Skip to main content
Wiley Open Access Collection logoLink to Wiley Open Access Collection
. 2018 Oct 10;28(1):101–122. doi: 10.1002/hec.3832

Pharmaceutical expenditure and gross domestic product: Evidence of simultaneous effects using a two‐step instrumental variables strategy

Mujaheed Shaikh 2,, Afschin Gandjour 1
PMCID: PMC6585646  PMID: 30306669

Abstract

This paper estimates the income elasticity of government pharmaceutical spending and assesses the simultaneous effect of such spending on gross domestic product (GDP). Using a panel dataset for 136 countries from 1995 to 2006, we employ a two‐step instrumental variable procedure where we first estimate the effect of GDP on public pharmaceutical expenditure using tourist receipts as an instrument for GDP. In the second step, we construct an adjusted pharmaceutical expenditure series where the response of public pharmaceutical expenditure to GDP is partialled out and use this endogeneity adjusted series as an instrument for pharmaceutical expenditure. Our estimations show that GDP has a strong positive impact on pharmaceutical spending with elasticity in excess of unity in countries with low spending on pharmaceuticals and countries with large economic freedom. In the second step, we find that when the quantitatively large reverse effect of GDP is accounted for, public pharmaceutical spending has a negative effect on GDP per capita particularly in countries with limited economic freedom.

Keywords: GDP per capita, income elasticity, instrumental variables, public pharmaceutical expenditure

1. INTRODUCTION

This paper confronts two questions related to medical spending. First, the paper estimates the income elasticity of government pharmaceutical spending, and second, it assesses the simultaneous effect of such spending on income itself. Both questions are important from a health economics and a public spending perspective. The rise in health expenditures in the latter half of the 20th century has increased fiscal constraints for governments worldwide. Policy makers therefore are keen on understanding the determinants of health expenditure to identify the right policy levers that can address budgetary concerns. Concurrently, the understanding of the impact of such spending on economic growth itself is limited. The effect of government spending on economic growth has been a central issue in the growth literature for more than 30 years (Aschauer, 1989; Barro, 1990; Landau, 1983). It is widely recognized that increasing or decreasing government expenditures should be informed on the basis of the contribution of each spending component to economic growth (Devarajan, Swaroop, & Zou, 1996).

There is a voluminous literature that tackles both these issues, yet these questions remain open for further research for several reasons. First, findings from previous literature remain inconclusive concerning the magnitude of the income elasticity of health spending. Some studies argue that health expenditure is a luxury good (Kleiman, 1974; Leu, 1986; Newhouse, 1977) whereas others find it to be a necessity good (Baltagi & Moscone, 2010; Di Matteo, 2003; Farag et al., 2012; Moscone & Tosetti, 2010; Parkin, McGuire, & Yule, 1987). Though findings from past literature thus disagree with respect to the magnitude of the relationship, they concur concerning the sign of the coefficients in that national income relates positively with health expenditure (see, among others, Barros, 1998; Hauck & Zhang, 2016; Hitiris & Posnett, 1992; Getzen, 2000; Xu, Saksena, & Holly, 2011).

The lack of consensus in the elasticities can be attributed to both theoretical and methodological differences. On the theoretical front, micro econometric analyses of health expenditures rely on standard demand theory and find elasticities less than unity. Macro level analyses use models similar in theory to those used by micro studies but find elasticities greater than unity (Gerdtham & Jönsson, 2000). Applying standard demand theory to aggregated data may therefore not be suitable because a nation's income constraint may be more binding than that of an individual, particularly in countries where the state is largely responsible for health care costs (Gerdtham & Jönsson, 2000; Moscone & Tosetti, 2010). On the methodological front, the incongruence in the estimates from different studies arises due to functional form differences in the econometric models, use of different conversion metrics for expenditure and income data, and unaccounted heterogeneity (see,e.g., Getzen, 2000; Gerdtham & Jönsson, 1991; Gerdtham & Jönsson, 1992; Parkin et al., 1987). Further, first generation studies largely relied on cross sections of countries whereas second‐generation studies employed more rigorous econometric methods such as panel data analyses, thereby controlling for several sources of endogeneity (see Gerdtham & Jönsson, 2000, for a detailed overview of these). Despite the research efforts, it is therefore still an open debate whether health care is a luxury good or a necessity good. With regard to The Organisation for Economic Co‐operation and Development (OECD) countries, some papers report that income elasticity is larger than unity, that is, health care is a luxury good (e.g., Gerdtham & Löthgren, 2002; Okunade & Murthy, 2002), whereas others state that the elasticity is less than unity, that is, health care is a necessity good (e.g., Baltagi & Moscone, 2010; Bilgel & Tran, 2013; Dreger & Reimers, 2005; Freeman, 2003). In studies on developing countries, the results also diverge. For example, Bhat and Jain (2004), Jaunky and Khadaroo (2008), and Mehrara and Musai (2011) report income elasticities larger than one, whereas Sahn (1992) among others provides evidence that the income elasticity is less than one. Owing to the differential findings, the income elasticity of health spending remains an open question.

Moreover, past literature has largely focused on total health expenditures, ignoring the different components it comprises. It seems plausible to presume that the elasticity of health spending will depend on the very component of spending being considered. As such, the source of variation in health expenditure matters for the income elasticity of expenditures (Acemoglu, Finkelstein, & Notowidigdo, 2013). To the best of our knowledge, there is no country level analysis that explores the income elasticity of public pharmaceutical expenditures in both high‐ and low‐income countries. This seems surprising because there are several reasons why this type of spending should be of particular interest. First, it forms a large part of total health expenditure and has increased by almost 50% since 2000 (OECD, 2011), which has exposed it to several regulations and cost containment measures. Second, policy makers are endorsing the view that savings can be achieved by regulating pharmaceutical markets and reducing costs without affecting the quality of care (Carone, Schwierz, & Xavier, 2012). Finally, income elasticity of pharmaceutical spending has important implications in terms of pharmaceutical policy itself.

With respect to the second question of our paper, the effect of public pharmaceutical spending on economic growth, the question is of interest from different perspectives just as the answer remains ambiguous from these perspectives. From a health economics perspective, inasmuch as spending on health leads to improved health outcomes, a positive relationship between health spending and economic growth can be expected. Although some papers find a positive link between health and economic growth (Bloom, Canning, & Sevilla, 2004), others find no effect of health on growth (Acemoglu & Johnson, 2007; Ashraf, Lester, & Weil, 2008; Hansen & Lønstrup, 2015). The effect of health spending therefore remains questionable. From a pure public spending perspective, findings from the literature also add to the debatable effects of health spending on gross domestic product (GDP). Some of the previous literature finds a negative relationship between excessive public spending and GDP (Devarajan et al., 1996; Miller & Russek, 1997) whereas others consider health spending a “productive” form of public expenditure that affects growth positively (Bleaney, Gemmell, & Kneller, 2001; Glomm & Ravikumar, 1997).

Therefore, in this paper, we assess the effect of income measured in GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita and the reverse effect using a sample of 136 countries from 1995 to 2006. We use a relatively recent two‐step instrumental variable (IV) procedure (from the aid effectiveness literature; see Brückner, 2011) to assess the causal effect of GDP on pharmaceutical spending in the first step and then assess the effect of pharmaceutical spending on GDP in the second step after accounting for the simultaneous effect of GDP from the first step. We find that the income elasticity of public pharmaceutical expenditure is greater than unity in the full sample, and that there is a negative effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP per capita. However, important heterogeneous patterns exist. GDP per capita has a statistically significant positive effect on pharmaceutical spending only for high‐income countries, and pharmaceutical spending has a statistically significant negative effect only for low‐income countries. Quantile regressions show that the income elasticity of pharmaceutical spending varies across the distribution of pharmaceutical spending. Similarly, the negative effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP is statistically significant only for the middle (25th, 50th, and 75th) quantiles of income. Finally, based on the index of Economic Freedom of the World (EFW) by the Fraser Institute, we find that GDP per capita does not have an effect on pharmaceutical expenditure in countries that are classified as “not free.” However, pharmaceutical spending has a statistically significant negative effect on GDP per capita in these countries.

Our paper contributes at several levels. First, it contributes directly to the literature that assesses the effect of public spending on economic growth. Although there is some literature on the effect of total health expenditure, we found no paper specifically analyzing public spending on pharmaceuticals. This paper attempts to fill that gap. Second and more importantly, our contribution to the literature in health economics is twofold by—(a) assessing the income elasticity of public pharmaceutical spending across a multitude of countries using IVs, something which past studies have not considered, and (b) assessing the effect of pharmaceutical spending on a nonhealth outcome such as economic growth.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the econometric methodology. Section 3 introduces the data and presents descriptive statistics. In Section 4, we present and discuss our findings along with different sensitivity tests. Section 5 revisits instrument validity, and Section 6 presents results of the heterogeneity analysis. Section 7 discusses the effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP, and Section 8 concludes with policy implications.

2. ECONOMETRIC FRAMEWORK

To assess the effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical spending per capita and the reverse effect within the same econometric framework, we employ a two‐step IV procedure outlined in Brückner (2011) and Moreno‐Serra and Smith (2015). Throughout the remainder of the paper, GDP refers to GDP per capita and pharmaceutical expenditure refers to public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita. In the first step, we assess the causal effect of GDP on pharmaceutical expenditure using an IV approach. In the second step, because we are also interested in estimating the effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP, we generate a new endogeneity adjusted pharmaceutical expenditure series using the residual variation in pharmaceutical expenditure from the first step (where the response of pharmaceutical spending to GDP is partialled out). We describe the two‐step procedure in detail now.

  • Step 1:

    Estimating the causal effect of GDP on pharmaceutical expenditure.

Consider the following regression specification:

Yit=βXit+μWit+αi+γt+εit, (1)

where the subscripts i and t represent country and time, respectively. Yit is the dependent variable (public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita) to be explained by Xit, which is the variable of main interest (GDP per capita). Wit is a vector of time varying controls that is included in the specification along with a full set of country dummies αi that capture the effect of time‐invariant unobservables, and a full set of time dummies γt aimed at capturing common shocks to the countries. εit represents the error term that captures all sources of endogeneity. Although fixed effects may serve as a useful framework to overcome time‐invariant unobserved heterogeneity, two sources of bias remain and therefore Cov(Xit, εit) ≠ 0. First, time varying unobserved variables (omitted variables) are particularly concerning because these have the potential to upward or downward bias the estimates. Second and more crucial is the reverse causal effect of pharmaceutical expenditure itself on GDP, which can lead to an upward bias in Equation (1) if pharmaceutical expenditure is positively related to GDP. In order to overcome these issues and to appropriately estimate the effect of GDP on pharmaceutical expenditure, we need an instrument Zit that is correlated strongly with Xit (i.e., GDP; condition of relevance) and is excluded from the second stage (exclusion restriction).

We use international tourist receipts as an instrument for GDP. International tourist receipts reflect expenditures by international inbound visitors. These are, as defined by the World Tourism Organization, receipts earned by the destination country and cover spending on lodging, food and drinks, fuel, transport, entertainment, shopping, etc. The relationship between tourism and the economy is intuitively straightforward. Tourism directly or indirectly generates an increase in economic activity and results in an increase in the wealth of the residents through, for instance, the services they provide and employment. As such, it should be positively related to the GDP of a country. The tourism led growth hypothesis has been extensively tested and supported in the tourism‐growth literature (Brida & Pulina, 2010; Brida, Risso, Lanzilotta, & Lionetti, 2010; Gunduz & Hatemi‐J, 2005; Lean & Tang, 2009; Risso & Brida, 2009). Although the instrument easily satisfies the relevance criteria as shown by the first stage results and F‐statistics that are well beyond the conventional benchmark of 10, we argue for the validity of the IV in what follows.

Our exclusion restriction requires that Cov(Zit, εitWit, αi, γt) = 0, that is, international tourist receipts be unrelated to public pharmaceutical expenditure except through GDP. We do not fathom why tourist expenditures should be related to public pharmaceutical expenditures or should have a substantial effect on them that should be of concern. However, one possible threat to the instrument is the existence and extent of medical tourism in a country. Even then, we posit that this should at least not be related to “public” pharmaceutical expenditures of a country, because a medical tourist will in general pay for his health care privately. Even if insurance pays for the tourists, it should be reflected in the expenditure of the home country. We also conduct other tests in support of our instrument, which are discussed in Section 6.

  • Step 2:

    Estimating the effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP.

Now consider a reverse econometric framework of Equation (1)

Xit=δYit+μWit+αi+γt+εit. (2)

If GDP has a significant causal effect on pharmaceutical spending estimated from Step 1, then the ordinary least squares estimate of the effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP will suffer from this endogeneity bias, that is, Cov(Yit, εit) ≠ 0. This endogeneity bias however can be taken care of by constructing an adjusted pharmaceutical spending series ( Yit*in Equation ((3)) below) where the response of pharmaceutical spending to GDP is partialled out, that is,

Yit*=YitβXit. (3)

This endogeneity adjusted pharmaceutical expenditure series is free of the simultaneity bias due to GDP by construction. Using the residual variation in expenditure that is not driven by GDP as an instrument for pharmaceutical expenditure in ((1)) adjusts for the reverse causality and provides a consistent estimate. This procedure assumes that the exclusion restriction in ((1)) holds, that is, error terms in ((1)) and ((2)) are uncorrelated. If there are omitted variables that are part of both Equations (1) and 2, then the correlation between the two error terms is likely. However, the procedure will still solve the reverse causality problem and provide consistent estimates (see Brückner, 2011, for details on the procedure). It is important to mention here that there will be correlation between the error terms of the two equations only if there are omitted variables that will affect the within‐country changes in both GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure simultaneously. For this reason, we also include several time varying controls in Wit that may be important and may determine both GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure along with country and time fixed effects that take into account other unobservable heterogeneity related to country specific characteristics and common shocks, respectively.

3. DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

The data we use in this paper come from different sources. The data on pharmaceutical expenditures come from the World Health Organization's World Medicines Situation 2011—Medicine Expenditures' annex. The data are publicly available at http://apps.who.int/medicinedocs/en/d/Js20052en/ [Last accessed 23 February 2018]. The remainder of the data that we use in our analysis comes either from the World Bank Open Data or from the International Monetary Fund's World Economic Outlook database. The dataset we use is an unbalanced panel from 1995 to 2006 for a total of 136 countries. Therefore, we have around 1,389 observations in total with around 10 observations per country on average. The variables of interest are described in detail in the following.

Public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita comes from the World Health Organization (WHO) and is expressed in U.S. dollars (at exchange rate). Comparability of expenditures between countries has been a key issue in past studies. One of the advantages of this dataset is that it is based on a WHO methodology that promotes comparable country data on health system expenditures. Total pharmaceutical expenditures that provide a measure of consumption of pharmaceuticals are disaggregated to reflect public and private expenditures. The data, however, do not distinguish between generic or branded medicines and are regardless of the means or place of distribution. For a detailed overview of the data, we refer readers to the World Medicines Situation 2011 report. In our analysis sample, average annual public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita is $64 with a maximum of $832. For high‐income countries, it is $108 whereas for low‐income countries it is $5. Table 1 shows the summary statistics for all variables for the overall sample and by income group and Table A1 lists the countries used in the analysis. Later on in the analysis, we use the two‐income groups as one way of assessing heterogeneity.

Table 1.

Summary statistics

Variable Full sample Std. dev. Min Max
Obs. Mean
Public pharmaceutical exp. per capita ($US) 1,389 64.12639 106.3668 0.041849 831.9869
GDP per capita ($US) 1,389 13583.8 17704.4 233.1437 103060.5
Remaining health exp. per capita ($US) 1,389 798.5446 937.5408 12.56647 6787.797
Tourist receipts (millions [$US]) 1,389 4.76E + 09 1.25E + 10 400000 1.27E + 11
Life expectancy at birth (years) 1,369 70.14461 7.928318 42.1582 82.32195
Gross savings (% of GDP) 1,175 20.94163 10.89711 −146.164 64.71603
Capital formation (% of GDP) 1,309 24.34591 12.91513 0 219.0694
Total government expenditure (% of GDP) 1,289 31.22698 12.44523 9.328 128.289
Population over 65 years (% of total) 1,365 8.537837 4.868295 2.198119 20.39357
High income
Variable Obs. Mean Std. dev. Min Max
Public pharmaceutical exp. per capita ($US) 797 107.9008 123.2819 1.442033 831.9869
GDP per capita ($US) 797 22307.84 19147.86 981.5044 103060.5
Remaining health exp. per capita ($US) 797 1257.722 1011.799 68.26747 6787.797
Tourist receipts (millions ($US)) 797 7.45E + 09 1.58E + 10 400000 1.27E + 11
Life expectancy at birth (years) 777 74.39379 4.87424 50.35488 82.32195
Gross savings (% of GDP) 709 21.95556 11.25445 −146.164 64.71603
Capital formation (% of GDP) 781 25.44211 15.1979 0.298644 219.0694
Total government expenditure (% of GDP) 751 35.91555 11.07614 11.77 128.289
Population over 65 years (% of total) 773 11.19371 4.541596 2.198119 20.39357
Low income
Variable Obs. Mean Std. dev. Min Max
Public pharmaceutical exp. per capita ($US) 592 5.19356 6.165289 0.041849 42.5232
GDP per capita ($US) 592 1838.763 1229.937 233.1437 5596.732
Remaining health exp. per capita ($US) 592 180.362 135.5475 12.56647 692.0238
Tourist receipts (millions ($US)) 592 1.15E + 09 3.34E + 09 800000 3.39E + 10
Life expectancy at birth (years) 592 64.56755 7.707776 42.1582 76.28613
Gross savings (% of GDP) 466 19.39897 10.14878 −14.3849 54.65947
Capital formation (% of GDP) 528 22.72446 8.229088 0 61.90938
Total government expenditure (% of GDP) 538 24.68214 11.24678 9.328 104.389
Population over 65 years (% of total) 592 5.069947 2.546296 2.420117 16.10646

Note. GDP: gross domestic product.

GDP per capita data are from the World Bank database and expressed in U.S. dollars based on purchasing power parities. GDP per capita is a common measure of economic growth and has been used extensively in the literature (some examples are Barro, 1991; Barro & McCleary, 2003; Bloom et al., 2004; Grossman & Krueger, 1995). The average GDP per capita in our full sample is $13,584; for high‐income countries, it is $22,308, and for low‐income countries, it is $1,839.

The instrument, international tourist receipts, also comes from the World Bank database and is expressed in U.S. dollars. As mentioned earlier, international tourism receipts are expenditures by international inbound visitors and were found to have a strong positive relationship with economic growth by previous literature. As seen in the summary statistics in Table 1, income from tourist receipts is much lower for low‐income countries compared with high‐income countries. One can speculate that the contribution of tourist receipts to GDP may be heterogeneous based on income levels, and hence, the first stage relationship between tourist receipts and GDP may be stronger for high‐income than low‐income group of countries. Figure 1 shows the raw correlation of tourist receipts with GDP per capita per year. It can be seen that the correlation between tourism receipts and GDP per capita is positive across all the years of the analysis. Our first stage F‐statistics shown later in the results section are clearly above the thumb rule of 10 for both the income groups and for the overall sample, thus alleviating the concern of a weak first stage relationship for the low income group.

Figure 1.

Figure 1

Gross domestic product (GDP) and international tourist receipts [Colour figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]

We include a host of other variables in our analysis that could be possible sources of omitted variable bias in the regressions. First, we control for health expenditure other than public pharmaceutical expenditure because it seems likely that this may drive both GDP and public pharmaceutical spending. We also control for life expectancy at birth as a measure of health at the country level. The direction in which health will bias the results is ambiguous a priori because it may be either positively (Bloom et al., 2004; Bloom & Canning, 2000) or negatively (Acemoglu & Johnson, 2007; Ashraf et al., 2008; Hansen & Lønstrup, 2015) related to income. Although we are not interested in the effect of health per se, it is necessary that we show robustness of our results to the inclusion of this variable. We also control for variables that are considered important in the macro literature such as savings rate, demographic structure of the country (population over 65 years of age), gross capital formation, and total government expenditures. Summary statistics for all these variables can also be seen in Table 1. To interpret the estimates as elasticities, we take the log form of both GDP and public pharmaceutical expenditure.

4. MAIN RESULTS

4.1. Effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditure

Table 2 shows the results of the effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita. Column (1) presents fixed effects estimates which show a significant positive relationship between GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure. The magnitude of the coefficient indicates that pharmaceutical expenditure has an income elasticity of less than unity, similar to the findings of some of the previous literature with respect to total health expenditures. However, these estimates cannot be considered as reflecting the causal effect of GDP on pharmaceutical spending because these are riddled with endogeneity problems discussed previously. Although the regression includes country and time fixed effects, thereby accounting for fixed sources of heterogeneity, other issues with regard to time varying variables and reverse causality remain. Hence, these estimates should be taken at face value simply for comparison purposes with the IV estimates.

Table 2.

GDP per capita and public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
FE OLS First stage Reduced form 2SLS
Pharmaceutical expenditure GDP per capita (natural log) Pharmaceutical expenditure Pharmaceutical expenditure
GDP per capita (natural log) 0.709*** (0.215) 1.406** (0.653)
Tourist receipts 0.0935*** (0.0240) 0.131** (0.0514)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,389 1,389 1,389 1,389
R‐squared 0.476 0.563 0.458 0.445
First stage F‐stat 15.12
p value 0.0002
Kleibergen‐Paap LM statistic 9.97
p value 0.0016
Hausman test statistic 25.46 29.60 279.908 279.907
p value 0.0128 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Endogeneity test 2.37
p value 0.1232
No. of countries 136 136 136 136

Note. The DV in columns (1), (3), and (4) is public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita (natural log), whereas in column (2), it is GDP per capita (natural log). Column (1) shows the fixed effects estimate of the effect of GDP per capita (natural log) on the DV. Column (2) shows the first stage relationship between GDP per capita and the instrument tourist receipts (natural log). Column (3) shows the reduced form effect of the instrument on the DV. Column (4) shows the IV estimate of the effect of GDP on the DV. DV: dependent variable; GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable; OLS: ordinary least squares.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

Before presenting the IV estimates, we show the first stage relationship of the instrument and the endogenous variable. Column (2) presents the results of the first stage relationship between tourist receipts and GDP per capita. The regression results confirm the graphical evidence from Figure 1. In line with the “tourism led growth” hypothesis and findings of previous literature (Brida et al., 2010; Brida & Pulina, 2010; Gunduz & Hatemi‐J, 2005; Lean & Tang, 2009; Risso & Brida, 2009), we see that tourism expenditures by international inbound visitors are positively and significantly related to GDP per capita. First stage R‐squared is high, indicating that the instrument fulfills the relevance criteria, and it provides estimates in the direction that one would expect. Next, in column (3), we show the reduced form estimate, that is, the relationship between the instrument and pharmaceutical expenditure. If the reduced form effect is not significantly different from zero, the effect of interest can be presumed to be absent or the instrument too weak (Angrist & Krueger, 2001). Column (3) shows that tourist receipts have a statistically significant positive effect on pharmaceutical expenditure per capita in the reduced form as one would have expected. Finally, in column (4), we present the two‐stage least squares estimate that uses tourist receipts as an instrument for GDP per capita. The first stage F‐statistic is 15.12 (significant at a 1% level), indicating that the instrument is strong enough to predict GDP. The Kleibergen‐Paap LM statistic is also strongly significant. The second stage estimate of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditure is positive and significant at a 1% level, and the magnitude of the coefficient is much larger than the least squares estimate in column (1). The larger coefficient size could be due to a number of reasons. If there are unobserved variables that are negatively (positively) related to GDP and positively (negatively) related to pharmaceutical spending, a downward bias could be observed. For example, disease burden of a country could lead to an underestimate of the true effect of GDP on pharmaceutical expenditure.

Quantitatively, the IV estimate suggests that a 1% increase in GDP per capita increases public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita by 1.4%, implying that public pharmaceutical spending has an elasticity greater than unity and hence is a luxury good. This two‐stage least squares estimate is causal to the extent that the exclusion restriction is satisfied, that is, tourist receipts do not have any systematic relationship with public pharmaceutical expenditure other than through GDP per capita. We further discuss the validity of the instrument later in Section 6.

4.2. Robustness tests

To test the sensitivity of our results, we perform different robustness checks. First, issues around sample size and outliers are dealt with. Second, robustness of the point estimates is tested to the inclusion of other covariates that have the potential to confound the relationship between GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure.

Table 3 provides all these robustness checks. In column (1), we run regressions only on observations that produce a balanced panel from 1995 to 2006. The point estimates of column (1) are similar in magnitude to those of column (4) in Table 2. Next, in column (2), we exclude outliers from the balanced panel, identified using the Hadi (1992) procedure. This leads to the exclusion of 363 observations. The point estimates are still positive and statistically significant at a 10% level; however, the magnitude of the coefficient is now slightly higher. Further, in column (3), we include variables deemed important in both the health and growth literature as controls in our models. Specifically, we control for what we consider demand side variables such as health (proxied by life expectancy at birth) and demographic structure of the population by controlling for population over the age of 65 years. On the supply side, we control for health expenditure per capita excluding pharmaceutical expenditure and total government expenditure as a percentage of GDP. Variables considered important in the macro growth literature such as gross savings (as a percentage of GDP) and gross capital formation (as a percentage of GDP) are also included as further control variables. In column (4), we include these control variables along with the exclusion of identified outliers. In both cases, the coefficients are qualitatively similar. The coefficients are significant at a 5% level in both columns (3) and (4) and the magnitudes well above unity.

Table 3.

Robustness tests

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Balanced panel Outliers (O) Controls (C) O + C C + L
Pharmaceutical expenditure Pharmaceutical expenditure Pharmaceutical expenditure Pharmaceutical expenditure Pharmaceutical expenditure
GDP per capita (natural log) 1.654* (0.989) 2.046* (1.175) 2.566** (1.008) 1.878** (0.853) 1.953** (0.833)
Health expenditure −0.305 (0.317) −0.203 (0.255) −0.273 (0.264)
Life expectancy −0.621 (2.058) −0.299 (1.909) −1.039 (2.074)
Capital formation −0.00186 (0.00686) 0.00195 (0.00864) −0.00254 (0.00398)
Savings rate −0.00931* (0.00477) −0.00757 (0.00502) −0.00699 (0.00489)
Govt. expenditure 0.0120*** (0.00392) 0.0143*** (0.00364) 0.00365 (0.00542)
Population over 65 0.177 (0.574) 0.318 (0.494) −0.136 (0.444)
Lag (1) pharmaceutical exp. 0.573*** (0.0839)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,152 789 1,063 551 970
R‐squared 0.486 0.325 0.468 0.358 0.657
First stage F‐stat 7.42 5.35 11.03 8.57 10.65
p value 0.007 0.023 0.0012 0.004 0.0015
Kleibergen‐Paap LM statistic 6.12 4.60 7.30 5.47 8.22
p value 0.0133 0.032 0.0069 0.0193 0.0041
Hausman test statistic 17.328 204.099 77.100 67.704 181.19
p value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Endogeneity test 1.58 2.52 2.86 2.09 4.21
p value 0.2083 0.1119 0.0905 0.1476 0.0401
Number of countries 96 72 120 73 110

Note. The DV in all columns is public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita. All estimates are IV estimates. Column (1) shows estimates using a balanced sample; column (2) shows estimates after excluding outliers from the balanced panel identified using the Hadi procedure; column (3) shows estimates after inclusion of relevant controls in the full sample; column (4) shows estimates after inclusion of controls and exclusion of outliers from the full sample; column (5) shows estimates from a dynamic model that includes the first lag of pharmaceutical expenditure and thereby accounts for inertia in pharmaceutical spending. Health expenditure here refers to all other health spending excluding public pharmaceutical spending. DV: dependent variable; GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

Finally, an important issue, also raised in prior analyses, relates to health expenditure inertia. It seems reasonable to assume that current pharmaceutical spending depends on past spending behavior. Therefore, it becomes important to assess robustness by accounting for this inertia in pharmaceutical expenditure. We run a dynamic model including the lags of pharmaceutical expenditure in the regressions where we follow prior literature concerning the choice of the number of lags. Okunade and Suraratdecha (2000) consider one lag as appropriate, whereas Moreno‐Serra and Smith (2015) use up to two lags. For brevity, we show the results of the dynamic model in column (5) of Table 3 using only one lag; however, we have also tested robustness using two lags of expenditure. The results are similar.

Overall, the point estimates are always above unity implying that pharmaceutical spending is a luxury good, which is in contrast to findings from some of the recent studies that use panel data and assess the income elasticity of total health expenditures (Baltagi & Moscone, 2010; Di Matteo, 2003; Farag et al., 2012; Freeman, 2003; Sen, 2005). Our results therefore point out that different components of health spending may behave differently and exhibit different elasticity estimates. Therefore, policy makers should consider this heterogeneity before introducing measures targeting health expenditures.

4.3. Effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP per capita

Our second research question aims at assessing the effect of public pharmaceutical spending on economic growth. We present the results here. The analysis so far suggests that public pharmaceutical expenditure is highly endogenous to GDP per capita. To be precise, the IV estimates suggest that per capita GDP has a strong positive effect on public pharmaceutical spending per capita, which is both economically and statistically significant. Therefore, an ordinary least squares estimation of the effect of public pharmaceutical spending on GDP will most likely be upward biased if the reverse positive effect of per capita GDP on pharmaceutical expenditure is not addressed. While controlling for unobserved heterogeneity in the form of fixed effects and several other confounders may solve the problem of omitted variable bias to some extent, the bias due to reverse causality will still persist. We therefore run our regressions as mentioned in Step 2 of the econometric framework (outlined in Section 2) where the residual variation in public pharmaceutical expenditure is used as an instrument for public pharmaceutical expenditure.

Table 4 presents results of the effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita on GDP per capita. Column (1) shows IV estimates using the full sample. We find that public pharmaceutical spending is negatively related to GDP per capita. The estimate is significant at a 5% level and quantitatively means that a 1% increase in public pharmaceutical expenditure is related to a 0.09% decrease in GDP per capita. Although this result seems counter‐intuitive to what most health economics literature would presume, it is in line with some of the other literature that assesses the effect of government spending on economic growth (Devarajan et al., 1996; Miller & Russek, 1997). Next, we assess the robustness of the results in a similar way as we did in Table 3. Analyzing only a balanced sample of countries, excluding outliers using the Hadi (1992) procedure, and including further control variables, we find the same result. In each of these tests, public pharmaceutical expenditure is negatively related to GDP per capita.

Table 4.

Public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita and GDP per capita

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Overall Balanced panel Outliers (O) Controls (C) O + C C + L
GDP per capita (natural log) GDP per capita (natural log) GDP per capita (natural log) GDP per capita (natural log) GDP per capita (natural log) GDP per capita (natural log)
Pharmaceutical exp. −0.0915** (0.0400) −0.0978*** (0.0363) −0.158*** (0.0526) −0.0842*** (0.0242) −0.071*** (0.0239) −0.112*** (0.0313)
Health expenditure 0.244*** (0.0542) 0.166** (0.0688) 0.260*** (0.0470)
Life expectancy −0.712 (0.498) −0.743 (0.585) −0.251 (0.566)
Capital formation 0.00444*** (0.00103) 0.00490*** (0.00157) 0.00251* (0.00138)
Savings rate 0.00176 (0.00139) 0.00351* (0.00173) 0.00296* (0.00168)
Govt. expenditure −0.000201 (0.00119) −0.000728 (0.001645) 0.000493 (0.00186)
Population over 65 0.328** (0.135) 0.336 (0.221) 0.311*** (0.118)
Lag (1) pharmaceutical exp. 0.108*** (0.0322)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,389 1,152 789 1,063 551 970
R‐squared 0.479 0.564 0.443 0.655 0.603 0.657
First stage F‐stat 395.2 366.1 146.6 372.7 605.2 385.63
p value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Kleibergen‐Paap LM statistic 32.14 24.26 15.94 22.00 12.45 14.47
p value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0004 0.0001
Endogeneity test 10.77 20.06 16.43 27.98 17.35 29.56
p value 0.0010 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
No. of countries 136 96 72 120 73 110

Note. The DV in all columns is GDP per capita (natural log). All estimates are IV estimates. Column (1) shows estimates of the effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita on GDP per capita (natural log) for the full sample. Column (2) shows estimates using a balanced panel; column (3) shows IV estimates after excluding outliers from the balanced panel identified using the Hadi procedure; column (4) shows estimates after inclusion of relevant controls in the full sample; column (5) shows estimates after inclusion of controls and exclusion of outliers from the full sample; column (6) shows estimates from a dynamic model that includes the first lag of pharmaceutical expenditure and thereby accounts for inertia in pharmaceutical spending. Health expenditure here refers to all other health spending excluding public pharmaceutical spending. DV: dependent variable; GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

4.4. Intertemporal effects

Given the typical short term thinking of policy makers, we have so far focused on an analysis of concomitant effects. However, it is plausible that the relationship between GDP and pharmaceutical spending is intertemporal in nature. We therefore assess whether there is any effect of lagged GDP on current pharmaceutical expenditure and that of lagged pharmaceutical expenditure on current GDP. We show results for up to three lags of GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure in Table 5. Although the point estimates of the effect of GDP per capita on pharmaceutical expenditure are quantitatively similar, they are statistically significant at a 10% level. Pharmaceutical expenditure, however, continues to show similar effects on GDP as before, both quantitatively and qualitatively. We discuss the negative effect of pharmaceutical spending on GDP in more detail in the conclusion section and provide several explanations in support of our findings.

Table 5.

Intertemporal effects of GDP per capita and public pharmaceutical expenditure

Panel A: Lagged effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditures
Variables (1) (2) (3)
Lag 1 year Lag 2 years Lag 3 years
GDP per capita (natural log) 1.856* (1.073) 2.182* (1.126) 2.083* (1.184)
Panel B: Lagged effect of public pharmaceutical expenditures on GDP per capita
Variables (1) (2) (3)
Lag 1 year Lag 2 years Lag 3 years
Pharmaceutical exp. −0.147*** (0.0415) −0.143*** (0.0373) −0.136*** (0.0361)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,056 960 864
No. of countries 96 96 96

Note. Panel A (columns [1] to [3]) shows the lagged effect of GDP per capita (natural log) on public pharmaceutical expenditure using 1‐year to 3‐year lags of GDP per capita. Panel B shows the reverse effect, that is, of public pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP per capita using 1‐year to 3‐year lags of public pharmaceutical expenditure. All models include country and year fixed effects and a balanced sample of countries. GDP: gross domestic product.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

So far, our results are consistent regarding the different specifications and sensitivity tests. However, concerns around the validity of the instrument may remain. We address such concerns in the next section related to instrument validity.

5. INSTRUMENT VALIDITY

The first stage F‐statistics clearly support the notion of relevance of the instrument. However, validity (exclusion restriction) is not directly testable. It is therefore worthwhile to discuss issues related to validity of the instrument and potential threats to validity. We show unadjusted and adjusted (partial) correlation coefficients in Tables A2a and A2b. When we look at the partial correlations, we find a strong relationship between GDP per capita and pharmaceutical expenditure. However, the partial correlation between tourist receipts and pharmaceutical expenditure is virtually zero; these descriptive findings therefore support the relevance and validity arguments for our instrument. Further, although it seems plausible to us that tourist receipts (spending by international visitors on food, travel, etc.) should not be related to public pharmaceutical expenditures of the host country directly other than through GDP, one can argue that medical tourism could be a potential source of contamination. Nevertheless, we argue that even if this were a likely source of correlation between the instrument and pharmaceutical spending, it seems plausible to presume that this spending will not be reflected in the public pharmaceutical expenditure of a country. In addition, it may also be argued that tourism itself may depend on the underlying health conditions of a country. For instance, an outbreak of a disease may affect the number of tourists visiting a country and therefore be related to GDP, health, and health expenditure. A priori one can expect disease outbreaks to be positively related to pharmaceutical expenditures (as they are likely to increase utilization of health services) and negatively related to GDP. In this scenario, if anything, our results would be an underestimate of the true effect. As unlikely as we perceive these effects to be on average, we collect data on disease outbreaks from 1996 up to the years in our sample. We first show in column (1) of Table 6 that there is no systematic relationship between disease outbreaks in a country and tourist receipts earned by the country, indicating that disease outbreaks are unlikely to affect tourism in our sample and thereby contaminate our IV strategy. Then, in column (2), we show the IV estimate of the effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita controlling for disease outbreaks. Our point estimates are robust to the inclusion of this control variable. Column (3) shows the effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP controlling for disease outbreaks. We continue to find a negative and significant (at the 10% level) effect of pharmaceutical spending on GDP.

Table 6.

Instrument validity

Variables (1) (2) (3)
Tourist receipts Pharmaceutical expenditure GDP per capita (natural log)
No. of outbreaks −0.0500 (0.0353) −0.0183 (0.0272) 0.0153 (0.0107)
GDP per capita (natural log) 2.251*** (0.484)
Pharmaceutical exp. −0.0739* (0.0431)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes
Observations 797 592 797
R‐squared 0.343 0.182 −0.213
No. of countries 71 65 71

Note. Column (1) shows the relationship between disease outbreaks in a country and tourist receipts. Column (2) shows the IV estimates of the effect of GDP per capita (natural log) on public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita controlling for disease outbreaks. Column (3) shows the IV estimates of the effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita on GDP per capita (natural log) controlling for disease outbreaks. GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

6. EFFECT HETEROGENEITY

The fixed effects in our analysis ensure that long‐standing differences between countries do not bias the estimates in any way, that is, differences pertaining to the country level such as preferences for spending on health care and production functions play no role. However, it is likely that the elasticity of pharmaceutical expenditure differs across countries as is observed in past literature on health expenditures. Prior literature that investigates elasticity of health expenditure usually assesses heterogeneity by simply segmenting countries into income groups, development levels, health spending, and time periods (Blazquez‐Fernandez, Cantarero, & Perez, 2014; Farag et al., 2012). We extend the investigation of effect heterogeneity in several ways by considering (a) different quantiles of the response variables and (b) politico‐economic freedom of countries.

6.1. Income groups

First, similar to prior research on determinants of health expenditure, we investigate heterogeneity by income group. Columns (1) and (3) of Table 7.1 show the estimates of the effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditure for high‐ and low‐income countries, respectively. The effect is significant only for the group of high‐income countries where the elasticity exceeds unity; however, it is not significant for low‐income countries. Columns (2) and (4) show the corresponding estimates of the effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP per capita. The estimates are negative, significant at a 5% level only for low‐income countries and not significant at any conventional level for high‐income countries. It is important to note here that due to sample size issues, we classified high‐income and upper middle‐income countries together as high‐income countries. Similarly, we classified low‐income and lower middle‐income countries together as low‐income countries. We therefore need to bear in mind that not all high‐income countries and not all low‐income countries are at the same level of GDP or pharmaceutical spending. For example, in our sample in 2006, the difference between GDP per capita of the country with the highest GDP (Luxembourg) in the high‐income group and the country with the lowest GDP (Fiji) in the upper middle‐income group was as much as U.S. $99,328. Similarly, the difference is as much as U.S. $5,345 between the country with the highest GDP (Colombia) in the lower‐middle income group and the lowest GDP country (Ethiopia) in the low‐income group. There is high variation in both GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure within the two income groups and therefore combining these countries in the same group may not provide an accurate picture. We therefore employ additional strategies to assess heterogeneity, as described next.

Table 7.1.

Effect heterogeneity: Income groups

High income Low income
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables Pharmaceutical expenditure GDP per capita (natural log) Pharmaceutical expenditure GDP per capita (natural log)
GDP per capita (natural log) 1.766*** (0.849) 1.319 (1.017)
Pharmaceutical exp. −0.136 (0.092) −0.098*** (0.038)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 797 797 592 592
R‐squared 0.531 0.445 0.315 0.481
First stage F‐stat 24.81 56.55 4.28 474.10
p value 0.000 0.000 0.042 0.000
Kleibergen‐Paap LM statistic 6.58 15.35 3.66 15.37
p value 0.0103 0.0001 0.0557 0.0001
Endogeneity test 2.221 4.586 2.081 10.677
p value 0.1362 0.0322 0.1491 0.0011
Number of countries 71 71 65 65

Note. The DV in columns (1) and (3) is public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita; in columns (2) and (4), it is GDP per capita (natural log). Columns (1) and (2) show IV estimates for high‐income countries whereas columns (3) and (4) show IV estimates for low‐income countries. GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

6.2. IV quantile regressions

We recognize the importance of going beyond conditional means, something that the empirical economics literature makes a compelling case for (Koenker & Hallock, 2001), and adopt an IV quantile regression approach to assess the effects of GDP and pharmaceutical expenditure. Quantile regressions are robust to nonnormal errors and outliers. In addition, they allow us to estimate the impact of GDP per capita on the entire distribution of pharmaceutical expenditure and vice versa.

Table 7.2 shows the results of the IV quantile regressions. Panel A shows the results of the income elasticity of pharmaceutical expenditure at the 10th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and 90th quantiles of pharmaceutical expenditure. We find that the elasticity systematically decreases as we move to higher quantiles of expenditure. For countries that are at the lower end of the distribution, that is, spend very little on pharmaceutical expenditure, a 1% increase in GDP per capita leads to an approximately 2% increase in pharmaceutical expenditures. However, for countries at the upper end of the distribution we find that the increase in pharmaceutical expenditure in response to an increase in GDP per capita is near unity. The results seem plausible given that countries with limited spending on pharmaceuticals increase spending with increases in GDP, because they have not yet reached the “flat part of the curve” of medical spending, that is, marginal productivity of expenditure may still be increasing (Farag et al., 2012). However, countries that are already at the high end of spending face diminishing returns to health spending and, hence, contain health spending.

Table 7.2.

Effect heterogeneity: Quantile IV regressions

Panel A: Effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditures
(10th) (25th) (50th) (75th) (90th)
Variables
GDP per capita (natural log) 1.957*** (0.286) 1.320*** (0.153) 1.205*** (0.121) 1.056*** (0.0781) 1.069*** (0.0565)
Panel B: Effect of public pharmaceutical expenditures on GDP per capita
(10th) (25th) (50th) (75th) (90th)
Variables
Pharmaceutical exp. −0.0290 (0.0206) −0.0486*** (0.00772) −0.0490*** (0.0121) −0.0509*** (0.0158) −0.0398 (0.0265)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 1,389 1,389 1,389 1,389 1,389
No. of countries 136 136 136 136 136

Note. The DV in panel A is public pharmaceutical expenditure per capita, and in panel B, it is the natural log of GDP per capita. The coefficients represent estimates from IV quantile regressions at the 10th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and 90th quantile of the respective dependent variable as indicated. All regressions include year fixed effects and country fixed effects. GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.1.

The difference in the income elasticity of pharmaceutical expenditure between an analysis by pharmaceutical expenditure (quantile regressions) and an analysis by income is noteworthy because countries spending less on pharmaceuticals are also poorer countries; Table A3 in the appendix shows the percentage of high‐ and low‐income countries at each quantile of pharmaceutical spending. However, there is significant between‐country heterogeneity even within an income group. For example, between‐country variation in GDP per capita in the low‐income group is as much as $1,234.63. This heterogeneity between countries reduces to half for low‐income countries with low spending, that is, lowest quantile of pharmaceutical expenditure, thus pointing towards the role of spending. Therefore, a simple classification into high‐ and low‐income groups does not show the complete picture; quantile regressions enrich our understanding of the results and reveal that the existing spending level is important for explaining heterogeneity. Although prior literature that analyses overall health expenditures finds an income elasticity of less than unity over the entire distribution (Tian, Gao, & Yang, 2016), results for specific type of expenditure such as pharmaceuticals thus show a different picture.

With respect to the impact of pharmaceutical spending on GDP per capita, we find that the results are negative and significant only for the 25th, 50th, and 75th quantiles. These results imply that pharmaceutical expenditure does not have any impact on GDP at the lowest and the highest end of the distribution, that is, in the poorest and richest countries. These results are to some extent similar to the results we observe with the income groups where the richer countries do not show a significantly negative effect of pharmaceutical spending. We posit that the budget constraint these countries face relative to middle‐ and low‐income countries is not as stringent in that, they invest significantly in other productive types of government activities as well. As such, the investment diversion that low‐income countries face might be higher.

6.3. Politico‐economic situation

As the World Health Report, 2000, argues, health law enforcement and political‐economic conditions play an important role in shaping national policies on health care that may be either health promoting or health restricting. For example, trade embargoes in countries can restrict import–export of essential medicines, thereby affecting health outcomes. Hence, the degree of political freedom in a country may determine health policies and subsequent health spending. As such, two countries may grow apart by their income levels; yet it is not income but political and economic freedom that determines spending on pharmaceuticals.

We therefore assess heterogeneity in the effects by political‐economic situation (see Table 7.3) using the EFW index from the Fraser Institute. For details on the EFW index, we refer readers to https://www.fraserinstitute.org/. We use data on the overall score along with scores on civil and political rights that classify countries as economically “free” or “not free.” We find that GDP per capita has a significant impact on pharmaceutical spending only in countries classified as “free.” It is not significant for countries classified as “not free.” This implies that for these countries, it is not GDP, but the political environment that matters. In contrast, we find that the impact of pharmaceutical expenditure has a significantly negative effect only in countries that are “not free.” It is not significant for countries classified as “free.”

Table 7.3.

Effect heterogeneity: Politico‐economic freedom

Panel A: Effect of GDP per capita on public pharmaceutical expenditures
Civil liberty Political rights Overall score
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Free Not free Free Not free Free Not free
GDP per capita (natural log) 1.573*** (0.603) 1.486 (0.937) 1.854*** (0.712) 1.606 (1.212) 1.479** (0.619) 1.361 (0.972)
Panel B: Effect of public pharmaceutical expenditures on GDP per capita
Civil liberty Political rights Overall score
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Free Not free Free Not free Free Not free
Pharmaceutical exp. −0.0292 (0.0260) −0.157** (0.0660) −0.0461 (0.0296) −0.192** (0.0837) −0.00344 (0.0232) −0.151** (0.0636)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 654 733 791 591 780 601
No. of countries 66 89 79 78 78 79

Note. The DV in panel A is Public pharmaceutical expenditures, and in Panel B, it is GDP per capita. The EFW index is used to classify countries as “free” and “not free” based on civil liberties (columns [1] and [2]), political rights (columns [3] and [4]), and an overall score (columns [5] and [6]). All regressions include year fixed effects and country fixed effects. DV: dependent variable; EFW: Economic Freedom of the World; GDP: gross domestic product; IV: instrumental variable.

***

p < 0.01.

**

p < 0.05.

*

p < 0.10.

Overall, heterogeneity of countries with respect to economic development, pharmaceutical spending, and political environment plays an important role. As the results show, low‐income countries respond differently to an increase in GDP and an increase in health spending compared with high‐income countries. Most of the low‐income countries in our sample are also classified as “not free” (75%), whereas most of the high‐income countries are classified as “free” (80%). This heterogeneity in the effects can have important implications for pharmaceutical policy and regulation, which we discuss in Section 8.

7. EXPLAINING THE NEGATIVE EFFECT OF PUBLIC PHARMACEUTICAL EXPENDITURE

An obvious question that arises from the results concerns the negative effect of public pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP per capita, that is, how the negative effect can be explained. Theoretically, Ram (1986) suggests that government size can be growth reducing; empirically, findings of some of the prior literature support this notion (Barro, 1991; Landau, 1983). We draw on this literature and provide arguments that are both general to government spending and specific to pharmaceutical spending. Government size can be harmful for growth due to inefficiency, regulatory costs, and distorted economic incentives arising out of government fiscal policies (Ram, 1986). Distortionary taxes to finance government spending may negatively affect savings and hence growth (Barro, 1991). If public spending crowds out private investment, and if government spending is on inefficient and unproductive activities, it can impinge negatively on growth (Afonso & Furceri, 2010). Financing of government spending by means of increased taxation may have negative spillovers to the economy (Asimakopoulos & Karavias, 2016).

Another reason through which public spending on pharmaceuticals affects GDP negatively may be an investment diversion effect. With respect to health spending, others (Acemoglu & Johnson, 2007; Ashraf et al., 2008) have found that it takes a long time for health‐related economic returns to be witnessed. Even if we witness health benefits that translate into economic returns contemporaneously, they might not be large enough to justify the disproportionate spending, which is an opportunity cost in itself and diverts resources away from potentially more productive sources of public expenditure such as transport and infrastructure spending (Easterly & Rebelo, 1993; Kelley, 1988). Third, most countries have a significant demand for imported pharmaceutical products, and spending a lot on imported drugs may lead to a downward multiplier effect in the economy. For example, in the Unites States, direct imports of pharmaceuticals rose from $15.4 billion out of the $63.3 billion pharmaceutical sales in 1998 to around $68 billion out of the $151 billion sales in 2012 (Werling et al., 2014). Finally, the method of financing government expenditures might play a crucial role in determining the relationship between spending and growth; debt financed increases in health spending can have negative effects on economic growth (Ahmed & Miller, 1999). Increased government borrowing and higher taxes to finance health expenditures can be detrimental to economic growth in that it reduces income for private spending. A large part of health expenditure is indeed financed by taxes or social insurance contributions (Gerdtham & Jönsson, 2000). In addition, spending on ineffective drugs (in terms of both cost and illness) results in unproductive expenditure, which does not contribute to the economy. This may be particularly true for less developed and politico‐economically unfree countries that not only lack efficient allocative mechanisms but also face accessibility problems to high quality medicines (Kyle & McGahan, 2012). Our results are particularly significantly negative for such less developed and poor countries. Pharmaceuticals covered by public resources in these countries may not be cost‐saving or even cost‐effective because public resources may be misdirected. Hence, the allocation of government expenditures may not be rational in this sense. As a result, inefficient spending coupled with a stringent budget constraint raises the opportunity cost and reduces productive returns much more in these countries. Although we are unable to investigate specifically each mechanism due to data unavailability, we leave this avenue open for future research. We discuss the implications of our findings for policy in the next section.

8. CONCLUSION

This paper answers two questions that are both important and strongly debated in the health economics literature. First, it assesses the income elasticity of medical spending focusing on public pharmaceutical expenditures. Second, it assesses the effect of public pharmaceutical spending on income measured by GDP per capita. To this end, the paper employs a two‐step IV procedure using data for 136 countries from 1995 to 2006 and answers both research questions within the same econometric framework. Briefly, our IV estimates suggest that the least squares regression model significantly underestimates the response of public pharmaceutical spending to GDP per capita, and once endogeneity is accounted for, public pharmaceutical expenditure shows an income elasticity that is greater than unity. Further, once the reverse causal effect of GDP on pharmaceutical spending is accounted for, public pharmaceutical spending itself has a negative effect on GDP per capita. Heterogeneity of countries with respect to economic development, pharmaceutical spending, and politico‐economic environment plays an important role in the understanding of these results and their implications for health policy. Overall, countries that spend little on pharmaceuticals show an income elasticity above one, whereas countries that spend a lot are unitary elastic. Countries that are politico‐economically “free” in our analysis show elasticity greater than unity, whereas countries that are “not free” show no significant relationship with income. On the contrary, pharmaceutical spending itself has a negative impact on GDP in “unfree” countries and countries at the lower end of the distribution of GDP.

Given these results, the question is how do they inform health care policy. As Acemoglu et al. (2013) point out, understanding the role of income in the rise of health expenditures is important for forecasting the evolution of health expenditures and analyzing the social optimality of health spending. Further, an assessment of the elasticity of pharmaceutical spending is crucial for policy in that it will aid policy makers in deciding whether to intervene in the market or to let market forces play a role in improving welfare. Finally, our findings show that countries that spend little on pharmaceuticals have an income elasticity greater than one; which begs the question—are we achieving convergence in pharmaceutical spending across the world. Concerning the negative effect of pharmaceutical spending on GDP, the results point towards a need for improving efficiency and effectiveness of medical spending as well as limiting waste. Although “irrational” use of medicines is a problem in both low‐ and high‐income countries, in developed countries, routine monitoring and strong electronic systems limit wasteful spending to a certain extent. In developing countries, however, such monitoring systems are not available, resulting in more than 60% of the patients in the public sector not being treated according to appropriate guidelines (WHO, 2011). Furthermore, even if medicines are prescribed appropriately, patient adherence is weak with over 80% drugs being dispensed by unqualified personnel and about one‐third of patients lacking knowledge on how to take medicines (WHO, 2011). Therefore, despite incurring costs, medicines may not translate into health benefits.

Furthermore, high‐income countries have strong regulations such as reference pricing, national or regional procurement contracts and reimbursement policies that provide them with a certain degree of control over prices. As a result, there is less differential between originator brands and lowest price generics than in low‐income countries where the difference may be over 300% (WHO, 2011). Therefore, the higher prices that low‐income countries are subjected to further raise the opportunity cost of spending on pharmaceuticals.

Improving allocative efficiency of government budgets taking into account the opportunity costs of spending on health care, and investing optimally in other areas are crucial steps for the sustainability of fiscal budgets. An important policy implication due to the heterogeneity in the results is that encouraging the uptake of cost‐effective medicines in less developed countries may be key for efficient health spending. Revill et al. (2014) argue that current cost‐effectiveness thresholds set by the WHO are not adequate as they impose opportunity costs under budget constraints. Given our findings of the negative effect on growth, this becomes important for long‐term sustainability of health care systems in these countries. On a similar note, policy should be geared towards price control so that more can be achieved with the same level of spending without having to reduce volume (which is not an option in low‐income countries anyway given the low level of spending).

The results based on the politico‐economic freedom mean that greater politico‐economic freedom may help counter the negative effect of health spending by improving within‐ and cross‐border pharmaceutical trade, thus increasing access to essential medicines. This may improve the marginal productivity of health expenditure. Also, providing subsidies and encouraging local R&D to reduce dependence on imported and expensive pharmaceuticals may help counter the negative multiplier effect in the economy. Finally, it needs to be acknowledged that even if economic growth is negative and pharmaceutical spending is wasteful to some degree, there may be reasons beyond economic growth to increase public funds for pharmaceuticals, for example, a reduction in inequality in access to pharmaceuticals.

Before we conclude, it is important to mention a few caveats of the analysis and provide recommendations for future research related to this topic. First, our analysis largely addresses contemporaneous effects. The short‐term perspective is of particular interest to policy makers as they generally have a short planning horizon. This is similar to the perspective of a budget impact analysis, a standard tool for estimating the financial consequences of adopting new health interventions. However, long‐run effects cannot be ruled out, and hence, we analyze lagged effects within the limits of data availability. As longer time series data becomes available, future work should look into long‐run elasticities of health spending and the long‐run effect of health spending on income. As a word of caution, even in the long‐term increased public pharmaceutical expenditure may not lead to economic growth because of the reasons mentioned previously and because savings in health expenditures may not be realized (see, e.g., Shroufi et al., 2013, and Horton et al., 2017). Second, we consider public pharmaceutical spending because it forms a major part of total health expenditure and is exposed to many regulations. Needless to say, that future work should consider different types of health spending such as preventive and rehabilitative expenditures. Finally, we consider pharmaceutical expenditure in its final form ignoring that it is a combination of price and quantity (Lu, Hernandez, Abegunde, & Edejer, 2011). To the extent that prices reflect the innovativeness of a drug or a drug being branded/generic, and quantity reflects the disease burden of the country, analyzing the elasticity by separating expenditures into these components could provide interesting insights for policy. As better data become available in the future, this could be a potential question for researchers to pursue.

CONFLICTS OF INTEREST

None

FUNDING SOURCES

This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not‐for‐profit sectors.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We are grateful to Simone Ghislandi, Carol Propper, Pedro Pita Barros, Renata Kosova, Mark Alan Dusheiko, Peter Carney, Paul G Schmidt, Michael Koetter, and Marisa Miraldo for helpful discussions and detailed comments on early versions of this paper. We would like to thank participants at the HESG conference Lancaster, European Health Economics Association Student Supervisor conference, and the University of Lucerne doctoral workshop 2015. We would also like to thank participants of the research seminars at London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, City University London, Frankfurt School Brown Bag seminar, and Wifor Darmstadt Seminar Series. All errors are our own.

APPENDIX A.

Appendix A.1 xxx

Table A1.

Countries and number of observations per country

Country Observations Country Observations Country Observations
Albania 4 Fiji 12 Netherlands 12
Algeria 12 Finland 12 New Zealand 12
Antigua and Barbuda 12 France 12 Nicaragua 12
Argentina 12 Gabon 11 Niger 2
Armenia 12 Georgia 10 Norway 12
Australia 12 Germany 12 Oman 2
Austria 12 Greece 12 Pakistan 7
Azerbaijan 12 Grenada 12 Panama 12
The Bahamas 12 Guatemala 12 Papua New Guinea 12
Bahrain 12 Guinea 2 Paraguay 12
Bangladesh 12 Guyana 12 Peru 12
Barbados 12 Haiti 11 Philippines 12
Belarus 12 Honduras 12 Poland 12
Belgium 12 Hungary 12 Portugal 12
Belize 12 Iceland 12 Russian Federation 12
Benin 2 India 12 Rwanda 2
Bhutan 10 Indonesia 12 Samoa 12
Bolivia 12 Ireland 12 Senegal 12
Bosnia and Herzegovina 4 Israel 12 Serbia 5
Brazil 12 Italy 12 Singapore 7
Brunei Darussalam 6 Jamaica 12 Slovak Republic 12
Bulgaria 12 Japan 12 Slovenia 12
Burkina Faso 7 Jordan 3 Solomon Islands 8
Cabo Verde 12 Kazakhstan 12 Spain 12
Cambodia 12 Kenya 7 Sri Lanka 12
Cameroon 7 Kiribati 8 St. Kitts and Nevis 12
Canada 12 Korea, Rep. 12 St. Lucia 12
Central African Republic 12 Kuwait 2 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 12
Chad 8 Kyrgyz Republic 12 Suriname 12
Chile 12 Lao PDR 12 Sweden 12
China 12 Latvia 12 Switzerland 12
Colombia 12 Lesotho 3 Thailand 12
Costa Rica 12 Lithuania 12 Tonga 10
Croatia 12 Luxembourg 12 Trinidad and Tobago 12
Cyprus 12 Macedonia, FYR 12 Tunisia 4
Czech Republic 12 Malawi 4 Turkey 9
Denmark 12 Malaysia 12 Uganda 8
Djibouti 7 Maldives 6 Ukraine 12
Dominica 12 Mali 7 United Kingdom 12
Dominican Republic 12 Malta 12 United States 12
Ecuador 12 Mexico 12 Uruguay 12
El Salvador 12 Moldova 10 Uzbekistan 7
Equatorial Guinea 7 Mongolia 12 Venezuela, RB 4
Estonia 12 Myanmar 12 Vietnam 4
Ethiopia 2 Nepal 12 Yemen, Rep. 3
Zambia 7

Table A2a.

Pearson's correlation coefficients between public pharmaceutical expenditure, GDP per capita, and tourist receipts

Public pharmaceutical expenditure GDP per capita (natural log)
GDP per capita (natural log) 0.9193
p value (0.0000)
Tourist receipts 0.6027 0.6751
p value (0.0000) (0.0000)

Note. The table shows Pearson's correlations. The p value is reported in parentheses below the correlation coefficient. GDP: gross domestic product.

Table A2b.

Partial correlations between public pharmaceutical expenditure, GDP per capita, and tourist receipts

Public pharmaceutical expenditure GDP per capita (natural log)
GDP per capita (natural log) 0.8704
p value (0.0000)
Tourist receipts −0.0616 0.3854
p value (0.0217) (0.0000)

Note. The table shows partial correlations. The p value is reported in parentheses below the correlation coefficient. GDP: gross domestic product.

Table A3.

Percentage of high‐ and low‐income group of countries at quantiles of pharmaceutical expenditure

Quantiles of public pharmaceutical expenditure
1 (%) 2 (%) 3 (%) 4 (%) 5 (%)
High‐income group 2.13 29.03 60.79 96.77 100.00
Low‐income group 97.87 70.97 39.21 3.23 0.00

Shaikh M, Gandjour A. Pharmaceutical expenditure and gross domestic product: Evidence of simultaneous effects using a two‐step instrumental variables strategy. Health Economics. 2019;28:101–122. 10.1002/hec.3832

Footnotes

1

Acemoglu et al. (2013) assess the response of hospital expenditures to income and further break it down into payroll expenditure, employee expenditures, skill composition, hospital utilization, etc.

2

We acknowledge that in order to understand the full picture of the response of pharmaceutical spending to GDP growth and vice‐versa, an analysis of total pharmaceutical expenditures and not just the public component of it is essential. This is particularly relevant for low‐income countries where public spending levels are low and private spending is an important method of financing. However, we are limited in our analysis owing to data concerns with respect to private spending that is part of total spending. Certain components are not included in total spending such as medicines covered by private insurance, produced by local pharmacists and hospitals, and informal sales or payments (e.g., unregistered or resale pharmaceuticals). These largely represent private spending in low‐income countries that would be heavily underestimated. Moreover, we consider the question of how private spending on pharmaceuticals affects growth only of relevance if it were an option to contain private spending. Yet, based on the values of a democratic society and its public discourse, citizens shall not be prohibited from purchasing pharmaceuticals in a private market if these pharmaceuticals are not covered by their insurance. That is, based on democratic values strict rationing seems hardly defendable and requires enforcement, rendering the question of whether to contain private spending essentially a hypothetical one.

3

Farag et al. (2012) and Acemoglu et al. (2013) are notable exceptions that used instrumental variables. However, their dependent variables were different.

4

To the best of our knowledge, Moreno‐Serra and Smith (2015) are the only other authors within health economics to have used the two‐step IV procedure.

5

The choice of a fixed effects model is motivated by the fact that there could be omitted variables (time‐invariant and time varying) that relate to both pharmaceutical expenditure and GDP. For example, geographic location may have a strong impact on disease burden and on economic growth (Boulhol, de Serres, & Molnar, 2008; Gallup, Sachs, & Mellinger, 1999). The assumptions of a random effects model are, therefore, not satisfied. Nevertheless, we report results of the Hausman tests in Table 2, which support fixed‐effects specifications.

6

Due to sample size issues, we pool high‐income and upper middle‐income countries into one group called “high‐income” countries and lower and lower‐middle income countries into another group called “low‐income” countries.

7

Note that the endogeneity test suggests that GDP per capita is exogenous; however, results presented in columns (3) and (5) of Table 3 below suggest that it is indeed endogenous. In any case, we have outlined strong theoretical reasons and prior empirical evidence that leaves little contention concerning the endogenous nature of economic growth. Moreover, in Step 2 of the empirical strategy where we assess the impact of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP, the test strongly suggests pharmaceutical expenditures as endogenous (see Table 4).

8

In addition, to avoid generated regressor bias in step 2 of the analysis, i.e. the effect of pharmaceutical expenditure on GDP, we run these regressions with bootstrapped standard errors to which the results remain robust. These results are available from the authors upon request.

9

To the extent that health expenditures improve health, and health improves productivity, health expenditures should be positively related to economic growth (Bhargava, Jamison, Lau, & Murray, 2001; Bloom et al., 2004; Bloom & Canning, 2000). A recent study examining the direct link between public health spending and economic growth has found a positive relationship between the two (Halıcı‐Tülüce, Doğan, & Dumrul, 2016).

10

We lose almost 30% of our sample by the fourth lag of pharmaceutical expenditure. Hence, due to data limitations, the analysis is restricted to three lags.

11

The data for disease outbreaks per country per year are from Google's public database on infectious disease outbreaks taken from HealthMap.org, Harvard Medical School. Due to missing data on most of the countries, we have a smaller sample in comparison with our main results. The data are available from https://www.google.com/publicdata/explore?ds=gh9ira29bjcpl_&ctype=l&strail=false&nselm=h&met_y=num_outbreaks&scale_y=lin&ind_y=false&rdim=whoregion&idim=whoregion%3AAfrica%3AAmericas%3AEastern+Mediterranean%3AEurope%3ASouth‐East+Asia%3AWestern+Pacific&tdim=true&tstart=&hl=en&dl=en [Last accessed February 23, 2018].

12

We are grateful to a reviewer for recommending these strategies that have helped enrich the analysis.

13

We are grateful to a referee for pointing this out.

15

Note that Farag et al. (2012) find lower income elasticity of health spending and argue to the contrary that convergence in health and health spending is unlikely anytime soon.

REFERENCES

  1. Acemoglu, D. , Finkelstein, A. , & Notowidigdo, M. J. (2013). Income and health spending: Evidence from oil price shocks. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1079–1095. [Google Scholar]
  2. Acemoglu, D. , & Johnson, S. (2007). Disease and development: The effect of life expectancy on economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 925–985. [Google Scholar]
  3. Afonso, A. , & Furceri, D. (2010). Government size, composition, volatility and economic growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 517–532. [Google Scholar]
  4. Ahmed, H. , & Miller, S. M. (1999). Crowding‐out and crowding‐in effects of the components of government expenditure. Economics Working Papers. Paper 199902, University of Connecticut DigitalCommons@UConn.
  5. Angrist, J. D. , & Krueger, A. B. (2001). Instrumental variables and the search for identification: From supply and demand to natural experiments. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), 69–85. [Google Scholar]
  6. Aschauer, D. A. (1989). Is public expenditure productive? Journal of Monetary Economics, 23(2), 177–200. [Google Scholar]
  7. Ashraf, Q. H. , Lester, A. , & Weil, D. N. (2008). When does improving health raise GDP? NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 23, 157–204. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  8. Asimakopoulos, S. , & Karavias, Y. (2016). The impact of government size on economic growth: A threshold analysis. Economic Letters, 139, 65–68. [Google Scholar]
  9. Baltagi, B. F. , & Moscone, F. (2010). Health care expenditure and income in the OECD reconsidered: Evidence from panel data. Economic Modelling, 27(4), 804–811. [Google Scholar]
  10. Barro, R. J. (1990). Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S103–S125. [Google Scholar]
  11. Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 407–443. [Google Scholar]
  12. Barro, R. J. , & McCleary, R. (2003). Religion and economic growth. American Sociological Review, 68(5), 760–781. [Google Scholar]
  13. Barros, P. P. (1998). The black box of health care expenditure growth determinants. Health Economics, 7(6), 533–544. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  14. Bhargava, A. , Jamison, D. T. , Lau, L. J. , & Murray, C. J. (2001). Modeling the effects of health on economic growth. Journal of Health Economics, 20(3), 423–440. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  15. Bhat, R. , & Jain, N. (2004). Analysis of public expenditure on health using state level data. Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad: Retrieved from http://www.iima.edu.in/publications/data/2004‐06‐08rbhat.pdf (Last accessed 02 May 2017). [Google Scholar]
  16. Bilgel, F. , & Tran, C. K. (2013). The determinants of Canadian provincial health expenditures: evidence from a dynamic panel. Applied Economics, 45(2), 201–212. [Google Scholar]
  17. Blazquez‐Fernandez, C. , Cantarero, D. , & Perez, P. (2014). Disentangling the heterogeneous income elasticity and dynamics of health expenditure. Applied Economics, 46(16), 1839–1854. [Google Scholar]
  18. Bleaney, M. , Gemmell, N. , & Kneller, R. (2001). Testing the endogenous growth model: Public expenditure, taxation and growth in the long run. Canadian Journal of Economics, 34(1), 36–57. [Google Scholar]
  19. Bloom, D. E. , & Canning, D. (2000). The health and wealth of nations. Science, 287(5456), 1207–1209. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  20. Bloom, D. E. , Canning, D. , & Sevilla, J. (2004). The effect of health on economic growth: A production function approach. World Development, 32(1), 1–13. [Google Scholar]
  21. Boulhol, H. , de Serres, A. , & Molnar, M. (2008). The contribution of economic geography to GDP per capita. OECD Working Paper No. 602. 10.2139/ssrn.1258222 [DOI]
  22. Brida, J. G. , & Pulina, M. (2010). A literature review on the tourism‐led‐growth hypothesis. Working Paper CRENoS No. 201017, Centre for North South Economic Research, University of Cagliari and Sassari, Sardinia.
  23. Brida, J. G. , Risso, W. A. , Lanzilotta, B. , & Lionetti, S. (2010). The tourism‐led‐growth hypothesis for Uruguay. Tourism Economics, 16(3), 765–771. [Google Scholar]
  24. Brückner, M. (2011). On the simultaneity problem in the aid and growth debate. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 28(1), 126–150. [Google Scholar]
  25. Carone, G. , Schwierz, C. , & Xavier, A. (2012). Cost‐containment policies in public pharmaceutical spending in the EU. Economics Papers 461, European Commission.
  26. Devarajan, S. , Swaroop, V. , & Zou, H. (1996). The composition of public expenditure and economic growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 37(2), 313–344. [Google Scholar]
  27. Di Matteo, L. (2003). The income elasticity of health care spending: A comparison of parametric and nonparametric approaches. The European Journal of Health Economics, 4(1), 20–29. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  28. Dreger, C. , & Reimers, H.‐E. (2005). Health care expenditures in OECD countries: A panel unit root and cointegration analysis. IZA DP No. 1469.
  29. Easterly, W. , & Rebelo, S. (1993). Fiscal policy and economic growth: An empirical investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 417–458. [Google Scholar]
  30. Farag, M. , NandaKumar, A. K. , Wallack, S. , Hodgkin, D. , Gaumer, G. , & Erbil, C. (2012). The income elasticity of health care spending in developing and developed countries. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 12(2), 145–162. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  31. Freeman, D. G. (2003). Is health care a necessity or a luxury? Pooled estimates of income elasticity from US state‐level data. Applied Economics, 35(5), 495–502. [Google Scholar]
  32. Gallup, J. L. , Sachs, J. D. , & Mellinger, A. D. (1999). Geography and economic development. International Regional Science Review, 22(2), 179–232. [Google Scholar]
  33. Gerdtham, U.‐G. , & Jönsson, B. (1991). Conversion factor instability in international comparisons of health care expenditure. Journal of Health Economics, 10(2), 227–234. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  34. Gerdtham, U.‐G. , & Jönsson, B. (1992). International comparisons of health care expenditure: Conversion factor instability, heteroscedasticity, outliers and robust estimators. Journal of Health Economics, 11(2), 189–197. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  35. Gerdtham, U.‐G. , & Jönsson, B. (2000). International comparisons of health expenditure: Theory, data an econometric analysis In Culyer A. J., & Newhouse J. P. (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics. North‐Holland: Elsevier. [Google Scholar]
  36. Gerdtham, U.‐G. , & Löthgren, M. (2002). New panel results on cointegration of international health expenditure and GDP. Applied Economics, 34(13), 1679–1686. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  37. Getzen, T. E. (2000). Health care is an individual necessity and a national luxury: Applying multilevel decision models to the analysis of health care expenditures. Journal of Health Economics, 19(2), 259–270. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  38. Glomm, G. , & Ravikumar, B. (1997). Productive government expenditures and long‐run growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21(1), 183–204. [Google Scholar]
  39. Grossman, G. M. , & Krueger, A. B. (1995). Economic growth and the environment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 353–377. [Google Scholar]
  40. Gunduz, L. , & Hatemi‐J, A. (2005). Is the tourism‐led growth hypothesis valid for Turkey? Applied Economics Letters, 12(8), 499–504. [Google Scholar]
  41. Hadi, A. (1992). Identifying multiple outliers in multivariate data. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 54(3), 761–771. [Google Scholar]
  42. Halıcı‐Tülüce, N. D. , Doğan, İ. , & Dumrul, C. (2016). Is income relevant for health expenditure and economic growth nexus? International Journal of Health Economics and Management, 16(1), 23–49. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  43. Hansen, C. W. , & Lønstrup, L. (2015). The rise in life expectancy and economic growth in the 20th century. The Economic Journal, 125(584), 838–852. [Google Scholar]
  44. Hauck, K. , & Zhang, X. (2016). Heterogeneity in the effect of common shocks on healthcare expenditure growth. Health Economics, 25(9), 1090–1103. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  45. Hitiris, T. , & Posnett, J. (1992). The determinants and effects of health expenditure in developed countries. Journal of Health Economics, 11(2), 173–181. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  46. Horton, S. , Gelband, H. , Jamison, D. , Levin, C. , Nugent, R. , & Watkins, D. (2017). Ranking 93 health interventions for low‐ and middle‐income countries by cost‐effectiveness. PLoS One, 12(8), e0182951. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  47. Jaunky, V. C. , & Khadaroo, A. J. (2008). Health care expenditure and GDP: An African perspective. Applied Econometrics and International Development, 8(1), 131–146. [Google Scholar]
  48. Kelley, A. C. (1988). Population pressures, saving, and investment in the third world: Some puzzles. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36(3), 449–464. [Google Scholar]
  49. Kleiman, E. (1974). The determinants of national outlay on health In Perlman M. (Ed.), The economics of health and medical care (pp. 66–81). London: Macmillan. [Google Scholar]
  50. Koenker, R. , & Hallock, K. F. (2001). Quantile regression. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), 143–156. [Google Scholar]
  51. Kyle, M. , & McGahan, A. M. (2012). Investments in pharmaceuticals before and after TRIPS. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(4), 1157–1172. [Google Scholar]
  52. Landau, D. (1983). Government expenditure and economic growth: A cross‐country study. Southern Economic Journal, 49(3), 783–792. [Google Scholar]
  53. Lean, H. , & Tang, C. (2009). Is the tourism‐led growth hypothesis stable for Malaysia? A note. International Journal of Tourism Research, 12(4), 375–378. [Google Scholar]
  54. Leu, R. (1986). The public–private mix and international health care costs In Culyer A., & Jonsson B. (Eds.), Public and private health services. London: Blackwell. [Google Scholar]
  55. Lu, Y. , Hernandez, P. , Abegunde, D. , & Edejer, T. (2011). The world medicines situation 2011 medicine expenditures. Geneva: WHO. [Google Scholar]
  56. Mehrara, M. , & Musai, M. (2011). The causality between health expenditure and economic growth in Iran. International Journal of Economic Resources, 2(4), 13–19. [Google Scholar]
  57. Miller, S. , & Russek, F. (1997). Fiscal structures and economic growth. Economic Inquiry, 35(3), 603–613. [Google Scholar]
  58. Moreno‐Serra, R. , & Smith, P. C. (2015). Broader health coverage is good for the nation's health: Evidence from country level panel data. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series a (Statistics in Society), 178(1), 101–124. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  59. Moscone, F. , & Tosetti, E. (2010). Health expenditure and income in the United States. Health Economics, 19(12), 1385–1403. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  60. Newhouse, J. P. (1977). Medical care expenditure: A cross‐national survey. Journal of Human Resources, 12(1), 115–125. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  61. OECD . (2011). Pharmaceutical expenditure. In Health at a Glance 2011: OECD Indicators, OECD Publishing. Retrieved from 10.1787/health_glance-2011-63-en. [DOI]
  62. Okunade, A. A. , & Murthy, V. N. (2002). Technology as a ‘major driver’ of health care costs: a cointegration analysis of the Newhouse conjecture. Journal of Health Economics, 21(1), 147–159. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  63. Okunade, A. A. , & Suraratdecha, C. (2000). Health care expenditure inertia in the OECD countries: A heterogeneous analysis. Health Care Management Science, 3(1), 31–42. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  64. Parkin, D. , McGuire, A. , & Yule, B. (1987). Aggregate health care expenditures and national income: Is health care a luxury good. Journal of Health Economics, 6(3), 109–127. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  65. Ram, R. (1986). Government size and economic growth: A new framework and some evidence from cross‐section and time‐series data. The American Economic Review, 76(1), 191–203. [Google Scholar]
  66. Revill, P. , Walker, S. , Madan, J. , Ciaranello, A. , Mwase, T. , Gibb, D. M. , … Sculpher, M. J. (2014). Using cost‐effectiveness thresholds to determine value for money in low‐and middle‐income country healthcare systems: Are current international norms fit for purpose? York: Centre for Health Economics, University of York, CHE Research Paper Series, No. 98.
  67. Risso, W. A. , & Brida, J. G. (2009). The contribution of tourism to economic growth: An empirical analysis for the case of Chile. European Journal of Tourism Research, 2(2), 178–185. [Google Scholar]
  68. Sahn, D. E. (1992). Public expenditures in sub‐Saharan Africa during a period of economic reforms. World Development, 20(5), 673–693. [Google Scholar]
  69. Sen, A. (2005). Is health care a luxury? New evidence from OECD data. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 5(2), 147–164. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  70. Shroufi, A. , Chowdhury, R. , Anchala, R. , Stevens, S. , Blanco, P. , Han, T. , … Franco, O. H. (2013). Cost effective interventions for the prevention of cardiovascular disease in low and middle income countries: A systematic review. BMC Public Health, 13(1), 285. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  71. Tian, F. , Gao, J. , & Yang, K. (2016). A quantile regression approach to panel data analysis of health care expenditure in OECD countries. Retrieved from SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2865062 (Last accessed: 12 Jan 2018). [DOI] [PubMed]
  72. Werling, J. , Keehan, S. , Nyhus, D. , Heffler, S. , Horst, R. , & Meade, D. (2014). The supply side of health care. U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis: Survey of Current Business. Retrieved from https://www.bea.gov/scb/pdf/2014/04%20April/0414_supply_side_of_health_care.pdf (Last accessed: 02 May 2017).
  73. World Health Organization . (2000). The world health report 2000—Health systems: Improving performance. Geneva: WHO. [Google Scholar]
  74. World Health Organization . (2011). World medicines situation 2011. Geneva: World Health Organisation (WHO). [Google Scholar]
  75. Xu, K. , Saksena, P. , & Holly, A. (2011). The determinants of health expenditure: A country level panel data analysis. Geneva: World Health Organisation (WHO). [Google Scholar]

Articles from Health Economics are provided here courtesy of Wiley

RESOURCES