this paper at 10.1038/s41467-018-05259-5.
Publisher's note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Contributor Information
Zhen Wang, Email: w-zhen@nwpu.edu.cn.
Marko Jusup, Email: mjusup@gmail.com.
Lei Shi, Email: lshi@ynufe.edu.cn.
References
- 1.Von Neumann, J. & Morgenstern, O. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior (Princeton University Press, 2007).
- 2.Friedman M, Savage LJ. The utility analysis of choices involving risk. J. Polit. Econ. 1948;56:279–304. doi: 10.1086/256692. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Marschak J. Rational behavior, uncertain prospects, and measurable utility. Econometrica. 1950;18:111–141. doi: 10.2307/1907264. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 4.Friedman M, Savage LJ. The expected-utility hypothesis and the measurability of utility. J. Polit. Econ. 1952;60:463–474. doi: 10.1086/257308. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Herstein IN, Milnor J. An axiomatic approach to measurable utility. Econometrica. 1953;21:291–297. doi: 10.2307/1905540. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Tversky A. Elimination by aspects: a theory of choice. Psychol. Rev. 1972;79:281–299. doi: 10.1037/h0032955. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica. 1979;47:263–291. doi: 10.2307/1914185. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Schoemaker PJ. The expected-utility model: Its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. J. Econ. Lit. 1982;20:529–563. [Google Scholar]
- 9.Tversky A. Intransitivity of preferences. Psychol. Rev. 1969;76:31–48. doi: 10.1037/h0026750. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Kahneman D, Tversky A. Subjective probability: a judgment of representativeness. Cogn. Psychol. 1972;3:430–454. doi: 10.1016/0010-0285(72)90016-3. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Tversky A, Kahneman D. Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science. 1974;185:1124–1131. doi: 10.1126/science.185.4157.1124. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Huber J, Payne JW, Puto C. Adding asymmetrically dominated alternatives: violations of regularity and the similarity hypothesis. J. Consum. Res. 1982;9:90–98. doi: 10.1086/208899. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Ariely D, Wallsten TS. Seeking subjective dominance in multidimensional space: an explanation of the asymmetric dominance effect. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 1995;63:223–232. doi: 10.1006/obhd.1995.1075. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 14.Mishra S, Umesh U, Stem DE., Jr Antecedents of the attraction effect: an information-processing approach. J. Mark. Res. 1993;63:331–349. doi: 10.2307/3172885. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Pettibone JC, Wedell DH. Examining models of nondominated decoy effects across judgment and choice. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 2000;81:300–328. doi: 10.1006/obhd.1999.2880. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 16.O’Curry, Y. P. S. & Pitts, R. The attraction effect and political choice in two elections. J. Consum. Psychol. 4, 85–101 (1995).
- 17.Ratneshwar S, Shocker AD, Stewart DW. Toward understanding the attraction effect: The implications of product stimulus meaningfulness and familiarity. J. Consum. Res. 1987;13:520–533. doi: 10.1086/209085. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 18.Malaviya P, Sivakumar K. The influence of choice justification and stimulus meaningfulness on the attraction effect. J. Mark. Theor. Pract. 2002;10:20–29. doi: 10.1080/10696679.2002.11501923. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 19.Frederick S, Lee L, Baskin E. The limits of attraction. J. Mark. Res. 2014;51:487–507. doi: 10.1509/jmr.12.0061. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 20.Huber J, Payne JW, Puto CP. Let’s be honest about the attraction effect. J. Mark. Res. 2014;51:520–525. doi: 10.1509/jmr.14.0208. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 21.Yang S, Lynn M. More evidence challenging the robustness and usefulness of the attraction effect. J. Mark. Res. 2014;51:508–513. doi: 10.1509/jmr.14.0020. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Houston AI, McNamara JM, Steer MD. Violations of transitivity under fitness maximization. Biol. Lett. 2007;3:365–367. doi: 10.1098/rsbl.2007.0111. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Trimmer PC. Optimal behaviour can violate the principle of regularity. Proc. R. Soc. B. 2013;280:20130858. doi: 10.1098/rspb.2013.0858. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 24.Fawcett TW, et al. The evolution of decision rules in complex environments. Trends Cogn. Sci. 2014;18:153–161. doi: 10.1016/j.tics.2013.12.012. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 25.Wang Z, Kokubo S, Jusup M, Tanimoto J. Universal scaling for the dilemma strength in evolutionary games. Phys. Life Rev. 2015;14:1–30. doi: 10.1016/j.plrev.2015.04.033. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 26.Perc M, et al. Statistical physics of human cooperation. Phys. Rep. 2017;687:1–51. doi: 10.1016/j.physrep.2017.05.004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Wedekind C, Milinski M. Cooperation through image scoring in humans. Science. 2000;288:850–852. doi: 10.1126/science.288.5467.850. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 28.Fehr E, Gächter S. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature. 2002;415:137–140. doi: 10.1038/415137a. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 29.Dreber A, Rand DG, Fudenberg D, Nowak MA. Winners don’t punish. Nature. 2008;452:348–351. doi: 10.1038/nature06723. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 30.Wu JJ, et al. Costly punishment does not always increase cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA. 2009;106:17448–17451. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0905918106. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 31.Rand DG, Nowak MA, Fowler JH, Christakis NA. Static network structure can stabilize human cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA. 2014;111:17093–17098. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1400406111. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 32.Wang Z, et al. Onymity promotes cooperation in social dilemma experiments. Sci. Adv. 2017;3:e1601444. doi: 10.1126/sciadv.1601444. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 33.Sigmund K, Hauert C, Nowak MA. Reward and punishment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA. 2001;98:10757–10762. doi: 10.1073/pnas.161155698. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 34.Hauert C, Traulsen A, Brandt H, Nowak MA, Sigmund K. Via freedom to coercion: the emergence of costly punishment. Science. 2007;316:1905–1907. doi: 10.1126/science.1141588. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 35.Sánchez A. Physics of human cooperation: experimental evidence and theoretical models. J. Stat. Mech. Theory Exp. 2018;2018:024001. doi: 10.1088/1742-5468/aaa388. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 36.Tudge SJ, Brede M. A tale of two theorems: Comment on “Universal scaling for the dilemma strength in evolutionary games” by Z. Wang et al. Phys. Life Rev. 2015;14:49–51. doi: 10.1016/j.plrev.2015.07.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 37.Taylor C, Nowak MA. Transforming the dilemma. Evolution. 2007;61:2281–2292. doi: 10.1111/j.1558-5646.2007.00196.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 38.Gächter S, Renner E, Sefton M. The long-run benefits of punishment. Science. 2008;322:1510. doi: 10.1126/science.1164744. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 39.Fischbacher U. z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp. Econ. 2007;10:171–178. doi: 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 40.Wang, Z. et al. Exploiting a cognitive bias promotes cooperation in social dilemma experiments: Datasets. Open Science Framework, 10.17605/OSF.IO/EHJS3 (2018). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Supplementary Materials
Data Availability Statement
The datasets generated and analysed during the current study are available in the Open Science Framework repository, 10.17605/OSF.IO/EHJS340.