Skip to main content
International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health logoLink to International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health
. 2018 Sep 12;15(9):1985. doi: 10.3390/ijerph15091985

Competition among Supply Chains and Governmental Policy: Considering Consumers’ Low-Carbon Preference

Xujin Pu 1, Zhiping Song 1, Guanghua Han 2,*
PMCID: PMC6164740  PMID: 30213066

Abstract

Many manufacturers and retailers have cooperated for low-carbon production in various industries. This study examines the role of consumers’ low-carbon preference in this cooperation. We construct four scenarios to investigate the effects of consumers’ low-carbon preference on the market equilibrium of supply chains’ product selection strategy. Based on the game theoretic models, optimal solutions for the two supply chains are derived with different consumers’ preference for low-carbon products. Through the discussion, we uncovered the influence of consumers’ preference on price and demand and the relationship between the influence coefficient of retailers’ promotional effort on consumers’ utility and retailer profits. In addition, given the increase of government’s low-carbon production subsidy, two supply chains will both more likely choose low-carbon production. Interestingly, under the government subsidy, the profit of manufacturer will increase or decrease more than its retailer and the market structure will not change if the two supply chains have chosen low-carbon production.

Keywords: low-carbon production, consumers’ preference, cooperation, supply chain competition

1. Introduction

The 2017 report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change shows that the global emissions of greenhouse gases (GHG) have increased to unprecedented levels [1]. Consequently, the increasing rate of global temperature has increased significantly over the past few years. Thus, for sustainable and environmental production, activities must be taken by industries to reduce carbon emissions with the help of sustainable and environmental production (Barbier [2]; Nesticò and Sica [3]). Many countries are exerting their best effort to reduce carbon emissions. For example, Australia has promised to cut its carbon emissions by 5% by 2020 and 80 percent by 2050. The European Union has ensured that GHG emissions will be at least 20% lower in 2020 than they were in 1990. The Chinese government has also pledged to reduce emissions per unit of GDP by 60 to 65% from 2005 levels by 2030. Moreover, a substantial increase in consumers’ environmental awareness facilitates the protection of the environment. An increasing number of consumers are concerned with products’ environment performance and show low-carbon preference to green consumption. Accordingly, products with low carbon emissions would have a considerably high market share, reputation, and market value. These factors prompt enterprises in all industrial sectors to reduce emissions. A total of 30 leading companies, including Volvo, Coca-Cola, and Yingli Solar, have participated in the WWF Climate Savers Program and promised a large-scale reduction of carbon emissions [4].

Given that the market competition has become increasingly fierce, the cooperation between the supply chain’s upstream (manufacturer) and downstream (retailer) is also becoming considerably important to the supply chain. The competition among manufacturers is changing to the competition between supply chains (Christopher [5]; Ai et al. [6]). For example, Ford and GM, together with their respective retailers, sell cars to consumers to obtain maximum profit. Apple and Xiaomi sell mobile phones through their respective retailers and generally compete with other mobile phone companies. Manufacturers and retailers may also collaborate to use “low carbon” as their selling point. For example, Gome cooperates strategically with Haier to encourage the latter to implement low-carbon production and actively guide consumers on low-carbon consumption to reduce carbon emission. By cooperating with each other, Haier and Gome’s profits have been increasing despite the general downturn in demand. Given the consumers’ low-carbon preference and the competition between the two supply chains, the future of the market equilibrium is an interesting point of research.

However, low-carbon production can be costly because it needs additional resources, including specialized equipment, additional inputs, and complicated human resource management. If the premium that consumers are willing to pay is insufficiently large to cover the additional costs, then subsidy, which is the most common instrument for governments, is the key to promote low-carbon products. Many countries, including the US, Japan, Germany, and France, have subsidized car companies to produce new energy vehicles. Effective policies can regulate and guide the behaviors of supply chains in the market and also promote social sustainable development. However, if the subsidy is inappropriate, then such instrument will damage the market structure. Thus, it is important for the government to know what the market equilibrium between the two supply chains will be with the increment of government subsidy. This study will also focus on this topic.

In this study, chain-to-chain competition is the competition between two supply chains, with each chain consisting of a manufacturer and its exclusive retailer. We use game theoretic models to analyze the chain-to-chain competition and obtain market equilibrium of the two supply chains. Nash equilibrium, one of most essential ingredients in game theory named after American mathematician John Forbes Nash Jr., is a solution concept of a non-cooperative game involving two or more players. In Nash equilibrium, each player is assumed to know the equilibrium strategies of the other players, and no player has anything to gain by changing their own strategies. In this study, we consider the competition between two different supply chains, the decision conditions of each participators are public information and known to all supply chain members. Therefore, the supply chains we considered in this paper compete following a Nash equilibrium game process. In particular, we employ Nash equilibrium to formulate the decision process and provide insights into the following questions: (1) What are the effects of consumers’ low-carbon preference on the market equilibrium of supply chains’ product selection strategy? (2) What is the influence of consumers’ preference on price and demand? (3) What is the relationship between the influence coefficient of retailers’ promotional effort on consumers’ utility and retailer profits? (4) What is the impact of government subsidy on the market structure of two supply chains?

The supply chains and government can benefit from this study. On the one hand, the supply chains can obtain an improved understanding of the effects of consumers’ low-carbon preference and achieve a good market equilibrium. On the other hand, the government can learn the influences of low-carbon production subsidy on supply chains’ product selection. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 positions the relevant literature on low-carbon production and chain-to-chain supply competition. Section 3 provides the model formulation and assumptions. Section 4 presents four models on the manufacturers’ production selection and discusses the results. Section 5 extends to investigate the effects of government subsidy on low-carbon production. Section 6 summarizes our main findings and discuss opportunities for further research.

2. Literature Review

Our study is related to two research streams that are briefly reviewed as follows. The first stream is the literature review on manufacturers’ low-carbon production. Among the early studies, Zhao et al. [7] investigated the impact of allowance allocation systems in markets and obtained an equilibrium production based on cap-and-trade setting under a perfect competition. Benjaafar et al. [8] studied the impact of operational decisions on carbon emissions by incorporating carbon emission considerations (e.g., carbon caps, carbon taxes, and carbon offsets) into simplified inventory models, as well as constructed mixed-integer linear programming models to determine the associated costs, thereby providing a potential template for further study. Du et al. [9] incorporated consumer preference into low-carbon production management and analyzed the effects of carbon emissions on a supply chain. Tang et al. [10] analyzed three approaches related to the effects of controlling carbon emissions in transportation and inventory management. Drake et al. [11] studied the impact of emission tax and emission cap-and-trade regulation on a firm’s technology choice and capacity decisions. Fan and Dong [12] investigated how the government can select a subsidy strategy in low-carbon diffusion by considering heterogeneous agents’ behavior. Du et al. [13] proposed a carbon-related price–discount sharing-like scheme to achieve channel coordination. Meng et al. [14] investigates product selection strategies of two competitive firms in the presence of carbon tax and conducts an analytical examination of the effect of power structure on the firm’s product selection strategy over different levels of carbon tax rate.

Another relevant stream of literature explores the competition among supply chains. McGuire and Staelin [15] contributed immensely in this area by investigating the equilibrium supply chain structures in a duopoly market, in which two manufacturers compete with each other by selling products through their exclusive retailers. McGuire and Staelin showed that for the majority of specifications, product substitutability does influence the equilibrium distribution structure. Thereafter, McGuire and Staelin’s research has been extended by other researchers. For example, Xiao and Choi [16] studied how the channel structure strategies and wholesale prices of manufacturers depend on the risk sensitivity, pricing power, and purchasing option of retailers. Xiao and Yang [17] developed a price-service competition model of two supply chains to investigate the optimal decisions of players under demand uncertainty; they determined that the higher the risk sensitivity of one retailer, the lower his optimal service level and retail price will be. They also determined that the effects of a rival’s risk sensitivity on the retailer’s decisions depend on the substitutability of the two products. Zhao and Shi [18] incorporated contracting strategy into the supply chain structure selection problem. Accordingly, they determined that decentralized supply chains perform better under strong market competition, whereas integrated supply chains perform better when many suppliers exist. Mahmoodi and Eshghi [19] introduced demand uncertainty to investigate which supply chain structure is preferable in an industry consisting of two distinct supply chains that compete with each other over price. Amin-Naseri and Khojasteh [20] developed a price competition model under a demand uncertainty environment between two leader-follower supply chains. Each supply chain consists of one risk-neutral manufacturer and one risk-averse retailer. Thereafter, the optimal wholesale and retail prices for the leader and follower supply chains are obtained under various supply chain network structures. Taleizadeh et al. [21] considered two competing supply chains, in which both chains launch the same product (under different brands) to the market by applying different composite coordinating strategies. The researchers aimed to determine the optimal selling prices and the order quantities of the manufacturer and retailers in each chain in the presence of different composite coordinating strategies. Wang et al. [22] incorporated markup pricing strategies into the chain-to-chain supply competition and determined that the equilibrium pricing strategy depends on the level of chain-to-chain supply competition.

Evidently, the management of low-carbon supply chains is becoming an important research topic in recent years. However, the related studies either only analyze consumers’ low-carbon preference on manufacturers or merely investigate the completion between supply chains. To the best of our knowledge, no previous supply chain study has incorporated consumers’ low-carbon preference into the competition among supply chains. Therefore, this topic is of interest for further research. In addition, the effect of the government’s low-carbon production subsidy on the competitive market structure is included in our research.

3. Model Description

This study considers two competitive supply chains (i.e., supply chains 1 and 2) in a duopolistic market. Supply chain 1 consists of manufacturer 1 and retailer 1, while supply chain 2 comprises manufacturer 2 and retailer 2. The manufacturers are the leaders in the supply chain and decide whether to produce low-carbon or regular products. If the manufacturer chooses to produce low-carbon products, then its own retailer will choose to promote them. The low-carbon and regular products are completely substitutable in a competitive market. For example, IKEA and the World Wildlife Fund (WWF) work together to reduce greenhouse gas (carbon dioxide) emissions from IKEA’s production operations. The project includes improving energy efficiency and enabling IKEA suppliers to use renewable energy. Apple claims that all its facilities around the world, including Apple’s offices, retail stores and data centers, are now powered entirely by clean energy. In order to reduce greenhouse gas emissions and act against climate change more efficiently, Apple also requires its partners to use clean energy. The low-carbon products of IKEA and Apple can be replaced by their competitors who choose regular products. In this paper, we consider the same products (e.g., IKEA product) are made by two different manufacturers, both of which choose low-carbon production or regular-carbon production. Both the products made by low-carbon production and regular-carbon production are available to markets and consumers’ consumption is directly affected by their low-carbon preference. Figure 1 illustrates the schematics for the problem.

Figure 1.

Figure 1

Structure of the manufacturing supply chain under duopoly model.

Consumers’ valuation for a regular product is V (V > 0), where V is sufficiently large. The market size of the product is 1 and consumers are uniformly distributed over [0, 1] with two retailers at opposite ends. When consumers come to any one retailer to buy products, the travelling cost is t (t > 0) per unit distance. Consumers prefer low-carbon products because of their awareness for protecting the environment. The consumers’ preference for low-carbon products is assumed as τ (τ > 0). We use e (0 < e < 1) to denote the carbon emission reduction rate of low-carbon products, while the carbon emission reduction rate of regular products is 0. The premium that consumers are willing to pay for low-carbon products is τe.

The cost of regular production is ci, i = 1, 2. If the manufacturer wants to produce low-carbon products, then he/she must invest money to employ low-carbon technologies. The quadratic function form is extensively adopted to describe the cost pattern in the literature (e.g., Yao and Liu [23]; Atasu et al. [24]). Accordingly, the cost of carbon emission reduction will accelerate to achieve a high level of emission reduction and the additional cost is kie22, i = 1, 2, where ki represents the per unit cost to adopt low-carbon production. Assume that the per unit cost to adopt low-carbon production is lower for manufacturer 1 than for manufacturer 2 (k1 > k2). Because the retailer’s low-carbon promotion incurs extra a few additional costs, we also use quadratic function to describe it. That is, c(θ)=δθi22, i = 1, 2, where θi denotes the retailer’s promotional effort when the manufacturer chooses low-carbon production. Without loss of generality, we assume that θ1 > θ2. δ (δ > 0) is the influence coefficient of the retailers’ promotional effort on consumers’ utility. Table 1 summarizes these notions.

Table 1.

Notations for the parameters and variables.

Model Parameters Underling Meaning of the Model Parameters
V Consumers’ valuation for the regular product
t Consumers’ travelling cost
τ Consumers’ preference for low-carbon products
ci Cost of regular production
e Carbon emission reduction rate
ki Per unit fare to take low-carbon production
ξ Promotional sensitivity coefficient
θi Retailers’ low-carbon promotional efforts
Ui Consumer utility
Πi Profit of manufacturer/retailer
Di Demand of products
Decision Parameters Underling Meaning of the Decision Parameters
pi Unit price
wi Unit wholesale price

Each supply chain has two choices, namely, N (regular) and L (low-carbon), for their product strategies. Thus, a total of four scenarios are used for their product selections, which are denoted as follows:

Scenario NN. Two manufacturers choose to produce regular products. The net utilities that a consumer derives from buying from two retailers are U1NN=Vp1NNtx and U2NN=Vp2NNt(1x).

Scenario NL. Manufacturers 1 and 2 choose to produce regular and low-carbon products, respectively. The net utilities that a consumer derives from buying regular and low-carbon products are U1NL=Vp1NLtx and U2NL=Vp2NLt(1x)+τe+ξθ2, respectively.

Scenario LN. Manufacturers 1 and 2 choose to produce low-carbon and regular products, respectively. The net utilities that a consumer derives from buying low-carbon and regular products are U1LN=Vp1LNtx+τe+ξθ1 and U2LN=Vp2LNt(1x), respectively.

Scenario LL. Two manufacturers choose to produce low-carbon products. The net utilities that a consumer derives from buying products from two retailers are U1LL=Vp1LLtx+τe+ξθ1 and U2LL=Vp2LLt(1x)+τe+ξθ2.

Table 2 presents the game matrix between supply chains 1 and 2.

Table 2.

Strategy selection game matrix of the two supply chains.

Scenarios Supply Chain 1
(Regular Products)
Supply Chain 1
(Low-Carbon Products)
Supply chain 2
(Regular products)
Scenario NN Scenario LN
Supply chain 2
(Low-carbon products)
Scenario NL Scenario LL

4. Equilibrium Solutions and Discussions

As stated previously, we are interested in the influence of consumers’ low-carbon preference on supply chains’ low-carbon production strategy, wholesale price, retail price as well as market demand. Meanwhile, retailer’s promotion behavior and governments’ influence on the market structure might affect consumers’ utility and retailer’s profits, we analytically explore their relations in this section. Since the supply chain partners act following a N ash pricing games, we answer the above questions with Nash game processes and present the mathematical results by Table A1, Table A2, Table A3 and Table A4 in Appendix A. Based on the mathematical results, we employ four lemmas and three propositions to illustrate our findings regarding our concerns. We first present the following proposition to characterize the manufacturer’s optimal response strategies within two supply chains.

Proposition 1.

For the product selection strategies of the two manufacturers, a strategy equilibrium NN exists if τ < A, a strategy equilibrium LL exists if τ ≥ B, and a strategy equilibrium LN exists if A ≤ τ < B, we denote A=12k1eξθ1e and  B=12k2eξθ2e .

Proof. 

See Appendix B.

Proposition 1 shows that when the low-carbon environmental awareness that consumers have is not evident, both manufacturers in the market will choose to produce regular products (Figure 2). When consumers’ low-carbon environmental awareness increases, the manufacturer with low cost of low-carbon production will choose low-carbon production, whereas the other manufacturers will choose regular production. When consumers actively pursue low-carbon products, both manufacturers will choose to produce low-carbon products. Consequently, environmental awareness is the key factor. The government should encourage low-carbon product consumption as a way to improve low-carbon production with market demand. This method is crucial to urge manufacturers to produce low-carbon products.

Figure 2.

Figure 2

Division of the market structure.

After investigating the trend of A(B) in Proposition 1, the threshold of two manufacturers choosing different production strategies is positively associated with the unit cost of low-carbon production. The threshold also increases with the increment of the carbon emission reduction rate. Meanwhile, the threshold has negative correlation with the retailers’ low-carbon promotional efforts and the effect of low-carbon promotion on the level of consumer utility. Figure 3, Figure 4 and Figure 5 show the trend of A(B) in relation to the other factors.

Figure 3.

Figure 3

Trend of A(B) with k.

Figure 4.

Figure 4

Trend of A(B) with θ.

Figure 5.

Figure 5

Trend of A(B) with ξ.

Figure 3, Figure 4 and Figure 5 illustrate that it is the result of superposition of multiple factors for manufacturers to choose production strategy. Manufacturers can produce more low-carbon products via reducing their low-carbon production cost and strengthening the low-carbon promotion effort of their retailers.

The demand gap of the two supply chains will change with the increment of consumers’ preference coefficient. We can derive Lemma 1 after conducting an investigation.

Lemma 1.

Let ΔDNN=D1NND2NN, ΔDLN=D1LND2LN, and ΔDLL=D1LLD2LL. If τ > A, then ΔDNN<ΔDLN<ΔDLL; if A ≤ τ < B, then ΔDNNΔDLN<ΔDLL; and if τ ≥ B, then ΔDNNΔDLNΔDLL.

Proof. 

See Appendix B.

Figure 6 shows the relationship between the consumers’ preference coefficient and the demand gap of the two supply chains. Moreover, Figure 6 shows that when the consumers’ low-carbon preference is relatively weak, if two manufacturers both produce low-carbon products, then the shortfall between their market share is the biggest. If manufacturers 1 and 2 choose to produce low-carbon and regular products, respectively, then the difference between their market share is minimal.

Figure 6.

Figure 6

Trend of ΔD with τ.

This phenomenon illustrates that if consumers’ low-carbon preference is relatively weak, then manufacturer 1 has a small competitive advantage. In this situation, when both manufacturers choose to produce low-carbon products, no significant difference is observed between the two types of products. Then the competition between two supply chains is transformed into the promotion competition and the manufacturer will have the advantage when its retailer has larger low-carbon promotional efforts. If the influence of consumers’ low-carbon preference on their purchasing behavior is big, the manufacturer who chooses low-carbon production will have a huge market competitive advantage.

Proposition 2.

If τ < B, then p1NN*<p1LN*<p1LL* ; if τ ≥ B, then p1NN*<p1LL*<p1LN* .

Proof. 

See Appendix B.

Proposition 2 indicates that when products’ carbon emission reduction has low impact on the consumer purchase decision, the price of low-carbon product from manufacturer 1 is the largest in the LL scenario. When the impact of products’ carbon emission reduction on the consumer purchase decision exceeds a certain level, low-carbon products from manufacturer 1 have the largest price in the LN scenario. This finding implies that consumers’ low-carbon preference can affect the price that they are willing to pay. If low-carbon products on the market is all from manufacturer 1 and consumers’ preference for low-carbon products is large, then the retailer 1 will increase the prices. Moreover, the price of low-carbon products is always higher than that of regular products regardless of consumers’ preference because the former costs more. Figure 7 shows the trend of the price of retailer 1 to the consumers’ preference coefficient.

Figure 7.

Figure 7

Trend of pi with τ.

Thereafter, we investigate the demand of manufacturer 1 in three scenarios.

Lemma 2.

When τ < A, thenD1LN<D1NN<D1LL; when A ≤ τ < B,D1NN<D1LN<D1LL, when τ ≥ B,D1NN<D1LL<D1LN.

Proof. 

See Appendix B.

Lemma 2 indicates that if consumers’ preference on low-carbon products is relatively weak and only manufacturer 1 chooses to produce low-carbon products, then the market share between the two supply chains is the smallest. When consumers’ preference on low-carbon products increases, manufacturer 1 gradually achieves a large market share with the expansion of its competitive advantage. Figure 8 shows the trend of manufacturer 1’s demand to consumers’ preference coefficient.

Figure 8.

Figure 8

Trend of D1 with τ.

Evidently, the market share of manufacturer 1 is larger in scenario LL than in scenario NN regardless of the low-carbon preferences of consumers. The reason is that in scenario LL, manufacturer 1 has a lower low-carbon production cost than that of manufacturer 2 and retailer 1 also devotes more promotion effort than retailer 2.

Lemma 3.

ΠR1LNδξ>0, ΠR2LNδξ<0, ΠR1LLδξ>0, ΠR2LLδξ<0.

Proof. 

See Appendix B.

Lemma 3 presents that in scenarios LN and LL, the profit of retailer 1 is positively related to its influence of promotional effort on consumer utility, whereas the profit of retailer 2 is negatively related to it. That is, when only one manufacturer chooses to produce low-carbon products, if the influence of promotional efforts on consumers is big, then consumers have more tendency to buy low-carbon products and the retailer will receive more profits. In the situation where both manufacturers choose to produce low-carbon products, the promotion effort of retailer 1 is larger than that of retailer 2. Therefore, when the influence of promotional effort of low-carbon production on consumers is large, the retailer 1 receives more profits. Figure 9 and Figure 10 show the trend of the profit of retailers to the influence coefficient of the promotional effort on consumers’ utility.

Figure 9.

Figure 9

Trend of ΠRLN with ξ.

Figure 10.

Figure 10

Trend of ΠRLL with ξ.

Lemma 4.

δp1LLδe>0, δp2LLδe>0, δp1LNδe>0. 

Proof. 

See Appendix B.

Lemma 4 indicates that the price of a low-carbon product is positively correlated with its carbon emission rate. The reason is that low-carbon production means that companies need to pay additional costs, such as using clean energy and low-carbon materials. When the carbon emission rate of low-carbon products is high, the cost will be high and the price of low-carbon products will also be high. The government should set suitable carbon emission standards for low-carbon products based on the actual conditions of enterprises.

5. Governmental Subsidy Policy

The model analyzed in Section 4 and Section 5 only discusses the low-carbon production selection strategy of two supply chains. However, in reality, governments constantly use subsidy policies to promote low-carbon production for controlling carbon emissions. Accordingly, the government is assumed to provide a subsidy at a rate of λ (λ > 0) for each unit of carbon emission. Compared with the original model in Section 4, in scenario NL, the other remains unchanged, while the profit of manufacturer 2 changes to ΠM2NL=(w2NLc212k2e2+λe)D2NL. In scenario LN, the other remains unchanged, while the profit of manufacturer 1 changes to ΠM1LN=(w1LNc112k1e2+λe)D1LN. In scenario LL, the profits of manufacturers 1 and 2 change. That is, ΠM1LL=(w1LLc112k1e2+λe)D1LL and ΠM2LL=(w2LLc212k2e2+λe)D2LL. In scenario NN, the equilibrium will not be affected by a government subsidy. We summarize all these results in Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5.

Table 3.

Equilibrium outcomes with subsidy under scenario NL.

Scenario NL Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2λe3 c1+2c2+9t+τe+ξθ2+k2e22λe3
p 5c1+4c2+36t4τe4ξθ2+2k2e24λe9 4c1+5c2+36t+4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e25λe9
D c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2λe18t c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2+λe18t
ΠM (c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2λe)254t (c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2+λe)254t
ΠR (c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2λe)2162t (c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2+λe)281tu2θ22162t

Table 4.

Equilibrium outcomes with subsidy under scenario LN.

Scenario LN Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9t+τe+ξθ1+k1e22λe3 c1+2c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2λe3
p 5c1+4c2+36t+4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e25λe9 4c1+5c2+36t4τe4ξθ1+2k1e24λe9
D c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2+λe18t c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2λe18t
ΠM (c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2+λe)254t (c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2λe)254t
ΠR (c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2+λe)281tu1θ12162t (c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2λe)2162t

Table 5.

Equilibrium outcomes with subsidy under scenario LL.

Scenario LL Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)+k1e2+12k2e23λe c1+2c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e2+k2e23λe
p 5c1+4c2+36t+4ξ(θ1θ2)+52k1e2+2k2e29λe 4c1+5c2+36t4ξ(θ1θ2)+2k1e2+52k2e29λe
D c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e218t c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e218t
ΠM [c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]254t [c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]254t
ΠR [c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]281tu1θ12162t (c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2λe)2162t

For simplicity, let A¯=12k1eξθ1eλ and B¯=12k2eξθ2eλ. The following proposition characterizes the optimal response strategies of two supply chains’ leader (manufacturer) with government subsidy policy.

Proposition 3.

Given government’s low-carbon production subsidy, the dividing lines of two manufacturers’ optimal response strategies changes from A and B into A¯ and B¯ . Moreover, AA¯, BB¯ .

Proposition 3 illustrates that given government’s low-carbon production subsidy, two manufacturers are more likely to choose scenarios LL and LN and less likely to choose scenario NN. This proves that subsidy is a beneficial tool for governments to regulate and guide the behavior of supply chains in the market. To reduce carbon emissions, governments should subsidize the low-carbon products. Figure 11 shows the changes of the market structure with certain value of subsidy.

Figure 11.

Figure 11

Changes of the market structure (a) λ = 0 (b) λ = 0.3 (c) λ = 0.6 (d) λ = 0.9.

Thereafter, we investigate the specific effect of subsidy on the supply chain. We find that when only one manufacturer chooses low-carbon production (scenarios NL and LN) and the government implements low-carbon production subsidy policy:

  • (1)

    The low-carbon supply chain’s wholesale price and sale price will decrease and the decrement is more than the wholesale price and sale price of regular supply chain.

  • (2)

    The profit of the manufacturer who chooses low-carbon production and its retailer will both increase, whereas the profit of the manufacturer that chooses regular production and its retailer will both decrease.

  • (3)

    The profit of a manufacturer will increase or decrease more than that of its retailer.

The above conclusions imply that when only one low-carbon supply chain exists in the market, the government’s low-carbon subsidy has a huge effect on both supply chains. The subsidy will cause the low-carbon manufacturer to decrease its wholesale price to its retailer, thereby leading to the decrement of retailer’s sale price to the consumers. This situation will also force the other supply chain to decrease its wholesale price and sale price. However, the decrement is smaller than that of low-carbon supply chain. Although the decrement of wholesale price and sale price, the low-carbon manufacturer and its retailer receive more profits with the government’s subsidy, whereas the regular manufacturer and its retailer receive less profit and are forced to loss some market share. As the leader of the supply chain, the manufacturer takes more responsibility and the change in profit of manufacturer is bigger than its retailer during the competition.

We also find that when two manufacturers choose low-carbon production (scenario LL), the government’s low-carbon production subsidy has no influence on the market structure. Moreover, the government’s low-carbon production subsidy will be totally acquired by consumers and the profit of the manufacturers and retailers remain the same as the situation without subsidy. This conclusion illustrates that if the two supply chains choose low-carbon production, then the government’s subsidy loses its effect on the market structure and is only beneficial for consumers. Therefore, government subsidy is not suggested when two supply chains have chosen low-carbon production.

6. Conclusions and Future Directions

This study incorporates consumers’ low-carbon preference into the supply chain competition. Analytical models are constructed to investigate the Nash pricing game. The main results are as follows:

  • (1)

    When consumers’ low-carbon preference is low, two manufacturers will choose regular production. When consumers’ low-carbon preference increases, the manufacturer with low cost of low-carbon production will choose low-carbon production, whereas the other manufacturer will still choose regular production. When consumers have a high preference for low-carbon products, both manufacturers will choose low-carbon production.

  • (2)

    When products’ carbon emission reduction has a low impact on the consumer purchase decision, the price of low-carbon product from manufacturer 1 is the largest in scenario LL, only manufacturer 1 choose low-carbon production, and the market share between the two manufacturers is the smallest. When the impact of products’ carbon emission reduction on consumers exceeds a certain level, low-carbon products from manufacturer 1 have the largest price in scenario LN and manufacturer 1 gradually achieves a large market share with the expansion of its competitive advantage.

  • (3)

    If the manufacturer with low fare to reduce carbon emissions chooses to take low-carbon production, regardless of what the other manufacturer chooses, then the profit of its retailer is positively linked to the influence coefficient of promotional efforts on consumer utility, whereas the other retailer’s profit is negatively linked to it.

  • (4)

    Given the increase of government’s low-carbon production subsidy, two manufacturers will more likely choose scenarios LL and LN and less likely choose scenario NN. This proves that government subsidy have an important role to play in reducing carbon emissions.

However, a few limitations are presented in this study. First, we assume that consumers’ low-carbon preference is the same for every consumer. An interesting extension is to consider the case where consumers have different low-carbon preference and thus we can further discuss what effect it will have when consumers’ low-carbon preference is represented by quadratic function. Second, this study assumes the demand function to be deterministic. It will be interesting to conduct research when consumers’ demand is stochastic. Third, the current research supposes that the manufacturers’ emission reduction level and the retailers’ low-carbon promotion level are linearly separable. In practice, the two types of effort are complementary. Therefore, the complementary effect is able to be considered in the future. Thus, future studies can extend this study by considering more complex decision conditions by the similar approaches; we believe that investigating the impact of low-carbon preference offers a fertile avenue on operation research and regulation policy in future.

Appendix A

Equilibrium solutions of supply chains under different decision scenarios are calculated and presented in the following context below.

Appendix A.1. Solutions under Scenario NN

By solving U1NN=U2NN, we can derive x=tp1NN+p2NN2t. The demand functions of the two retailers are D1NN=x=tp1NN+p2NN2t and D2NN=1x=t+p1NNp2NN2t.

The profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers can be modeled as follows based on the previously presented demand functions:

ΠM1NN=(w1NNc1)D1NN and ΠM2NN=(w2NNc2)D2NN, (A1)
ΠR1NN=(p1NNw1NN)D1NN and ΠR2NN=(p2NNw2NN)D2NN. (A2)

By solving equations ΠR1NNp1NN=0 and ΠR2NNp2NN=0, we can obtain the following optimal functions: p1NN=2w1+w2+3t3 and p2NN=w1+2w2+3t3.

After substituting the function of p1NN and p2NN into D1NN and D2NN and solving equations ΠM1NNw1NN=0 and ΠM2NNw2NN=0, we can derive:

w1NN*=2c1+c2+9t3 and w2NN*=c1+2c2+9t3. (A3)

By substituting w1NN* and w2NN* into the equations about p1NN and p2NN, we can derive

p1NN*=5c1+4c2+36t9 and p2NN*=4c1+5c2+36t9. (A4)

By substituting p1NN* and p2NN* into the equations on D1NN and D2NN, we can obtain

D1NN=c2c1+9t18t and D2NN=c1c2+9t18t. (A5)

By substituting the optimal solution into the equations about profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers, we can obtain

ΠM1NN=(c2c1+9t)254t and ΠM2NN=(c1c2+9t)254t, (A6)
ΠR1NN=(c2c1+9t)2162t and ΠR2NN=(c1c2+9t)2162t. (A7)

Equilibrium solutions under scenario NN are summarized and presented in Table A1.

Table A1.

Equilibrium outcomes under scenario NN.

Scenario NN Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9t3 c1+2c2+9t3
p 5c1+4c2+36t9 4c1+5c2+36t9
D c2c1+9t18t c1c2+9t18t
ΠM (c2c1+9t)254t (c1c2+9t)254t
ΠR (c2c1+9t)2162t (c1c2+9t)2162t

Appendix A.2. Solutions under Scenario NL

By solving U1NL=U2NL, we can derive x=tp1NL+p2NLτeξθ22t. The demand functions of the two retailers are as follows: D1NL=x=tp1NL+p2NLτeξθ22t and D2NL=1x=t+p1NLp2NL+τe+ξθ22t.

The profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers can be modeled as follows based on the previously presented demand functions:

ΠM1NL=(w1NLc1)D1NL and ΠM2NL=(w2NLc212k2e2)D2NL, (A8)
ΠR1NL=(p1NLw1NL)D1NL and ΠR2NL=(p2NLw2NL)D2NL12u2θ22. (A9)

By solving equations ΠR1NLp1NL=0 and ΠR2NLp2NL=0, we can obtain the following optimal functions:

p1NL=2w1NL+w2NL+3tτeξθ23 and p2NL=w1NL+2w2NL+3t+τe+ξθ23. (A10)

After substituting the function of p1NL and p2NL into D1NL and D2NL and solving equations ΠM1NLw1NL=0 and ΠM2NLw2NL=0, we can derive

w1NL*=2c1+c2+9tτeξθ2+12k2e23 and w2NL*=c1+2c2+9t+τe+ξθ2+k2e23  (A11)

By substituting w1NL* and w2NL* into the equations about p1NL and p2NL, we can derive

p1NL*=5c1+4c2+36t4τe4ξθ2+2k2e29 and p2NL*=4c1+5c2+36t+4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e29  (A12)

By substituting p1NL* and p2NL* into the equations on D1NL and D2NL, we can obtain

D1NL=c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e218t and D2NL=c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e218t. (A13)

By substituting the optimal solution into the equations about profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers, we can obtain the following equations:

ΠM1NL=(c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2)254t and ΠM2NL=(c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2)254t, (A14)
ΠR1NL=(c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2)2162t and ΠR2NL=(c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2)281tu2θ22162t. (A15)

We summarize equilibrium solutions under scenario NL and presented in Table A2.

Table A2.

Equilibrium outcomes under scenario NL.

Scenario NL Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9tτeξθ2+12k2e23 c1+2c2+9t+τe+ξθ2+k2e23
p 5c1+4c2+36t4τe4ξθ2+2k2e29 4c1+5c2+36t+4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e29
D c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e218t c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e218t
ΠM (c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2)254t (c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2)254t
ΠR (c2c1+9tτeξθ2+12k2e2)2162t (c1c2+9t+τe+ξθ212k2e2)281tu2θ22162t

Appendix A.3. Solutions under Scenario LN

By solving U1LN=U2LN, we can derive x=tp1LN+p2LN+τe+ξθ12t. The demand functions of the two retailers are as follows:

D1LN=x=tp1LN+p2LN+τe+ξθ12t and D2LN=1x=t+p1LNp2LNτeξθ12t. (A16)

The profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers can be modeled as follows based on the previously presented demand functions:

ΠM1LN=(w1LNc112k1e2)D1LN and ΠM2LN=(w2LNc2)D2LN, (A17)
ΠR1LN=(p1LNw1LN)D1LN12u1θ12 and ΠR2LN=(p2LNw2LN)D2LN  (A18)

By solving equations ΠR1LNp1LN=0 and ΠR2LNp2LN=0, we can obtain the optimal functions

p1LN=2w1LN+w2LN+3t+τe+ξθ13 and p2LN=w1LN+2w2LN+3tτeξθ13. (A19)

After substituting the function of p1LN and p2LN into D1LN and D2LN and solving equations ΠN1LNw1LN=0 and ΠN2LNw2LN=0, we can derive

w1LN*=2c1+c2+9t+τe+ξθ1+k1e23 and w2LN*=c1+2c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e23  (A20)

By substituting w1LN* and w2LN* into the equations about p1LN and p2LN, we can derive

p1LN*=5c1+4c2+36t+4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e29 and p2LN*=4c1+5c2+36t4τe4ξθ1+2k1e29. (A21)

By substituting p1LN* and p2LN* into the equations on D1LN and D2LN, we can obtain

D1LN=c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e218t and D2LN=c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e218t. (A22)

By substituting the optimal solution into the equations about profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers, we can obtain the following equations:

ΠM1LN=(c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2)254t and ΠM2LN=(c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2)254t, (A23)
ΠR1LN=(c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2)281tu1θ12162t and ΠR2LN=(c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2)2162t  (A24)

Equilibrium solutions under scenario LN are summarized and presented in Table A3.

Table A3.

Equilibrium outcomes under scenario LN.

Scenario LN Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9t+τe+ξθ1+k1e23 c1+2c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e23
p 5c1+4c2+36t+4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e29 4c1+5c2+36t4τe4ξθ1+2k1e29
D c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e218t c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e218t
ΠM (c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2)254t (c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2)254t
ΠR (c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2)281tu1θ12162t (c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2)2162t

Appendix A.4. Solutions under Scenario LL

By solving U1LL=U2LL, we can derive x=tp1LL+p2LL+ξ(θ1θ2)2t. The demand functions of the two retailers are as follows:

D1LL=x=tp1LL+p2LL+ξ(θ1θ2)2t and D2LL=1x=t+p1LLp2LLξ(θ1θ2)2t. (A25)

The profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers can be modeled as follows based on the previously presented demand functions:

ΠM1LL=(w1LLc112k1e2)D1LL and ΠM2LL=(w2LLc212k2e2)D2LL, (A26)
ΠR1LL=(p1LLw1LL)D1LL12u1θ12 and ΠR2LL=(p2LLw2LL)D2LL12u2θ22  (A27)

By solving equations ΠR1LLp1LL=0 and ΠR2LLp2LL=0, we can obtain the optimal functions p1LL=2w1LL+w2LL+3t+ξ(θ1θ2)3 and p2LL=w1LL+2w2LL+3tξ(θ1θ2)3.

After substituting the function of p1LL and p2LL into D1LL and D2LL and solving equations ΠM1LLw1LL=0 and ΠM2LLw2LL=0, we can derive

w1LL*=2c1+c2+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)+k1e2+12k2e23 and w2LL*=c1+2c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e2+k2e23  (A28)

By substituting w1LL* and w2LL* into the equations about p1LL and p2LL, we can derive

p1LL*=5c1+4c2+36t+4ξ(θ1θ2)+52k1e2+2k2e29, p2LL*=4c1+5c2+36t4ξ(θ1θ2)+2k1e2+52k2e29  (A29)

By substituting p1LL* and p2LL* into the equations on D1LL and D2LL, we can obtain

D1LL=c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e218t and D2LL=c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e218t. (A30)

By substituting the optimal solution into the equations about profits of the two manufacturers and two retailers, we can obtain the following equations:

ΠM1LL=[c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]254t, ΠR1LL=[c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]281tu1θ12162t. (A31)
ΠM2LL=[c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]254t, ΠR2LL=[c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]281tu2θ22162t  (A32)

We summarize equilibrium solutions under scenario LL and presented in Table A4.

Table A4.

Equilibrium outcomes under scenario LL.

Scenario LL Supply Chain 1 Supply Chain 2
w 2c1+c2+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)+k1e2+12k2e23 c1+2c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e2+k2e23
p 5c1+4c2+36t+4ξ(θ1θ2)+52k1e2+2k2e29 4c1+5c2+36t4ξ(θ1θ2)+2k1e2+52k2e29
D c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e218t c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e218t
ΠM [c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]254t [c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]281tu1θ12162t
ΠR [c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]254t [c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]281tu2θ22162t

Next, we analyze the choice of manufacturers. Table A5 lists the equilibrium profit between manufacturers 1 and 2 under the four scenarios.

Table A5.

Equilibrium profit of the two manufacturers under the four scenarios.

NN NL LN LL
M1 M254t (Mτeξθ2+12k2e2)254t (M+τe+ξθ112k1e2)254t [M+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]254t
M2 N254t (N+τe+ξθ212k2e2)254t (Nτeξθ1+12k1e2)254t [Nξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]254t

Where M = C2C1 + 9t, N = C1C2 + 9t.

Appendix B

Appendix B contains the proofs of the propositions and lemmas stated in the text.

Proof of Proposition 1.

Due to e>0, k1<k2, and θ1>θ2, we can derive 12k1eξθ1e<12k2eξθ2e; thus, A<B.

Manufacturer 1’s profit gap between scenario NN and scenario LN is

ΠM1NNΠM1LN=[M+(M+τe+ξθ112k1e2)][M(M+τe+ξθ112k1e2)]54t. (A33)

Due to D1NN=M18t>0, D1LN=M+τe+ξθ112k1e218t>0, t>0, we can derive M>0,

M+τe+ξθ112k1e2>0; then, (M+τe+ξθ112k1e2)+M>0. (A34)
M(M+τe+ξθ112k1e2)=12k1e2τeξθ1  (A35)

When ΠM1NN>ΠM1LN, 12k1e2τeξθ1>0. Thus, τ<12k1eξθ1e.

In the same manner, we can determined that when ΠM1NL>ΠM1LL, τ<12k1eξθ1e.

Thus, if τ<12k1eξθ1e, regardless of what manufacturer 2 chooses to produce, then manufacturer 1 will choose to produce regular products.

In the same manner, we can determine that when ΠM2NN>ΠM2NL, τ<12k2eξθ2e; when ΠM2LN>ΠM2LL, τ<12k2eξθ2e. This finding means that if τ<12k2eξθ2e, regardless of what manufacturer 1 chooses to produce, then manufacturer 2 will choose to produce regular products.

Due to 12k1eξθ1e<12k2eξθ2e, when τ<12k1eξθ1e, the equilibrium scenario is NN.

Similarly, when 12k1eξθ1eτ<12k2eξθ2e, the equilibrium scenario is LN; when τ12k2eξθ2e, the equilibrium scenario is LL.

However, when 12k2eξθ2e<τ<12k1eξθ1e, the equilibrium scenario should be NL, although because of 12k1eξθ1e<12k2eξθ2e, this equilibrium will not exist.

Proof of Lemma 1.

ΔDNN=D1NND2NN=c2c1+9t18tc1c2+9t18t=c2c19t.

ΔDLN=D1LND2LN=c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e218tc1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e218t=c2c1+τe+ξθ112k1e29t  (A36)
ΔDLL=D1LLD2LL=c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e218tc1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e218t=c2c1+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e29t  (A37)

First, the difference of the demand gap in scenarios LL and NN is determined as follows: ΔDLLΔDNN=ξ(θ1θ2)+12(k2k1)e29t.

Given that θ1>θ2, k2>k1, ξ>0, t>0, e2>0, ξ(θ1θ2)+12(k2k1)e29t>0. Thus, ΔDLL>ΔDNN.

In the same manner, we can derive ΔDLLΔDLN=12k2e2ξθ2τe9t. When ΔDLLΔDLN τ12k2eξθ2e. In summary, when τ12k2eξθ2e, ΔDNNΔDLLΔDLN.

Similarly, when 12k1eξθ1eτ<12k2eξθ2e, we can derive ΔDNNΔDLN<ΔDLL; when τ<12k1eξθ1e, we can derive ΔDLN<ΔDNN<ΔDLL.

Proof of Proposition 2.

Manufacturer 1’s price gap between scenario LN and scenario NN is p1LN*p1NN*=4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e29. Given that τ>0, e>0, θ1>0, ξ>0, k1>0, e2>0, we can derive 4τe+4ξθ1+52k1e29>0. Thus, p1LN*>p1NN* is constantly true.

Manufacturer 1’s price gap between scenario LL and scenario NN is p1LL*p1NN*=4ξ(θ1θ2)+52k1e2+2k2e29. Given that ξ>0, θ1>θ2, k1>0, k2>0, e2>0, we can derive 4ξ(θ1θ2)+52k1e2+2k2e29>0. Thus, p1LL*>p1NN* is constantly true.

Manufacturer 1’s price gap between scenario LL and scenario LN is p1LL*p1LN*=4ξθ24τe+2k2e29. If p1LL*>p1LN*, 4ξθ24τe+2k2e29>0, then we can derive τ<12k2eξθ2e; if p1LL*<p1LN*, then we can derive τ>12k2eξθ2e.

In summary, if τ<B, then p1NN*<p1LN*<p1LL*; if τB, then p1NN*<p1LL*<p1LN*.

Proof of Lemma 2.

Manufacturer 1’s demand gap between scenario LL and scenario NN is D1LLD1NN=ξ(θ1θ2)+12(k2k1)e218t. Given that ξ>0, t>0, θ1>θ2 and k2>k1, thus D1LL>D1NN is constantly true.

Manufacturer 1’s demand gap between scenario LL and scenario LN is:

D1LLD1LN=ξθ2τe+12k2e218t. If D1LL<D1LN, then 12k2e2ξθ2τe18t<0, and we can derive τ>12k2eξθ2e.

In summary, when τ>12k2eξθ2e, D1NN<D1LL<D1LN.

Similarly, when 12k1eξθ1eτ<12k2eξθ2e, we can derive D1NN<D1LN<D1LL; when τ<12k1eξθ1e, we can derive D1LN<D1NN<D1LL.

Proof of Lemma 3.

ΠR1LNξ=θ1(c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e2)81t, given that D1LN*=c2c1+9t+τe+ξθ112k1e218t>0, θ1>0, t>0; then, ΠR1LNξ>0.

Similarly, we can prove ΠR2LN*ξ=θ1(c1c2+9tτeξθ1+12k1e2)81t<0,

ΠR1LL*ξ=(θ1θ2)[c2c1+9t+ξ(θ1θ2)12k1e2+12k2e2]81t>0, (A38)
ΠR2LL*ξ=(θ2θ1)[c1c2+9tξ(θ1θ2)+12k1e212k2e2]81t<0  (A39)

Proof of Lemma 4.

p1LL*e=(5k1+4k2)e9, given that k1>0, k2>0, e>0, we can derive (5k1+4k2)e9>0. Thus, p1LL*e>0. In the same manner, we can derive p2LL*e=(4k1+5k2)e9>0 and p1LN*e=5k1e+4τ9>0.

Author Contributions

X.P. contribute to Conceptualization, Methodology, Software, Validation, Investigation, Supervision, Writing-Original Draft preparation, Project Administration and Funding Acquisition. Z.S. contribute to Conceptualization, Investigation, Validation, Formal Analysis, Data curation, Visualization. G.H. contribute to Validation, Resources, Conceptualization, Supervision, Writing-Review and Editing, Project Administration and Funding Acquisition.

Funding

Financial support from National Natural Science Foundation of China under research project number 71871105, 71501128, 71632008, the Fifth Project “333 Project” of Jiangsu Province number BRA2016412 and the Six Talent Peak Project of Jiangsu Province JY-012 are gratefully acknowledged.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  • 1.FAO-IPCC Expert Meeting on Climate Change, Land Use and Food Security. [(accessed on 11 July 2018)]; Available online: http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/supporting-material/EM_FAO_IPCC_report.pdf.
  • 2.Barbier E. The concept sustainable economic development. Environ. Conserv. 1987;14:101–110. doi: 10.1017/S0376892900011449. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Nesticò A., Sica F. The sustainability of urban renewal projects: A model for economic multi-criteria analysis. J. Prop. Invest. Financ. 2017;35:397–409. doi: 10.1108/JPIF-01-2017-0003. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Climate Savers. [(accessed on 11 July 2018)]; Available online: http://www.worldwildlife.org/partnerships/climate-savers.
  • 5.Christopher M. Logistics and supply chain management: Strategies for reducing cost and improving service (second edition) Int. J. Logist. Res. Appl. 1999;2:103–104. doi: 10.1080/13675569908901575. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Ai X., Chen J., Zhao H., Tang X. Competition among supply chains: Implications of full returns policy. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2012;139:257–265. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.04.018. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Zhao J., Hobbs B.F., Pang J.S. Long-run equilibrium modeling of emissions allowance allocation systems in electric power markets. Oper. Res. 2010;58:529–548. doi: 10.1287/opre.1090.0771. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Benjaafar S., Li Y., Daskin M. Carbon footprint and the management of supply chains: Insights from simple models. IEEE Trans. Autom. Sci. Eng. 2013;10:99–116. doi: 10.1109/TASE.2012.2203304. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Du S., Zhu J., Jiao H., Ye W. Game-theoretical analysis for supply chain with consumer preference to low carbon. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2015;53:3753–3768. doi: 10.1080/00207543.2014.988888. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Tang S., Wang W., Cho S., Yan H. Reducing emissions in transportation and inventory management: (R, Q) policy with considerations of carbon reduction. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2018;269 doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2017.10.010. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Drake D.F., Kleindorfer P.R., Van Wassenhove L.N. Technology choice and capacity portfolios under emissions regulation. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2016;25:1006–1025. doi: 10.1111/poms.12523. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Fan R., Dong L. The dynamic analysis and simulation of government subsidy strategies in low-carbon diffusion considering the behavior of heterogeneous agents. Energy Policy. 2018;117:252–262. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2017.12.003. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Du S., Hu L., Wang L. Low-carbon supply policies and supply chain performance with carbon concerned demand. Ann. Oper. Res. 2017;255:569–590. doi: 10.1007/s10479-015-1988-0. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Meng X., Yao Z., Nie J., Zhao Y., Li Z. Low-carbon product selection with carbon tax and competition: Effects of the power structure. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2018;200:224–230. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2018.03.029. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Mcguire T.W., Staelin R. An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Mark. Sci. 1983;2:161–191. doi: 10.1287/mksc.2.2.161. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Xiao T., Choi T.M. Purchasing choices and channel structure strategies for a two-echelon system with risk-averse players. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2009;120:54–65. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2008.07.028. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Xiao T., Yang D. Price and service competition of supply chains with risk-averse retailers under demand uncertainty. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017;114:187–200. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2008.01.006. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Zhao X., Shi C. Structuring and contracting in competing supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011;134:434–446. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2009.11.016. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Mahmoodi A., Eshghi K. Price competition in duopoly supply chains with stochastic demand. J. Manuf. Syst. 2014;33:604–612. doi: 10.1016/j.jmsy.2014.05.008. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Amin-Naseri M.R., Khojasteh M.A. Price competition between two leader–follower supply chains with risk-averse retailers under demand uncertainty. Int. J. Adv. Manuf. Technol. 2015;79:377–393. doi: 10.1007/s00170-014-6728-0. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Taleizadeh A.A., Nooridaryan M., Govindan K. Pricing and ordering decisions of two competing supply chains with different composite policies: A stackelberg game-theoretic approach. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016;54:2807–2836. doi: 10.1080/00207543.2016.1154621. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Wang Y.Y., Hua Z., Wang J.C., Lai F. Equilibrium analysis of markup pricing strategies under power imbalance and supply chain competition. IEEE Trans. Eng. Manag. 2017;64:464–475. doi: 10.1109/TEM.2017.2693991. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Yao D.Q., Liu J.J. Competitive pricing of mixed retail and e-tail distribution channels. Omega. 2009;33:235–247. doi: 10.1016/j.omega.2004.04.007. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Atasu A., Souza G.C. How does product recovery affect quality choice? Prod. Oper. Manag. 2013;22:991–1010. doi: 10.1111/j.1937-5956.2011.01290.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]

Articles from International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health are provided here courtesy of Multidisciplinary Digital Publishing Institute (MDPI)

RESOURCES