Skip to main content
Scientific Reports logoLink to Scientific Reports
. 2019 Aug 1;9:11202. doi: 10.1038/s41598-019-47697-1

The Heider balance and the looking-glass self: modelling dynamics of social relations

Małgorzata J Krawczyk 1, Maciej Wołoszyn 1, Piotr Gronek 1, Krzysztof Kułakowski 1,, Janusz Mucha 2
PMCID: PMC6671965  PMID: 31371775

Abstract

We consider the dynamics of interpersonal relations which leads to balanced states in a fully connected network. Here this approach is applied to directed networks with asymmetric relations, and it is generalized to include self-evaluation of actors, according to the ‘looking-glass self’ theory. A new index of self-acceptance is proposed: the relation of an actor to him/herself is positive, if the majority of his/her positive relations to others are reciprocated. Sets of stable configurations of relations are obtained under the dynamics, where the self-evaluation of some actors is negative. Within each set all configurations have the same structure.

Subject terms: Applied mathematics; Statistical physics, thermodynamics and nonlinear dynamics

Introduction

Graphs are known as convenient mathematical representation of social networks for long time13. In most applications, unweighted links have been used, with the only option that a link is present or not between each pair of nodes. Weak and strong links have been famously distinguished by Mark Granovetter4,5; the difference was motivated by their roles in diffusion of information. Directed networks seem to be a natural next step in construction of sociological models, in particular when dealing with conflicts, social inequality and violence69. Yet asymmetric social relations have been modeled relatively rarely1014.

Here we are interested in computational modeling of structural balance, which is a canonical example of an application of graphs in social science15. Briefly, the balance theory has been formulated by Fritz Heider in terms of positive and negative relations in triads16,17. Soon, a network of balanced triads has been shown to be equivalent to a balanced network18. This step has enabled applications of concepts of statistical mechanics, where signed links were equivalent to spin-like variables, and the number of unbalanced triads to energy. Stochastic algorithms designed to locate energy minima have been applied to social networks19,20. Besides global minima, equivalent to the structural balance, unbalanced stationary states have been identified19, hereafter called ‘jammed’ or ‘glassy’ states19,2123.

On the other hand, the concept of balanced triads has found a psychological support in terms of cognitive dissonance24. While most of works have been concentrated on the case of symmetric relations, where negative and positive relations towards each other are always reciprocated, some papers have dealt also with the asymmetric case21,25. Although asymmetric relations are established in social modeling26,27, their consequences for the structural balance are not fully explored. Here we intend to classify jammed states according to the network structure. Instead of stochastic algorithms19,20, we intend to apply a set of differential equations28,29 which is supposed to drive the system to a stationary state most close to the initial state. In most cases, jammed states are obtained21; this is the main difference with respect to algorithms of simulated annealing, a standard method formulated as to reach a global minimum of energy30. Although some jammed states are possible also for symmetric case19, for asymmetric relations they are generic21.

Our aim here is twofold. First, we are looking for generic jammed states of networks; such states are asymmetric counterparts of the structurally balanced state15. This task is far from trivial; it can be compared to a classification of stationary states of a neural network, where the mutual influence of neurons can be asymmetric31,32, or to a classification of stationary states of a Boolean network33 with asymmetric actions of genes. This comparison highlights that our problem belongs to a general family defined as: given the network evolution, find a classification of the fixed points. In our case, the solution is obtained by means of an original algorithm of classification of states of complex systems, worked out in34,35. Up to now, the algorithm has been applied successfully to Ising and Potts systems of spins, traffic systems, polymer chains, elementary cellular automata, Hubbard rings and Boolean networks; for details we refer to35. Here the algorithm is applied for the first time to signed and directed, fully connected networks. Our second aim is more specific and it is related to social relations. Namely, we are able to identify nodes in the network where outgoing positive links are accompanied with negative links from other nodes. Inferring from the Cooley theory of self-looking glass36, we claim that such a state of a node is equivalent to low self-evaluation.

In the next section we highlight sociological roots of the self-evaluation, based on social relations. In section 3 we clarify the role of the directions of links in the network triads. In two subsequent sections the scheme of calculation is described and the main results are given. The last but one section is devoted to discussion, where we demonstrate that our generic results are reproduced when sociometric data from literature are used. Short remarks on the applied numerical method close the text.

Self-Evaluation by Cooley

The issue of ‘social relations’ is, naturally, one of foundations of sociology (including microsociology) and social psychology. Broadly understood ‘interpretative social sciences’ concentrate on proving that human attitudes (including emotions) and behaviors are reactions to the self-perceptions and self-images of the actors and their perceptions and images of their partners (human and non-human) rather than reactions to ‘objective’ human and non-human objects, processes and situations. Charles H. Cooley’s contribution (see, e.g.36) is particularly significant in this context. His work is very influential until today in the broadly understood ‘symbolic interactionism’ (see, e.g.3740), in social psychology (see, e.g.41,42), in ‘sociology of individuals’ (see, e.g.43,44), even if practitioners of the latter do not quote Cooley directly. The influence of American classic’s version of symbolic interactionism on today’s ‘sociology of emotions’ (see, e.g.45) is highly visible. In this article, Cooley, as the founding father of original concepts and hypotheses still applied in various fields of social sciences, is a major source of inspiration.

Famous studies authored by Cooley were based on his analysis and interpretation of belles-lettres (particularly William Shakespeare’s dramas) and his observations of social (including emotional) relations within his immediate family, mostly between his children. If a boy […] has any success, […] he gloats over it […]. He is eager to call in his friends […], saying to them, ‘See what I am doing! Is it not remarkable?’ feeling elated when it is praised, and resentful or humiliated when fault is found with it (36, p. 178).

Let us quote a significant piece of Cooley’s book ‘Human Nature and the Social Order’: A self-idea […] seems to have three principal elements: the imagination of our appearance to the other person; the imagination of his judgment of that appearance, and some sort of self-feeling, such as pride or mortification. […] The thing that moves us to pride or shame is not the mere mechanical reflection of ourselves, but an imputed sentiment, the imagined effect of this reflection upon another’s mind. This is evident from the fact that the character and weight of that other, in whose mind we see ourselves, makes all the difference with our feeling. We are ashamed to seem evasive in the presence of a straightforward man, cowardly in the presence of a brave one, gross in the eyes of a refined one, and so on. We always imagine, and in imagining share, the judgments of the other mind. A man will boast to one person of an action - say some sharp transaction in trade - which he would be ashamed to own to another (36, pp. 184-5).

From a sociological perspective, our results indicate that negative self-evaluations come from unreciprocated relations. We dare say that this statement links the concept of Heider balance with the idea of ‘looking-glass self’ of C. H. Cooley (36, p.152). Sometimes reported in the form of an aphorism: each to each a looking glass/ reflects the other that doth pass36, the idea highlights the role of society in formation of human identity. Namely, opinion of an individual on herself/himself is formed by perceived opinions of other people.

Equations of Motion

Consider a fully connected network of N nodes and K = N(N − 1) links between them, xij = ±1. If links are set to be symmetric (xij = xji), the condition of structural balance is that for each triad (i, j, k) of nodes the links between them obey the rule xijxjkxki = +1. It is known18, that in this case the whole network is split in two parts, where xij = +1 if nodes i, j belong to the same part, otherwise xij = −1. This split is termed as ‘structural balance’ or ‘Heider balance’ (HB). Putting this in terms of friendly and hostile relations, all relations within each group are friendly, and all relations between groups are hostile. This means in particular, that the hostile relation is not transitive: an enemy of my enemy is my friend.

If the link variables xij are allowed to be real, the following set of differential equations of time evolution leads generically to HB28,29:

dxijdt=(1xij2)kN2xikxkj 1

where k ≠ i, k ≠ j in the sum. The rationale of Eq. (1) is as follows. Once k is either a common friend of i and j or their common enemy, the product xikxkj is positive and contributes to an increase of xij in time. On the other hand, if k is a friend of i but an enemy of j (or the opposite), the product xikxkj is negative and contributes to a decrease of xij. The factor 1xij2 keeps the relation xij in the finite range [−1, +1]; this is the price we pay for the lack of analytical solution of Eq. (1) 29. We note that discrete algorithms leading to HB have been formulated also for the symmetric case19,20.

When the condition of symmetry is released, the order of indices does matter. Basically, the inference of actor i about her/his relation to j could be modeled in several ways of ordering; several possible types of directed and signed triads have been considered10,11,4648. Our choice to keep the ordering as in Eq. (1)21,25 is driven by the lack of transitivity, mentioned above. In terms of social relations, the question on transitivity2 is: once actor A wonders about his feeling about B, how important is that A dislikes C and C dislikes B? We can imagine that the issue is less important when B is a product11, on the contrary to the case when B is an enemy or a friend. We note also that another ordering xikxjk, symmetric vs an exchange i and j, would drive the system to symmetric relations, and therefore is out of interest here. Finally, we should add that we treat the character of all relations as known to all actors, what is appropriate only when dealing with small groups; more general picture has been discussed by Carley and Krackhardt10.

The index Fi of self-evaluation of each actor (i = 1, 2, ..., N) is calculated as

Fi=12k(1+xik)xki. 2

This form of Fi is appropriate as long as we are interested only in the opinions of actors k liked by i (xik = +1); those whom i dislikes (xik = −1) do not contribute to Fi. Here we are motivated by the concept od significant others49. Basically, −N < Fi < N.

Calculations

Some initial configurations lead to balanced states which are necessarily symmetric. In a symmetric state Fi ≥ 0 for each actor i; Fi is just the number of friends of i, and this friendship is reciprocated. Some others lead to asymmetric states, which cannot be balanced; here we are interested in those states where Fi < 0 for some actors i. Among those liked by her/him, such an actor has more enemies than friends; Fi is just the difference between friends and enemies of this kind.

At this stage, the outcome of the calculation is a set of K(N) matrices xij. We prefer to keep N odd to evade the cases where the right side of Eq. (1) is equal to zero in a stationary state. We have got results for K = 104 for each N = 7, 9, 11, 41, 55 and 77; for N = 99, the dynamic system is found to be less stable numerically. For each N, the matrices are classified as equivalent to unlabeled graphs of classes of nodes. In short, the algorithm is as follows34,35:

  1. for each node i, the number M(i) of nodes is found such that xim = +1, and the number L(i) of nodes is found such that xli = +1;

  2. nodes of the same M, L are provisionally classified as belonging to the same class;

  3. neighbours of nodes in the same class are checked if they belong to the same classes;

  4. if not, more fine classes are introduced;

  5. steps 3 and 4 are repeated until the condition 3 is true.

The resulting graph is encoded as the matrix of relations between the classes plus information on the numbers of nodes in each class. We note that all nodes in the same class have the same numbers of neighbors in the same classes; the same applies to neighbors of neighbors etc34,35. Obviously, all nodes i in the same class have the same value of Fi.

Results

The results on the matrices of relations between classes can be written in the form of graph of classes. To make it more clear, we provide two examples in Fig. 1. There, a continuous (dashed) arrow from class A to class B means a positive (negative) relation of members of A towards class B. The same applies to arrows from A to A; in this case the relation is of the group members towards other members of the same group; the relation Fi of an actor to him/herself is not marked in the figures. On the left there (HB), a classical case of the Heider balance is shown; all links are symmetric, then there are no nodes with Fi negative, and the graph is shown for completeness only. On the right side of the figure, the graph CII contains two classes: class 1 with internal relations friendly, and class 2 with internal relations hostile. The stability conditions for a friendly relation xij is that the sum xikxkj (as in Eq. (1)) should be positive. For the internal links within the class 1 this sum is equal N1 − 2 − N2, hence the stability in this case yields N1 > N2 + 2. For the internal links within the class 2, the appropriate sum should be negative, then their stability is assured if N2 − 2 − N1 < 0 - a less demanding condition. Accordingly, the negative link from class 1 to class 2 is stable if −(N1 − 1) + N2 < 0, and the positive link from class 2 to class 1 is stable if −(N2 − 1) + (N1 − 1) > 0. Summarizing this thread, the stability condition for the graph CII is that N1 > N2 + 2. The self-evaluation index Fi = N1 − 1 for the class 1, and Fi = −N1 for the class 2. Yet we note that the graphs CII are more rare, than the others.

Figure 1.

Figure 1

The generic graphs of two classes. The graph noted as HB shows the usual form of the Heider balance: the classes contain N1 and N2 nodes (actors), with all relations within the same class friendly, all relations between the classes hostile, and all links of this graph symmetric. The graph noted as CII contains class 1 with friendly internal relations and class 2 with internal relations hostile. The relations of those from N1 towards those from N2 are hostile (dashed arrow), and the relations of those from N2 towards those from N1 are friendly (continuous arrow).

Numerical results indicate that two kinds of configurations of graphs of classes appear much more frequently than others. These two kinds can be classified as CIII and CIV, as they are composed of three and four classes, respectively. Both CIII and CIV appear for different numbers N of actors in particular classes. These graphs are shown in Fig. 2, with the same meaning of continuous and dashed arrows.

Figure 2.

Figure 2

The generic graphs of three (CIII) and four (CIV) classes. N1–N4 mean the numbers of nodes (actors) in a given class. Continuous arrows from N1 to N2 mean friendly relations of N1 towards N2 (members of 1 like those in 2), and dashed arrows mean hostile relations. The same applies to self-directed arrows: a dashed self-directed arrow means that all members of a given class dislike each other.

For the graph CIII, the stability condition xij=sign(kxikxkj) is equivalent to the following: N1 + N2 > N3 + 2 for links within class 1, within 2, from 1 to 2 and back, and within class 3. For other links (from 1 to 3 and back, and from 2 to 3 and back), the condition is weaker: N1 + N2 > N3. Similarly, for CIV the most demanding condition is N1 + N2 > N3 + N4 + 2. As we see in Table 1, all the obtained links are stable. In the last column of Table 1 we show the obtained statistics of CIII and CIV for N = 7. The results indicate that asymmetric solutions appear in about 73 percent of our sample of 104 networks.

Table 1.

Most frequent configurations of graphs of classes for CIII (N4 = 0) and CIV (N4 > 0) for N = 7. N1 ÷ N4 mean the numbers of nodes (actors) in a given class 1 ÷ 4, and # counts how many times the graph appeared at the end of evolution in the sample of 104 networks.

N1 N2 N3 N4 #
3 3 1 0 1465
4 2 1 0 1125
2 4 1 0 1111
3 2 2 0 474
2 3 2 0 462
1 5 1 0 443
5 1 1 0 422
1 4 2 0 226
4 1 2 0 224
2 3 1 1 929
4 1 1 1 442

The structure of graphs is shown in Fig. 2. For CIII, configurations are shown for # > 100, and for CIV - for # > 5.

For larger values of N, the number of configurations is larger, but again CIII and CIV appear more frequently. For N = 9, the number of actors in the graphs of classes of leading frequencies are listed in Table 2. The sum of the right column covers more than 78 percent of the sample. For N = 11, we got 3686 graphs CIII and 5120 graphs CIV, what makes 88 percent of the sample. For N = 41 the population changes: 6974 graphs CIV (only those with frequency n not less than 10) and only 10 single graphs CIII. For N = 55 and N = 71 there are no graphs CIII at all. This effect is presumably a consequence of the fact that the number of partitions of N into four non-zero sets increases with N much quicker, than the number of partitions of N into three non-zero sets. Basically, these numbers are known as the Stirling numbers of second kind, S(N, 4) and S(N, 3). The ratio S(N, 4)/S(N, 3) is 1.2 for N = 7, 2.6 for N = 9, 5.1 for N = 11 but about 3 × 104 for N = 4150. This calculation is not exact because the stability conditions are ignored there, but even a very rough evaluation explains the observed lack of CIII for N > 40. In Fig. 3 the frequencies of various graphs CIV (with different numbers N1 ÷ N4) are shown. We can conclude that the percentage of asymmetric graphs is meaningful.

Table 2.

Most frequent configurations of graphs of classes for CIII (N4 = 0) and CIV (N4 > 0) for N = 9.

N1 N2 N3 N4 #
4 4 1 0 721
5 3 1 0 610
3 5 1 0 597
4 3 2 0 547
3 4 2 0 545
5 2 2 0 347
2 5 2 0 327
2 6 1 0 294
6 2 1 0 276
3 3 3 0 172
3 4 1 1 1084
5 2 1 1 664
3 3 1 2 435
4 2 1 2 375
4 2 2 1 353
1 6 1 1 196
5 1 1 2 139
5 1 2 1 138

The notation is as in Table 1. For CIII, configurations are shown for # > 150, and for CIV - for # > 3.

Figure 3.

Figure 3

Frequency # of different graphs CIV for N = 41, N = 55, and N = 71. By different graphs we mean that the numbers N1 ÷ N4 are different. The graphs are ordered with increasing frequency; higher rank is assigned to those which appear more frequently. When the rank is multiplied by Nα, an approximate scaling yields α ≈ 1.7.

Another question is the sign of Fi in the obtained classes. Here we are interested in the cases where Fi < 0. For CIII, this condition is equivalent to: N1 < 1, N2 < N3 + 1 and N1 > 0 for the actors in the class 1, 2 and 3, respectively. As we can infer from the data in Table 1 for N = 7, Fi is always negative only for actors in class 3. The self-feeling Fi of the remaining nodes is sometimes zero, sometimes positive, sometimes it can be negative as well. Similarly, for CIV the values of Fi are equal to N1 − N3 − 1, N2 − N4 − 1, N4 − N2 and N3 − N1 for actors in classes 1, 2, 3 and 4, respectively. As we can infer from the stability condition given above (N1 + N2 > N3 + N4 + 2), Fi is negative for most actors in classes 3 and 4.

Discussion

Our numerical results indicate that:

  • the evolution Eq. (1) frequently drives the system to asymmetric states with structure CIII or CIV as shown in Fig. 2,

  • in small systems (N ≈ 10) graphs of classes CIII and CIV are abundant, while in larger systems (N > 40) graphs CIII disappear,

  • the stability conditions demand that the classes 1 and 2 (with positive internal relations) contain more actors than the classes 3 and 4,

  • for actors in the classes 3 and 4, negative values of Fi are quite typical.

As it was demonstrated in refs28,29 in the case of symmetric relations (xij = xji) the generic stable solution of the Eq. (1) is balanced in the Heider sense. An example of such solution is shown in Fig. 2 (HB) in the form of a graph of classes. Recall that there are two classes, one with N1 actors and one with N2. Here we show that when the condition of symmetry is released, the graphs of classes CIII and CIV (shown in Fig. 2) are most probable solutions of Eq. (2). When the number of actors N increases, the frequency of CIV prevails. While the numbers of actors N1, N2, N3, N4 vary, the structure of the graph of classes remains unchanged. We dare say that the structure of CIII and foremost CIV with its specific symmetry are counterparts of the balanced state for asymmetric relations. What we do not know is, if there is no more solutions of this kind. Recall that for symmetric relations and N = 9, a stable state of three triads has been found, which is different from a classical balanced partition into two groups19. At this stage we cannot state that there is no other asymmetric and stable states, different from CIII and CIV.

To comment the structure of the graphs, the graph CII could represent peer rejection51 of those in class 2 by those in class 1 and by other members of the class 2. The class 3 in CIII can be assigned to a person (or persons) at intermediate position between two mutually hostile groups. She/he aspires to belong to one of them, but is not accepted there; the aspiration makes her/him unwilling to join the other group, where she/he would be accepted. This scheme reminds some fictitious characters known in belles-lettres, as Werther52 or Julian Sorel53. In general, the structure of CIII should be visible when characterizing social positions of mobile individuals, aspiring to move between mutually hostile groups. A similar scheme of relations has been identified in ethnic conflicts, where higher educated immigrants perceive more discrimination that their less educated compatriots. The phenomenon is known as ‘paradox of integration’ (see5457 and references therein). The structure of the graph CIV is the most complex of those found here. There we see two mutually hostile groups 1 and 2 (as usually in the balanced state) plus two relatively small groups 3 and 4.

As it can be inferred from our numerical results, the graphs CIII and CIV appear to be generic. Therefore we can expect that they should be present in some sociometric data. This expectation has been verified by using the Sampson data58. Namely, four pairs of non-symmetric, valued matrices (X, Y) = (SAMPLK, SAMPDLK), (SAMPES, SAMPDES), (SAMPIN, SAMPNIN), (SAMPPR, SAMPNPR)58 were used to form four signed and valued non-symmetric matrices (X − Y)/5. The difference measures the positive minus the negative relations, and the factor 1/5 was used to keep the relations in the range (−1, 1). These four matrices have been used as the initial values of xij. We have found that only one pair (SAMPLK-SAMPDLK)/5 was dense enough to produce a fully connected graph by means of Eq. (1). The structure of this graph has been found to be identical with CIII. There, the class 1 contains ten actors (1, 2, 4, 5, 6, 7, 11, 12, 14, 16), the class 2: four actors (13, 16, 17, 18), and the class 3 also four (3, 8, 9, 10), with enumeration as the rows and columns of the matrices given in58. Two other matrices (SAMPES-SAMPDES)/5 and (SAMPIN-SAMPNIN)/5 appeared to be dense enough, i.e. their evolution lead to fully connected graphs, only if the first row and column was removed; the first actor was apparently less connected than the others. With this cut, the pair (SAMPIN-SAMPNIN)/5 has been found to lead to CIII, with the composition N1 = 7, N2 = 9, N3 = 1. The matrix (SAMPES-SAMPDES)/5 gave CIV with the composition N1 = 5, N2 = 7, N3 = 3, N4 = 2. The matrix (SAMPES-SAMPDES)/5 gave CIV with the composition N1 = 5, N2 = 7, N3 = 3, N4 = 2, and the same composition has been produced by (SAMPLK-SAMPDLK)/5 as the initial state. The fact that both CIII and CIV are reproduced from the well-known set58 suggests that these graphs are generic also in other sociometric data.

To conclude, the former theory of removal of cognitive dissonance28 has been extended here to include asymmetric relations. Our results indicate, that the time evolution starting from generic initial conditions leads in most cases to the graphs of classes CIII and CIV. In other words, for the dynamics given by Eq. 1 these two classes appear to be universal. This computational result is obtained by an application of the classifying algorithm34,35 to the states of signed and directed fully connected networks. Further, according to the Cooley theory, the structure of these graphs is particularly harmful for actors at some positions in these graphs, indicated above. On the other hand, this structure can be identified in field experiments by means of standard sociometric methods. These results can be of interest for scientists working on conflicts in groups, and for teachers in classes where conflicts appear.

Methods

For each sample out of a set of K fully connected networks of size N, initial conditions for N(N − 1) links xij(t = 0) have been chosen randomly from a homogeneous distribution ρ(x) = 1/2 for −1 < x < 1, zero otherwise. Next, the time evolution of xij has been initialized according to Eq. (1). The resulting set of differential equations has been solved numerically using the Mathematica software for a sample of K = 104 networks for each N. Typically, the system has ended at one of hypercube corners where xij = ±1 (with the relative accuracy 10−8 serving as the stop condition of the simulation) for each pair i, j. The convergence to xij = ±1 has been reached in 97% of the cases for N = 7, 9, 11, in 96% cases for N = 41, in 95% cases for N = 55, and in 93% cases for N = 77. For N = 99, the numerical solution of the system of differential equations has proved to be unstable, with at least 55% of the cases not converging.

Acknowledgements

This work was partly supported by the Faculty of Physics and Applied Computer Science (11.11.220.01/2) and by the Faculty of Humanities (11.11.430.158) AGH UST statutory tasks within subsidy of Ministry of Science and Higher Education. Support by the facilities of the PL-Grid infrastructure is also acknowledged.

Author Contributions

K.K. designed the research, M.J.K., M.W. and P.G. performed the simulations, K.K. analysed the results, K.K., J.M. and M.W. wrote the text. All authors reviewed the manuscript.

Data Availability

The data used here are publicly available at the last position of the list of References (Bagatelj V. and Mrvar A. UCINET IV Datasets (2006)).

Competing Interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Footnotes

Publisher’s note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

References

  • 1.Moreno, J. L. Who Shall Survive? A New Approach to the Problem of Human Interrelations (Nervous and Mental Disease Publishing Co., Washington DC 1934).
  • 2.Wasserman, S. & Faust, K. Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications (Structural Analysis in the Social Sciences) (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 1994).
  • 3.Scott, J. Social Network Analysis: A Handbook (Sage Publ., London 1991).
  • 4.Granovetter MS. The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology. 1973;78:1360–1380. doi: 10.1086/225469. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Granovetter MS. The strength of weak ties: a network theory revisited. Sociological Theory. 1983;1:201–233. doi: 10.2307/202051. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Vala, J., Valdzus, S. & Calheiros, M. M. (Eds), The Social Developmental Construction of Violence and Intergroup Conflict (Springer Int. Publ. Switzerland 2016).
  • 7.York R, Light R. Directional asymmetry in sociological analyses. Socius: Sociological Research in a Dynamic World. 2017;3:1–13. [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Staerklé C, Clémence A, Spini D. A social psychology of human rights rooted in asymmetric intergroup relations. Peace and Conflict: J. of Peace Psychology. 2015;21:133–141. doi: 10.1037/pac0000088. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Soylu S, Sheehy-Skeffington J. Asymmetric intergroup bullying: The enactment and maintenance of societal inequality at work. Human Relations. 2015;68:1099–1129. doi: 10.1177/0018726714552001. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Carley KM, Krackhardt D. Cognitive inconsistencies and non-symmetrical friendship. Social Networks. 1996;18:1–27. doi: 10.1016/0378-8733(95)00252-9. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Leskovec, J., Huttenlocher, D. & Kleinberg, J. Signed networks in social media., Proc. SIGHI Conf. on Human Factors in Computing Systems (CHI’10) (ACM, New York 2010).
  • 12.Cohen S, Kimelfeld B, Koutrika G. A survey on proximity measures for social networks. Lect. Notes Comp. Sci. 2012;7538:191–206. doi: 10.1007/978-3-642-34213-4_13. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Barker JL, Loope KJ, Reeve HK. Asymmetry within social groups: division of labor and intergroup competition. J. of Evol. Biol. 2016;29:560–571. doi: 10.1111/jeb.12805. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Ramirez P, Legendre S. Revisiting asymmetric marriage rules. Social Networks. 2018;52:261–269. doi: 10.1016/j.socnet.2017.09.004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Bonacich P. & Lu, P. Introduction to Mathematical Sociology (Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton 2012).
  • 16.Heider F. Attitudes and cognitive organization. J. of Psychology. 1946;21:107–112. doi: 10.1080/00223980.1946.9917275. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Heider, F. The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations (Lawrence Erlbaum Assoc., 1958).
  • 18.Cartwright D, Harary F. Structural balance: a generalization of Heider’s theory. Psychol. Rev. 1956;63:277–293. doi: 10.1037/h0046049. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Antal T, Krapivsky PL, Redner S. Dynamics of social balance on networks. Phys. Rev. E. 2005;72:036121. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.72.036121. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Antal T, Krapivsky PL, Redner S. Social balance on networks: the dynamics of friendship and enmity. Physica D. 2006;224:130–136. doi: 10.1016/j.physd.2006.09.028. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Hassanibesheli F, et al. Gain and loss of esteem, direct reciprocity and Heider balance. Physica A. 2017;468:334–339. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2016.10.091. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Hedayatifar L, Hassanibesheli F, Shirazi AH, Vasheghani Farahani S, Jafari GR. Pseudo paths towards minimum energy states in network dynamics. Physica A. 2017;483:109–116. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2017.04.132. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Hassanibesheli F, Hedayatifar L, Safdari H, Ausloos M, Jafari GR. Glassy states of aging social networks. Entropy. 2017;19:246. doi: 10.3390/e19060246. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Festinger, L. A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance (Stanford Univ. Press, 1957).
  • 25.Gawroński P, Kułakowski K. A numerical trip to social psychology: long-living states of cognitive dissonance. Lect. Notes in Comp. Sci. 2007;4490:43–50. doi: 10.1007/978-3-540-72590-9_6. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Vitanov NK, Dimitrova ZI, Ausloos M. Verhulst-Lotka-Volterra (VLV) model of ideological struggle. Physica A. 2010;389:4970–4980. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2010.06.032. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Toranj Simin P, et al. Dynamical phase diagrams of a love capacity constrained prey-predator model. Eur. Phys. J. B. 2018;91:43. doi: 10.1140/epjb/e2017-80531-7. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Kułakowski K, Gawroński P, Gronek P. The Heider balance - a continuous approach. Int. J. Mod. Phys. C. 2005;16:707–716. doi: 10.1142/S012918310500742X. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Marvel SA, Kleinberg J, Kleinberg RD, Strogatz SH. Continuous-time model of structural balance. PNAS. 2011;108:1771–1776. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1013213108. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Kirkpatrick S, Gelatt CD, Jr., Vecchi MP. Optimization by simulated annealing. Science. 1983;220:671–680. doi: 10.1126/science.220.4598.671. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Parisi G. Asymmetric neural networks and the process of learning. J. Phys. A: Math. Gen. 1986;19:L675–L680. doi: 10.1088/0305-4470/19/11/005. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Folli V, Gosti G, Leonetti M, Ruocco G. Effect of dilution in asymmetric recurrent neural networks. Neural Networks. 2018;104:50–59. doi: 10.1016/j.neunet.2018.04.003. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Drossel, B. Random Boolean networks. (Reviews of Nonlinear Dynamics and Complexity, Vol.1, Ed. HG Schuster, Wiley, 2008).
  • 34.Krawczyk MJ. Symmetry induced compression of discrete phase space. Physica A. 2011;390:2181–2191. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2011.02.014. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Krawczyk MJ. Classes of states of discrete systems. Int. J. of Modern Phys. C. 2015;26:1550126. doi: 10.1142/S0129183115501260. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Cooley, C. H. Human Nature and the Social Order (Schocken Books, New York 1964).
  • 37.Thomas, W. I. & Znaniecki, F. The Polish Peasant in Europe and America (Badger, Boston 1918).
  • 38.Mead, G. H. Mind, Self and Society. From the Standpoint of a Social Behaviorist (The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1934).
  • 39.Blumer, H. Symbolic Interactionism. Perspective and Method (The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1969).
  • 40.McCall G. J. Symbolic interaction in Contemporary social psychological theories (ed. Burke, P. J.) 1–23 (Stanford Univ. Press, 2006).
  • 41.Znaniecki, F. The Laws of Social Psychology (The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1925).
  • 42.Scheff, T. Microsociology. Discourse, Emotion, and Social Structure (The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1990).
  • 43.Elias, N. Die Gesellschaft der Individuen (Suhrcamp Verlag, Berlin 1987).
  • 44.Kaufmann, J. C. Ego. Pour une sociologie de l’individu. Une autre vision de l’homme et de la construction du sujet (Nathan, Paris 2001).
  • 45.Turner, J. H. & Stets, J. E. The Sociology of Emotions (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 2005).
  • 46.Rambaran JA, Dijkstra JK, Munniksma A, Cillessen AHN. The development of adolescents’ friendships and antipathies: A longitudinal multivariate network test of balance theory. Social Networks. 2015;43:162–176. doi: 10.1016/j.socnet.2015.05.003. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 47.Molet M, Craddock P, Grassart A. An application of Heider’s P-O-X balance model to change evaluative conditioning effects. Learning and Motivation. 2015;51:43–49. doi: 10.1016/j.lmot.2015.04.001. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 48.Sadilek M, Klimek P, Thurner S. Asocial balance—how your friends determine your enemies: understanding the co-evolution of friendship and enmity interactions in a virtual world. J. Comput. Soc. Sci. 2018;1:227–239. doi: 10.1007/s42001-017-0010-9. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Woelfel J, Haller AO. Significant others, the self-reflexive act and the attitude formation process. Amer. Soc. Rev. 1971;36:74–87. doi: 10.2307/2093508. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.Graham, R. L., Knuth, D. E. & Patashnik O. Concrete Mathematics (Addison-Wesley, Reading MA 1988).
  • 51.Salmivalli C. Bullying and the peer group. A review. Aggression and Violent Behavior. 2010;15:112–120. doi: 10.1016/j.avb.2009.08.007. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 52.Goethe, W. The Sorrows of Young Werther. (Oxford World’s Classics, Oxford University Press, 2012).
  • 53.Beyle, H. (Stendhal) Le Rouge et le Noir : chronique du XIXe siècle. (La Bibliothèque Gallimard, Paris 1999).
  • 54.ten Teije I, Coenders M, Verkuyten M. The paradox of integration. Immigrants and their attitude toward the native population. Social Psychology. 2013;44:278–288. doi: 10.1027/1864-9335/a000113. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 55.de Vroome T, Martinovic B, Verkuyten M. The integration paradox: Level of education and immigrants’ attitudes towards natives and the host society. Cultural Diversity and Ethnic Minority Psychology. 2014;20:166–175. doi: 10.1037/a0034946. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 56.Dixon J, Durrheim K, Tredoux C, Tropp L. A paradox of integration? Interracial contact, prejudice reduction, and perceptions of racial discrimination. J. of Social Issues. 2010;66:401–416. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-4560.2010.01652.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 57.Tolsma, J. Ethnic hostility among ethnic majority and minority groups in the Netherlands, http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.840.8624&rep=rep1&type=pdf (PhD Thesis, Radboud University Nijmegen, 2009).
  • 58.Bagatelj, V. & Mrvar, A. UCINET IV Datasets, http://vlado.fmf.uni-lj.si/pub/networks/data/ucinet/ucidata.htm (2006).

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Data Availability Statement

The data used here are publicly available at the last position of the list of References (Bagatelj V. and Mrvar A. UCINET IV Datasets (2006)).


Articles from Scientific Reports are provided here courtesy of Nature Publishing Group

RESOURCES