Skip to main content
American Journal of Public Health logoLink to American Journal of Public Health
. 2019 Jul;109(7):1007–1014. doi: 10.2105/AJPH.2019.305067

Strategies to Reduce Illicit Trade of Regular Nicotine Tobacco Products After Introduction of a Low-Nicotine Tobacco Product Standard

Kurt M Ribisl 1,, Dorothy K Hatsukami 1, Jidong Huang 1, Rebecca S Williams 1, Eric C Donny 1
PMCID: PMC6603473  PMID: 31166743

Abstract

The US Food and Drug Administration is considering mandating a substantial reduction in the nicotine level of cigarettes and possibly other combusted tobacco products to render them minimially addictive. This would likely result in several public health benefits, including increased cessation, decreased progression to dependence, and reduced consumption of combusted tobacco products.

However, findings from clinical trials of reduced-nicotine cigarettes suggest that many smokers consuming low nicotine–content cigarettes sought out regular nicotine–content cigarettes, even when they were asked to only smoke free low-nicotine cigarettes. If this policy were implemented without ensuring that cessation treatments and appealing alternative products (e.g., e-cigarettes) were readily available, some consumers would be likely to seek banned regular nicotine–content combusted tobacco products from illicit sources: retail, online, and individuals. Left unchecked, this illicit market could undermine the public health benefits of the policy.

We describe supply and demand factors in an illicit market. Informed by the literature on controlling Internet tobacco sales and reducing illicit trade in low-cost cigarettes when there are price differentials, we recommend tracking and tracing products and greater surveillance and enforcement efforts to minimize illicit trade in normal nicotine products under a low-nicotine tobacco product standard.


The 2009 Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Control Act enabled the US Food and Drug Administration (FDA) Center for Tobacco Products to establish nicotine product standards for tobacco products if they are likely to improve public health.1 Although researchers initially proposed the idea of reducing the levels of nicotine in cigarettes more than 2 decades ago,2 the FDA recently issued an Advance Notice of Proposed Rule-Making for a Reduced-Nicotine Standard.3 The FDA could mandate reduced-nicotine content in cigarettes and other combusted tobacco products to minimize their addictive potential.3–5 Clinical trials showed that current smokers randomly assigned to very low nicotine–content (VLNC) cigarettes reduced their nicotine exposure and dependence, smoked fewer cigarettes, and experienced more smoke-free days.6–10 If reduced-nicotine products encouraged current smokers to quit and made new smokers less likely to develop dependence, the public health impact of the low-nicotine product standard would be enormous.11–13 In fact, a recent estimate of the impact of the reduced-nicotine standard would be 2.8 million tobacco-related deaths averted and 33.1 million life-years gained by 2060.13

Product standards to reduce nicotine content in all combusted tobacco products will render the most harmful products less addictive. Otherwise, consumers may switch to combusted cigarette substitutes, such as little cigars.14–16 As the reduced-nicotine product standard is implemented, it is important to ensure the widespread availability of cessation treatments and appealing noncombusted substitutes, such as e-cigarettes.17

Cigarettes with VLNC are markedly different from “light” or low-yield cigarettes. Light cigarettes (e.g., Marlboro Gold) decrease the machine-measured nicotine yield through filter ventilation and other design features, but the nicotine content is similar to “normal” cigarettes.18,19 Research shows that light cigarettes do not lower nicotine exposure; consumers can maintain their nicotine exposure by smoking more cigarettes, blocking filter ventilation holes, and inhaling deeper.19 By contrast, nicotine product standards would target the actual nicotine content of the filler tobacco, drastically reducing users’ nicotine exposure. As a result, smoking more cigarettes is unlikely to maintain normal nicotine levels for VLNC users. In fact, numerous studies did not observe compensatory smoking beyond the first few VLNC cigarettes smoked.6–8,20–22

We anticipate that after implementing a new reduced-nicotine standard some smokers will seek combusted tobacco products with normal nicotine–content, thus creating demand for the development of an illicit market. A recent analysis of controlled clinical trials showed that, without adherence incentives, 75% to 80% of participants supplemented the study-provided VLNC cigarettes with commercial normal nicotine cigarettes.23 Compared with studies providing commercial or normal nicotine cigarettes, the rate of nonadherence in studies of VLNC cigarettes is substantially higher.6 These nonadherence rates with VLNC cigarettes are not surprising, considering that normal nicotine cigarettes are legal and readily available. Nevertheless, in VLNC cigarette studies, total nicotine exposure is reduced for most participants.

These findings raise an important question: “If normal nicotine–content combusted products were removed from the legal market, what would smokers do?” Some may quit using tobacco products, some may attempt to add nicotine to VLNC products (e.g., by dripping e-liquids on them), and some may switch to noncombusted products (e.g., medicinal nicotine, e-cigarettes). Indeed, smokers in 1 study assigned to VLNC cigarettes demonstrated a greater uptake of alternative nicotine-containing delivery systems, such as e-cigarettes, than did those assigned to normal nicotine–content cigarettes.24 However, some smokers would seek combusted tobacco products with normal nicotine–content from a potential black market.

The FDA has stated that it expects “there would be a subset of consumers uninterested in switching to VLNC cigarettes or quitting tobacco products altogether. This subset of consumers may seek to obtain illicit tobacco products.”3 Others note that a potential illicit market would be a significant barrier to implementing a reduced-nicotine standard and are concerned that nicotine reduction will be viewed as a form of prohibition, giving rise to a black market similar to that during the US prohibition of alcohol.25,26 However, this analogy fails to recognize at least 1 important distinction: a reduced-nicotine standard will not prohibit smoking or nicotine use, but instead reduces nicotine content only in combusted products because they cause the most harm.27

A better analogy is lowering alcohol content in spirits associated with high-risk adverse health consequences, while allowing alcohol content to remain high in other spirits with lower risk. In essence, the reduced-nicotine standard would shape the market, motivating smokers to quit or switch to less harmful nicotine-containing products, without prohibiting the drug itself. Indeed, alternative nicotine-containing products (e.g., e-cigarettes) may help reduce the size of a potential illicit market under a reduced-nicotine standard.28 Our goal is to provide an analysis of the factors that will likely influence the development of an illicit market should the FDA proceed with establishing a low-nicotine product standard. Precisely estimating how many smokers will turn to an illicit market is beyond the scope of this essay. Rather, we present a framework that outlines the determinants of illicit supply and demand and suggest strategies that regulators could employ to reduce the risk of illicit trade in normal nicotine–content cigarettes.

ILLICIT TRADE SUPPLY CHAIN AND CONSUMER DEMAND

Modeled after reports by the US General Accounting Office and the National Academy of Science on illicit trade29,30 of untaxed or undertaxed cigarettes, Figure 1 shows the supply chain for the distribution of VLNC and normal nicotine–content tobacco products through the legal and illegal markets. If implemented, a reduced-nicotine standard would make it illegal for US manufacturers to distribute normal nicotine–content products in the domestic market. However, a manufacturer could legally export normal nicotine–content products for overseas distribution. These products could be diverted at export warehouses or exported and reimported into so-called gray market distribution. Legal VLNC products could be manufactured domestically or imported from other countries and ultimately reach retailers and consumers. Demand for normal nicotine products could provide incentives for illegal manufacturing of normal nicotine–content products. These products would likely be sold illegally through interpersonal (e.g., street) or Internet supply channels without exportation. Additionally, normal nicotine–content cigarettes could be imported (or purchased online from overseas vendors) and join the supply chain.

FIGURE 1—

FIGURE 1—

Opportunities to Divert Normal Nicotine–Content Combusted Products Into the Illicit Market

Note. VLNC = very low nicotine content.

Source. Adapted from General Accountability Office and National Academy of Science.29,30

Figure 2 is a conceptual model adapted from a report by the National Academy of Sciences on illicit trade.29 It illustrates the factors influencing smokers’ participation in the illicit market after implementation of a reduced-nicotine standard. Although product and brand characteristics (e.g., price, marketing, and taste), as well as user characteristics (e.g., demographics and degree of nicotine dependence), affect consumer demand for tobacco products, a reduced-nicotine standard would reduce the appeal and addictiveness of these combusted products. The model shows the supply and demand–based moderators that may influence a consumer’s propensity to engage in the illicit market or pursue other tobacco products.

FIGURE 2—

FIGURE 2—

Model of Factors Influencing Smoker’s Participation in the Illicit Market to Procure Normal Nicotine–Content Tobacco Products

Source. Adapted from the National Academy of Sciences.29

Several supply-side factors will affect the number and type of illicit tobacco products, the availability of legal alternative nicotine-containing products (e.g., e-cigarettes, medicinal nicotine), and the availability of VLNC products. These factors include enforcement efforts, policies, and the tobacco industry. These factors coupled with the demand-side factors (e.g., consumer acceptability of legal alternative nicotine-containing products, acceptability of illicit tobacco use, and appeal of VLNC products) will influence the behavioral changes resulting from a reduced-nicotine standard. Although illicit products would avoid taxation, other “costs” of procuring normal nicotine products will be higher because they are more inconvenient to purchase and are illegal. We propose 5 primary behavioral changes that current smokers could demonstrate:

  • 1.

    quit use of all tobacco products;

  • 2.

    completely switch to a legal alternative nicotine-containing product;

  • 3.

    exclusively use a VLNC product;

  • 4.

    use a combination of illicit normal nicotine–content products, legal VLNC products, or legal alternative nicotine-containing products; or

  • 5.

    completely switch to an illicit normal nicotine–content product.

From a public health standpoint, the first option—quitting—is, of course, the best. Although it will be difficult for some users, most smokers want to quit, and the lowered nicotine will facilitate quitting. Option 2 (e.g., using an e-cigarette or medicinal nicotine exclusively) is the next best option. Implementation of a reduced-nicotine standard would be a catalyst creating large economic incentives for manufacturers of e-cigarettes, other noncombusted products, and nicotine replacement therapies to promote their products to eager smokers looking for alternative products. Ensuring minimal youth uptake during this transition will be essential. Option 3 involves continued use of a combusted product, which is undesirable and is not likely to lead to a substantial public health benefit. Switching to illicit tobacco products along with other products (option 4) or exclusively using illicit products (option 5) will be deleterious to public health, especially if either is a common choice.

Factors that can discourage options 4 and 5 include the appeal, marketing, and pricing of VLNC options; the appeal, marketing, and pricing of alternative nicotine-containing legal products; and regulation and enforcement to control illicit tobacco products. Policymakers should ensure that alternative nicotine-containing products are available and are properly marketed and priced to promote substitution while minimizing uptake among youths.

Thoughtful marketing and pricing strategies can help smokers successfully transition to lower risk products. First, because many smokers think nicotine causes cancer, the misconception that smoking VLNC cigarettes will reduce the risk of cancer compared with smoking normal cigarettes must be rectified.31 Second, nearly 40% of US current or former smokers mistakenly believe that e-cigarettes are as or more harmful than cigarettes.32 In reality, completely switching to e-cigarettes from combusted cigarettes reduces exposure to toxicants and carcinogens founds in tobacco smoke, resulting in fewer short-term adverse health outcomes although unknown long-term outcomes.33 These misconceptions may contribute to interest in illicit tobacco products. Therefore, the FDA may want to implement a paid media campaign addressing misperceptions to complement their reduced-nicotine standard and promote cessation resources or complete switching to alternate products.

ILLICIT TRADE VIA THE INTERNET

One mechanism by which illicit normal nicotine products could be sold is the Internet. Cigarette sales have a long history of illicit trade via mail order. The 1949 Jenkins Act34 was originally established to require tax reporting for cross-border cigarette sales, allowing states to collect taxes from consumers buying cigarettes from states with lower excise tax rates. In 2002, the General Accounting Office found that 195 Internet cigarette vendors (ICVs) failed to comply with the Jenkins Act35 when selling to US customers. Two years later, the number of ICVs peaked at 775, before federal agreements with credit card companies and shippers were implemented. During this peak, 78% of ICVs advertised their noncompliance with tax laws.36 Additionally, 95% of Internet sales failed to properly verify the age of purchasers to prevent sales to minors.37

With a wide variety of cheap tobacco products available online, ICVs were an easy alternative source of tobacco products for those seeking to skirt cigarette minimum age policies and high excise taxes. For instance, a pack-a-day smoker could save more than $1500 annually by buying cigarettes online compared with buying them in a high-tax jurisdiction, such as New York City.38 If the reduced-nicotine product standard is implemented, both the lure of cheap cigarettes online and the availability of illicit regular nicotine–content products could stimulate demand, leading to a resurgence of the ICV market, which was substantially hampered through recent US regulations described in the next paragraph.39

Internet sales are notoriously difficult to regulate because of the evasiveness of Internet vendors and the thorny jurisdictional issues, whereby the customer, Web site, business, and delivery site may each reside in different states or countries. The Quarantine of Unhealthy Internet Trade framework40 was proposed to regulate Internet sales by severing the relationship between noncompliant Internet vendors and the companies that help them sell and ship their products to their customers (e.g., Web hosts, payment processors, shippers). In 2005, the federal government and state attorneys general implemented aspects of the Quarantine of Unhealthy Internet Trade framework by convincing credit card companies (e.g., Visa, PayPal), UPS, FedEx, and DHL to voluntarily agree to stop being a party to illicit Internet cigarette sales transactions.41–44 Before the payment and shipping bans, the 50 most popular ICVs had, on average, approximately 36 000 visits per month. In the year following the bans, monthly traffic dropped to fewer than 8000 visits per month, and 61.8% of ICVs went out of business.45 This demonstrates that it is possible to regulate Internet sales and reduce the flow of illicit tobacco products.

Unfortunately, the highly adaptable ICVs switched to unbanned shipping and payment methods.45,46 A loophole in the agreements allowed the US Postal Service to continue shipping products, and payment methods like e-checks, wire transfers, and PayPal-like services were not banned. In response, the US Congress passed the Prevent All Cigarette Trafficking (PACT) Act in 2009,47 adding the US Postal Service to the list of banned shippers, requiring rigorous age verification for Internet cigarette sales, and providing a framework for enforcing the Jenkins Act and collecting taxes from ICV customers. Before PACT, lack of enforcement had resulted in little initial change in ICV sales practices38; eventually nearly all ICVs moved overseas (while still targeting US customers) or went out of business.39

Other types of illicit tobacco products sold online are formerly legal products that are now restricted by the FDA. In 2009, the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Control Act1 prohibited the sale of flavored cigarettes (other than menthol) and of cigarettes labeled with misleading descriptors (e.g., “light”). Despite the new law, a significant proportion of ICVs continued to sell these prohibited light and flavored products. Many of these ICVs were based internationally, but that did not matter because they are still accessible to US consumers.48 Google searches for the banned Djarum clove-flavored cigarettes remained twice as high as the nonbanned Djarum flavored cigars 3 years after the ban. This demonstrates some consumers’ enduring interest in searching for and purchasing banned products online.49 To our knowledge, the prevalence of purchasing these banned products from online sources is unknown.

Considering that many Internet tobacco vendors have sold banned or restricted products, it seems likely that they will attempt to sell normal nicotine–content cigarettes to US customers if the FDA mandates VLNC combusted tobacco products. Therefore, policymakers must effectively restrict online sales of normal nicotine products from US and international sources as well as expand PACT to include all regular nicotine combusted products. Better enforcement of PACT to ban delivery of cigarettes to consumers is 1 way to thwart ICVs. For example, effective package screening to detect cigarettes, particularly in packages delivered from overseas, could substantially affect the illicit supply chain of normal nicotine–content cigarettes. Lessons learned from previous studies of the ICV industry include regularly surveilling the sales and marketing practices of Internet vendors, restricting shipping and payment options for vendors, and conducting regular enforcement through monitoring Web site content and conducting test purchases.

ILLICIT TRADE AND TAX AVOIDANCE

Because most illicit trade for tobacco products is related to taxation, we reviewed the similarities and differences between what is known about tax-related illicit trade and potential reduced nicotine content–related trade. Although raising tobacco taxes is 1 of the most effective ways to reduce tobacco use,50–52 it may also lead to compensatory behaviors aimed at circumventing tax increases through both licit (i.e., tax avoidance) and illicit (i.e., tax evasion) channels.50,51 Tax avoidance activities include purchasing tobacco products in other jurisdictions (e.g., cross-border shopping) in amounts allowable under tax laws and stockpiling. Tax evasion and illicit trade involve transporting or purchasing smuggled and illegally manufactured tobacco products (both genuine tobacco products diverted through illegal channels and counterfeit products).

The extent to which compensatory behaviors may undermine the public health benefits of raising tobacco taxes is largely determined by the prevalence of tax avoidance and evasion behaviors. The reduced-nicotine standard, if implemented, is unlikely to create cross-border purchase within the United States because it will be at the federal level. However, cross-border purchase could occur in areas that share a border with Canada and Mexico. The extent that large-scale smuggled and illegally manufactured normal nicotine–content cigarettes could occur will be largely determined by law enforcement and penalties associated with these behaviors.

Several measures have been used to estimate the extent of tobacco tax avoidance and evasion, including collecting littered cigarette packs from sidewalks and trash cans, examining cigarette packs in face-to-face interviews with smokers, and asking smokers to submit their empty cigarette packs to researchers. In the United States, researchers collected littered cigarette packs in high-tax jurisdictions, such as Chicago, Illinois, and New York City, to assess the extent of tax avoidance and evasion. They found that about 75% of cigarette packs collected in Chicago lacked the proper tax stamp.53

However, this overestimates the extent of tax avoidance and evasion among Chicago residents, because it includes the large numbers of daily visitors in Chicago who may have purchased their cigarettes elsewhere. After the state cigarette excise tax rate increased from $1.50 to $2.75, researchers found that tax avoidance in New York City increased from 15% to 24%, as measured by the percentage of littered packs without a New York tax stamp.54 Examining littered cigarette packs as a way to determine tax evasion has also been used in France55 and Poland.56 Other measure of illicit trade related to higher tobacco taxes are examining discrepancies between imports and exports57 and between sales and consumptions,58 as well as survey-59 and model-based57,60 methods. These same methods can be applied to estimate the potential size of the illicit market attributable to the reduced-nicotine standard.

In 2007, illicit cigarettes accounted for an estimated 11.6% of cigarette consumption in 84 countries.61 Also in 2007, the National Academy of Medicine estimated that between 8.5% and 21.0% of the total cigarette market in the United States was accounted for by illicit sales.29 Estimates of the potential size of the illicit market for regular content cigarettes under a reduced-nicotine standard are not available. Although tobacco tax and price differences across jurisdictions incentivize tobacco tax avoidance and evasion behaviors,57,62–64 research has demonstrated that tobacco tax evasion was largely attributable to weak governance, corruption, lack of control of authorities, ineffective tax and customs administration, complex tax structures, loopholes in tobacco tax systems, weak control of illicit trade, and lack of enforcement and strong penalties.57,65–68

Countries that strengthened their governance, tax administration, control of illicit trade, and law enforcement have seen large declines in tobacco tax avoidance and evasion.29,51,69 Although the implementation and strengthening of these measures have financial costs, the resulting economic and public health benefits outweigh those costs. For example, in the 10 years following the implementation and upgrading of California’s encrypted cigarette tax stamp, California recovered an estimated $450 million in additional tax revenue, which well exceeded implementation and enforcement costs.29 A similar pattern was observed in Massachusetts after implementing an encrypted cigarette stamp in 2010.70 Similarly, strong governance, effective administration, strong control of illicit trade, and strong enforcement and penalties will reduce the likelihood that an illicit market could occur after a reduced-nicotine standard is implemented; these measures will also reduce the size of the potential illicit market.

CONCLUSIONS

Although a new FDA product standard to reduce nicotine levels in cigarettes and other combusted tobacco products would reduce tobacco use and related harms, the extent to which smokers would be motivated and able to obtain illicit regular nicotine content products would reduce those gains. A large body of research has demonstrated that raising tobacco taxes reduces tobacco use and that tax avoidance and evasion diminishes but does not eliminate the beneficial impact of these taxes.51,71 Research on factors that affect both the supply and demand of illicit combusted tobacco products offers valuable lessons for the FDA and other regulators outside the United States considering lowering the nicotine content of combusted tobacco products. From the supply side, the federal government and law enforcement agencies can reduce the supply of illicit combusted tobacco products through coordinated and stronger law enforcement efforts (e.g., better screening of packages and purchase operations), improved tax stamp technology (e.g., encrypted tax stamps29), and higher penalties for engaging in illicit trade.

If a large illicit supply chain were to develop, it should be apparent to enforcement authorities, who could swiftly address it. Additionally, the government could implement measures, such as developing a tracking and tracing system for all tobacco products from seeds to sale (as is done with marijuana in many states); licensing those involved in tobacco product manufacturing or distribution, as well as those involved in the manufacturing or distribution of the machinery used to produce tobacco products; and strengthening control measures in international free trade zones and for tobacco products in international transit. From the demand side, the government can use tobacco tax and other policy options to increase smokers’ access to and use of alternative nicotine-containing products, thereby reducing the demand for illicit combusted tobacco products. At the same time, to reduce the potential uptake of these alternative products among youths, several policies could be considered, including, but not limited to, policies that reduce their appeal (e.g., restricting e-cigarette flavors or marketing), public education campaigns, and excise taxes.

On the basis of research reviewed in previous sections for minimizing tax evasion and illicit trade online and through retail channels, several methods for controlling an illicit market for normal nicotine–content combusted tobacco products could inform the FDA if they require US cigarette manufacturers to market only VLNC cigarettes in the United States. The 5 key lessons for the United States and other countries considering implementing a reduced-nicotine standard are as follows:

  • 1.

    Implement a robust track and trace system for all combusted tobacco products that includes encrypted tax stamps and other product markings on tobacco packages.

  • 2.

    Strengthen and enforce regulations prohibiting online payment processing and shipping options for Internet tobacco vendors.

  • 3.

    Require licenses for those involved in the tobacco manufacturing and distribution chain, conduct regular compliance testing and enforcement operations to curtail illicit manufacturing, and strengthen penalties for engaging in illicit trade.

  • 4.

    Apply the reduced-nicotine standard to cigarettes and all other combusted products, because of their high toxicity, to deter smokers from substituting little cigars and other products for VLNC cigarettes.

  • 5.

    Ensure that both smoking cessation treatments and alternative nicotine-containing products (e.g., e-cigarettes) are readily available, priced at a lower rate than combusted products but high enough that it prevents uptake among youths, and are appealing to smokers but not youths.

The FDA and other stakeholders should consider these recommendations to minimize the potential size of an illicit trade of tobacco products under a reduced-nicotine standard. Not implementing these or other strategies could allow the illicit market to develop and flourish, and the great public health benefit of VLNC products will not be fully realized. Fortunately, decades of experience in regulating the sales, taxation, and marketing of tobacco products can inform strategies to minimize an illicit market and increase the likelihood of a successful implementation of a reduced-nicotine product standard.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

Research reported in this publication was supported by the National Cancer Institute (NCI) and the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) Center for Tobacco Products (grant P50CA180907), the National Institute of Drug Abuse (NIDA; grant U54 DA031659), the NIDA and the FDA (grant P50DA036128), and the NCI (grant R01CA169189).

We thank Tracey Fine, MS, for editing the essay.

Note. The content is solely the responsibility of the authors and does not necessarily represent the official views of the National Institutes of Health or the FDA.

CONFLICTS OF INTEREST

K. M. Ribisl has served as an expert consultant in litigation against cigarette manufacturers and Internet tobacco vendors. R. S. Williams has served as an expert consultant in litigation against delivery services shipping products to Internet tobacco vendors.

HUMAN PARTICIPANT PROTECTION

No protocol approval was necessary because there were no human participants in this study.

Footnotes

See also Lindblom, p. 960.

REFERENCES

  • 1.111th US Congress, US General Accounting Office. HR 1256: Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Control Act. 2009. [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Benowitz NL, Henningfield JE. Establishing a nicotine threshold for addiction. The implications for tobacco regulation. N Engl J Med. 1994;331(2):123–125. doi: 10.1056/NEJM199407143310212. [Comment in Regulation of the nicotine content of cigarettes. N Engl J Med. 1994] [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Food and Drug Administration. Tobacco product standard for nicotine level of combusted cigarettes, a proposed rule by the Food and Drug Administration on 03/16/2018. Fed Regist. 2018:26619–26620. [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Benowitz NL, Henningfield JE. Reducing the nicotine content to make cigarettes less addictive. Tob Control. 2013;22(suppl 1):i14–i17. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2012-050860. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Hatsukami DK, Perkins KA, Lesage MG et al. Nicotine reduction revisited: science and future directions. Tob Control. 2010;19(5):e1–e10. doi: 10.1136/tc.2009.035584. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Donny EC, Denlinger RL, Tidey JW et al. Randomized trial of reduced-nicotine standards for cigarettes. N Engl J Med. 2015;373(14):1340–1349. doi: 10.1056/NEJMsa1502403. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Hatsukami DK, Kotlyar M, Hertsgaard LA et al. Reduced nicotine content cigarettes: effects on toxicant exposure, dependence and cessation. Addiction. 2010;105(2):343–355. doi: 10.1111/j.1360-0443.2009.02780.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Benowitz NL, Dains KM, Hall SM et al. Smoking behavior and exposure to tobacco toxicants during 6 months of smoking progressively reduced nicotine content cigarettes. Cancer Epidemiol Biomarkers Prev. 2012;21(5):761–769. doi: 10.1158/1055-9965.EPI-11-0644. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Donny EC, Hatsukami DK, Benowitz NL, Sved AF, Tidey JW, Cassidy RN. Reduced nicotine product standards for combustible tobacco: building an empirical basis for effective regulation. Prev Med. 2014;68:17–22. doi: 10.1016/j.ypmed.2014.06.020. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Hatsukami DK, Luo X, Jensen JA et al. Effect of immediate vs gradual reduction in nicotine content of cigarettes on biomarkers of smoke exposure. JAMA. 2018;320(9):880–891. doi: 10.1001/jama.2018.11473. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Hatsukami DK, Benowitz NL, Donny E, Henningfield J, Zeller M. Nicotine reduction: strategic research plan. Nicotine Tob Res. 2013;15(6):1003–1013. doi: 10.1093/ntr/nts214. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Tengs TO, Ahmad S, Savage JM, Moore R, Gage E. The AMA proposal to mandate nicotine reduction in cigarettes: a simulation of the population health impacts. Prev Med. 2005;40(2):170–180. doi: 10.1016/j.ypmed.2004.05.017. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Apelberg BJ, Feirman SP, Salazar E et al. Potential public health effects of reducing nicotine levels in cigarettes in the United States. N Engl J Med. 2018;378(18):1725–1733. doi: 10.1056/NEJMsr1714617. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Gammon DG, Loomis BR, Dench DL, King BA, Fulmer EB, Rogers T. Effect of price changes in little cigars and cigarettes on little cigar sales: USA, Q4 2011-Q4 2013. Tob Control. 2016;25(5):538–544. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2015-052343. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Casseus M, Garmon J, Hrywna M, Delnevo CD. Cigarette smokers’ classification of tobacco products. Tob Control. 2016;25(6):628–630. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2015-052535. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Huang J, Gwarnicki C, Xu X, Caraballo RS, Wada R, Chaloupka FJ. A comprehensive examination of own- and cross-price elasticities of tobacco and nicotine replacement products in the. U.S. Prev Med. 2018;pii:S0091-7435(0018)30135-X. doi: 10.1016/j.ypmed.2018.04.024. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Hatsukami DK, Donny EC. The debate about nicotine addiction and the role of medicinal products: commentary on Zeller. Nicotine Tob Res. 2019;21(3):338–339. doi: 10.1093/ntr/nty195. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Risks Associated With Smoking Cigarettes With Low Machine-Measured Yields of Tar and Nicotine Bethesda, MD: US National Cancer Institute; 2001NIH publication, no. 02-5047 [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Kozlowski LT, O’Connor RJ. Cigarette filter ventilation is a defective design because of misleading taste, bigger puffs, and blocked vents. Tob Control. 2002;11(suppl 1):i40–i50. doi: 10.1136/tc.11.suppl_1.i40. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.MacQueen DA, Heckman BW, Blank MD, Janse Van Rensburg K, Evans DE, Drobes DJ. Transient compensatory smoking in response to placebo cigarettes. Psychopharmacology (Berl) 2012;223(1):47–54. doi: 10.1007/s00213-012-2685-1. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Donny EC, Houtsmuller E, Stitzer ML. Smoking in the absence of nicotine: behavioral, subjective and physiological effects over 11 days. Addiction. 2007;102(2):324–334. doi: 10.1111/j.1360-0443.2006.01670.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Hatsukami DK, Donny EC, Koopmeiners JS, Benowitz NL. Compensatory smoking from gradual and immediate reduction in cigarette nicotine content. Cancer Epidemiol Biomarkers Prev. 2015;24(2):472–476. doi: 10.1158/1055-9965.EPI-14-0739. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Nardone N, Donny EC, Hatsukami DK et al. Estimations and predictors of non-compliance in switchers to reduced nicotine content cigarettes. Addiction. 2016;111(12):2208–2216. doi: 10.1111/add.13519. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Hatsukami DK, Luo X, Dick L et al. Reduced nicotine content cigarettes and use of alternative nicotine products: exploratory trial. Addiction. 2017;112(1):156–167. doi: 10.1111/add.13603. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Kozlowski LT. Cigarette prohibition and the need for more prior testing of the WHO TobReg’s global nicotine-reduction strategy. Tob Control. 2016;26(e1):e31–e34. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2016-052995. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Bates C. The tobacco endgame: a critique of policy proposals aimed at ending tobacco use. 2015. Available at: http://www.clivebates.com/documents/endgame.pdf. Accessed April 22, 2019.
  • 27.Hatsukami DK, Zaatari G, Donny E. The case for the WHO advisory note, global nicotine reduction strategy. Tob Control. 2017;26(e1):e29–e30. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2016-053134. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Benowitz NL, Donny EC, Hatsukami DK. Reduced nicotine content cigarettes, e-cigarettes and the cigarette end game. Addiction. 2017;112(1):6–7. doi: 10.1111/add.13534. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.National Research Council; Institute of Medicine. Understanding the U.S. Illicit Tobacco Market: Characteristics, Policy Context, and Lessons From International Experiences. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; 2015. [Google Scholar]
  • 30.US Government Accountability Office. Illicit tobacco: various schemes are used to evade taxes and fees. Available at: https://www.gao.gov/assets/320/316372.pdf. 2011. Accessed April 22, 2019.
  • 31.Byron MJ, Jeong M, Abrams DB, Brewer NT. Public misperception that very low nicotine cigarettes are less carcinogenic. Tob Control. 2018 doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2017-054124. pii: tobaccocontrol-2017-054124. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Majeed BA, Weaver SR, Gregory KR et al. Changing perceptions of harm of e-cigarettes among U.S. adults, 2012–2015. Am J Prev Med. 2017;52(3):331–338. doi: 10.1016/j.amepre.2016.08.039. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Stratton KR, Kwan LY, Eaton DL. Public Health Consequences of E-Cigarettes: A Consensus Study Report of the National Academies of Sciences, Health, Medicine. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; 2018. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34. The Jenkins Act. Pub L No. 364, 63 Stat. 994 (1949).
  • 35.Internet Cigarette Sales: Giving ATF Investigative Authority May Improve Reporting and Enforcement. Washington, DC: US General Accounting Office; 2002. GAO-02-743. [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Internet Cigarette Sales: Limited Compliance and Enforcement of the Jenkins Act Result in Loss of State Tax Revenue. Washington, DC: US General Accounting Office; 2002. GAO-03-714T. [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Ribisl KM, Williams RS, Kim AK. Internet sales of cigarettes to minors. JAMA. 2003;290(10):1356–1359. doi: 10.1001/jama.290.10.1356. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 38.Hall MG, Williams RS, Gammon DG, Ribisl KM. Internet cigarette vendors make tax-free claims and sell cigarettes cheaper than retail outlets. Tob Control. 2015;25(6):616–618. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2015-052359. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Williams RS, Derrick J, Phillips KJ. Cigarette sales to minors via the Internet: how the story has changed in the wake of federal regulation. Tob Control. 2016;26(4):415–420. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2015-052844. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Ribisl KM, Kim AE, Williams RS. Sales and marketing of cigarettes on the Internet: emerging threats to tobacco control and promising policy solutions. In: Bonnie RJ, Stratton K, Wallace RB, editors. Ending the Tobacco Problem: A Blueprint for the Nation. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; 2007. pp. M1–M27. [Google Scholar]
  • 41. Attorney General of the State of New York Health Care Bureau. In the Matter of United Parcel Service: Assurance of Discontinuance. 2005. Available at: http://www.ag.ny.gov/sites/default/files/press-releases/archived/9tiupsaodfinal.oct.pdf. Accessed April 22, 2019.
  • 42. Attorney General of the State of New York Health Care Bureau. In the Matter of DHL Holdings USA, and DHL Express (USA): Assurance of Discontinuance. 2005. Available at: http://www.ag.ny.gov/sites/default/files/press-releases/archived/dhlaogfinal.pdf. Accessed January 15, 2015.
  • 43. Attorney General of the State of New York Health Care Bureau. In the Matter of Federal Express Corporation, and FedEx Ground Package Systems: Assurance of Compliance. 2006. Available at: https://ag.ny.gov/sites/default/files/press-releases/archived/FedEx%20-%20Executed%20AOC.pdf. Accessed April 22, 2019.
  • 44. Alt Powell E. Deal aims to prevent Web cigarette sales. New York, NY: Associated Press; 2005.
  • 45.Ribisl KM, Williams RS, Gizlice Z, Herring AH. Effectiveness of state and federal government agreements with major credit card and shipping companies to block illegal Internet cigarette sales. PLoS One. 2011;6(2):e16754. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0016754. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Williams RS, Ribisl KM. Internet cigarette vendor compliance with credit card payment and shipping bans. Nicotine Tob Res. 2013;16(2):243–246. doi: 10.1093/ntr/ntt159. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 47. 111th US Congress. Prevent All Cigarette Trafficking Act of 2009 (PACT Act). Vol Public Law 111-154, S. 1147 2010.
  • 48.Jo CL, Williams RS, Ribisl KM. Tobacco products sold by Internet vendors following restrictions on flavors and light descriptors. Nicotine Tob Res. 2015;17(3):344–349. doi: 10.1093/ntr/ntu167. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Allem JP, Ayers JW, Althouse BM, Williams R. When a ban really is not a ban: Internet loopholes and Djarum flavoured cigarettes in the USA. Tob Control. 2015;25(4):489–490. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2015-052309. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.IARC Handbook of Cancer Prevention Volume 14: Effectiveness of Tax and Price Policies for Tobacco Control. Lyon, France: International Agency for Research on Cancer; 2011. [Google Scholar]
  • 51.US National Cancer Institute; World Health Organization. The Economics of Tobacco and Tobacco Control. Bethesda, MD: Department of Health and Human Services; NIH publication; 2017. no. 16-CA-8029A. [Google Scholar]
  • 52.WHO Report on the Global Tobacco Epidemic, 2017: Monitoring Tobacco Use and Prevention Policies Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Organization; 2017 [Google Scholar]
  • 53.Merriman D. The micro-geography of tax avoidance: evidence from littered cigarette packs in Chicago. Am Econ J Econ Policy. 2010;2(2):61–84. [Google Scholar]
  • 54.Chernick H, Merriman D. Using littered pack data to estimate cigarette tax avoidance in NYC. Natl Tax J. 2013;66(3):635–668. [Google Scholar]
  • 55.Lakhdar CB. Quantitative and qualitative estimates of cross-border tobacco shopping and tobacco smuggling in France. Tob Control. 2008;17(1):12–16. doi: 10.1136/tc.2007.020891. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 56.Stoklosa M, Ross H. Contrasting academic and tobacco industry estimates of illicit cigarette trade: evidence from Warsaw, Poland. Tob Control. 2014;23(e1):e30–e34. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2013-051099. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 57.Merriman D, Yurekli A, Chaloupka F. How big is the worldwide cigarette smuggling problem? In: Jha P, Chaloupka F, editors. Tobacco Control in Developing Countries. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press; 2000. pp. 365–392. [Google Scholar]
  • 58.Report to Congress on Federal Tobacco Receipts Lost Due to Illicit Trade and Recommendations for Increased Enforcement. Washington, DC: US Department of the Treasury; 2010. [Google Scholar]
  • 59.Guindon GE, Driezen P, Chaloupka FJ, Fong GT. Cigarette tax avoidance and evasion: findings from the International Tobacco Control Policy Evaluation (ITC) Project. Tob Control. 2014;23(suppl 1):i13–i22. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2013-051074. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 60.Thursby J, Thursby M. Interstate cigarette bootlegging: extent, revenue losses, and effects of federal intervention. Natl Tax J. 2000;53(1):59–78. [Google Scholar]
  • 61.Joossens L, Merriman D, Ross H, Raw M. How Eliminating the Global Illicit Cigarette Trade Would Increase Tax Revenue and Save Lives. Paris, France: International Union Against Tuberculosis and Lung Disease; 2009. [Google Scholar]
  • 62.Baltagi B, Levin D. Estimating dynamic demand for cigarettes using panel data: the effects of bootlegging, taxation and advertising reconsidered. Rev Econ Stat. 1986;68(1):148–155. [Google Scholar]
  • 63.Farrelly MC, Nimsch CT, James J. State cigarette excise taxes: implications for revenue and tax evasion. 2003. Available at: http://www.rti.org/pubs/8742_Excise_Taxes_FR_5-03.pdf. Accessed April 22, 2019.
  • 64.Yurekli AA, Zhang P. The impact of clean indoor-air laws and cigarette smuggling on demand for cigarettes: an empirical model. Health Econ. 2000;9(2):159–170. doi: 10.1002/(sici)1099-1050(200003)9:2<159::aid-hec499>3.0.co;2-t. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 65.Haidinjak M. Smuggling in Southeast Europe: The Yugoslav Wars and the Development of Regional Criminal Networks in the Balkans. Sofia, Bulgaria: Center for the Study of Democracy; 2002. [Google Scholar]
  • 66.Joossens L, Raw M. From cigarette smuggling to illicit tobacco trade. Tob Control. 2012;21(2):230–234. doi: 10.1136/tobaccocontrol-2011-050205. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 67.Shelley LI, Melzer SA. Nexus of organized crime and terrorism: two case studies in cigarette smuggling. Int J Comp Appl Crim Justice. 2008;32(1):43–63. [Google Scholar]
  • 68.Titeca K, Joossens L, Raw M. Blood cigarettes: cigarette smuggling and war economies in central and eastern Africa. Tob Control. 2011;20(3):226–232. doi: 10.1136/tc.2010.041574. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 69.Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Preventing and reducing illicit tobacco trade: preventing and reducing illicit tobacco trade in the United States. 2015. Available at: https://www.cdc.gov/tobacco/stateandcommunity/pdfs/illicit-trade-report-121815-508tagged.pdf. Accessed April 22, 2019.
  • 70.Report of Commission on Illegal Tobacco on the Illegal Tobacco Market and Resulting Loss of Revenue in the Commonwealth of Massachusetts. Boston, MA: Massachusetts Commission on Illegal Tobacco; 2014. [Google Scholar]
  • 71.Merriman D. Cigarette smuggling does not reduce the public health benefits of cigarette taxes. Appl Econ Lett. 2002;9(8):493–496. [Google Scholar]

Articles from American Journal of Public Health are provided here courtesy of American Public Health Association

RESOURCES