Skip to main content
EPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to EPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2018 Sep 11.
Published in final edited form as: Environ Toxicol Chem. 2017 Apr;36(4):867–868. doi: 10.1002/etc.3763

Ecosystem Services Deserve Better than “Dirty Paper” – Reply to Peter Calow

PM Chapman 1,*, H Selck 2, N Doorn 3, WR Munns Jr 4
PMCID: PMC6132052  NIHMSID: NIHMS1504140  PMID: 28370294

We thank Calow [1] for his Letter supporting our recommendation for the use of the ecosystem services approach as the common currency for risk assessment and management [2]. However, he also expressed concern about capturing the preferences that the public have for the services that they get from ecosystems in a way that can be weighed against the inevitable cost of interventions. This is a valid concern.

Calow advocates monetary terms [1, 3]. As we noted, preferences (i.e., ecosystem services valuation) can be captured in monetary or non-monetary terms [2]. However, Calow [1] does not acknowledge that other systems of valuation can usefully inform decision-making. In contrast, we side with writer Carolyn Brown, who in her book ‘The Trouble with Texas Cowboys’, aptly noted that money is just dirty paper. There are other, arguably better ways to value ecosystem services.

Monetization of changes in ecosystem services has substantial uncertainty because most ecosystem services are not traded in markets; thus, they have no set monetary value. Other methods of valuing ecosystem services also have uncertainty. However, economic methods of valuation such as indirect revealed preference (e.g., determining a value for clean air by comparing property values in areas with clean air compared to areas with polluted air), avoidance of costs (e.g., natural sewage treatment resulting in negligible impacts [4] vs costly treatment plants), and contingent valuation (e.g., hypothetical surveys of how individuals value incremental changes) are unreliable [5]. Monetization of ecosystem services is not always feasible, practical, nor desirable [6], particularly for complex social-ecological systems [7].

We fully agree with Calow [1] that the ecosystem services concept is anthropocentric – ecosystems have “rights” (i.e., we have duties toward them) because we value them for the benefits they provide for us. We also fully agree with a cost-benefit approach, with decisions based upon the preferences of those affected. But people and their well-being are more valuable than is capital accumulation [7].

We acknowledge that preferences based on money may be beneficial when considering aspects of some situations; however, this is not universally the case [8]. Complete reliance on monetary valuation in the case study of pesticide use to enhance banana production in Costa Rica [9] may be problematic rather than the opposite as Calow [1] suggests. The benefits of using pesticides are (relatively) easily quantified in monetary terms; however, the impacts on the nearby aquatic ecosystem (e.g., not just fish sold for human consumption but cultural values) cannot as readily be fully evaluated in such terms.

More importantly, economic valuation of ecosystem services will vary significantly geographically. For instance, some developing countries may be focused on obvious material benefits such as the products obtained from nature, whereas others honor the natural world for cultural and spiritual reasons. In contrast, developed countries in general have the luxury of focusing on less obviously material benefits such as habitat and cultural services. And adaptive preferences can be an issue, for instance the situation in which people are not willing to pay monetarily for parks because they have adapted to a world without parks [10]. Valuation of ecosystem services should be based on a common unit that can be aggregated and compared [6]; money does not always meet this essential criterion.

Environmental management and decision-making should focus on the effects that decision alternatives will have on ecosystem services [2,11]; quantification of those effects should rely on sound economic principles. Economics does not necessarily imply monetization; rather, it is the discipline “concerned with the way in which resources are allocated among alternative uses to satisfy human wants” [12]. As such, economics as a science is concerned with understanding why people make the choices that they do. These choices need not be quantified in monetary terms. Calow seemingly equates monetization with economics; his arguments are based on economics yet couched in terms of money.

Non-monetary valuation (NMV) is well established, reflects the plurality of values attached to ecosystem services, and includes [13]: research techniques; participatory and deliberative tools; and, determination of non-monetary but quantifiable preferences. Monetary valuation comparatively evaluates entities that are not comparable, such as death, diseases, and environmental health. In contrast, as NMV does not require that all ecosystem services be expressed in the same unit, it recognizes that some values are not comparable [14]. Moreover, while monetary valuation cannot adequately capture critical thresholds beyond which ecological conditions and dynamics are uncertain, NMV allows definition of ecological tipping points or thresholds beyond which ecosystem services become endangered [15].

We generally favor NMV based on ecological standards, by which we mean impacts to ecosystem services [2]. This approach has been successfully used in the Amazon [16]; there is no reason that it cannot be further developed and applied globally to the benefit of human communities and their health [17], including human interdependence with the well-being of all life on the planet [18].

Acknowledgment:

This Response was circulated to and approved by the other authors of [2]. We thank Peter Bruce, Amalie Thit Jensen, Susana Loureiro, and Kristian Syberg for useful input.

References

  • [1].Calow P 2017. Letter to the Editor: The importance of money as a common currency in ecosystem service valuation; a comment on the Roskilde Recommendations for risk assessment. Environ Toxicol Chem 36: this issue. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [2].Selck H, Adamsen PB, Backhaus T, Banta GT, Bruce PKH, G. Burton GA., Butts MB, Boegh E, Clague JJ, Dinh KV, Doorn N, Gunnarsson JS, Hauggaard-Nielsen H, Hazlerigg C, Hunka AD, Jensen J, Lin Y, Loureiro S, Miraglia S, Munns WR Jr, Nadim F, Palmqvist A, Rämö RA, Seaby LP, Syberg K, Tangaa SR, Thit A, Windfeld R, Zalewski M, Chapman PM. 2017. Assessing and managing multiple risks in a changing world – the Roskilde recommendations. Environ Toxicol Chem 36: 7–16. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [3].Calow P 2015. Why money matters in ecological valuation. Integr Environ Assess Manage 11: 331–332. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [4].Chapman PM, Cullen J, Garrett C, Littlepage J, Pedersen T, Varela D, Macdonald RW, Thomson R, Parsons T. 2008. Sewage treatment wasted – The Victoria (BC, Canada) example. Mar Pollut Bull 56: 815–816. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [5].Daily GC, Söderqvist T, Aniyar S, Arrow K, Dasgupta P, Ehrlich PR, Folke C, Jansson AM, Jansson B-O, Kautsky N, Levin S, Lubchenco J, Mäler K-G, Simpson D, Starrett P, Tilman D, Walker B. 2000. The value of nature and the nature of value. Science 289(5478): 395–396. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [6].Munns WR Jr, Rea AW. 2011. Ecosystem services: value is in the eye of the beholder. Integr Environ Assess Manage 11: 332–333. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [7].Kaputska L, McCormick R. 2011. The rationale for moving beyond monetization in valuing ecosystem services. Integr Environ Assess Manage 11: 329–331. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [8].Pascal N, Allenbach M, Brathwaite A, Burke L, Le Port G, Clua E. 2016. Economic valuation of coral reef ecosystem service of coastal protection: A pragmatic approach. Ecosyst Serv 21: 72–80. [Google Scholar]
  • [9].Syberg K, Banta G, Bruce P, Gunnarsson JS, Gustavsson M, Munns WR Jr, Ramo R, Selck H, Backhaus T. 2016. Towards a conceptual approach for assessing risks from chemical mixtures to coastal ecosystem services. Integr Environ Assess Manage DOI: 10.1002/ieam.1849. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [10].Matthew DA, Posner EA. 2000. Implementing cost-benefit analysis when preferences are distorted. J Legal Stud 29: 1105–1147. [Google Scholar]
  • [11].Munns WR Jr, Poulsen V, Gala W, Marshall S, Rea A, Sorensen M, von Stackelberg K. 2016. Ecosystem services in risk assessment and management. Integr Environ Assess Manage doi 10.1002/ieam/1835. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [12].Mansfield E, Yohe GW. 2003. Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, 11th Edition. WW Norton, New York, NY, USA. [Google Scholar]
  • [13].Kelemen E, García-Llorente M, Pataki G, Martín-López B, Gómez-Beggethun. 2016. Non-monetary techniques for the valuation of ecosystem service In Potschin M, Jax K, eds, OpenNESS Ecosystem Services Reference Book; www.openness-project.eu/library/reference-book. [Google Scholar]
  • [14].Hansson SO. 2007. Philosophical problems in cost-benefit analysis. Econom Philos 23: 163–183. [Google Scholar]
  • [15].Farber SC, Costanza R, Wilson MA. 2002. Economic and ecological concepts for valuing ecosystem services. Ecol Econ 41: 375–392. [Google Scholar]
  • [16].Zulma DH, Arguello H, Tapasco J. 2016. A methodological approach for the non-monetary valuation of ecosystem services in three communities of the Colombian Amazon. Agronomía Colombiana doi.org/10.15446/agron.colomb.v33n3.52154. [Google Scholar]
  • [17].Speldewinde PC, Slaney D, Weinstein P. 2015. Is restoring an ecosystem good for your health? Sci Tot Environ 502: 276–279. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [18].Costanza R, de Groot R, Sutton P, van der Ploeg S, Anderson SJ, Kubiszewski I, Farber S, Turner RK. 2014. Changes in the global value of ecosystem services. Glob Environ Change 26: 152–158. [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES