Abstract
The polarization of political opinions among members of the US legislative chambers measured by their voting records is greater today than it was 30 years ago. Previous research efforts to find causes of such increase have suggested diverse contributors, like growth of online media, echo chamber effects, media biases or disinformation propagation. Yet, we lack theoretic tools to understand, quantify and predict the emergence of high political polarization among voters and their legislators. Here, we analyse millions of roll-call votes cast in the US Congress over the past six decades. Our analysis reveals the critical change of polarization patterns that started at the end of 1980s. In earlier decades, polarization within each Congress tended to decrease with time. By contrast, in recent decades, the polarization has been likely to grow within each term. To shed light on the reasons for this change, we introduce here a formal model for competitive dynamics to quantify the evolution of polarization patterns in the legislative branch of the US government. Our model represents dynamics of polarization, enabling us to successfully predict the direction of polarization changes in 28 out of 30 US Congresses elected in the past six decades. From the evolution of polarization level as measured by the Rice index, our model extracts a hidden parameter–polarization utility which determines the convergence point of the polarization evolution. The increase in the polarization utility implied by the model strongly correlates with two current trends: growing polarization of voters and increasing influence of election campaign donors. Two largest peaks of the model’s polarization utility correlate with significant political or legislative changes happening at the same time.
Keywords: dynamical system, political polarization, equilibrium, stability
1. Introduction
Conflict and consensus play important role in the functioning of a social system. In the context of political competition, they manifest themselves as complementary processes, one is polarization of opinions and the other is collaboration to reach consensus on shared national interests [1]. Polarization arises from the politicians’ need to represent opinions of their voters while collaboration is required to balance the interests of many groups. Numerous previous publications have focused on the role of social conformity [2–4] in polarization. Among these publications, many hypotheses have been proposed to explain the observed emergence of increased polarization, including social homophily [5], opinion dynamics [6], selective exposure [7], social bots [8], echo chambers [9,10], propagation of low-quality information or fake news [11,12], as well as the effect of viral news [13] and social media [14]. While these models study different aspects of polarization of political views, they share some common assumptions about human social behaviour [15], including the following: (i) individuals iteratively update their views to reach consensus with their neighbours in a social network; (ii) the tolerance of conflicting views is limited in social context, so frequent active disagreements usually break of social ties [16]. These assumptions indicate that the loyalty to one’s group usually leads to the conformity with views of the group’s majority [17], and such conformity tightens social ties within the group. Therefore, in our model, we allow the current polarization level to influence its future growth.
We analyse millions of roll-call votes cast in the US Congress [18] over the past six decades to identify the evolution of political polarization patterns. Using the roll-call vote results, we quantify the level of polarization in the legislative branch of government over the last six decades. We assume a social system dominated by two parties. In such a system, polarization and collaboration can convert into each other but they maintain their sum constant at 1. A simple model of the dynamics of competition between exclusive groups [19] can be extended to the case of non-exclusive competing groups whose members can convert polarization and collaboration into each other. The dynamics of the extended model can be written as
1.1 |
where x ∈ [0, 1] is the current polarization level, as measured by the real legislative votes, while up is a parameter independent of the current polarization level. We call parameter up the polarization utility in analogy to the role of gravitational force in physics. The complementary values denoted as y = 1 − x and uc = 1 − up represent the current collaboration level and the non-partisan utility, respectively, while Pcp(x, up) is the probability of collaboration converting to polarization per unit of time. For symmetry, Ppc(x, up) represents the probability of polarization converting to collaboration per unit of time. When two parties have exactly the same ‘Yes’ ratio on a bill, the collaboration level reaches its maximum y = 1. Studying polarization in the US Congress, we assume the evolution is fully governed by the nonlinear dynamics defined in equation (1.1). However, every 2 years, the dynamical system moves to a new state (determined by the election of members of the next Congress) that becomes the initial state for that Congress.
Up to the end of 1980s, the polarization level within each Congress tended to decrease. However, our results show that since then, the polarization has been likely to grow within two-year term of each Congress. This phenomenon is represented in our model by the change of the polarization utility, since it determines the polarization level to which the system converges, regardless of its initial state. The nonlinear dynamics of our model successfully predict the direction of polarization change in 28 out of 30 US Congresses for the past six decades. The two Congresses that are in disagreement with the model predictions have very small variations of polarization, with a weakly defined polarization direction, making the predication error small. Moreover, our results show that the further away is the initial polarization caused by member replacement from the corresponding equilibrium defined by our model, the higher is the speed with which the polarization level changes during the two-year period between elections.
In our model, the nonlinear gain–loss function quantifies the conversion between collaboration and polarization among legislators. The model implies that the polarization level always converges to an equilibrium point, while replacement of members in each Congress caused by election sets the new initial polarization level. We also derive an analytic expression for the equilibrium points, which are defined by the polarization utility and the system’s sensitivity to the current polarization. Our model implies that the observed increased polarization in the recent few decades is caused by the growing polarization utility. This conclusion prompts the question about the causes of this growth. We address this question in the Discussion section.
2. Quantifying polarization in the legislative branch
We analyse millions of roll-call votes cast in the US Congress [18] over the past six decades to identify evolution of political polarization patterns. The statistics of the roll-call votes in Congresses with sessions numbered from 85 to 114 are shown in table 1. This dataset contains approximately 7 million votes in both the Senate and the House of Representatives cast by a total of 1498 and 1395 legislators from Democratic and Republican Parties, respectively. We adopt the well-known Rice index [20] to measure party dissimilarity in legislative voting. The Rice index is defined as the mean absolute distance between the ‘Yes’ ratios of Democratic and Republican Parties on the bth bill
2.1 |
where NRep and NDem denote the numbers of legislators from the Republican and Democratic Parties participating in the vote, while Repib and Demojb are the votes cast by Republican i and Democrat j for bill b, respectively. represents the corresponding average over all legislators in each party. The result of a vote is coded as 1 for ‘Yes’ and 0 otherwise because the bills pass by majority in both the Senate and the House of Representatives and therefore abstaining is effectively equivalent to opposing bill passage. This procedure is illustrated in figure 1a.
Table 1.
party | #members | #bills | #votes | #votes/members | #votes/years |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Democratic Party | 1498 | 31 879 | 7 368 921 | 4919.17 | 122815.35 |
Republican Party | 1395 | 31 879 | 6 275 886 | 4498.84 | 104598.1 |
Regardless of the content of bills, we compute the average distance of bill votes between the two parties over every 199 day intervals. Formally, the polarization level at the tth day of the kth Congress is quantified as
2.2 |
where {b : |tb − t| < 100} is the set of bills voted within 199 days centred at the tth day of the ith Congress and i starts at the 100th day of each Congress and ends 99 days before the last day of this Congress. Hence, each measurement includes exactly 200 days of voting. This step is illustrated by figure 1c. The averaging reduces the noise of the raw data because the topics of the legislative bills may differ day by day in each Congress, and there were several periods of times in the past six decades during which very few bills were voted on by the US Congresses. Compared to the approaches [21–23] defining the conflicting level between individuals, the Rice index defined in equation (2.1) reflects the general trend of behavioural partisanship while preserving its simplicity by quantifying polarization at party level. More importantly, the Rice index enables us to develop a dynamical equation, equation (1.1), which captures the macroscopic behaviour of the evolution of political polarization, regardless of the complex interactions between individual legislators considered in [21].
For every Congress and each bill, we measure the distance distb between two parties using equation (2.1). As distb ∈ [0, 1], the political preference for bill b is defined as Db = 0.5 − distb/2 for the Democratic Party and Rb = 0.5 + distb/2 for the Republican Party. Then, using the kernel density estimation (KDE) [24], we evaluate the distribution of distances Db and Rb, of Democratic and Republican Parties, respectively, from the centre of the polarization range. Figure 1b shows the distribution of these distances which represent positions of the two parties regarding the bills voted in each Congress.
3. Dynamical model of political polarization
We assume a two-party political system, such as exemplified by the UK, but applicable also to the USA and other countries with a multi-party system dominated by two major parties. We also assume a social system in which polarization and collaboration can convert into each other. The polarization is reflected by the Rice index as defined in equation (2.2). And we define the complementary of polarization level as the collaboration level. A simple model of the dynamics of such conversion is given in equation (1.1) using the same notation as previously.
Following [19], we assume that Pcp has the following simple form:
3.1 |
which is supported by the normative social influence theory [17] that postulates that the current polarization level x influences the probability of conversion. To preserve symmetry under the conversion from y to x and vice versa, we define Ppc as
3.2 |
Similar but not identical nonlinear gain–loss equations for the state dynamics have been successfully applied to model various types of polarization, ranging from religious affiliation [19], to language choice [25] and political affiliation [26]. The model introduced in [19] ‘idealizes a society as partitioned into two mutually exclusive social groups, X, the unaffiliated, and Y, those who adhere to a religion’. Furthermore, the model assumes the attractiveness of a group increases with the number of members and the perceived utility of the group, a quantity representing many factors including ‘the social, economic, political as well as security benefits derived from membership and the spiritual or moral consonance with a group’. In our case, the Congress members’ affiliation to different political ideologies may not be exclusive, like affiliation to a language or a religion is. Thus, we assume that in the legislative system polarization and collaboration may convert into each other. For each bill, the polarization is measured by the difference between the two parties’ ‘Yes’ ratios. Accordingly, we define the collaboration level y as complementary to polarization level x, setting, y = 1 − x. Another extension to the original model from [19] is the use of different up parameter for each individual Congress. This is motivated by the fact that the initial state for each Congress changes periodically, every 2 years when new members are elected. By contrast, the whole population affiliated with religions or languages can be assumed static, allowing the use of the same model parameters over time. In summary, the nonlinear dynamics defined here captures the conversion between polarization and collaboration during different periods which is not considered in [25]. The parameter up is independent of the polarization level x which varies as the time changes. This parameter reflects the internal perception of benefits that a legislator may gain by supporting polarizing opinion. Such support does not have to manifest itself immediately but rather in the future votes. The term xa captures the effect of the current polarization level on the evolution. The speed of evolution is defined by the parameter c in our model.
The total energy [27] in this dynamical system is governed by the following equation:
3.3 |
which is constant on the solution curves or trajectories of this system, i.e. for some constant C. The total energy function in relation to the current polarization x and its first-order derivative is shown in figure 2a for a < 1 and figure 2b for a > 1.
Given the model parameters a and up, besides the equilibrium points at x* = 0 and 1, the exact equilibrium points of the dynamical system defined by equation (1.1) can be derived as
3.4 |
The derivation of the equilibrium points is provided in the electronic supplementary material.
The trajectories of the nonlinear dynamical evolution are shown in figure 2c–f where the x-axis represents time t and the y-axis represents the polarization. Each trajectory curve starts from its initial polarization level x0 which is represented by the z-axis. We show the surface of these convergence process for a < 1 and the initial polarization in full range from x0 = 0 to x0 = 1, in figure 2e. Likewise, figure 2d contains similar visualization results with a > 1 and initial polarization levels x0 at the tipping points, i.e. the points at the edges drawn in dark shading in figure 2f . The equilibrium points of the dynamical model are stable when a < 1. In such case, the dynamical system of equation (1.1) always converges to the x* ∈ [0, 1] after the sufficient period of evolution; figure 2c,e shows example with a = 0.6. By contrast, when a > 1, the final state of the dynamical system depends on the initial state and the position of the tipping point; figure 2d,f shows example with a = 2.5. The dynamical system will eventually converge to either x = 0 or x = 1.
In the context of political polarization, the case with a < 1 corresponds to a healthy political system which maintains the polarization level within a certain range. However, the case with a > 1, corresponds to a system which switches easily between fully polarized equilibrium point and complete consensus convergence point. In the US political system, a change of the system’s initial state is caused periodically every 2 years by the election of new legislators. The system near the tipping point at the end of one Congress is vulnerable to extreme state switching under even a small change of the initial polarization for the next Congress.
We simulate the nonlinear dynamics defined by equation (1.1) until the polarization level x converges. When a < 1, the equilibrium point is exactly the final polarization level of convergence. When a > 1, the only equilibrium points are x = 1, which corresponds to the full polarization, and x = 0, which represents the full consensus. Moreover, some of the initial states are unstable; they are the tipping points from which the dynamical system converges in a non-deterministic way to either of the two stable equilibrium points. We grid-search for the tipping points with different values of up. In each iteration, we increase the value of x by a small Δx. If the final convergence states have changed from one state to another due to the increment of Δx, then the current x is identified as the tipping point.
4. Evolution of political polarization patterns
We fit the political polarization model defined by equation (1.1) to the data points xi(t) which represent 10 evenly distributed in time sampled polarization levels at ti = ti,1, ti,2, …, ti,10 of the ith Congress. The system is assumed to have the universal a and c values at all times, but each Congress i has its own parameter up defined as the polarization utility, and the particular initial state, xi,0, which is defined by the member replacements caused by the most recent election. In other words, the nonlinear dynamics here only model the evolution of polarization during a constant period of time between elections. Member replacements in each Congress resulting from election move the dynamical system to a new state which is the new Congress’s initial state. As seen in equation (1.1), the polarization utility up does not change over time like the current polarization level x does. We assume that each Congress has a consistent polarization utility as long as the same members stay. Therefore, the polarization utility is set as a fixed value for each Congress, independent of the evolving polarization level within each two-year term.
For the ith Congress, given parameters a and c, we grid-search the possible ui,p and xi,0 values to minimize the least absolute errors (LAE) between the real polarization level [xi(ti,1), xi(ti,2), …, xi(ti,10)] and theoretical polarization level found by numerical simulation of equation (1.1) at the corresponding time points. Next, we find the optimal values of a, c values which minimize the sum of the LAEs of all Congresses. Then, we repeat the grid-search for local and global parameters by narrowing neighbourhood of parameter values so each repetition increases the precision of the results. We stop when precision reaches 0.01.
The inference procedure estimates the values of universal parameters at a = 0.7, c = 0.37 while the set of values for up, x0 is shown in figure 3b,c. In figure 3b, we illustrate the estimated value ui,p of the ith Congress. In general, this value increases as the Congress session numbers grow from 85 to 114. The black solid curve in figure 3c shows the equilibrium points for different up values with global parameter a estimated from the voting data. To illustrate the impact of parameter a on values of the equilibrium points, the dotted lines represent these values for a = 0.1, a = 0.37 and a = 0.95, respectively. This figure also illustrates that most of the Congresses last too short for the system to reach the equilibrium point before the election of new members redefines the new starting point of the system for the next Congress.
Since the estimate a = 0.7 is smaller than 1, the dynamical system has a unique equilibrium point for any given up. As shown in figure 3c, when the polarization level x is larger than the stable equilibrium point x*, this level decreases to approach this point. This explains why the polarization level decreases in most of the Congresses in the 1970s and 1980s. After the member replacement caused by the election, the initial polarization levels x0’s during this period were usually higher than the corresponding stable equilibrium points of the dynamical system (figure 3c). Therefore, the polarization level decreases within the two-year term Congress. By contrast, when the equilibrium point x* is larger than the initial polarization x0, the polarization x increases over time to approach the equilibrium point. This explains why the polarization level increases in most Congresses after the 1980s. Hence, the observed polarization patterns are fully recreated by the dynamics of our model.
It is worth noting that the initial polarization levels of the Congresses in the 1990s are actually not significantly higher than those observed in the previous Congresses. However, the polarization utility up has become larger and in the later decades exceeded 0.5 as figure 3b and table 2 indicate. Consequently, the polarization levels at the end of Congresses have significantly increased. This explains the rapid growth of polarization in the later Congresses. The sudden growth of polarization utility in the 101st and 102nd Congresses (1989–1993), revealed by our model is in agreement with [21] which describes a dramatic change of polarization that started during Clinton’s term (1993–1994), and solidified during the 104th Congress (1995–1996). Thus, the growth of polarization utility came right before the growth of polarization because legislators need time to adjust voting to the increased polarization utility. As seen in figure 3d, the absolute change of polarization |Δx| grows as the distance between the initial state x0 and equilibrium point x* increases. If the initial polarization level of a Congress is far away from its final point of convergence, then the rapid change of polarization would be expected within the two-year term. The direction of such change in 28 out of all 30 Congresses is explained by the model, while the two Congresses in disagreement with the model prediction have very small variations of polarization level as shown by the light markers in figure 3c.
Table 2.
midterm election congresses |
presidential election congresses |
||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
number | up | change | percentage (%) | number | up | change | percentage (%) |
86th | 0.3 | −0.05 | −14.3 | 87th* | 0.54 | 0.24 | 80.0 |
88th | 0.4 | −0.14 | −25.9 | 89th | 0.37 | −0.03 | −7.5 |
90th | 0.32 | −0.05 | −13.5 | 91st | 0.43 | 0.11 | 34.4 |
92nd | 0.38 | −0.05 | −11.6 | 93rd | 0.31 | −0.07 | −18.4 |
94th | 0.33 | 0.02 | 6.5 | 95th | 0.4 | 0.07 | 21.2 |
95th | 0.4 | 0.00 | 0.00 | 97th | 0.44 | 0.04 | 10.0 |
98th | 0.43 | −0.01 | −2.3 | 99th | 0.46 | 0.03 | 7.0 |
100th | 0.4 | −0.06 | −13.0 | 101st | 0.47 | 0.07 | 17.5 |
102nd | 0.65 | 0.18 | 38.3 | 103rd* | 0.61 | −0.04 | −6.2 |
104th | 0.54 | −0.07 | −11.5 | 105th* | 0.61 | 0.07 | 13.0 |
106th | 0.5 | −0.11 | −18.0 | 107th* | 0.5 | 0.00 | 0.0 |
108th | 0.52 | 0.02 | 4.0 | 109th* | 0.57 | 0.05 | 9.6 |
110th | 0.48 | −0.09 | −15.8 | 111th | 0.42 | −0.06 | −12.5 |
112th* | 0.66 | 0.24 | 57.1 | 113th* | 0.73 | 0.07 | 10.6 |
114th | 0.71 | −0.02 | −2.74 | ||||
86th–100th | 0.370 | −0.043 | −9.3 | 0.421 | 0.056 | 18.1 | |
101st–114th | 0.580 | 0.021 | 7.3 | 0.559 | 0.023 | 4.6 | |
All | 0.468 | −0.013 | −1.5 | 0.481 | 0.039 | 11.3 | |
4 positive, 10 negative, 1a | 9 positive, 4 negative, 6a |
aDenotes the polarization utility up over 0.5, marked by italic font in the up column.
Another sign of changed polarization patterns is the number of Congresses in which initial polarization utility is at least 50%, making it equal to or stronger than the collaboration utility as defined in equation (1.1). Only one Congress among 15 in the first three decades reached this level, while it was achieved by 11 out of 14 Congresses in the last three decades.
In summary, our model explains the observed polarization patterns. In the 1970s and 1980s, the initial polarization x0 is generally larger than the stable polarization x*, so we observe a decrease of polarization within each of two-year term Congress. In other words, the legislators gradually agree more and more with the members of the opposite party than initially, while they held more conflicting views at the very beginning of each Congress session. After the 101st Congress (1989–1991), the initial polarization x0 is generally smaller than the stable polarization level x*. Therefore, during the corresponding Congresses, the polarization x increases to approach the corresponding equilibrium point defined by the given up. This trend matches the transition observed during the 103rd and 104th Congresses [21], when the moderate members of each party joined their majority-party coalitions, leaving the middle ground deserted.
5. Discussion
As discussed in [28], in the past the polarization in the Congress was higher in the early part of the Congress term during which procedural issues were voted and it is lower in the later part. This past pattern led to a hypothesis that ‘Lion’s share of party polarization in Congress can be accounted for by the changing dynamics of voting on procedures’ [28]. The first contribution of our paper is the analysis of voting that uses the Rice index to show this hypothesis does not hold anymore. Over the last 14 Congresses this pattern reversed, and polarization increases in the late part of each Congress. Our second contribution is to extend the model from [25] to non-exclusive and dynamically changing competing groups. The third is to recover the model parameters from the roll-call vote data to minimize the difference between the model and the data.
The polarization utility introduced here and its change over time explain observed polarization of each Congress in the last 60 years with high accuracy. Hence our dynamical model sheds some light on the causes of increased polarization in recent decades. As seen in figure 3c, when up is small, the resulting stable polarization level decreases as the value of a increases, in response to the decreased probability of conversion from collaboration to polarization (cf. equation (1.1)). In such case, the dynamical system is less sensitive to the current polarization level x because the term xa in equation (1.1) becomes smaller as a grows. Therefore, when up is small, a large value of a decreases the polarization level. However, when the value of a exceeds 1, some initial states become tipping points, from which the system evolves in a non-deterministic way towards one of the two possible extreme equilibrium points, one of which, x = 1, corresponds to the full polarization, while the other, x = 0, represents the full consensus. Below the tipping point, the system converges to one of these two points, and above, it evolves towards the other. In the US political system, a change of the initial system state happens periodically every 2 years when the new legislators are elected. The system in the neighbourhood of a tipping point is vulnerable to even small change in initial polarization that may switch the system convergence point from one extreme equilibrium point to another. Such abrupt and radical equilibrium point switching is absent when a is smaller than 1.
According to our model, we witness a growth of the polarization utility, up, over the recent decades. The question arises what are the causes of this increase. To answer this question, we start by observing that a politician needs to be elected to become legislators and repeatedly reelected to continue in this role. Thus, the polarization utility for them lies in its ability to bring votes. This can be accomplished either directly, by representing voters’ opinions, or by gaining resources for election campaign funding. In the case of direct support, the polarization of voters has been rising in recent decades for such reasons as the echo chambers effect [9,10] and the growth of new, often strongly biased social media [14] or spread of misinformation [11,12]. Voters increasing polarization raises the polarization utility, which is indirectly reflected as the phenomenon that legislators align their voting with positions of their electorates. The indirect support is gaining in importance because of escalating costs of political campaigns fuelled by the growing numbers of effective advertising channels and raising costs of advertising [29].
To corroborate this conclusion, we identified two largest jumps in polarization utility resulting from election of Congress members (table 2). The first jump of 0.24 happened in 1960 so it coincides with the start of civil right movement, increasing the US involvement in the Vietnam War, and generational changes in politics. In [22], the author observe that such ‘takeoff situations’ significantly increase polarization in the network structures of political connections. The second jump happened in year 2010, when the Supreme Court approved Super PACs which are allowed to collect unlimited contributions from many sources and to advocate for or against political candidates. Taming the causes of increased polarization is difficult. For example, requiring biased social media to provide time to advocates of the opposing opinions was shown to be counter productive [30].
Several interesting questions arise in relation to the presented work, that chart the paths for future research. The three of those are briefly discussed below. The first question arises about how much, if at all, polarization trends differ between the House of Representatives and the Senate. Our preliminary checking reveals that fitting the model parameters to the House votes yields c = 0.38 and a = 0.6, which is close to the results for both Senate and House together, c = 0.37 and a = 0.7. However, terms of representative and senators differ so in the future work we plan to study this issue. The second question is about differences in polarization dynamics between the Republican and Democratic Parties. To answer this question requires analysis of the bills that are voted on to measure how consistent each party is in its voting patterns. Again, we defer researching this interesting question to future work. Finally, the third question is related to the implications of the model introduced here that high polarization of voters makes the polarization utility higher to legislators. This trend may lead to higher polarization in the legislative chambers of government. The question arises under what conditions the polarized politicians may in turn influence their electorates to become polarized even more. Finding these conditions is important because should such feedback loop arise, it might destabilize democracy. In our future research, we will attempt to address this question by developing a quantitative model of polarization dynamic of voters that to larger extent than for legislators is shaped by the economic factors [31] and public opinions [32].
Supplementary Material
Acknowledgements
We thank two anonymous referees whose suggestions and comments enabled us to improved the manuscript.
Data accessibility
All data needed to evaluate the conclusions in the paper are available from the website listed in [18].
Authors' contributions
All authors conceptualized the study; X.L. simulated extensively; X.L. and B.K.S. solved analytically; X.L. and B.K.S wrote the paper; all authors edited the paper.
Competing interests
We declare we have no competing interests.
Funding
No funding has been received for this article.
References
- 1.Diamond L. 1990. Three paradoxes of democracy. J. Democr. 1, 48–60. ( 10.1353/jod.1990.0047) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 2.Feldman S. 2003. Enforcing social conformity: a theory of authoritarianism. Political Psychol. 24, 41–74. ( 10.1111/pops.2003.24.issue-1) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Turner J. 1991. Social influence. Pacific Grove, CA: Thomson Brooks/Cole Publishing Corp. [Google Scholar]
- 4.Klucharev V, Hytönen K, Rijpkema M, Smidts A, Fernández G. 2009. Reinforcement learning signal predicts social conformity. Neuron 61, 140–151. ( 10.1016/j.neuron.2008.11.027) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Mcpherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook J. 2001. Birds of a feather: homophily in social networks. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 27, 415–444. ( 10.1146/annurev.soc.27.1.415) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Castellano C, Fortunato S, Loreto V. 2009. Statistical physics of social dynamics. Rev. Mod. Phys. 81, 591–646. ( 10.1103/RevModPhys.81.591) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Stroud N. 2010. Polarization and partisan selective exposure. J. Commun. 60, 556–576. ( 10.1111/jcom.2010.60.issue-3) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Ferrara E, Varol O, Davis C, Menczer F, Flammini A. 2016. The rise of social bots. Commun. ACM 59, 96–104. ( 10.1145/2963119) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 9.Garrett R. 2009. Echo chambers online?: politically motivated selective exposure among Internet news users. J. Comput. Mediat. Commun. 14, 265–285. ( 10.1111/jcmc.2009.14.issue-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Madsen JK, Bailey RM, Pilditch TD. 2018. Large networks of rational agents form persistent echo chambers. Sci. Rep. 8, 12391 ( 10.1038/s41598-018-25558-7) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Jin F, Wang W, Zhao L, Dougherty E, Cao Y, Lu C, Ramakrishnan N. 2014. Misinformation propagation in the age of twitter. Computer 47, 90–94. ( 10.1109/MC.2014.361) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Allcott H, Gentzkow M. 2017. Social media and fake news in the 2016 election. J. Econ. Perspect. 31, 211–236. ( 10.1257/jep.31.2.211) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Lu X, Szymanski BK. 2018. Scalable prediction of global online media news virality. IEEE Trans. Comput. Soc. Syst. 99, 1–13. ( 10.1109/TCSS.2018.2857479) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 14.Garimella K. 2018. Polarization on social media. PhD thesis, Aalto University, Finland.
- 15.Dixit AK, Jorgen W. 2007. Political polarization. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 7351–7356. ( 10.1073/pnas.0702071104) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 16.Bahulkar A, Szymanski BK, Lizardo O, Chawla N, Chan K. 2017. Influence of personal preferences on link dynamics in social networks. Complexity 2017, 4543563 ( 10.1155/2017/4543563) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Deutsch M, Harold G. 1955. A study of normative and informational social influences upon individual judgment. J. Abnorm. Soc. Psychol. 51, 629–636. ( 10.1037/h0046408) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 18.Lewis JB, Poole K, Rosenthal H, Boche A, Rudkin A, Sonnet L. Voteview: congressional roll-call votes database. See https://voteview.com/ (accessed 27 July 2018).
- 19.Abrams D, Yaple H, Wiener R. 2011. Dynamics of social group polarization: modeling the decline of religious affiliation. Phys. Rev. Lett. 107, 088701 ( 10.1103/PhysRevLett.107.088701) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 20.Rice SA. 1928. Quantitative methods in politics. New York, NY: Knopf. [Google Scholar]
- 21.Moody J, Mucha PJ. 2013. Portrait of political party polarization. Netw. Sci. 1, 119–121. ( 10.1017/nws.2012.3) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Baldassarri D, Bearman P. 2007. Dynamics of political polarization. Am. Sociol. Rev. 72, 784–811. ( 10.1177/000312240707200507) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Gu Y, Sun Y, Gao J. 2017 The Co-evolution model for social network evolving and opinion migration. In Proc. of the 23rd ACM SIGKDD Int. Conf. on Knowledge Discovery and Data Mining.Halifax, NS, Canada, 13–17 August. New York, NY: ACM Press.
- 24.Silverman BW. 2018. Density estimation for statistics and data analysis. London, UK: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
- 25.Abrams D, Strogatz S. 2003. Linguistics: modelling the dynamics of language death. Nature 424, 900 ( 10.1038/424900a) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 26.Frachebourg L, Krapivsky P. 1996. Exact results for kinetics of catalytic reactions. Phys. Rev. E 53, R3009–R3012. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.53.R3009) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Perko L. 2013. Differential equations and dynamical systems. Berlin, Germany: Springer Science & Business Media. [Google Scholar]
- 28.Theriault SM. 2008. Party polarization in congress, vol. 168 Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 29.Ansolabehere S, Gerber A, Snyder JM Jr. 2001. Corruption and the growth of campaign spending. A User’s Guide to Campaign Finance Reform, pp. 25–46.
- 30.Bail CA. et al. 2018. Exposure to opposing views on social media can increase political polarization. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 115, 9216–9221. ( 10.1073/pnas.1804840115) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 31.Gelman A. 2011. Economic divisions and political polarization in red and blue America. Pathways 3 (Summer), 3–6. [Google Scholar]
- 32.Baldassarri D, Gelman A. 2008. Partisans without constraint: political polarization and trends in American public opinion. Am. J. Sociol. 114, 408–446. ( 10.1086/590649) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Data Citations
- Lewis JB, Poole K, Rosenthal H, Boche A, Rudkin A, Sonnet L. Voteview: congressional roll-call votes database. See https://voteview.com/ (accessed 27 July 2018).
Supplementary Materials
Data Availability Statement
All data needed to evaluate the conclusions in the paper are available from the website listed in [18].