Skip to main content
NIHPA Author Manuscripts logoLink to NIHPA Author Manuscripts
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2019 Feb 9.
Published in final edited form as: Theor Popul Biol. 2015 Jul 15;104:26–45. doi: 10.1016/j.tpb.2015.07.001

The entropy of the life table: A reappraisal

Oscar E Fernandez a,*, Hiram Beltrán-Sánchez b
PMCID: PMC6368683  NIHMSID: NIHMS1000828  PMID: 26188244

Abstract

The life table entropy provides useful information for understanding improvements in mortality and survival in a population. In this paper we take a closer look at the life table entropy and use advanced mathematical methods to provide additional insights for understanding how it relates to changes in mortality and survival. By studying the entropy (H) as a functional, we show that changes in the entropy depend on both the relative change in life expectancy lost due to death (e) and in life expectancy at birth (e0). We also show that changes in the entropy can be further linked to improvements in premature and older deaths. We illustrate our methods with empirical data from Latin American countries, which suggests that at high mortality levels declines in H (which are associated with survival increases) linked with larger improvements in e0, whereas at low mortality levels e made larger contributions to H. We additionally show that among countries with low mortality level, contributions of e to changes in the life table entropy resulted from averting early deaths. These findings indicate that future increases in overall survival in low mortality countries will likely result from improvements in e.

Keywords: Mortality, Life table, Entropy, Survival

1. Introduction

The life table is perhaps the most useful tool in mortality analyses, as it summarizes the mortality experience of a population at a given point in time into a set of simple indicators (Preston et al., 2000). For example, life expectancy, a by-product of the life table, has been used extensively and widely as a measure of population health in national and international contexts (United Nations, 2012). Other life table measures such as the life table entropy, however, have received much less attention, although the entropy could also be considered an equally useful indicator for understanding improvements in mortality and survival in a population (Wilmoth and Horiuchi, 1999).

In this paper we take a closer look at the life table entropy and provide additional insights for understanding how it relates to changes in mortality and survival. Unlike previous work that relied on univariate calculus (e.g., Demetrius, 1974, 1975, 1976, 1978, 1979; Goldman and Lord, 1986; Keyfitz, 1977), we provide a more rigorous development and a further description of the life table entropy using the calculus of variations. This approach has previously been used in demographic research (Arthur, 1984; Beltrán-Sánchez and Soneji, 2011; Preston, 1982), and as we show, it provides us with additional tools to deepen our understanding of the population entropy and overall population survival. We focus, in particular, on a widely used measure of mortality improvement - life expectancy at birth (which represents the average length of life in the survival curve of a population) - and an additional measure called e that has recently been proposed as a marker of lifespan inequality (Zhang and Vaupel, 2009). For example, averting deaths at younger ages (premature deaths) is associated with reductions in lifespan inequality (Zhang and Vaupel, 2008). Recent evidence from 40 countries shows a negative correlation between life expectancy (e0) and lifespan disparity (e) from 1840 to 2009, with most of the increase in life expectancy resulting from improvements in premature deaths (Vaupel et al., 2011). The authors conclude that improvements in life expectancy at birth can also be accompanied by reductions in lifespan disparity (e). In this paper we provide a mathematical foundation for these empirical findings by linking changes in the life table entropy, life expectancy at birth, and lifespan disparity. We demonstrate, mathematically and empirically, that changes in the entropy depend on both the relative change in life expectancy lost due to death (e) and in life expectancy at birth (e0). We also show that changes in the entropy can be further linked to averting premature and older deaths. These results provide important implications for understanding current and future changes in the overall survival of a population. For instance, using data from Latin American countries for 1950–2005, we show that at low mortality levels changes in e contributed the most to overall survival, indexed by the entropy, which resulted from improvements in premature deaths. This implies that in these countries future increases in overall survival will likely come from changes in e and that these improvements are likely to reduce lifespan inequality as a result of averting early deaths (Zhang and Vaupel, 2008, 2009).

The paper is organized as follows. We begin in Section 2 with a brief overview of the mathematical definitions of the mortality and survival functions, and the life expectancy and entropy (for the interested reader, Appendix A.1 contains a brief literature review of the entropy). We then review how the entropy is used to measure relative changes in life expectancy in Section 2.1, and discuss the functional nature of the entropy in Section 2.2. We present our main results in Sections 2.32.4, where we use the calculus of variations (reviewed in Appendix B) to show that changes in the entropy depend on both the relative change in life expectancy lost due to death (e) and in life expectancy at birth (e0) - c.f. (2.5) - and also provide a new way to describe the effect of changes in the mortality function on the population entropy (c.f. Proposition 2). In Section 3 we further link changes in the entropy with improvements in premature and older deaths in relation to e0 and e. Section 4 applies our results to mortality data from 18 Latin American countries from about 1950 to 2008. Therein we discuss our finding that at high mortality levels declines in H (which are associated with survival increases) linked with larger improvements in e0, whereas at low mortality levels e made larger contributions to H. We end with concluding remarks in Section 5.

2. The entropy

The life table entropy is commonly used throughout demography to study the relative changes in life expectancy associated with changes in age-specific mortality rates. In this section we review the construction of the entropy due to Keyfitz (1977) (see Appendix A.1 for a brief history), and then present our main analytical results.

2.1. The demographic motivation for introducing the entropy

Let μ(x) be the force of mortality at age x. The probability of surviving from birth to age x is then

S(x)=e0xμ(s)ds, (2.1)

so that life expectancy at age x is given by

e(x)=xe0aμ(s)dsda.

In many of the situations of interest to us in this paper, x is fixed and μ(s) may vary. For instance, we may be interested in studying changes in life expectancy at birth (which implies that x = 0). We therefore introduce the following notation to reflect these cases:

Sx[μ(s)]=e0xμ(s)ds,ex[μ(s)]=xe0aμ(s)dsda. (2.2)

Consider now a relative increase ϵ > 0 in μ - that is, a proportional increase in μ at all ages - similar to that proposed by Keyfitz (1977). Then the new mortality function is (1 + ϵ)μ(s) (note that Δμ = ϵ μ, so that Δμ/μ = ϵ), the new probability of surviving from birth to age x is

Sx[(1+ϵ)μ(s)]=e0x(1+ϵ)μ(s)ds=(e0xμ(s)ds)1+ϵ=(Sx[μ(s)])1+ϵ,

and the new life expectancy at age x is

ex[(1+ϵ)μ(s)]=xS(a)1+ϵda.

Without loss of generality, let us specialize to the most studied case of life expectancy—life expectancy at birth:

e0[(1+ϵ)μ(s)]=0S(a)1+ϵda.

We expect the relative increase in mortality to cause a relative decrease in life expectancy. To measure this decrease, Keyfitz and Caswell (2005, sec. 4.3.1) calculate de0/|ϵ=0 and then consider ϵ to be finite but small to arrive at the approximation

Δe0e0(0S(x)ln(S(x))dx0S(x)dx)ϵ. (2.3)

Since 0 ≤ S(x) ≤ 1 (this follows from (2.1)), the ratio in the parentheses is negative, confirming our expectation that a relative increase in mortality should result in a relative decrease in life expectancy. Accordingly, the negative of the expression in parentheses is known as the entropy of the life table, and is customarily denoted by H. More formally, we make the following definition.

Definition 1. Given a survival function S(x), the quantity defined by

H[S(x)]=0S(x)ln(S(x))dx0S(x)dx (2.4)

is called the entropy of the population.

We will explain the bracket notation in the next section, but for now let us note that the approximation in (2.3) suggests the following interpretation for H (Goldman and Lord, 1986): a small proportional increase ϵ in the death rate at all ages results in a proportional decrease in life expectancy of approximately H times ϵ. For example, for H = 1 “when the death rates at all ages increase by 1 percent, the expectation of life diminishes by 1 percent Keyfitz and Caswell (2005, Sec. 4.3.1)”. Thus, H measures how relative changes in the mortality function affect the relative change in life expectancy of a population. In other contexts H has other interpretations (see Appendix A.2), but it is commonly known to be “in general highly sensitive to variations in age-specific mortality” Demetrius (1979) (Appendix A.3 contains a more thorough discussion of this point), which makes it a useful tool for characterizing a population’s survivorship.

2.2. Understanding the life table entropy (H) as a functional of the survival function (S) and the force of mortality (μ)

The preceding analysis described the effect on H of a specific change in the mortality function μ(x) (and consequently, by (2.2), in S(x)). This suggests that we view H as a functional—a quantity whose input is a function and whose output is a real number. Indeed, as (2.4) makes clear, H is a functional of S(x), since it takes as input a survival function S(x) and outputs a real number (this is why we have used the H[S(x)] notation). Similarly, H can also be seen as a functional of μ(x), in which case we write H[μ(x)].

Functionals are similar to functions, except that the “independent variable” is now a function. To better see this important distinction (and also the functional nature of H), consider the so-called hyperbolic mortality example, where

μ(x)=as0x,S(x)=(1xs0)a,H[μ(x)]=H[S(x)]=aa+1.

For simplicity, set s0 = 1 so that we can uniquely identify a curve in the family of mortality and survival curves, μ(x) = a/(1 − x) and S(x) = (1 − x)a, by the parameter a. Since H = a/(a + 1), it follows that H assigns to each function μ(x) = a/(1 − x) (or, equivalently, S(x) = (1 − x)a) one number a/(a + 1), clearly illustrating the functional nature of H. A plot of μ(x) and S(x) for various a-values is shown in Fig. 1 panels (a) and (b), respectively, and the corresponding plot of the entropy H is shown in Fig. 1(c).

Fig. 1.

Fig. 1.

Plots of (a) μ(x) = a/(1 − x) for a = 0.2, 0.5, 1, 3, 10 (the a-values decrease as one moves from upper-left to lower-right), (b) S(x) = (1 − x)a for a = 0.2, 0.5, 1, 3, 10, and (c) the entropy H[μ(x)] = H[S(x)] = a/(a + 1).

A closer look at panels (b) and (c) reveals two more characteristics of H as a functional of S(x). Firstly, it detects the degree of concavity (also called convexity) in an S(x) function. Secondly, decreasing H values signal changes in the survival curve toward greater survivorship. (Appendix A.3 contains a discussion of these two general features of H.) By the same token, panels (a) and (c) also indicate similar characteristics of H as a functional of μ(x) but in this case decreasing H values signal changes in the force of mortality curve toward lower mortality. Because the survival function is bounded, 0 ≤ S(x) ≤ 1, changes in S(x) have “less room” to operate and this leads to different dynamics when studying changes in H as a functional of S(x) versus when H is a functional of μ(x)—which, at least theoretically, is unbounded. Thus, the entropy H would express differential effects in response to changes in the survival function (S(x)) or to changes in the force of mortality (μ(x)), and calculus of variations offers a unique opportunity to study these changes. We study these two cases in Sections 2.3 and 2.4, respectively.

2.3. A theorem concerning the entropy as a functional of the survival function

Changes in functions are described by calculus, while changes in functionals are described by the calculus of variations. (Appendix B contains a brief review of the subject, as well as the notation we will use throughout the remainder of the paper.) Importantly, calculus of variations allow us to look at variations in the entire survival function S(x) and their link with changes in H (as in Fig. 1), as opposed to univariate calculus in which changes are localized at a given point in the survival function. In this section we focus our attention on δH and δ2H - the analogues of the first and second derivatives of a single-variable function, respectively - and what they can tell us about changes in the survival function. To begin, let us note that the denominator of (2.4) is just e0[S(x)] (recall (2.2)). Moreover, Goldman and Lord (1986) and Vaupel (1986) have shown that the numerator of (2.4) - which includes the minus sign - can be re-expressed as

0μ(x)S(x)e(x)dx,

which has been traditionally denoted by e (Vaupel, 1986). Therefore,

e[S(x)]=0S(x)ln(S(x))dx,

so that the entropy (2.4) then becomes

H[S(x)]=e[S(x)]e0[S(x)].

Now, denote by S(x; ϵ) a family of smooth “varied curves”: curves that are small perturbations of S(x) but have the same endpoint values as S(x) (i.e., for all ϵ, S(0; ϵ) = S(0) and S(x; ϵ) → 0 as x → ∞).1 The difference S(x; ϵ) − S(x) is called the variation of S(x) and is traditionally denoted by δS (c.f. Appendix B). We can now prove the following theorem.

Proposition 1.

Let δS be a variation of the survival function S(x). Then:

  1. The relative change in H[S(x)] is
    δH[S(x)]H[S(x)]=δe[S(x)]e[S(x)]+δe0[S(x)]e0[S(x)], (2.5)
    where the first variations of e[S(x)] and e0[S(x)] are given by
    δe[S(x)]=δe0[S(x)]0ln(S(x))v(x)dx, (2.6)
    δe0[S(x)]=0v(x)dx, (2.7)
    and where δS(x) has been expanded to first-order in ϵ: δ S(x) = ϵv(x), with v(x) a smooth function that vanishes at zero and as x → ∞.
  2. The second variation δ2H[S(x)] is
    δ2H[S(x)]=1e0[0(v(x))2S(x)dx+2{δe0δH+(0w(x)dx)(H+1)+0w(x)ln(S(x))dx}], (2.8)
    where δ S(x) has been expanded to second-order in ϵ: δ S(x) = ϵv(x) + ϵ2w(x), where v(x) and w(x) are smooth functions that vanish at zero and as x → ∞.

The proof of Proposition 1 can be found in Appendix C.

Eq. (2.5) decomposes the relative change in H into the sum of the relative changes in e and e0. Therefore, this equation shows that changes in overall survival, indexed by H, depend on improvements in both e and in e0. In addition, Eq. (2.6) shows that e0 and e change in opposite directions in response to a variation in the survival function, since for small variations in S(x), where v(x) → 0, the first variations of e0 and e would be the exact opposites of each other.

We end this section by noting that when ϵ is finite but small we can use the first and second variation to approximate H[S + δS] to second order in ϵ (see also (B.8)):

H[S(x)+δS(x)]H[S(x)]+ϵδH[S(x)]+ϵ22δ2H[S(x)]. (2.9)

2.4. The entropy as a functional of the mortality function

Let us now return to the problem of studying the effect on H of varying μ(x). The following theorem is the analogue of Proposition 1.

Proposition 2.

Let δμ be a variation of the mortality function μ(s). Then the relative change in H[μ(s)] is given by

δH[μ(s)]H[μ(s)]=δe[μ(s)]e[μ(s)]+δe0[μ(s)]e0[μ(s)], (2.10)

where the first variations of e[μ(x)] and e0[μ(x)] are given by

δe[μ(s)]=δe0[μ(s)]0Sx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[μ(s)])ln(Sx[v(s)])dx, (2.11)
δe0[μ(s)]=0Sx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[v(s)])dx, (2.12)

with Sx[v(s)]=e0xv(s)ds, and where δμ(s) has been expanded to first-order in ϵ: δμ(s) = ϵv(s), with v(s) a smooth function that vanishes at zero and as s → ∞.

The proof of Proposition 2 can be found in Appendix C.

Although (2.10) is a direct analogue of (2.5), note that the equations identifying the first variations of δe[S(x)] and δe0[S(x)] ((2.6) and (2.7)) are very different from those shown above in (2.11) and (2.12). The extra terms shown in the latter case come from the non-linear link between the force of mortality and average years of life (δe and δe0). These equations highlight the differential effect on the entropy H resulting from changes in the survival function (S(x)) versus changes in the force of mortality (μ(x)).

Similar to Eq. (2.6), Eq. (2.11) shows that there is a negative association between the first variation of e[μ(x)] and that of e0[μ(x)]—when one increases the other one decreases. Moreover, for very small variations (δμ(s) close to zero) the second term in (2.11) becomes negligible (because Sx[v(s)]|v(s)≈0 → 1 and ln(Sx[v(s)]) → 0), and the two variations become negatives of each other.

2.5. Reproducing the Keyfitz result with Propositions 1 and 2

As a quick application of Propositions 1 and 2, let us show that the calculation performed by Keyfitz and Caswell (2005, Sec. 4.3.1) and reviewed in Section 2.1 is indeed an investigation of the change in the functional H under the variation δμ = ϵμ(s) of the mortality function (Beltrán-Sánchez and Soneji, 2011).

To begin, note that the new mortality function (1 + ϵ)μ(s) in that calculation can be written

(1+ϵ)μ(s)=μ(s)+ϵμ(s)=μ(s)+δμ(s).

In the language of Proposition 2, this means that v(s) = μ(s), so that (2.12) immediately gives

δe0e0=0S(x)ln(S(x))dx0S(x)dx. (2.13)

If we now consider ϵ to be finite but small, applying (B.7) yields

Δe0e0ϵδe0e0=(0S(x)ln(S(x))dx0S(x)dx)ϵ,

which verifies the entropy result of Keyfitz and Caswell (2005, sec. 4.3.1) (Eq. (2.3)).

We can also derive (2.13) (and therefore again reproduce (2.3)) using Proposition 1 as follows. The variation in the mortality function causes a variation in the survival function S(x) of

δS(x)=S(x)1+ϵS(x)=S(x)(S(x)ϵ1)=S(x)(eϵln(S(x))1)=S(x)(ϵln(S(x))+ϵ2(ln(S(x)))22+).

(The terms in parentheses in the last equation come from Taylor-expanding eϵ ln(S(x)) − 1.) Therefore, to first-order in ϵ, the variation in the mortality function results in a variation δS = ϵS(x) ln(S(x)) in the survival function. Then, using (B.6) to compute the first variation of e0[S(x)] we arrive at

δe0[S(x)]=[ϵe0{S(x)+ϵS(x)ln(S(x))}]ϵ=0=0S(x)ln(S(x))dx.

Dividing this equation by e0 then yields (2.13).

Analytical expressions for the entropy are also known for other special scenarios. In Appendix D we consider a few of these special cases and apply Propositions 1 and 2 to again verify the results found in the literature.

3. Early deaths from late deaths

Propositions 1 and 2 allow us to study changes in the life table entropy (H) associated with improvements in the survival and mortality functions across all ages. These propositions can also be used to provide additional insights to link premature and older deaths with life table entropy, and to inform about changes in lifespan disparity. For instance, an important property of e as a measure of life disparity is that there is a unique threshold age, a, that separates early from late deaths (Zhang and Vaupel, 2009). The importance of this age for overall survival is that improvements in reducing early (premature) deaths reduces variation in lifespans (overall survival), while improvements in late (older) deaths increases variation in lifespans (Vaupel et al., 2011). An age a separates early from late deaths if 0 = e(a)−e0(a)[1 −Λ(a)], where Λ(a)=0aμ(s) is the cumulative hazard function (Zhang and Vaupel, 2009).

Proposition 1 can be re-expressed to incorporate a given threshold age a. The result is (Appendix E):

δH[S(x)]H[S(x)]={δe[S(x|x<a)]e[S(x)]+δe0[S(x|x<a)]e0[S(x)]}+{δe[S(x|xa)]e[S(x)]+δe0[S(x|xa)]e0[S(x)]}, (3.1)

where the first conditional variations of e[S(x)] and e0[S(x)] are given by

δe[S(x|x<a)]=δe0[S(x|x<a)]0aln(S(x))v(x)dx, (3.2)
δe[S(x|xa)]=δe0[S(x|xa)]aln(S(x))v(x)dx, (3.3)
δe0[S(x|x<a)]=0av(x)dx, (3.4)
δe0[S(x|xa)]=av(x)dx, (3.5)

where v(x) is a smooth function that vanishes at zero and as x → ∞.

Eq. (3.1) shows that relative changes in the entropy can be decomposed as the sum of relative changes in e[S(x)] and e0[S(x)] associated with early and late deaths. In addition, Eqs. (3.2)(3.5) highlight the interplay between e[S(x)] and e0[S(x)] in determining overall survival when early and/or late deaths are averted. Proposition 2 can also be written in analogous form to (3.1) with its respective conditional variations in e[μ(s)] and e0[μ(s)] (Appendix E).

Note that the above equations are general in the sense that they work with any threshold age. For instance, one may be interested in investigating changes in the entropy associated with mortality improvements below and above the mean, median, mode2 or any other moment of the survival probability function or the force of mortality (Appendix E).

4. Application to Latin American mortality data

In this section we describe the results of applying Proposition 1 to assess changes in the entropy, H, and their corresponding link with changes in e0 and e.

4.1. Data and methods

We use period mortality data from 18 countries in Latin America from about 1950 to 2008 from the Latin American Mortality Database (Palloni et al., 2014) (Table 1).This data covers the period when major improvements in mortality took place in the region, with particularly fast declines in infant mortality and sizeable increases in life expectancy at birth (Palloni and Wyrick, 1981; Palloni and Pinto, 2011).

Table 1.

Latin American countries with available period mortality data by age and sex.

Country Years
Argentina 1953,1965, 1975, 1985, 1996, 2005
Brazil 1985,1995, 2005
Chile 1956,1965, 1976, 1987, 1997, 2006
Colombia 1957,1968, 1979, 1989, 1999, 2008
Costa Rica 1956,1968, 1978, 1992, 2005
Cuba 1961,1975, 1991, 2006
Dominican Republic 1955,1965, 1975, 1987, 1997, 2006
Ecuador 1956,1968, 1978, 1986, 1995, 2005
El Salvador 1955,1966, 1981, 1999, 2008
Guatemala 1957,1968, 1977, 1987, 1998, 2005
Honduras 1955,1967, 1981, 1989
Mexico 1955,1965, 1975, 1985, 1995, 2005
Nicaragua 1956,1967, 1983, 2000, 2007
Panama 1955,1965, 1975, 1985, 1995
Paraguay 1956,1967, 1977, 1987, 1997, 2006
Peru 1966,1976, 1987, 2000, 2008
Uruguay 1969,1980, 1990, 2000, 2007
Venezuela 1955,1966, 1976, 1985, 1995, 2006

Source:Latin American Mortality Database (LAMBdA).

We focus here on age 0, that is, life expectancy at birth (e0) with its corresponding life expectancy lost due to death (e) and life table entropy (H). To highlight the usefulness of Proposition 1 for studying changes in overall survival, we also provide an application decomposing changes in H associated with improvements in early vs. late deaths. Because population data typically comes in discrete form, we use standard techniques to estimate e(0), e(0), and H at time t (life table notation) - see Appendix F.1 - and also use the discrete versions of the first variations in Proposition 1 - see Appendix F.2.

4.2. Results

As a first application of Proposition 1, for each country in Table 1 we compare the observed change in H between two consecutive time periods t1 and t2 (H[S(x, t2)] − H[S(x, t1)]) to the predicted change in H (δH[S(x, t1)]).3 Using advanced numerical integration techniques (Appendix F.2), we find that in each country the average percentage error in the estimation across all periods is <0.16%4

Next, Fig. 2 shows estimates of the life table entropy, H, for all countries included in the analyses for males and females (see Appendix Table 2 for specific values). Results indicate a decline in H over time suggesting improvements in overall survival in all these countries since the 1950’s. Interestingly, there is a different pattern in H between countries that had an early demographic transition and those with a late transition. For instance, countries with an early demographic transition (e.g., Argentina, Costa Rica, Cuba, and Uruguay) start at lower levels in H in the 1950’s and show slower pace of decline over time; the opposite is true for countries with a late demographic transition (e.g., El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras and Nicaragua). This result reflects the fact that countries with an early demographic transition had already attained relatively low mortality levels in the 1950’s (Palloni and Pinto, 2011); thus, their corresponding life table entropy early on is lower than that of countries with a late demographic transition. In addition, improvements in overall survival tend to be larger when starting at high mortality levels, suggesting that H would show faster declines for countries with a late demographic transition.

Fig. 2.

Fig. 2.

Life table entropy by country, year and gender.

As a second application of Proposition 1 - and (2.5) specifically - we now decompose changes in H over time to assess whether increases in overall survival in Latin America in the second part of the 20th century are due to larger improvements in e vs. e0.

The percentage contribution of e and e0 to the change in H between two consecutive periods for each country for males and females is shown in Figs. 3 and 4, respectively (Appendix Table 3). Results clearly indicate a differential contribution of e0 and e to changes in H over time. Improvements in e0 show larger contributions to increasing overall survival at high mortality levels (e.g., before 1990), but improvements in e contributed the most as the mortality level declines. For instance, for males in El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras and Nicaragua, increases in e0 contributed about 60% of the change in H before 1980, but after 2000, a similar percentage contribution is due to improvements in e. On the other hand, increases in survival for males in countries with low mortality levels (e.g., Argentina, Cuba and Uruguay) were mostly due to improvements in e. There is a similar pattern for females, but in this case, e made larger contributions to overall survival because females tend to experience lower mortality rates than males.

Fig. 3.

Fig. 3.

Contribution of e (blue) and e0 (pink) to changes in Male Life Table Entropy by Country and Period. (For interpretation of the references to color in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.)

Fig. 4.

Fig. 4.

Contribution of e (blue) and e0 (pink) to changes in Female Life Table Entropy by Country and Period. (For interpretation of the references to color in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.)

Importantly, there was a different age pattern of mortality decline in Latin America since the 1950’s between countries with early and late demographic transitions (Palloni and Wyrick, 1981). For the latter countries, declines in infant and childhood mortality are likely responsible for the bulk of overall survival, but for the former countries, declines in adult and older adult mortality are the most likely contributors (Palloni and Pinto, 2011). Thus, as a third application of Proposition 1, we estimate the age separating early (premature) from late (older) deaths (a, Appendix Table 2) and further decompose changes in H over time associated with averting premature and older deaths using Eqs. (3.1)–(3.5) (Appendix Table 4).

Due to space limitations we only show results for males (Fig. 5); results for females are shown in the Appendix Fig. 6. Results for the age separating premature from older deaths show that in countries with a late demographic transition, a starts at lower values and increases at a faster pace over time relative to countries with a late demographic transition (Appendix Table 4, Appendix Fig. 7). This time trend corresponds to a faster mortality reduction over time among the former countries.

Fig. 5.

Fig. 5.

Contribution of changes in premature (blue for e and pink for e0) and older (light blue for e and light pink for e0) deaths to changes in male life table entropy by country and period. Negative values in older e (light blue) indicate that there was an increase over the period in average years of life lost due to death at older ages. (For interpretation of the references to color in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.)

Fig. 6.

Fig. 6.

Contribution of changes in premature (blue for e and pink for e0) and older (light blue for e and light pink for e0) deaths to changes in female life table entropy by country and period. Negative values in older e (light blue) indicate that there was an increase over the period in average years of life lost due to death at older ages. Source: Authors’ calculations using data from LAMBdA (Palloni et al., 2014) and Eqs. (3.1)-(3.5). (For interpretation of the references to color in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.)

Fig. 7.

Fig. 7.

Threshold age, a, separating premature and older deaths for males and females by country and period.

Source: Authors’ calculations using data from LAMBdA (Palloni et al., 2014) and formula 0 = e (a) − e0(a)[1 − Λ(a)], where Λ(a)=0aμ(s)ds is the cumulative hazard function (Zhang and Vaupel, 2009).

Fig. 5 shows results decomposing changes in the male entropy due to improvements in premature and older deaths. In countries with a late demographic transition (e.g., El Salvador, Guatemala, and Honduras), increases in overall survival are mainly due to increases in e0 resulting from improvements in older deaths (light pink). As the mortality level declines in these countries there is a larger contribution to overall survival from premature deaths (pink). On the contrary, in countries with an early demographic transition (e.g., Argentina, Cuba, and Uruguay), increases in overall survival are due to improvements in e resulting from averting premature deaths (dark blue). In some of these countries, for example in Argentina, Cuba and Uruguay, males at older ages experienced worsening rather than improving average years of life lost due to death—hence the negative contribution to overall survival in the figure. Nonetheless, premature deaths made large enough contributions to overall survival that they offset the mortality deterioration at older ages.

5. Concluding remarks

In this paper we provide a demographic interpretation of changes in the life table entropy by studying this concept from the functional viewpoint. This approach allow us to provide additional insights for understanding changes in overall survival in a population. In particular, we find that changes in the entropy depend on the relative changes in both life expectancy lost due to death (e) and in life expectancy at birth (e0), with the exact relationship given by (2.5). Our results also provide a new way to describe the effect of changes in the mortality function on the population entropy (c.f. Proposition 2). These are well-studied demographic concepts that now have a natural and consistent link to a population’s entropy and changes in its mortality and survival functions.

When we apply our methods to period mortality data in Latin American countries since the 1950’s, we obtain an especially useful description of the interplay between e0 and e in determining changes in overall survival of a population. We show that, in these countries, declines in H - which are associated with increases in overall survival - are driven by faster improvements in e0 in high mortality regimes, and by e in low mortality regimes. This insight reinforces the interpretation of e as an indicator of life disparity (Vaupel et al., 2011; Shkolnikov et al., 2011). Thus, in countries experiencing a low-mortality regime, improvements in overall survival will increasingly depend on reducing disparities in length of life in adulthood.

Moreover, we show that changes in the survival function produce changes in opposite direction between e and e0 (see Eq. (2.11)). In fact, for very small changes in the survival function, e.g. those currently experienced in low-mortality countries, e and e0 are direct opposites. Thus, our equation helps elucidate previous research that shows a negative correlation between e and e0 among low-mortality countries, why this correlation is higher in recent times, and why countries with low life disparity (e) tend to have higher values in life expectancy at birth (e0) (Vaupel et al., 2011).

For Latin American countries, our decomposition of changes in the entropy due to averting premature and older deaths shows that improvements in overall survival (i.e., declines in H) are associated with averting premature deaths. The implication of this result is that countries in Latin America are likely reducing lifespan inequality, which is a consequence of averting early deaths (Zhang and Vaupel, 2009, 2008).

Our methods and the substantive results have immediate applications for envisioning future changes in overall survival in other countries. For instance, it is likely that most increases in survival in high-income countries will result from improvements in e, while in low- and middle-income countries e0 is likely to still play an important role in determining overall survival of the population. Our methods also provide additional insights for linking changes in the life table entropy with improvements in premature and older deaths. Our formulas are general in the sense that they work with any threshold age. For instance, one may be interested in investigating changes in the entropy associated with mortality improvements below and above the mean, median, and mode.

The results we have achieved have been made possible by casting the problems we have studied within the domain of the calculus of variations. The examples considered in Appendix D further showcase how demographic questions, like the change in a population’s life expectancy given a relative change in their overall mortality, can be answered with variational calculus. These tools have already proven useful in the field (see e.g., Arthur, 1984; Beltrán-Sánchez and Soneji, 2011; Preston, 1982; Engelman et al., 2014), and we would like to further advocate their use, especially given the potential insights - such as those contained in Proposition 1 and the applications of it we have discussed - that may surface as a result of their usage.

Source: Latin American Mortality Database (LAMBdA).

Acknowledgments

OEF was partially supported by the Woodrow Wilson National Fellowship Foundation’s Career Enhancement Fellowship. HBS was supported by funding from the Harvard Center for Population & Development Studies (David E. Bell fellowship) and the Center for Demography of Health & Aging at the University of Wisconsin- Madison (R24HD047873 and P30AG017266).

Appendix A. Origin and interpretations of the entropy

A.1. A brief history of the origin of the life table entropy

The concept of entropy was initially proposed in the physical sciences as a measure of the level of disorder in a system. A similar concept in population studies - population entropy or life table entropy - was independently developed by Demetrius and Keyfitz in the 1970’s using different principles. The first approach, developed by Demetrius (1974, 1975, 1976, 1978), is a direct analogue of the entropy of physical systems. Demetrius considers a population to be a system of n interacting age classes that can be represented by a lattice system. This system has a phase space with an associated set of (invariant) probability measures. Thus, given a finite partition of the lattice system there is a Kolmogorov entropy which, in an equilibrium state (i.e., a state that maximizes the entropy for a fixed mean energy), corresponds to “the variability of the contribution of the different age classes to the stationary age distribution (Demetrius, 1974)”.

Table 2.

Estimates of life expectancy at birth (e0), life expectancy lost due to death (e), entropy of the life table (H), and the age separating early from late deaths (a) for males and females for 18 countries in Latin America.

Year Males
Females
e0 e a H e0 e a H
Argentina
1953 59.6 16.1 53.0 0.27 64.7 15.1 61.0 0.23
1965 61.8 15.1 55.0 0.24 68.0 13.4 65.0 0.20
1975 63.2 14.5 56.0 0.23 69.9 12.6 66.0 0.18
1985 66.1 13.1 59.0 0.20 72.4 10.9 69.0 0.15
1996 67.6 12.6 61.0 0.19 74.3 10.2 71.0 0.14
2005 69.5 11.7 63.0 0.17 75.6 9.5 73.0 0.13
Brazil
1985 60.6 16.6 53.0 0.27 66.5 14.2 62.0 0.21
1995 64.4 15.2 57.0 0.24 70.9 12.4 67.0 0.17
2005 67.7 13.7 61.0 0.20 73.9 10.8 71.0 0.15
Chile
1956 51.6 20.6 39.0 0.40 56.3 20.0 47.0 0.36
1965 55.3 18.8 45.0 0.34 61.0 17.7 55.0 0.29
1976 61.9 15.7 54.0 0.25 67.7 13.6 63.0 0.20
1987 67.0 13.1 60.0 0.20 72.9 10.6 69.0 0.15
1997 70.3 11.5 65.0 0.16 75.8 9.1 72.0 0.12
2006 72.4 10.5 68.0 0.14 77.6 8.2 75.0 0.11
Colombia
1957 50.9 21.4 36.0 0.42 54.0 20.8 42.0 0.39
1968 56.1 18.7 47.0 0.33 60.0 18.1 53.0 0.30
1979 61.9 16.2 55.0 0.26 66.4 14.4 61.0 0.22
1989 63.4 15.6 56.0 0.25 69.9 12.3 65.0 0.18
1999 66.0 14.7 60.0 0.22 72.9 11.0 69.0 0.15
2008 69.1 12.9 65.0 0.19 75.2 9.8 73.0 0.13
Costa Rica
1956 58.6 19.0 52.0 0.33 60.8 18.2 55.0 0.30
1968 62.8 16.6 58.0 0.26 65.8 15.3 62.0 0.23
1978 68.5 13.5 64.0 0.20 72.4 11.5 69.0 0.16
1992 71.6 11.5 67.0 0.16 75.7 9.4 72.0 0.12
2005 73.1 10.9 69.0 0.15 77.6 8.6 75.0 0.11
Cuba
1961 64.6 15.1 59.0 0.23 67.3 14.3 63.0 0.21
1975 69.4 12.7 65.0 0.18 72.2 11.5 69.0 0.16
1991 71.0 11.2 66.0 0.16 74.3 9.8 70.0 0.13
2006 73.3 10.3 68.0 0.14 76.8 8.7 73.0 0.11
Dominican Republic
1955 49.0 22.8 31.0 0.47 50.9 22.7 34.0 0.44
1965 54.8 20.8 44.0 0.38 57.4 20.3 48.0 0.35
1975 58.3 18.7 50.0 0.32 61.5 18.1 55.0 0.29
1987 62.7 16.6 56.0 0.26 67.6 14.9 63.0 0.22
1997 66.1 15.4 60.0 0.23 71.5 13.0 68.0 0.18
2006 67.8 14.0 62.0 0.21 72.9 11.7 69.0 0.16
Ecuador
1956 46.9 23.9 24.0 0.51 49.7 23.7 30.0 0.48
1968 54.3 21.3 43.0 0.39 56.7 20.7 47.0 0.36
1978 58.8 19.2 50.0 0.33 62.6 17.9 58.0 0.29
1986 63.2 16.7 57.0 0.26 67.5 14.8 64.0 0.22
1995 66.0 15.3 60.0 0.23 71.2 12.9 68.0 0.18
2005 69.5 13.5 65.0 0.19 74.7 10.8 72.0 0.15
El Salvador
1955 44.0 23.9 19.0 0.54 47.2 23.7 26.0 0.50
1966 50.7 21.9 36.0 0.43 54.9 20.9 45.0 0.38
1981 53.4 20.6 38.0 0.39 62.3 17.7 57.0 0.28
1999 61.2 16.9 50.0 0.28 70.8 12.5 67.0 0.18
2008 62.9 15.9 52.0 0.25 72.5 11.3 68.0 0.16
Guatemala
1957 42.4 24.4 13.0 0.58 42.6 24.0 15.0 0.56
1968 46.5 22.9 26.0 0.49 48.4 22.5 30.0 0.47
1977 50.9 21.6 35.0 0.43 54.4 20.8 43.0 0.38
1987 55.9 19.4 44.0 0.35 60.7 17.8 54.0 0.29
1998 61.3 17.4 51.0 0.28 67.1 14.6 62.0 0.22
2005 64.2 15.8 57.0 0.25 69.4 13.1 65.0 0.19
Honduras
1955 39.6 24.8 9.0 0.63 40.7 24.3 12.0 0.60
1967 48.5 22.6 30.0 0.47 51.4 22.0 37.0 0.43
1981 60.6 18.8 53.0 0.31 64.5 17.0 60.0 0.26
1989 65.4 16.7 60.0 0.26 69.6 14.6 67.0 0.21
Mexico
1955 48.5 22.8 30.0 0.47 51.7 22.1 37.0 0.43
1965 54.2 20.5 42.0 0.38 59.3 19.1 52.0 0.32
1975 59.3 18.9 50.0 0.32 64.3 16.9 59.0 0.26
1985 63.4 16.3 56.0 0.26 69.1 13.6 65.0 0.20
1995 66.8 14.4 61.0 0.22 72.1 11.8 68.0 0.16
2005 69.8 12.6 64.0 0.18 74.3 10.3 70.0 0.14
Nicaragua
1956 42.5 24.0 17.0 0.56 47.0 24.0 25.0 0.51
1967 49.0 22.7 31.0 0.46 52.9 22.0 40.0 0.42
1983 57.7 19.4 47.0 0.34 63.8 16.8 58.0 0.26
2000 64.7 15.3 57.0 0.24 69.5 13.1 64.0 0.19
2007 65.8 14.2 58.0 0.22 70.8 12.0 65.0 0.17
Panama
1955 57.4 18.8 49.0 0.33 58.6 19.0 49.0 0.32
1965 61.7 16.7 56.0 0.27 63.7 16.3 58.0 0.26
1975 65.7 14.8 60.0 0.23 67.9 14.1 63.0 0.21
1985 70.0 13.1 66.0 0.19 72.9 11.6 70.0 0.16
1995 71.4 12.3 67.0 0.17 74.9 10.6 72.0 0.14
Paraguay
1956 58.6 18.2 51.0 0.31 60.5 18.2 53.0 0.30
1967 61.2 16.8 55.0 0.27 63.4 16.3 58.0 0.26
1977 62.6 16.2 56.0 0.26 65.3 15.4 60.0 0.24
1987 65.0 14.6 59.0 0.23 68.1 13.5 64.0 0.20
1997 65.2 14.5 59.0 0.22 69.1 12.9 64.0 0.19
2006 68.1 13.0 63.0 0.19 71.9 11.2 68.0 0.16
Peru
1966 48.1 22.9 30.0 0.48 50.9 22.9 34.0 0.45
1976 55.6 20.4 46.0 0.37 58.5 19.7 51.0 0.34
1987 61.0 17.6 54.0 0.29 64.4 16.5 60.0 0.26
2000 66.3 14.5 61.0 0.22 70.4 12.8 67.0 0.18
2008 69.2 12.7 64.0 0.18 73.0 11.0 69.0 0.15
Uruguay
1969 63.0 14.5 56.0 0.23 68.8 12.8 65.0 0.19
1980 65.4 13.5 59.0 0.21 71.6 11.5 68.0 0.16
1990 67.5 12.5 61.0 0.19 73.9 10.3 71.0 0.14
2000 68.8 12.1 62.0 0.18 75.3 9.6 72.0 0.13
2007 70.2 11.5 64.0 0.16 76.3 9.1 73.0 0.12
Venezuela
1955 55.6 19.5 46.0 0.35 58.5 19.1 50.0 0.33
1966 60.8 16.8 53.0 0.28 64.5 15.6 58.0 0.24
1976 62.1 15.7 55.0 0.25 67.6 13.9 62.0 0.21
1985 65.1 14.4 58.0 0.22 70.5 12.2 65.0 0.17
1995 66.5 14.0 60.0 0.21 72.3 11.3 68.0 0.16
2006 67.3 13.9 61.0 0.21 74.2 10.4 70.0 0.14

Source: Authors’ calculations using data from LAMBdA (Palloni et al., 2014).

Contrary to Demetrius, Keyfitz (1977) uses demographic principles to derive an analogous formula of population entropy. Keyfitz develops his concept while searching for an alternative indicator to assess changes in life expectancy associated with fractional declines in age-specific mortality rates. Both approaches lead to similar entropy formulations, although their focus is rather different as Demetrius (1979) emphasizes the net maternity function while Keyfitz (1977) focuses on changes in the mortality schedule.

A.2. Other interpretations of the entropy

While the entropy of a physical system has the same meaning regardless of the context - the higher the entropy the higher the disorder in the system - the many applications in human and non-human populations of the population entropy have resulted in a variety of context-specific interpretations. For example, population entropy has been associated with the fitness of an age-structured population (Demetrius, 1974), the life-history of a population (e.g., populations that only reproduce once have zero entropy—semelparous populations) (Demetrius, 1975), the rate of convergence of a population to its stable equivalent age distribution (Tuljapurkar, 1982, 1993), the general shape of the survival function (e.g., entropy = 0 if all mortality concentrates at one age or entropy = 1 if mortality is the same at all ages) (Demetrius, 1978; Keyfitz and Caswell, 2005), and the “degree” of concavity of the survival function, such that increasing concentration of deaths at some age corresponds to lower entropy values (e.g., low entropy in high-income countries as deaths concentrate at older ages) (Wilmoth and Horiuchi, 1999; Nagnur, 1986).

Table 3.

Contribution to changes in the life table entropy (H) due to changes in life expectancy at birth (e0) and in life expectancy lost due to death (e) for males and females for 18 countries in Latin America.

Period Males
Females
Change in H
Overall cont
% cont
Change in H
Overall cont
% cont
Observed Predicteda δee δe0e0 δee δe0e0 Observed Predicteda δee δe0e0 δee δe0e0
Argentina
1953–1965 −0.026 −0.028 −0.018 −0.010 65.2 34.8 −0.036 −0.035 −0.023 −0.012 65.5 34.5
1965–1975 −0.015 −0.016 −0.010 −0.006 63.6 36.4 −0.018 −0.017 −0.012 −0.005 69.1 30.9
1975–1985 −0.032 −0.033 −0.022 −0.010 68.2 31.8 −0.029 −0.029 −0.023 −0.006 77.9 22.1
1985–1996 −0.012 −0.011 −0.007 −0.005 59.9 40.1 −0.014 −0.014 −0.010 −0.004 72.3 27.7
1996–2005 −0.018 −0.017 −0.012 −0.005 70.3 29.7 −0.011 −0.011 −0.009 −0.002 77.7 22.3
Brazil
1985–1995 −0.038 −0.035 −0.018 −0.017 51.9 48.1 −0.039 −0.034 −0.019 −0.014 57.5 42.5
1995–2005 −0.033 −0.032 −0.020 −0.012 62.9 37.1 −0.028 −0.028 −0.020 −0.007 73.6 26.4
Chile
1956–1965 −0.058 −0.062 −0.033 −0.029 53.4 46.6 −0.066 −0.069 −0.039 −0.030 57.0 43.0
1965–1976 −0.087 −0.090 −0.049 −0.041 54.6 45.4 −0.088 −0.090 −0.058 −0.032 64.4 35.6
1976–1987 −0.058 −0.058 −0.037 −0.021 64.0 36.0 −0.056 −0.055 −0.039 −0.015 71.7 28.3
1987–1997 −0.031 −0.029 −0.019 −0.010 66.4 33.6 −0.025 −0.023 −0.017 −0.006 75.1 24.9
1997–2006 −0.019 −0.019 −0.014 −0.005 74.3 25.7 −0.015 −0.014 −0.011 −0.003 80.5 19.5
Colombia
1957–1968 −0.087 −0.090 −0.047 −0.043 51.9 48.1 −0.084 −0.087 −0.044 −0.043 50.6 49.4
1968–1979 −0.072 −0.075 −0.040 −0.035 53.6 46.4 −0.084 −0.085 −0.053 −0.032 62.2 37.8
1979–1989 −0.016 −0.016 −0.010 −0.006 61.4 38.6 −0.041 −0.041 −0.030 −0.011 72.4 27.6
1989–1999 −0.024 −0.022 −0.011 −0.010 52.7 47.3 −0.025 −0.022 −0.015 −0.008 66.5 33.5
1999–2008 −0.036 −0.035 −0.025 −0.010 70.4 29.6 −0.021 −0.021 −0.016 −0.005 76.6 23.4
Costa Rica
1956–1968 −0.060 −0.061 −0.038 −0.024 61.4 38.6 −0.067 −0.067 −0.043 −0.025 63.5 36.5
1968–1978 −0.068 −0.068 −0.044 −0.024 64.5 35.5 −0.073 −0.072 −0.049 −0.023 67.7 32.3
1978–1992 −0.037 −0.037 −0.028 −0.009 76.2 23.8 −0.035 −0.035 −0.028 −0.007 79.2 20.8
1992–2005 −0.011 −0.010 −0.006 −0.003 65.0 35.0 −0.013 −0.013 −0.010 −0.003 74.7 25.3
Cuba
1961–1975 −0.050 −0.048 −0.031 −0.017 64.2 35.8 −0.054 −0.051 −0.036 −0.016 69.6 30.4
1975–1991 −0.025 −0.025 −0.021 −0.004 82.6 17.4 −0.027 −0.028 −0.023 −0.004 83.7 16.3
1991–2006 −0.017 −0.018 −0.013 −0.005 71.6 28.4 −0.018 −0.016 −0.011 −0.005 71.4 28.6
Dominican Republic
1955–1965 −0.086 −0.089 −0.033 −0.056 37.4 62.6 −0.091 −0.093 −0.036 −0.057 39.0 61.0
1965–1975 −0.058 −0.058 −0.034 −0.024 58.8 41.2 −0.060 −0.061 −0.036 −0.025 58.9 41.1
1975–1987 −0.057 −0.057 −0.033 −0.024 57.7 42.3 −0.074 −0.073 −0.043 −0.025 59.4 40.6
1987–1997 −0.032 −0.030 −0.016 −0.014 53.4 46.6 −0.038 −0.036 −0.024 −0.013 65.6 34.4
1997–2006 −0.026 −0.027 −0.021 −0.006 77.5 22.5 −0.021 −0.021 −0.018 −0.004 82.8 17.2
Ecuador
1956–1968 −0.117 −0.121 −0.040 −0.081 32.9 67.1 −0.113 −0.116 −0.048 −0.067 41.9 58.1
1968–1978 −0.065 −0.066 −0.034 −0.032 51.3 48.7 −0.078 −0.079 −0.041 −0.038 52.5 47.5
1978–1986 −0.064 −0.065 −0.041 −0.025 62.3 37.7 −0.067 −0.068 −0.046 −0.022 67.1 32.9
1986–1995 −0.032 −0.031 −0.019 −0.012 61.9 38.1 −0.039 −0.039 −0.027 −0.012 68.9 31.1
1995–2005 −0.037 −0.036 −0.024 −0.012 66.4 33.6 −0.035 −0.035 −0.026 −0.009 74.8 25.2
El Salvador
1955–1966 −0.113 −0.117 −0.033 −0.084 28.4 71.6 −0.120 −0.123 −0.042 −0.082 33.8 66.2
1966–1981 −0.046 −0.047 −0.024 −0.023 51.2 48.8 −0.098 −0.097 −0.046 −0.051 47.0 53.0
1981–1999 −0.111 −0.113 −0.057 −0.056 50.5 49.5 −0.106 −0.109 −0.071 −0.038 64.8 35.2
1999–2008 −0.023 −0.023 −0.016 −0.007 68.1 31.9 −0.022 −0.022 −0.017 −0.004 79.9 20.1
Guatemala
1957–1968 −0.083 −0.086 −0.030 −0.056 35.2 64.8 −0.098 −0.099 −0.022 −0.077 22.3 77.7
1968–1977 −0.067 −0.069 −0.022 −0.047 32.4 67.6 −0.084 −0.085 −0.027 −0.057 32.4 67.6
1977–1987 −0.077 −0.081 −0.039 −0.042 48.5 51.5 −0.089 −0.092 −0.048 −0.044 51.8 48.2
1987–1998 −0.065 −0.063 −0.029 −0.034 46.2 53.8 −0.076 −0.074 −0.043 −0.031 58.6 41.4
1998–2005 −0.037 −0.037 −0.024 −0.013 63.9 36.1 −0.029 −0.029 −0.021 −0.008 74.0 26.0
Honduras
1955–1967 −0.160 −0.163 −0.021 −0.142 12.9 87.1 −0.169 −0.163 −0.006 −0.157 3.6 96.4
1967–1981 −0.155 −0.150 −0.034 −0.116 22.6 77.4 −0.164 −0.156 −0.047 −0.108 30.3 69.7
1981–1989 −0.055 −0.053 −0.029 −0.024 54.2 45.8 −0.055 −0.053 −0.032 −0.021 60.0 40.0
Mexico
1955–1965 −0.091 −0.096 −0.041 −0.055 42.7 57.3 −0.105 −0.104 −0.041 −0.063 39.5 60.5
1965–1975 −0.059 −0.058 −0.022 −0.035 38.9 61.1 −0.061 −0.060 −0.033 −0.027 55.1 44.9
1975–1985 −0.063 −0.063 −0.041 −0.022 64.6 35.4 −0.065 −0.066 −0.046 −0.020 70.1 29.9
1985–1995 −0.040 −0.040 −0.027 −0.014 66.0 34.0 −0.033 −0.034 −0.025 −0.009 74.2 25.8
1995–2005 −0.035 −0.035 −0.026 −0.010 72.4 27.6 −0.026 −0.026 −0.021 −0.005 80.6 19.4
Nicaragua
1956–1967 −0.102 −0.107 −0.021 −0.086 19.8 80.2 −0.094 −0.099 −0.035 −0.064 35.2 64.8
1967–1983 −0.127 −0.130 −0.048 −0.082 37.0 63.0 −0.152 −0.153 −0.067 −0.086 43.9 56.1
1983–2000 ‒0.099 −0.102 −0.061 −0.041 59.7 40.3 −0.074 −0.076 −0.052 −0.023 69.1 30.9
2000–2007 −0.021 −0.021 −0.017 −0.004 80.2 19.8 −0.020 −0.020 −0.017 −0.004 82.5 17.5
Panama
1955–1965 −0.057 −0.057 −0.032 −0.025 56.8 43.2 −0.067 −0.067 −0.039 −0.028 58.3 41.7
1965–1975 −0.045 −0.044 −0.027 −0.017 60.7 39.3 −0.049 −0.049 −0.032 −0.017 65.1 34.9
1975–1985 −0.039 −0.036 −0.021 −0.015 58.2 41.8 −0.047 −0.044 −0.029 −0.015 65.5 34.5
1985–1995 −0.014 −0.014 −0.010 −0.004 73.0 27.0 −0.019 −0.018 −0.014 −0.004 76.5 23.5
Paraguay
1956–1967 −0.035 −0.036 −0.023 −0.014 62.0 38.0 −0.043 −0.043 −0.029 −0.014 67.0 33.0
1967–1977 −0.017 −0.018 −0.012 −0.006 64.8 35.2 −0.022 −0.022 −0.014 −0.008 64.1 35.9
1977–1987 −0.033 −0.033 −0.023 −0.010 71.1 28.9 −0.037 −0.038 −0.028 −0.010 73.5 26.5
1987–1997 −0.003 −0.004 −0.003 −0.001 78.2 21.8 −0.012 −0.012 −0.009 −0.003 75.5 24.5
1997–2006 −0.032 −0.030 −0.021 −0.010 67.8 32.2 −0.030 −0.030 −0.022 −0.008 74.6 25.4
Peru
1966–1976 −0.108 −0.110 −0.035 −0.075 31.9 68.1 −0.113 −0.114 −0.046 −0.068 40.7 59.3
1976–1987 −0.078 −0.079 −0.044 −0.035 55.3 44.7 −0.081 −0.082 −0.049 −0.034 58.9 41.1
1987–2000 −0.070 −0.071 −0.046 −0.025 64.9 35.1 −0.074 −0.075 −0.051 −0.024 68.3 31.7
2000–2008 −0.036 −0.036 −0.026 −0.010 72.9 27.1 −0.031 −0.031 −0.025 −0.007 78.7 21.3
Uruguay
1969–1980 −0.023 −0.024 −0.015 −0.009 63.6 36.4 −0.026 −0.025 −0.017 −0.007 70.2 29.8
1980–1990 −0.022 −0.022 −0.016 −0.006 70.7 29.3 −0.021 −0.020 −0.015 −0.005 74.6 25.4
1990–2000 −0.010 −0.010 −0.006 −0.004 60.7 39.3 −0.011 −0.010 −0.008 −0.003 74.1 25.9
2000–2007 −0.012 −0.011 −0.008 −0.004 68.1 31.9 −0.008 −0.008 −0.007 −0.002 79.3 20.7
Venezuela
1955–1966 −0.076 −0.079 −0.046 −0.033 58.2 41.8 −0.084 −0.086 −0.053 −0.033 61.3 38.7
1966–1976 −0.023 −0.023 −0.017 −0.006 74.6 25.4 −0.038 −0.037 −0.026 −0.012 68.4 31.6
1976–1985 −0.030 −0.031 −0.019 −0.012 61.5 38.5 −0.031 −0.031 −0.023 −0.009 72.5 27.5
1985–1995 −0.011 −0.010 −0.005 −0.005 49.3 50.7 −0.017 −0.016 −0.012 −0.004 72.4 27.6
1995–2006 −0.005 −0.004 −0.002 −0.002 43.8 56.2 −0.016 −0.016 −0.012 −0.004 73.4 26.6
a

Predicted values are estimated as: δH[S(x,t1)]H[S(x,t1)](δe[S(x)]e(0,t1)δe0[S(x)]e(0,t1))(see Appendix F.2); ‘cont’, contribution.

Source: Authors’ calculations using data from LAMBdA (Palloni et al., 2014) and formulas from Proposition 1.

Table 4.

Contribution to changes in the life table entropy (H) due to changes in early (premature) and late (older) deaths in life expectancy at birth (e0) and in life expectancy lost due to death (e) for males and females for 18 countries in Latin America.

Period Males
Females
Overall contribution
% contribution
Overall contribution
% contribution
Pred δe/e
δe0/e0
δe/e
δe0/e0
Pred δe/e
δe0/e0
δe/e
δe0/e0
Δ in Ha Early Late Early Late Early Late Early Late Δ in Ha Early Late Early Late Early Late Early Late
Argentina
1953–1965 −0.028 −0.018 0.000 −0.006 −0.004 64.4 0.9 20.5 14.3 −0.035 −0.023 0.001 −0.006 −0.005 67.5 −2.0 18.7 15.8
1965–1975 −0.016 −0.012 0.002 −0.003 −0.002 78.9 −15.3 22.0 14.4 −0.017 −0.014 0.002 −0.003 −0.002 83.1 −14.0 18.7 12.2
1975–1985 −0.033 −0.021 −0.002 −0.005 −0.005 62.8 5.4 16.5 15.3 −0.029 −0.021 −0.002 −0.004 −0.002 70.1 7.8 14.3 7.8
1985–1996 −0.011 −0.008 0.001 −0.002 −0.003 69.9 −10.0 15.5 24.5 −0.014 −0.011 0.001 −0.002 −0.002 76.2 −4.0 13.0 14.8
1996–2005 −0.017 −0.011 −0.001 −0.002 −0.003 63.7 6.6 13.4 16.3 −0.011 −0.009 0.001 −0.001 −0.001 82.8 −5.0 12.6 9.7
Brazil
1985–1995 −0.035 −0.023 0.005 −0.007 −0.010 65.7 −13.9 21.1 27.0 −0.034 −0.027 0.008 −0.007 −0.008 79.7 −22.2 19.7 22.7
1995–2005 −0.032 −0.020 0.000 −0.006 −0.006 63.4 −0.4 17.3 19.8 −0.028 −0.021 0.000 −0.004 −0.003 74.7 −1.2 14.7 11.7
Chile
1956–1965 −0.062 −0.027 −0.006 −0.014 −0.015 44.4 9.0 22.7 23.9 −0.069 −0.032 −0.007 −0.014 −0.015 46.2 10.8 20.8 22.2
1965–1976 −0.090 −0.044 −0.005 −0.018 −0.022 49.6 5.0 20.6 24.8 −0.090 −0.050 −0.007 −0.018 −0.014 56.1 8.3 19.6 16.0
1976–1987 −0.058 −0.034 −0.003 −0.010 −0.011 58.2 5.8 17.1 18.9 −0.055 −0.036 −0.003 −0.008 −0.007 65.9 5.8 15.2 13.0
1987–1997 −0.029 −0.018 −0.002 −0.004 −0.006 61.1 5.2 13.6 20.1 −0.023 −0.017 0.000 −0.003 −0.003 75.3 −0.2 12.3 12.6
1997–2006 −0.019 −0.012 −0.002 −0.002 −0.003 63.0 11.3 11.8 13.9 −0.014 −0.010 −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 72.5 8.0 9.9 9.6
Colombia
1957–1968 −0.090 −0.030 −0.017 −0.016 −0.027 33.1 18.9 18.2 29.9 −0.087 −0.034 −0.010 −0.017 −0.026 38.7 11.9 19.2 30.2
1968–1979 −0.075 −0.039 −0.001 −0.016 −0.019 52.2 1.4 21.5 24.9 −0.085 −0.046 −0.007 −0.017 −0.015 53.9 8.3 19.7 18.0
1979–1989 −0.016 −0.013 0.003 −0.004 −0.003 76.7 −15.3 22.2 16.4 −0.041 −0.028 −0.002 −0.007 −0.005 66.9 5.5 16.6 11.0
1989–1999 −0.022 −0.011 0.000 −0.003 −0.007 52.3 0.3 15.2 32.1 −0.022 −0.014 −0.001 −0.003 −0.005 63.8 2.7 12.9 20.6
1999–2008 −0.035 −0.019 −0.005 −0.005 −0.005 55.0 15.4 14.8 14.8 −0.021 −0.013 −0.003 −0.002 −0.003 62.6 14.0 10.9 12.5
Costa Rica
1956–1968 −0.061 −0.031 −0.007 −0.013 −0.011 50.6 10.8 20.4 18.2 −0.067 −0.035 −0.008 −0.013 −0.012 52.0 11.5 19.1 17.4
1968–1978 −0.068 −0.043 −0.001 −0.013 −0.010 63.7 0.8 20.0 15.5 −0.072 −0.047 −0.002 −0.013 −0.011 65.0 2.7 17.7 14.6
1978–1992 −0.037 −0.025 −0.003 −0.006 −0.003 67.2 8.9 15.0 CO
CO*
−0.035 −0.025 −0.002 −0.005 −0.003 72.7 6.5 13.0 7.9
1992–2005 −0.010 −0.008 0.001 −0.001 −0.002 80.0 −15.0 14.3 20.7 −0.013 −0.010 0.001 −0.001 −0.002 80.1 −5.4 11.1 14.2
Cuba
1961–1975 −0.048 −0.030 −0.001 −0.008 −0.009 62.5 1.6 16.9 19.0 −0.051 −0.032 −0.004 −0.008 −0.008 61.7 7.9 15.2 15.2
1975–1991 −0.025 −0.017 −0.004 −0.003 −0.001 66.7 15.9 13.4 4.0 −0.028 −0.020 −0.003 −0.004 −0.001 72.5 11.2 12.7 3.6
1991–2006 −0.018 −0.015 0.002 −0.003 −0.002 85.5 −13.9 15.1 13.3 −0.016 −0.015 0.004 −0.002 −0.002 97.0 −25.6 14.2 14.4
Dominican Republic
1955–1965 −0.089 −0.022 −0.011 −0.014 −0.042 25.1 12.3 15.6 47.0 −0.093 −0.025 −0.011 −0.015 −0.042 27.2 11.8 16.0 45.0
1965–1975 −0.058 −0.025 −0.009 −0.012 −0.012 43.3 15.6 21.0 20.2 −0.061 −0.028 −0.008 −0.013 −0.013 45.8 13.1 20.5 20.6
1975–1987 −0.057 −0.031 −0.002 −0.012 −0.012 53.9 3.7 21.1 21.2 −0.073 −0.038 −0.005 −0.014 −0.016 52.2 7.2 18.7 21.9
1987–1997 −0.030 −0.020 0.003 −0.006 −0.008 64.8 −11.4 20.1 26.5 −0.036 −0.024 0.000 −0.006 −0.006 66.7 −1.1 17.1 17.3
1997–2006 −0.027 −0.017 −0.004 −0.004 −0.002 62.0 15.5 16.7 5.8 −0.021 −0.016 −0.002 −0.003 0.000 73.1 9.6 15.0 2.2
Ecuador
1956–1968 −0.121 −0.022 −0.018 −0.015 −0.066 18.1 14.8 12.7 54.4 −0.116 −0.026 −0.022 −0.017 −0.050 22.7 19.2 14.8 43.3
1968–1978 −0.066 −0.030 −0.004 −0.015 −0.017 45.0 6.3 23.0 25.7 −0.079 −0.034 −0.007 −0.016 −0.021 43.5 9.0 20.5 27.0
1978–1986 −0.065 −0.033 −0.008 −0.013 −0.011 50.7 11.6 20.5 17.2 −0.068 −0.039 −0.007 −0.014 −0.009 57.4 9.7 20.2 12.8
1986–1995 −0.031 −0.021 0.002 −0.007 −0.005 68.0 −6.1 20.9 17.2 −0.039 −0.027 0.000 −0.007 −0.005 69.7 −0.7 17.8 13.3
1995–2005 −0.036 −0.022 −0.002 −0.006 −0.006 60.5 5.9 16.4 17.2 −0.035 −0.025 −0.002 −0.005 −0.004 70.5 4.3 14.6 10.6
El Salvador
1955–1966 −0.117 −0.018 −0.016 −0.013 −0.071 15.0 13.5 11.3 60.3 −0.123 −0.024 −0.018 −0.017 −0.065 19.5 14.3 13.4 52.8
1966–1981 −0.047 −0.028 0.004 −0.015 −0.008 58.7 −7.6 32.8 16.0 −0.097 −0.041 −0.004 −0.020 −0.031 42.3 4.6 20.9 32.1
1981–1999 −0.113 −0.049 −0.008 −0.023 −0.033 43.0 7.5 20.3 29.2 −0.109 −0.064 −0.007 −0.022 −0.016 58.4 6.4 20.0 15.2
1999–2008 −0.023 −0.013 −0.003 −0.004 −0.003 54.2 13.9 17.1 14.8 −0.022 −0.015 −0.002 −0.003 −0.001 70.9 8.9 14.1 6.1
Guatemala
1957–1968 −0.086 −0.010 −0.021 −0.008 −0.048 11.2 24.0 9.0 55.8 −0.099 −0.011 −0.011 −0.009 −0.068 11.5 10.8 8.8 68.8
1968–1977 −0.069 −0.019 −0.003 −0.013 −0.034 27.4 5.0 18.2 49.4 −0.085 −0.023 −0.005 −0.014 −0.043 26.5 5.8 16.6 51.0
1977–1987 −0.081 −0.031 −0.008 −0.017 −0.025 38.6 9.9 21.2 30.3 −0.092 −0.039 −0.009 −0.019 −0.025 42.1 9.7 20.7 27.5
1987–1998 −0.063 −0.032 0.003 −0.014 −0.020 51.4 −5.3 21.7 32.1 −0.074 −0.042 −0.002 −0.015 −0.016 56.4 2.2 20.1 21.3
1998–2005 −0.037 −0.016 −0.008 −0.005 −0.008 43.2 20.7 14.7 21.4 −0.029 −0.017 −0.004 −0.004 −0.003 60.3 13.7 15.3 10.8
Honduras
1955–1967 −0.163 −0.009 −0.012 −0.008 −0.134 5.4 7.5 4.6 82.4 −0.163 −0.012 0.006 −0.010 −0.147 7.3 −3.7 5.9 90.5
1967–1981 −0.150 −0.045 0.011 −0.028 −0.088 30.1 −7.5 18.8 58.6 −0.156 −0.054 0.007 −0.031 −0.078 34.8 −4.5 19.8 49.9
1981–1989 −0.053 −0.029 0.000 −0.011 −0.013 54.1 0.1 20.6 25.2 −0.053 −0.032 0.000 −0.010 −0.011 60.8 −0.8 19.3 20.7
Mexico
1955–1965 −0.096 −0.027 −0.013 −0.017 −0.038 28.6 14.0 17.9 39.4 −0.104 −0.035 −0.006 −0.020 −0.043 33.7 5.8 19.2 41.3
1965–1975 −0.058 −0.026 0.004 −0.012 −0.023 45.2 −6.4 21.6 39.6 −0.060 −0.031 −0.002 −0.013 −0.014 52.2 2.9 21.1 23.8
1975–1985 −0.063 −0.031 −0.010 −0.012 −0.010 48.9 15.7 18.9 16.5 −0.066 −0.038 −0.009 −0.012 −0.008 57.2 12.9 18.0 11.9
1985–1995 −0.040 −0.024 −0.003 −0.007 −0.007 58.6 7.5 17.7 16.2 −0.034 −0.023 −0.001 −0.005 −0.003 69.9 4.3 15.8 10.0
1995–2005 −0.035 −0.023 −0.003 −0.006 −0.004 64.3 8.1 16.0 11.6 −0.026 −0.019 −0.002 −0.003 −0.002 73.6 7.0 13.4 6.0
Nicaragua
1956–1967 −0.107 −0.016 −0.005 −0.012 −0.074 14.8 4.9 11.6 68.6 −0.099 −0.021 −0.014 −0.015 −0.049 21.4 13.8 14.9 49.9
1967–1983 −0.130 −0.041 −0.007 −0.025 −0.057 31.6 5.4 19.1 43.9 −0.153 −0.054 −0.013 −0.029 −0.056 35.5 8.4 19.2 36.8
1983–2000 −0.102 −0.049 −0.012 −0.020 −0.021 47.8 11.9 19.7 20.6 −0.076 −0.045 −0.007 −0.014 −0.009 59.7 9.4 18.6 12.4
2000–2007 −0.021 −0.013 −0.004 −0.003 −0.001 62.5 17.7 16.7 3.1 −0.020 −0.015 −0.002 −0.003 0.000 71.9 10.5 15.2 2.4
Panama
1955–1965 −0.057 −0.027 −0.006 −0.011 −0.014 47.0 9.8 19.1 24.1 −0.067 −0.029 −0.010 −0.012 −0.016 43.2 15.0 17.3 24.4
1965–1975 −0.044 −0.027 0.000 −0.009 −0.009 61.1 −0.4 19.7 19.6 −0.049 −0.030 −0.002 −0.009 −0.008 60.5 4.6 18.5 16.5
1975–1985 −0.036 −0.024 0.003 −0.006 −0.009 67.4 −9.3 17.7 24.1 −0.044 −0.028 −0.001 −0.007 −0.008 64.2 1.3 15.4 19.0
1985–1995 −0.014 −0.010 0.000 −0.002 −0.002 70.5 2.5 15.2 11.8 −0.018 −0.014 0.000 −0.003 −0.002 76.9 −0.4 14.1 9.5
Paraguay
1956–1967 −0.036 −0.019 −0.004 −0.007 −0.007 51.7 10.3 19.7 18.3 −0.043 −0.020 −0.008 −0.007 −0.007 47.6 19.4 17.5 15.6
1967–1977 −0.018 −0.013 0.001 −0.004 −0.002 69.6 −4.8 22.8 12.4 −0.022 −0.014 0.000 −0.004 −0.004 64.5 −0.4 19.9 16.0
1977–1987 −0.033 −0.019 −0.004 −0.006 −0.004 58.7 12.4 17.8 11.2 −0.038 −0.022 −0.005 −0.006 −0.004 59.2 14.3 16.4 10.1
1987–1997 −0.004 −0.004 0.001 −0.001 0.000 92.5 −14.2 21.7 0.0 −0.012 −0.010 0.001 −0.002 −0.001 80.9 −5.4 18.0 6.5
1997–2006 −0.030 −0.017 −0.004 −0.004 −0.005 56.2 11.7 14.4 17.7 −0.030 −0.018 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 61.4 13.2 13.1 12.3
Peru
1966–1976 −0.110 −0.029 −0.006 −0.019 −0.056 26.6 5.4 17.1 51.0 −0.114 −0.032 −0.014 −0.019 −0.048 28.2 12.5 17.0 42.3
1976–1987 −0.079 −0.035 −0.008 −0.016 −0.019 44.7 10.6 20.9 23.8 −0.082 −0.040 −0.009 −0.017 −0.017 48.3 10.6 20.6 20.5
1987–2000 −0.071 −0.041 −0.006 −0.014 −0.011 57.0 7.9 19.8 15.2 −0.075 −0.046 −0.005 −0.014 −0.010 61.9 6.4 18.9 12.7
2000–2008 −0.036 −0.023 −0.003 −0.006 −0.004 63.6 9.3 16.1 11.0 −0.031 −0.022 −0.003 −0.005 −0.002 70.5 8.2 14.6 6.7
Uruguay
1969–1980 −0.024 −0.016 0.001 −0.004 −0.005 67.3 −3.7 17.6 18.8 −0.025 −0.017 0.000 −0.004 −0.004 70.3 −0.2 14.9 14.9
1980–1990 −0.022 −0.015 −0.001 −0.003 −0.003 66.1 4.6 15.4 13.9 −0.020 −0.016 0.000 −0.003 −0.002 75.9 −1.3 13.7 11.7
1990–2000 −0.010 −0.008 0.002 −0.002 −0.002 82.4 −21.7 16.9 22.4 −0.010 −0.009 0.001 −0.001 −0.001 87.1 −13.0 13.5 12.4
2000–2007 −0.011 −0.007 −0.001 −0.001 −0.002 58.1 10.0 11.5 20.4 −0.008 −0.006 0.000 −0.001 −0.001 73.3 6.0 10.6 10.1
Venezuela
1955–1966 −0.079 −0.039 −0.008 −0.017 −0.016 48.7 9.5 21.3 20.5 −0.086 −0.043 −0.010 −0.017 −0.016 50.1 11.2 20.2 18.5
1966–1976 −0.023 −0.014 −0.004 −0.004 −0.002 58.4 16.2 18.6 6.7 −0.037 −0.022 −0.004 −0.006 −0.006 58.2 10.1 16.5 15.1
1976–1985 −0.031 −0.020 0.001 −0.006 −0.006 63.6 −2.1 18.5 20.0 −0.031 −0.020 −0.002 −0.005 −0.004 65.0 7.5 15.1 12.3
1985–1995 −0.010 −0.006 0.001 −0.002 −0.003 63.2 −13.9 15.6 35.0 −0.016 −0.011 −0.001 −0.002 −0.002 66.2 6.2 12.9 14.7
1995–2006 −0.004 −0.001 0.000 0.000 −0.002 34.7 9.1 7.0 49.2 −0.016 −0.011 −0.001 −0.002 −0.002 68.1 5.3 12.2 14.4
a

Predicted change in H (Pred Δ in H) is estimated as: δH[S(x,t1)]H[S(x,t1)]{[δe[S(x|x<a)]e[S(x)]+δe0|S(x|x<a)]e0[S(x)]]+[δe[S(x|xa)]e[S(x)]+δe0[S(x|xa)]e0[S(x)]]}(see Appendix F.2); Δ, change. The age that separates premature from older deaths, a, is shown in the Appendix Table 2.

Source: Authors’ calculations using data from LAMBdA (Palloni et al., 2014) and Eqs. (3.1)-(3.5).

In demography, most of the studies about population entropy follow Keyfitz’s principle by studying the relative change in life expectancy associated with changes in age-specific mortality rates. These studies have elucidated important properties of the entropy. For instance, Goldman and Lord (1986), Mitra (1979, 1978) and Vaupel (1986) re-expressed the entropy using life table notation as the weighted average of life expectancies at age x, which can be further described as the average years of future life that are lost by the observed deaths (Goldman and Lord, 1986), the proportional increase in life expectancy at birth if everyone’s first death were averted (Mitra, 1979; Vaupel, 1986), or alternatively, life expectancy lost due to death among those surviving to a given age (Vaupel and Canudas Romo, 2003; Zhang and Vaupel, 2009). This last definition, called e-dagger (e), was first coined by Vaupel (1986). This indicator has been further developed elsewhere (Vaupel and Canudas Romo, 2003; Zhang and Vaupel, 2009) and shown to be a useful indicator of life disparity (Vaupel et al., 2011; Shkolnikov et al., 2011).

A.3. The effect of changes in age-specific mortality on H

A population’s entropy also detects changes in age-specific mortality. To see this, consider first the case of constant mortality, where μ(s) = μ is constant5 and taken positive, for the moment. Then S(x) = eμx, and after inserting this into the formula for H (the negative of the parenthetical term in (2.3)) a straightforward calculation yields H = 1. The case when μ(s) = 0 - the zero mortality case6 - leads to S(x) = 1, ln S(x) = 0, and thus H = 0.7 Thus, we conclude that if the mortality function is constant across age, H = 0, 1. The contrapositive of this statement is that if H ≠ 0, 1 then the mortality function is non-constant across age. One more example further illustrates this point. Let us refer to this as the almost-constant mortality case, wherein

μ(s)={μ1,s0[a,b],μ2,s[a,b], (A.1)

where 0 < a < b and μ1, μ2 ≠ 0. We envision ba to be small, so that the force of mortality is the constant μ1 for most of the ages s, and only different (yet still constant) for a small subset of ages. The corresponding survival function is

S(x)=e(ba)(μ1μ2)μ1x,

and the corresponding entropy is

H=1(ba)(μ1μ2).

In the limit of ba, the force of mortality becomes constant and H → 1, which verifies our earlier results of the constant mortality case. But when ba, the change across age in the force of mortality in (A.1) is detected by H. To summarize, for a given population, values of H ≠ 0, 1 immediately tell us that the population’s mortality function varies across age. Moreover, the almost-constant mortality case also highlights the sensitivity of H: no matter how small the difference ba is, H detects the change in mortality, suggesting that H is “in general highly sensitive to variations in age-specific mortality” Demetrius (1979).

Because mortality is related to the survival function via (2.1), these results suggest that a population’s entropy may be a useful tool in characterizing its survivorship (in the cases when mortality is not constant across age). Indeed, in the literature H is often referred to as the “simple parameter” that can “characterize the shape of [survival] curves” Demetrius (1979). Often the “shape” refers to the degree of concavity (also convexity) of the survival curve, and we find several references agreeing that “H is a convenient summary of the degree of concavity in an l(x) column” Keyfitz and Caswell (2005, Sec. 4.3.2). We see clearly that as the concavity of the survival curves in Fig. 1(a) changes, the entropy H in Fig. 1(b) changes as well. Moreover, we note that decreasing H values - given by decreasing a-values - leads to increased survivorship.

Appendix B. Introduction to the calculus of variations

Consider the following calculus problem. Given a real-valued function y(x) of a real variable x that is differentiable on a given interval (a, b), approximate the change in y due in a small change ϵ in x from an initial point x0 ∈ (a, b).

This problem can be solved easily by using differentials as follows. The assumed differentiability of y guarantees the existence of y′(x0), defined by

y(x0)=limϵ0y(x0+ϵ)y(x0)ϵ. (B.1)

The infinitesimal change dy in y due to an infinitesimal change dx in x is then defined by

dy=y(x0)dx.

If we now suppose that the change in x is finite but small, we may drop the equality in (B.1) and use the approximation

y(x0)y(x0+ϵ)y(x0)ϵ,orequivalently,Δyy(x0)ϵ, (B.2)

where Δy = y(x0 + ϵ) − y(x0). The last approximation in (B.2) has a simple interpretation: the change in input Δx = ϵ produces an approximate change in the function’s values given by the derivative y′(x0) multiplied by Δx = ϵ. Moreover, from (B.2) we also see that the relative change in y, given by dy/y, is y′(x0) multiplied by the relative change dx/x:

dyy=y(x0)dxx,or,forafinitebutsmallchangeΔx=ϵ,Δyyy(x0)ϵx. (B.3)

The related problem of approximating the change in a differentiable multivariable function y(x) in the direction of a vector v can be treated similarly. The analogue of y′(x0) is the directional derivative y′(x0) defined by

y(x0)=limϵ0y(x0+ϵv)y(x0)ϵ. (B.4)

The approximate change in y in the direction v is then given by (B.2), with y′(x0) replaced by y′(x0).

Now, if the object of interest is not a function but instead a functional, the derivative (B.4) has an analogue. To describe it let us consider the simplest example of a functional: the familiar Riemann integral

I[y(x)]=aby(x)dx. (B.5)

Given a function y(x) that is Riemann integrable over the interval [a, b], the functional I[y(x)] produces a number—the net signed area between a and b under the graph of y(x). We can now ask the same question as before: what is the approximate change in I[y(x)] due to a change in y(x)?

The answer to this question is an exercise in the calculus of variations. Following Sagan (1992) one first defines a variation of y(x) - denoted by δy(x) - by ϵv(x), where v(a) = v(b) = 0. (Intuitively, the curve y(x)+δy(x) in general closely resembles y(x) but is not equal to it.) Then, the first variation of a functional

J[y(x)]=abF(x,y(x))dx,

where F is a smooth function defined as follows.

Definition 2. Let v(x) and y(x) be two functions differentiable on a domain A, with v satisfying v(a) = v(b) = 0. Then the first variation δJ[y(x)] is defined by

δJ[y(x)]=limϵ0J[y(x)+δy(x)]J[y(x)]ϵ=[ϵJ[y(x)+δy(x)]]ϵ=0=[ϵJ[y(x)+ϵv(x)]]ϵ=0 (B.6)

whenever the limit exists.

As in (B.4), this can be thought of as the derivative of J[y(x)] “in the direction of v(x)”.

In practice, the process of calculating δJ begins in one of two ways. In the first, one is given a family of varied curves parameterized by some parameter ϵ. In this case (B.6) is calculated by Taylor expanding these varied curves in powers of ϵ. For example, for the functional (B.5) let us consider the effect of the variations e(1+ϵ)x of the function ex on I[ex]. Here y(x) + δy(x) = e(1+ϵ)x, and to calculate (B.6) we Taylor expand the varied curves:

e(1+ϵ)x=exeϵx=ex(1+ϵx+ϵ2x22!+).

Then (B.6) gives

δI[ex]=[ϵabe(1+ϵ)xdx]ϵ=0=[ϵabex(1+ϵx+ϵ2x22!+)dx]ϵ=0=abxexdx.

To interpret this last result, we note that as in (B.2) we may write (Theorem 1.5 Sagan, 1992)

ΔJ[y(x)]=J[y(x)+δy(x)]J[y(x)]ϵδJ[y(x)] (B.7)

when ϵ is small. For example, if we choose a = 0 and b = 1 in the ex example and consider the variation to be y(x) + δy(x) = e(1.01)x, then

ΔI[ex]=I[e(1.01)x]I[ex](0.01)01xexdx=0.01.

This compares well with the actual increment I[e(1.01)x] − I[ex] = 01004.

In the second approach to calculating the first variation δJ one is given the variation δy. For example, for the functional (B.5) we have δy = ϵv(x)

δI[y(x)]=limϵ0I[y(x)+δy(x)]I[y(x)]ϵ=limϵ0ab(y(x)+ϵv(x))dxaby(x)dxϵ=abv(x)dx.

Using (B.7), we then have

ΔI[y(x)]ϵabv(x)dx,

which tells us that for small enough ϵ, changing the integrand y(x) to y(x) + ϵv(x) changes the net signed area by approximately ϵ multiplied by the net signed area of v(x), a conclusion made even more clear by drawing a few example graphs.

The preceding development has focused on the analogue of the first derivative in the calculus of variations. But as in the case with functions, where higher-order derivatives can be defined, we can also define higher-order variations of functionals.

Definition 3. Let y(x; ϵ) be a family of smooth varied curves for the function y(x) such that for all ϵ we have y(a; ϵ) = y(a) and y(b; ϵ) = y(b). Define δy(x) = y(x; ϵ) − y(x) and let

δy(x)=ϵv(x)+ϵ2w1(x)++ϵnwn+1(x)+

be the Taylor expansion in powers of ϵ of δy(x). Then the nth variation δnJ[y(x)] is defined by

δnJ[y(x)]=[nϵnJ[y(x)+δy(x)]]ϵ=0

whenever the derivative exists.

We note that in the case of n = 1 this definition reduces to definition (B.6).

For instance, continuing with the ex example, we have

δ2I[ex]=[2ϵ2abex(1+ϵx+ϵ2x22!+)dx]ϵ=0=abx2exdx.

We can then extend (B.7) to second order in ϵ (Theorem 1.8.1 Sagan, 1992):

J[y(x)+δy(x)]J[y(x)]ϵδJ[y(x)]+ϵ22δ2J[y(x)] (B.8)

when ϵ is small. For example, choosing a = 0 and b = 1 in the ex example and again considering the variation to be y(x) + δy(x) = e(1.01)x, then

I[e(1.01)x]I[ex](0.01)01xexdx+(0.01)2201x2exdx=0.0100359,

which is an even better approximation to the actual increment I[e(1.01)x ] − I[ex] = 0.01004.

Finally, motivated by (B.3), we make the following definition.

Definition 4. The relative change of a functional J[y(x)] is defined by

δJ[y(x)]J[y(x)]

everywhere J[y(x)] is nonzero.

Appendix C. Proofs of propositions

Proof of Proposition 1.

Let δS(x) = ϵv(x) be a variation of S(x), i.e. v(x) is a smooth function that vanishes at zero and as x → ∞.

  • 1

    To show: δHH=δeeδe0e0.

Proof. We begin with the observation that H[S + δS] = e[S + δS]/e0 [S + δS] can be written as

0=H[S+δS]e0[S+δS]e[S+δS]=H[S+ϵv]e0[S+ϵv]e[S+ϵv].

Now, taking the derivative with respect to ϵ yields

Hϵ[S+ϵv]e0[S+ϵv]+H[S+ϵv]e0ϵ[S+ϵv]eϵ[S+ϵv]=0, (C.1)

Setting ϵ = 0 now gives

δH[S]e0[S]+H[S]δe0[S]δe[S]=0. (C.2)

Solving for δH[S] yields

δH=δeHδe0e0δHH=e0e(δee0ee0δe0e0)=δeeδe0e0.

We now show that δe and δe0 are given by (2.6). By (B.6) we have

eϵ[S(x)+ϵv(x)]=ϵ[0(S(x)+ϵv(x))ln(S(x)+ϵv(x))dx]=0v(x)[ln(S(x)+ϵv(x))+1]dx.

Evaluating this expression at ϵ = 0 yields

δe[S(x)]=0v(x)[ln(S(x))+1]dx=0v(x)dx0ln(S(x))v(x)dx,

which is the first equation in (2.6). Lastly,

e0ϵ[S(x)+ϵv(x)]=ϵ[0(S(x)+ϵv(x))dx]=0v(x)dx.

Thus,

δe0[S(x)]=0v(x)dx,

reproducing the second equation in (2.6). □

  • 2
    To show: The second variation
    δ2H=1e0[2{δe0δH+(0w(x)dx)(H1)0w(x)ln(S(x))dx}0(v(x))2S(x)dx].

Proof. For ease of writing, let S(x) + δS(x) = S(x; ϵ) be a family of varied curves, where S(x; 0) = S(x), S(0; ϵ) = 0, and S(x; ϵ) → 0 as x → ∞. Expand S(x; ϵ) in an ϵ series:

S(x)+δS(x)=S(x)+ϵv(x)+ϵ2w(x)+.

Now, differentiate (C.1) with respect to ϵ twice to arrive at

H[S(x;ϵ)]e0[S(x;ϵ)]+2H[S(x;ϵ)]e0[S(x;ϵ)]+H[S(x;ϵ)]e0[S(x;ϵ)](e)[S(x;ϵ)]=0,

where the primes denote derivatives with respect to ϵ. Setting ϵ = 0 then yields

H[S(x;0)]e0[S(x;0)]+2H[S(x;0)]e0[S(x;0)]+H[S(x;ϵ)]e0[S(x;0)](e)[S(x;0)]=0. (C.3)

To calculate the quantities in this equation, we begin with e0[S(x;ϵ)]=0S(x;ϵ)dx. Then

e0[S(x;0)]=0v(x)dx=δe0[S(x)],e0[S(x;0)]=20w(x)dx. (C.4)

Similarly,

e[S(x;ϵ)]=0S(x;ϵ)ln(S(x;ϵ))dx(e)[S(x;0)]=0S(x;0)[ln(S(x;0))+1]dx(e)[S(x;0)]=0(S(x;0)(ln(S(x;0))+1)+(S(x;0))2S(x;0))dx.

Therefore,

(e)[S(x;0)]=20w(x)(ln(S(x))+1)dx0(v(x))2S(x)dx. (C.5)

Finally, substituting (C.4)(C.5) into (C.3) gives

(δ2H)e0+2(δH)(δe0)+(2H)(0w(x)dx)+20w(x)(ln(S(x))+1)dx+0(v(x))2S(x)dx=0.

Solving for δ2H reproduces (2.8). □

Proof of Proposition 2.

Proof. Let δμ(s) = ϵv(s) be a variation of the mortality function μ(s), and suppose that v(0) = 0 and v(s) → 0 as s → ∞. Then

e0[μ+δμ]=0e0x(μ(s)+ϵv(s))dsdx=0e0xμ(s)dseϵ0xv(s)dsdx=0e0xμ(s)ds(1ϵ(0xv(s)ds)+h.p.e.)dx=e0[μ]ϵ[0S[μ(s)](0xv(s)ds)dx]+h.p.e.,

where the abbreviation h.p.e. stands for “higher powers in epsilon”. Therefore,

δe0[μ(s)]=limϵ0e0[μ+δμ]e0[μ]ϵ=0S[μ(s)](0xv(s)ds)dx. (C.6)

Now, since S[v(s)]=e0xv(s)ds, then ln(S[v(s)])=0xv(s)ds. Therefore, (C.6) can be written as in (2.12). Similarly, we have that

e[μ+δμ]=0e0x(μ(s)+ϵv(s))ds×[0x(μ(s)+ϵv(s))ds]dx=0e0xμ(s)ds(1ϵ(0xv(s)ds)+h.p.e)×(0xμ(s)ds+ϵ0xv(s)ds)dx=e[μ]ϵ[0S[μ(s)](0xv(s)ds)×((0xμ(s)ds)1)dx]+h.p.e.

It follows that

δe[μ]=limϵ0e[μ+δμ]e[μ]ϵ=0S[μ(s)](0xv(s)ds)((0xμ(s)ds)1)dx=0S[μ(s)](ln(S[v(s)]))(ln(S[μ(s)])1)dx=0S[μ(s)]ln(S[v(s)])(ln(S[μ(s)])+1)dx=0S[μ(s)]ln(S[v(s)])dx0S[μ(s)]ln(S[v(s)])ln(S[μ(s)])dx=δe0[μ(s)]0S[μ(s)]ln(S[μ(s)])ln(S[v(s)])dx,

which reproduces (2.11). □

Appendix D. More applications of Propositions 1 and 2

In Appendix D.1 we reproduce the results of constant mortality case of Appendix A.3 as a basic illustration and check of Proposition 1. In Appendix D.2 we illustrate a particular case assuming a Gompertz force of mortality, i.e. μ(x) = a ebx and S(x)=ea/be(a/b)ebx, and evaluate the change in H when there is a proportional change in S(x) at all ages (similar to that shown by Keyfitz (1977)).

D.1. Reproducing the constant mortality case results

Let μ be a positive real number and S(x) = eμx, and consider a variation δS that produces the new survival curve S + δS = e−(μ+ϵ)x, where ϵ > 0. To illustrate the results of Proposition 1, we first Taylor expand S + δS in powers of ϵ:

S+δS=e(μ+ϵ)x=eμxeϵx=eμx(1ϵx+(ϵx)22!+)=S+eμx(ϵx+(ϵx)22!+).

From the last equation we see that

δS=ϵ(xeμx)+ϵ2(x2eμx/2)+.

Thus, comparing with the expansion δS(x) = ϵv(x) + ϵ2w(x) we see that v(x) = −xeμx and w(x) = x2eμx/2. From (2.6) we then have

δe[S(x)]=0[1μx](xeμx)dx=1μ2,δe0[S(x)]=0(xeμx)dx=1μ2. (D.1)

Now, since

e[eμx]=0(μx)eμxdx=1μ,e0[eμx]=0eμxdx=1μ,

we see that δe/e = −1/μ = δe0/e0. Therefore, according to (2.5) we have that δH = 0. This suggests that, for example, the survival functions S1(x) = e−2x and S2(x) = e2.01x both have the same H value. This is confirmed by the fact that H = 1 for the constant mortality case (c.f. Appendix A.3).

To illustrate (2.8) we make use of the following facts:

0x2eμxdx=2μ3,0x2eμx(μx)dx=6μ3.

Using these, along with the fact that H[S(x)] = 1, Eq. (2.8) gives

δ2H[S(x)]=μ[2μ3+{0+2μ3(1+1)6μ3}]=0.

Therefore, to second order in ϵ we have, according to (2.9),

H[S+δS]1+0ϵ+0ϵ2=1.

These calculations are again in accordance with our results from the constant mortality example of Appendix A.3.

To illustrate Proposition 2, note that the mortality function here is μ(s) = μ, and that the variation δμ(s) = ϵ. Thus, v(s) = 1 and (2.12) gives8

δe0[μ(s)]=0eμxln(e0x1ds)dx=0(xeμx)dx,

matching (D.1). Similarly, (2.11) gives

δe[μ(s)]=0(xeμx)dx0eμx(μx)(x)dx,

again matching (D.1). Since e, e0, δe, δe0 all have the same values as before, (2.10) leads to the same δH = 0 conclusion.

D.2. Proportional changes in S and their effect on H

Suppose that we consider a small proportional increase in S(x) to kS(x), where k > 1 is close to one. We can then write

kS(x)=(1+k1)S(x)=S(x)+(k1)S(x)=S(x)+δS(x),

where δS(x) = ϵS(x), with ϵ = k − 1 > 0 but close to zero. Note that v(x) = S(x) and w(x) = 0. From (2.6) we then have

δe[S(x)]=0[1+ln(S(x))]S(x)dx,δe0[S(x)]=0S(x)dx. (D.2)

Notice that the relative change in life expectancy δe0/e0 = 1, whereas the relative change in the average years of future life that are lost by observed deaths is

δe[S(x)]e[S(x)]=0[1+ln(S(x))]S(x)dx0S(x)ln(S(x))dx=0S(x)dx+0S(x)ln(S(x))dx0S(x)ln(S(x))dx=e0e+1,

So that (2.5) gives

δH[S(x)]H[S(x)]=(e0e+1)1=e0e=1H[S(x)]δH[S(x)]=1. (D.3)

Thus, we conclude that since δH[S(x)] < 0 the survival curves S(x) must be changing shape toward increased survivorship, which is true since we have assumed that k > 1.

For the second variation, using (D.2) and (D.3) in (2.8) yields

δ2H[S(x)]=[1e00(S(x))2S(x)dt+2{(1)(1)+0+0}]=[1e0e02]=1.

From (2.9) it follows that

H[kS(x)]H[S(x)]+ϵδH[S(x)]+ϵ22δ2H[S(x)]=H[S(x)]+(k1)(1)+(k1)22(1)=H[S(x)]+(1k)+(k1)22. (D.4)

We note that analogous calculations can be carried out for the k < 1 case.

Let us now compare these approximations to the exact results one obtains in the Gompertz case. Let μ(x) be the force of mortality at age x and assume it follows a Gompertz curve, i.e. μ(x)= a ebx. It follows that the corresponding survival function at age x is given by S(x)=Ce(a/b)ebx, where C=ea/b, and that

H[S(x)]=ab0e(a/b)ebxebxdx0e(a/b)ebxdxln(C). (D.5)

To calculate H[kS(x)] we first note that kS(x)=kCe(a/b)ebx, so that we can simply replace C by kC in (D.5). Therefore,

H[kS(x)]=ab0e(a/b)ebxebxdx0e(a/b)ebxdxln(kC)=ab0e(a/b)ebxebxdx0e(a/b)ebxdxln(k)ln(C)=H[S(x)]ln(k). (D.6)

Since we have assumed that k > 1 but close to one, writing ln k = ln (1 + (k − 1)) we can then Taylor expand ln(1 + (k − 1)) to express (D.6) as

H[kS(x)]=H[S(x)]((k1)(k1)22+)=H[S(x)]+(1k)+(k1)22. (D.7)

From this we see that the second-order approximation (D.4) matches the actual result (D.7) exactly (to second order).

Appendix E. Early and late deaths

E.1. Reworking of Proposition 1

Given a threshold age a, we can break up the first variations of e0[S(x)] and e[S(x)] as follows:

δe0[S(x)]=0av(x)dx+av(x)dx=:δe0[S(x|x<a)]+δe0[S(x|xa)], (E.1)
δe[S(x)]=(δe0[S(x|x<a)]+δe0[S(x|xa)])(0aln(S(x))v(x)dx+aln(S(x))v(x)dx)={δe0[S(x|x<a)]0aln(S(x))v(x)dx}+{δe0[S(x|xa)]aln(S(x))v(x)dx}=:δe[S(x|x<a)]+δe[S(x|xa)], (E.2)

where v(x) is a smooth function that vanishes at zero and as x → ∞.

Thus, Proposition 1 can be written as:

δH[S(x)]H[S(x)]={δe[S(x|x<a)]e[S(x)]+δe0[S(x|x<a)]e0[S(x)]}+{δe[S(x|xa)]e[S(x)]+δe0[S(x|xa)]e0[S(x)]}. (E.3)

E.2. Reworking of Proposition 2

Similarly, given a threshold age a, we can break up the first variations of e[μ(s)] and e0[μ(s)] as follows:

δe0[μ(s)]=0aSx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[v(s)])dx+aSx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[v(s)])dx=:δe0[μ(s|x<a)]+δe0[μ(s|xa)], (E.4)
δe[μ(s)]=(δe0[μ(s|x<a)]+δe0[μ(s|xa)])0aSx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[μ(s)])ln(Sx[v(s)])dxaSx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[μ(s)])ln(Sx[v(s)])dx=(δe0[μ(s|x<a)]0aSx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[μ(s)])ln(Sx[v(s)])dx)+(δe0[μ(s|xa)]aSx[μ(s)]ln(Sx[μ(s)])ln(Sx[v(s)])dx)=:δe[μ(s|x<a)]+δe[μ(s|xa)], (E.5)

where Sx[v(s)]=e0xv(s)ds.

Thus, Proposition 2 can be written as:

δH[μ(s)]H[μ(s)]={δe[μ(s|x<a)]e[μ(s)]+δe0[μ(s|x<a)]e0[μ(s)]}+{δe[μ(s|xa)]e[μ(s)]+δe0[μ(s|xa)]e0[μ(s)]}. (E.6)

Appendix F. Discrete approximations

F.1. Life table notation

One can use the following approximation formulas to estimate e(0), e(0), and H at time t (life table notation):

e(0,t)=0S(a,t)da1l(0,t)x=0ωL(x,t) (F.1)
e(0,t)=0S(a,t)ln(S(a,t))da1l(0,t)y=0ω1d(y,t)[e(y,t)+e(y+1,t)2] (F.2)
H(t)=e(0,t)e(0,t)

where l(0, t), L(x, t), d(x, t), and e(x, t) correspond to the following life table values at age x, time t: radix at age 0, person-years lived, deaths, and life expectancy.

F.2. Discrete version of Proposition 1

One can use the following approximation formulas to estimate the first variations shown in Proposition 1:

δe0[S(x)]1l(0)x=0ω[L(x,t2)L(x,t1)]δe[S(x)]=[e(0,t1)e(0,t2)][e(0,t1)e,*(0,t2)]

where the approximation formulas for e(0, t) and e(0, t) are shown in Eqs. (F.1) and (F.2), respectively. The estimation of e†,*(0, t2) can be carried out using Eq. (F.2) with d(y) replaced by d*(y); the latter corresponds to counterfactual life table deaths at age y estimated with mortality at time t1 and life table survivors at time t2.

To derive the two formulas above, let δS(x) = S(x, t2) − S(x, t1) be a variation of the survival function between times t1 and t2. Thus, v(x) = S(x, t2) − S(x, t1). The first variation of e0 is then given by:

δe0[S(x)]=0v(x)dx=0[S(x,t2)S(x,t1)]dx=0S(x,t2)0S(x,t1)dx=e(0,t2)e(0,t1)
δe0[S(x)]1l(0)x=0[L(x,t2)L(x,t1)],

where l(0, t1) = l(0, t2) = l(0).

The first variation of e is given by:

δe[S(x)]=[0v(x)dx+0ln(S(x,t1))v(x)dx]=[δe0[S(x)]+0ln(S(x,t1))S(x,t2)dx0ln(S(x,t1))S(x,t1)dx]=[δe0[S(x)]e,*(0,t2)+e(0,t1)]δe[S(x)]=[e(0,t1)e(0,t2)][e(0,t1)e,*(0,t2)] (F.3)

where

e,*(0,t2)=0ln(S(a,t1))S(a,t2)da=00aμ(x,t1)S(a,t2)dxda=0μ(x,t1)xS(a,t2)dadx=0μ(x,t1)l(x,t2)e(x,t2)dxe,*(0,t2)=0d*(x)e(x,t2)dx

d*(x) represents counterfactual life table deaths at age x estimated with mortality at time t1 and life table survivors at time t2. From Eq. (F.2), the discrete approximation of the above equation is given by:

e,*(0,t2)1l(0)y=0ω1d*(y)[e(y,t2)+e(y+1,t2)2], (F.4)

where l(0, t1) = l(0, t2) = l(0). Thus, a discrete approximation of δe[S(x)] (Eq. (F.3)) uses formulas (F.1), (F.2) and (F.4) corresponding to e(0, t), e(0, t) and e†,*(0, t), respectively.

The preceding discretizations imply that (2.5) can be discretized as

δH[S(x,t1)]H[S(x,t1)](δe[S(x)]e(0,t1)δe0[S(x)]e(0,t1))H[S(x,t1)](e(0,t1)e(0,t2)(e(0,t1)e,*(0,t2))e(0,t1)(e(0,t2)e(0,t1))e(0,t1))=H[S(x,t1)](e(0,t1)e(0,t2)+e,*(0,t2)e(0,t1)e(0,t2)e(0,t1))=(e(0,t1)e(0,t1))(e(0,t1)e(0,t2)+e,*(0,t2)e(0,t1)e(0,t2)e(0,t1)). (F.5)

Discretization of equations relating H with early and late deaths.

We use a similar discretization of Eqs. (3.1)(3.5) as shown above, except that now we have intervals for age (i.e., [0, a] or [a, ∞)).

Using these discretizations in practice requires numerical integration for some calculations (e.g., (2.4)). To reduce the calculation errors we use more advanced techniques from the theory of numerical integration. In particular, we fitted a third degree monotone cubic spline using Hyman filtering (Hyman, 1983) to the quinquennial S(x) column of the life table to produce single-year survival probabilities. We then estimated the area under this curve using trapezoids, which simplifies the numerical integration because the length of the intervals is one unit long.

Footnotes

1

For example, μ(x; ϵ) = (1 + ϵ)μ(x), the perturbation to the mortality function discussed in Section 2.1, is a family of smooth varied curves for μ(x).

2

One may need to bound the estimate of the mode, e.g. for ages >10, to avoid a bi-modal distribution due to high number of deaths in childhood. In doing so one would also need to bound the entropy accordingly.

3

This and all subsequent analyses were performed using the R software package (R Core Team, 2014).

4

The discrete approximations (F.1) and (F.2) lead to percentage errors in H as large as 4.5% in some cases (Ecuador between 1986 and 1995). We therefore employed the aforementioned advanced numerical methods for all subsequent analyses.

5

The corresponding survivorship curves are referred to as Type II curves (Demetrius, 1978), and describe a population in which no age group is favored at death (i.e. mortality is independent of age).

6

The corresponding survivorship curves are referred to as Type I curves (Demetrius, 1978), and describe a population in which all individuals reach the maximum possible lifespan of the species.

7

Wenote that 0 and 1 are in general the extrema of H, since 0 ≤ S(x) ≤ 1 implies that H ≥ 0, and – assuming the mean age of the stationary population is less than the value of the life expectancy – H ≤ 1 was shown true in (Demetrius, 1979). (If this assumption is not the case and the mean is μ, then H ≤ 1 + ln(μ/e0) (Goldman and Lord, 1986, footnote 1).)

8

We note that although v(s) = 1 does not vanish at zero and as s → ∞, one can easily replace it by a continuous function that does without affecting the results of the calculations.

References

  1. Arthur WB, 1984. The analysis of linkages in demographic theory. Demography 21, 109–127. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  2. Beltrán-Sánchez H, Soneji S, 2011. A unifying framework for assessing changes in life expectancy associated with changes in mortality: The case of violent deaths. Theor. Popul. Biol 80, 38–48. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  3. Demetrius L, 1974. Demographic paramaters and natural selection. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 71, 4645–4647. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  4. Demetrius L, 1975. Natural selection and age-structured populations. Genetics 79, 535–544. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  5. Demetrius L, 1976. Measures of variability in age-structured populations. J. Theoret. Biol 63, 397–404. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  6. Demetrius L, 1978. Adaptive value, entropy and survivorship curves. Nature 275, 213–214. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  7. Demetrius L, 1979. Relations between demographic parameters. Demography 16, 329–338. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  8. Engelman M, Caswell H, Agree E, 2014. Why do lifespan variability trends for the young and old diverge? A perturbation analysis. Demogr. Res 30, 1367–1396. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  9. Goldman N, Lord G, 1986. A new look at entropy and the life table. Demography 23, 275–282. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  10. Hyman J, 1983. Accurate monotonicity preserving cubic interpolation. SIAMJ. Sci. Stat. Comput 4, 645–654. [Google Scholar]
  11. Keyfitz N, 1977. What difference would it make if cancer were eradicated? An examination of the taeuber paradox. Demography 14,411–418. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  12. Keyfitz N, Caswell H, 2005. Applied Mathematical Demography. Springer, New York, USA. [Google Scholar]
  13. Mitra S, 1978. A short note on the taeuber paradox. Demography 15, 621–623. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  14. Mitra S, 1979. The effects of extra chances to live on life table functions. Theor. Popul. Biol 16, 315–322. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  15. Nagnur D, 1986. Rectangularization of the survival curve and entropy: The canadian experience, 1921–1981. Stud. Popul 13, 83–102. [Google Scholar]
  16. Palloni A, Pinto G, 2011. Adult mortality in Latin America and the Caribbean In: Rogers R, Crimmins EM (Eds.), International Handbook of Adult Mortality.Springer, pp. 101–132 (Chapter 21). [Google Scholar]
  17. Palloni A, Pinto-Aguirre G, Beltrán-Sánchez H, 2014. Latin American Mortality Database. Available: http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/cdha/latinmortality, [accessed October 2014].
  18. Palloni A, Wyrick R, 1981. Mortality decline in Latin-America—changes in the structure of causes of death, 1950–1975. Soc. Biol 28, 187–216. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  19. Preston S, 1982. Relations between individual life cycle and population characteristics. Am. Sociol. Rev 47, 253–264. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  20. Preston SH, Heuveline P, Guillot M, 2000. Demography: Measuring and Modeling Population Processes. Blackwell, Oxford, UK. [Google Scholar]
  21. R Core Team, 2014. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. Available: http://www.R-project.org/, [accesed October 2014].
  22. Sagan H, 1992. Introduction to the Calculus of Variations. Dover, Mineola, USA. [Google Scholar]
  23. Shkolnikov V, Andreev E, Zhang Z, Oeppen J, Vaupel JW, 2011. Losses of expected lifetime in the united states and other developed countries: Methods and empirical analyses. Demography 48, 211–239. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  24. Tuljapurkar SD, 1982. Why use population entropy? It determines the rate of convergence. J. Math. Biol 13, 325–337. [Google Scholar]
  25. Tuljapurkar SD, 1993. Entropy and convergence in dynamics and demography. J. Math. Biol 31, 253–271. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  26. United Nations, 2012. Demographic Yearbook. Tech. Rep. United Nations, Statistical Office, New York, United States. [Google Scholar]
  27. Vaupel JW, 1986. How change in age-specific mortality affects life expectancy. Popul. Stud 40, 147–157. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  28. Vaupel JW, Canudas Romo V, 2003. Decomposing change in life expectancy: A bouquet of formulas in honor of Nathan Keyfitz’s 90th birthday. Demography 40, 201–216. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  29. Vaupel JW, Zhang Z, van Raalte A, 2011. Life expectancy and disparity: an international comparison of life table data. BMJ Open 1, e000128. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  30. Wilmoth J, Horiuchi S, 1999. Rectangularization revisited: Variability of age at death within human populations. Demography 36, 475–495. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  31. Zhang Z, Vaupel JW, 2008. The Threshold between Compression and Expansion of Mortality. Paper presented at the Population Association of America Annual Meeting. [Google Scholar]
  32. Zhang Z, 2009. The age separating early deaths from late deaths. Demogr. Res 20, 721–730. [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES