Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2020 Mar 5;15(3):e0224347. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0224347

Realistic fisheries management reforms could mitigate the impacts of climate change in most countries

Christopher M Free 1,*, Tracey Mangin 1, Jorge García Molinos 2,3,4, Elena Ojea 5, Merrick Burden 6, Christopher Costello 1, Steven D Gaines 1
Editor: Judi Hewitt7
PMCID: PMC7058327  PMID: 32134926

Abstract

Although climate change is altering the productivity and distribution of marine fisheries, climate-adaptive fisheries management could mitigate many of the negative impacts on human society. We forecast global fisheries biomass, catch, and profits to 2100 under three climate scenarios (RCPs 4.5, 6.0, 8.5) and five levels of management reform to (1) determine the impact of climate change on national fisheries and (2) quantify the national-scale benefits of implementing climate-adaptive fisheries reforms. Management reforms accounting for shifting productivity and shifting distributions would yield higher catch and profits in the future relative to today for 60–65% of countries under the two least severe climate scenarios but for only 35% of countries under the most severe scenario. Furthermore, these management reforms would yield higher cumulative catch and profits than business-as-usual management for nearly all countries under the two least severe climate scenarios but would yield lower cumulative catch for 40% of countries under the most severe scenario. Fortunately, perfect fisheries management is not necessary to achieve these benefits: transboundary cooperation with 5-year intervals between adaptive interventions would result in comparable outcomes. However, the ability for realistic management reforms to offset the negative impacts of climate change is bounded by changes in underlying biological productivity. Although realistic reforms could generate higher catch and profits for 23–50% of countries experiencing reductions in productivity, the remaining countries would need to develop, expand, and reform aquaculture and other food production sectors to offset losses in capture fisheries. Still, climate-adaptive management is more profitable than business-as-usual management in all countries and we provide guidance on implementing–and achieving the benefits of–climate-adaptive fisheries reform along a gradient of scientific, management, and enforcement capacities.

Introduction

Marine fisheries provide a vital source of food for over half the world’s population and support the livelihoods of over 56 million people globally [1]. However, the ability for marine fisheries to provide these services is threatened by climate change [2], compromising the contribution of the oceans to sustainable development goals [3]. Ocean warming has already reduced the productivity of many fisheries around the globe, with some regions having experienced up to 35% declines in maximum sustainable yield [4]. An ensemble of marine ecosystem models forecasts continued decreases in marine animal biomass of 4.8% to 17.2% by 2100 under low- to high-end emissions scenarios, respectively [5]. In general, productivity is predicted to decrease in tropical and temperate regions and increase towards the poles [5], as marine organisms shift distributions to maintain their thermal niches [68]. These regional shifts in productivity, range, and fishing opportunity will result in regional discrepancies in food and profits from fisheries [9]. Under current policies, these effects will be unevenly distributed with tropical developing countries and small island developing states exhibiting the greatest vulnerability to the impacts of climate change on fisheries [1012].

The response of fishers and managers to these changes could either exacerbate or mitigate the impacts of climate change on human society and must be considered in forecasts of climate impacts on marine fisheries [13,14]. For example, a failure to reduce harvest rates in response to decreasing productivity could increase the risk of overfishing [15], which could subsequently reduce the resilience of stocks to climate change [4] and result in reduced long-term yields [16]. Similarly, a failure to establish transboundary institutions for managing stocks shifting distributions across territorial boundaries could result in the degradation of management and stock health, catch, and profits [17,18]. In both cases, failing to adapt fisheries management to climate change would exacerbate the impacts of the underlying shifts in productivity on human society. On the other hand, jointly reforming fisheries management and adapting it to account for these climate-driven shifts in productivity and distribution could reduce, or even reverse, the negative impacts of climate change on communities dependent on fishing [13,19].

Gaines et al. [19] provided a critical step towards understanding the opportunities for fisheries reforms to mitigate the impacts of climate change at a global-level. They showed, at a global scale, that business-as-usual fisheries management would exacerbate the negative impacts of climate change, but that climate-adaptive fisheries reforms would maintain global fisheries health, harvest, and profits into the future under all but the most severe emissions scenario evaluated (RCP 8.5). However, the effectiveness and feasibility of these reforms is likely to vary regionally, with higher capacity, poleward countries gaining productivity and lower capacity, tropical countries losing productivity. Furthermore, the benefits documented by Gaines et al. [19] are likely optimistic, as they assume real-time adaptations to shifting productivity. This degree of adaptation potential is unlikely even in the United States where stock assessments are conducted every two to five years [20] and do not frequently include environmental or ecosystem information [21]. Thus, a critical next step in understanding the potential for fisheries reform to mitigate the impacts of climate change on human livelihoods is to examine the performance of more realistic productivity adaptations at the country-level.

Here, we use the Gaines et al. [19] climate-linked bioeconomic model to evaluate the impacts of climate change and management reform on fisheries representing 156 countries, 779 marine fish and invertebrate species, and approximately 58.2% of reported global catch (45.6 of 78.4 mt in 2012; [1]). The evaluated management scenarios address shifting productivity and distributions along a gradient from no adaptation (a.k.a., business-as-usual management) to full adaptation, including scenarios with realistic intervals between management interventions. Overall, we (1) forecast the impacts of climate change on national fisheries and (2) quantify the national-scale benefits of implementing climate-adaptive fisheries reforms. We conclude with a brief overview of promising methods for achieving the benefits of climate-adaptive fisheries reform along a gradient of scientific, management, and enforcement capacities.

Methods

Overview

We used the Gaines et al. [19] climate-linked fisheries bioeconomic model to examine country-level changes in fisheries status, catches, and profits under three emissions scenarios (RCPs 4.5, 6.0, and 8.5; S1 Table) and five management scenarios (Table 1) from 2012 to 2100. Gaines et al. [19] evaluated the 915 single- and mixed-species stocks from Costello et al. [16] with the data required to assess current status and forecast future distributions. In this analysis, we evaluated only the 779 single-species stocks, because the spatial distributions of the mixed-species stocks could not be projected by Gaines et al. [19] and therefore could not be spatially allocated into national jurisdictions. Projections began in 2012 with initial biomasses, fishing mortalities, and conditions (i.e., B/BMSY) determined by aggregating values from Costello et al. [16] (S1 Fig) and initial distributions determined by AquaMaps [22]. Projections were made through 2100 using the following general procedure: (1) distributions were updated based on a modified version of the García Molinos et al. [23] species distribution model (see below); (2) carrying capacities were assumed to change in proportion to changes in range size, i.e., a 10% increase in range size results in a 10% increase in carrying capacity; and (3) biomass, catch, and profits were then updated based on a modified version of the Costello et al. [16] bioeconomic model and the selected management scenario. We provide brief descriptions of the species distribution and bioeconomic models below, but see Gaines et al. [19] and the original references for more details.

Table 1. Fisheries management scenarios evaluated in the analysis (HCR = harvest control rule; EEZ = exclusive economic zone).

Management scenario
Business-as-usual (no adaptation)
 This scenario assumes that no action is taken: management fails to account for range or productivity shifts or fix economically sub-optimal harvest rates. Thus, current fishing mortality is maintained for all static (non-shifting) stocks and gradually shifts to open access for all transboundary (shifting) stocks given the lack of transboundary agreements.
  HCR for static stocks: Current fishing mortality
  HCR for transboundary stocks: Gradual shift from current to open access fishing mortality
Range shift adaptation only
 This scenario assumes that management adapts to spatial changes in range location by implementing transboundary institutions that facilitate continued management of stocks as they shift into and out of EEZs. However, management does not address corresponding changes in productivity or fix economically sub-optimal harvest rates. Thus, the scenario prevents open access fishing of transboundary (shifting) stocks but does not otherwise improve fisheries management.
  HCR for static and transboundary stocks: Current fishing mortality
Productivity shift adaptation only
 This scenario assumes that management is naturally adaptive to changes in productivity and fixes economically sub-optimal harvest rates by adopting an economically optimal HCR where the appropriate harvest rate adjusts based on the total biomass that year. However, this scenario assumes that management does not address transboundary issues associated with spatial range shifts. Thus, this scenario optimizes harvest for static (non-shifting) stocks but sees a shift from optimal to open access harvest for transboundary (non-shifting) stocks.
  HCR for static stocks: Economically optimal fishing mortality; harvest rate depends on the total biomass that year
  HCR for transboundary stocks: Gradual shift from economically optimal to open access fishing mortality
Full adaptation
 This scenario assumes that management fixes economically sub-optimal harvest rates accounting for shifts in productivity and effectively prepares for range shifts by implementing transboundary institutions. Thus, this scenario assumes adaptive, economically optimal harvest rates even as stocks shift into and out of EEZs.
  HCR for static and transboundary stocks: Economically optimal fishing mortality; harvest rate depends on the total biomass that year
Realistic adaptation (implemented at 5, 10, and 20-year intervals)
 This scenario implements a more realistic representation of the full adaptation scenario by acknowledging that management rarely acts annually. Instead, this scenario assumes that management sets an economically optimal harvest rate based on the total biomass at regular assessment intervals and maintains this rate, regardless of shifts in productivity, until the next assessment. The scenario assumes that transboundary institutions maintain this management interval as stocks shift into and out of EEZs.
  HCR for static and transboundary stocks: Economically optimal rate in the year of assessment is maintained until the next assessment (5, 10, or 20 years later)

Species distribution model

The modified García Molinos et al. [23] species distribution model (SDM) is a bioclimatic envelope model that uses information on species depth preferences, thermal tolerances, and the direction and speed of thermal change, i.e., climate velocity, to project changes in species distributions under warming. AquaMaps species distribution maps [22] were used as the starting point (i.e., 2012) for the projections. In each subsequent time step, the SDM calculated the relocation of the distribution (thermal envelope) of each species as dictated by the spatial direction and rate of change of local (1° resolution) climate velocities based on sea surface temperatures under the selected emissions scenario (RCPs 4.5, 6.0, and 8.5; S1 Table). Range projections are restricted by species’ thermal tolerances and depth preferences [19].

Bioeconomic model and management scenarios

The modified Costello et al. [16] bioeconomic model uses a Pella-Tomlinson [24] surplus production model to forecast fish population dynamics under five management scenarios (Table 1). The Pella-Tomlinson production model requires four input parameters for each stock: the initial biomass, carrying capacity (K), intrinsic growth rate (g), and a shape parameter (ϕ) that determines the proportion of carrying capacity at which production is maximized. Parameters were developed for species-stocks following the procedure detailed in Gaines et al. [19] and are based on individual stock parameters [16] sourced from a combination of production models fit to the RAM Legacy Database [25] and catch-MSY models [26] fit to the FAO Catch Database [1]. The shape parameter is fixed at the meta-analytic average for fish [27], which maximizes productivity at 40% of carrying capacity. Carrying capacity is updated each year based on the resulting changes in range size from the SDM assuming a 1:1 proportional change (see [19] for a detailed justification of this assumption). A correlated change in range size and population abundance is predicted by the basin model hypothesis [28] which posits that range size will co-vary with population abundance through density-dependent habitat selection. Empirical support for this correlation has been shown for many marine species [2934] and the proportionality of this correlation was confirmed by an analysis of the distribution and relative abundance of 11 unfished species in Gaines et al. [19]. Although habitat degradation, resource limitation, disease, and other factors may also impact carrying capacity, we do not consider them here.

The harvest rate is based on the following five management scenarios: business-as-usual (i.e., no adaptation), productivity shift adaptation only, range shift adaptation only, full adaptation, and “realistic” adaptation (see Tables 1 and 2 for details). Productivity shift adaptations improve fisheries management by implementing a dynamic, economically-optimal harvest policy given current biological conditions, which optimally adjusts harvest mortality based on the total biomass that year, and is therefore naturally adaptive to climate-driven productivity changes. Range shift adaptations assume that transboundary cooperation results in the maintenance of management, rather than the degradation of management to open access, as stocks shift across boundaries. Business-as-usual management fails to implement either adaptation: it maintains current harvest rates for species that do not shift spatially, while management degrades to open access for stocks that shift across boundaries. Full adaptation assumes that both challenges are addressed: the dynamic economically-optimal harvest policy is implemented and maintained even as stocks shift across boundaries. Realistic adaptation refines the full adaptation scenario by implementing productivity shift adaptations at plausible management intervals: it determines the economically-optimal harvest rates on 5, 10, or 20-year intervals and maintains these rates until the next management intervention. The economically-optimal harvest rate was implemented without error; thus, scenarios implementing this policy represent the best case for fisheries assessment and management performance. In each scenario, all countries operate under the same management paradigm (e.g., they all implement business-as-usual management or they all implement realistic adaptive management; they never implement a mixture of management paradigms). Although we acknowledge that successful implementation of the required optimal fishery reforms is ultimately dependent on a country’s scientific, management, and enforcement capacities, this was a necessary simplification given our goal of modeling the impact of transboundary cooperation that either maintains or fails to maintain management as stocks shift across boundaries.

Table 2. Harvest control rules used in the management scenarios*.

Harvest control rule (HCR)
Current fishing mortality
 This HCR continues the initial fishing mortality rate (i.e., F in 2012) through all years.
Economically optimal fishing mortality
 This HCR achieves maximum net present value (NPV) over an infinite time horizon under the current climate and biological conditions. Each stock has its own optimized harvest policy where fishing mortality rate is a function of biomass. This HCR is determined using a dynamic optimization routine for each stock.
Gradual shift from current to open access fishing mortality
 This HCR is only relevant to transboundary stocks. For these stocks, fishing mortality begins at the initial fishing mortality rate (i.e., F in 2012), then changes at a constant rate towards open access fishing mortality (i.e., fishing mortality that achieves open access equilibrium at 30% of BMSY), which is reached in the year in which the first spatial shift into or completely out of an EEZ occurs. Fishing mortality remains at the open access rate for all subsequent years.
Gradual shift from economically optimal to open access fishing mortality
 This HCR is only relevant to transboundary stocks. For these stocks, fishing mortality begins at the economically optimal level given biomass in 2012, then changes at a constant rate towards open access fishing mortality (i.e., fishing mortality that achieves open access equilibrium at 30% of BMSY), which is reached in the year in which the first spatial shift into or completely out of an EEZ occurs. Fishing mortality remains at the open access rate for all subsequent years.

* See the Gaines et al. [19] supplementary information for more details on the management scenarios and harvest control rules.

Profits were calculated as revenues minus costs where (1) revenues were calculated as catch multiplied by species-specific ex-vessel prices [35] and (2) costs represent the costs of fishing, which were derived for each species-stock, and were assumed to increase exponentially with fishing effort (see Gaines et al. [19] and Costello et al. [16] for additional details and equations).

Country-level fisheries outcomes

We evaluated the impact of climate change and management reform on the fisheries of 156 coastal sovereign countries summing across their domestic and territorial exclusive economic zones (EEZs). We scaled the projections of Gaines et al. [19] from the global- to country-level by assuming that the proportion of a species’ overall range occurring inside a country’s EEZ (determined by the SDM) is identical to the proportion of the species’ overall carrying capacity occurring inside the country’s EEZ. This proportion was used to generate time series of biomass, harvest, and profit for each species in each country under all three emissions scenarios and five management scenarios. We summarized country-level projections by comparing fisheries outcomes: (1) in 2100 relative to today under each management scenario and (2) over the entire period (2012–2100) for each of the adaptation scenarios relative to the business-as-usual scenario. These approaches allow us to, respectively, estimate the projected impact of climate change on national fisheries outcomes under the different management scenarios and the cost of failing to adapt national fisheries management to account for climate change.

For Approach 1, we compared the percent difference in harvests and profits in 2100 relative to today (i.e., 2012) under each management scenario. While Gaines et al. [19] performed this comparison using only the projection endpoints (i.e., values in 2012 and 2100), we compared mean decadal values at the ends of the projection window (i.e., mean value in 2012–2021 and 2091–2100) to reduce sensitivity to specific endpoint values. For Approach 2, we compared the percent difference in cumulative harvest and cumulative profits between the four adaptation scenarios and the business-as-usual scenario. By examining differences in cumulative harvest and profits, this approach is also insensitive to endpoints and documents the accumulated benefits or losses of climate adaptive management. In both approaches, we quantified the impact of climate change and fisheries management on fisheries health as the mean proportion of stocks with biomass above BMSY, the biomass that produces MSY when fished at FMSY, by century’s end (2091–2100). This is a common target for fisheries management (i.e., U.S. Magnuson Stevens Act, E.U. Common Fisheries Policy, and U.N. Sustainable Development Goals). This performance metric better reflects the goals of fisheries management than percent change in biomass. For example, decreasing biomass in a previously undeveloped fishery is an expected consequence of economically optimal management and should only be perceived negatively when the decrease reduces biomass below the target.

Results

Impacts of climate change on maximum sustainable yield

Maximum sustainable yield (MSY) of the evaluated stocks is forecast to decrease by 2.0%, 5.0%, and 18.5% from 2012–2021 to 2091–2100 under RCPs 4.5, 6.0, and 8.5, respectively (Fig 1). Note that these values differ slightly from those reported in Gaines et al. [19] because we excluded mixed-species stocks and measured changes in MSY using decadal means. Across emissions scenarios, MSY is generally projected to decrease for equatorial countries and increase for poleward countries (Fig 1 and S2 Fig). Variability around this common prediction is explained by heterogeneity in local oceanographic conditions, climate velocities, and community compositions [36]. Particularly dramatic reductions in MSY are predicted for the equatorial West African countries. Even under the least severe emissions scenario, nineteen countries, fifteen of which are in West Africa, are projected to experience reductions in MSY of 50–100%. The number of countries projected to experience dramatic losses in MSY, and the intensity of these losses, expands under the more severe emissions scenarios. In the most severe scenario, 51 countries are expected to experience reductions in MSY of 50–100% (Fig 1). All eighteen West African countries south of Senegal and north of Angola (including these two countries) are forecast to experience reductions in MSY greater than 85%. The equatorial Indo-Pacific and South America are also projected to experience considerable losses in MSY under the three emissions scenarios, with especially pronounced losses under RCP 8.5 (Fig 1). Twenty-two countries are projected to experience increases in MSY under all three emissions scenarios with seven of these countries showing a 15% average increase in MSY across scenarios. The five most consistent and pronounced climate change “winners” are: Finland, Antarctica, Norway (4 EEZs: Norway plus Bouvet Island, Jan Mayen, and Svalbard), Portugal (3 EEZs: Portugal plus Azores and Madeira), and Fiji.

Fig 1. Percent change in maximum sustainable yield (MSY) under each emission scenario.

Fig 1

In the left column, maps show the percent change in MSY from 2012–2021 (“today”) to 2091–2100 in each exclusive economic zone. In the right column, the colored lines show the percent change in MSY (measured in 10-year running averages) relative to 2012–2021 (“today”) for each of 156 countries and the black lines show the percent change globally.

Ability for management reform to mitigate global climate impacts

Business-as-usual (BAU) management results in both lower catches and profits in the future relative to today under all three emissions scenarios (Fig 2). In contrast, full adaptation yields both higher catches and profits in the future in all but the most severe emissions scenario (RCP 8.5); in this scenario, full adaptation yields higher profits but lower catches in the future relative to today. Addressing productivity shifts and range shifts in isolation is insufficient for jointly maintaining catch and profits into the future under any of the emissions scenario (Fig 2). However, realistic adaptation, which recalibrates productivity management at 5, 10, and 20-year intervals and maintains this management regime as stocks shift across boundaries, frequently achieves better outcomes in the future relative to today (Fig 2). Notably, realistic adaption that implements adaptive management at 5-year intervals performs comparably to full adaptation and generates both higher catch and profits in the future relative to today under the two least severe emissions scenarios (Fig 2). The ability for management reforms to offset losses due to climate change is largely due to the global legacy of sub-optimal management: only 11.5% of the evaluated stocks were fished near optimal levels (i.e., 0.8 ≤ B/BMSY ≤ 1.2 and 0.8 ≤ F/FMSY ≤ 1.2) in the initial year (S1 Fig); thus, reforms that end overfishing and sustainably exploit new resources jointly improve long-term yields.

Fig 2. Percent difference in mean catch and profits in 2091–2100 relative to 2012–2021 (“today”) from all stocks under each emission and management scenario.

Fig 2

Ability for management reform to mitigate country-level climate impacts

While business-as-usual management results in lower catches and profits relative to today for the majority of countries (82–85% of countries), full adaptation yields higher catches and profits for a majority of countries in all but the most severe emission scenario (Fig 3 and S3 Fig). In this scenario, only 35% of countries experience both increased profits and catches, while 59% of countries experience both reduced catches and profits (Fig 3). Realistic adaptation implemented at 5-year intervals achieves outcomes quite similar to full adaptation: it results in higher catch and profits for the majority (56–63%) of countries under RCPs 4.5 and 6.0 but lower catch and profits for the majority (59%) of countries under RCP 8.5 (Fig 3). The ability for adaptation to maintain or increase fisheries outcomes under climate change is sensitive to the direction and magnitude of changes in underlying productivity (Figs 35). For example, the West African countries projected to experience the greatest losses in MSY are also projected to have the most limited ability to mitigate these impacts (Figs 1 and 4). Although realistic adaptation (5-yr) could increase both catch and profits for 51% of the countries projected to lose underlying productivity (i.e., lower MSY) in the least severe emissions scenario, it could increase outcomes despite losses in productivity for only 23% of countries in the most severe emissions scenario (Fig 4). In comparison, realistic adaptation (5-yr) could increase both catch and profit for a much larger proportion of countries projected to gain underlying productivity: 78% of these countries (n = 69) could increase both catch and profits in the least severe emissions scenario and this percentage actually increases to 95% in the most severe emissions scenario as these poleward countries (n = 22) inherit even more productivity (Fig 4). Neither realistic (5-yr) nor full adaptation are sufficient to maintain fisheries outcomes into the future for all countries, but they are nearly always preferable to business-as-usual management. In all but the most severe emissions scenario, both full adaptation and realistic adaptation yield both higher cumulative catches and profits than business-as-usual management for nearly all countries (98–99% of countries; Fig 6 and S4 Fig). In the most severe scenario, full adaptation and realistic adaptation yield higher cumulative profits than business-as-usual management, but achieve lower cumulative catches for 40–41% of countries (Fig 6).

Fig 3. Percent difference in mean catch and profits in 2091–2100 relative to 2012–2021 (“today”) for 156 countries under three emissions scenarios (columns) and three management scenarios (rows).

Fig 3

The percentage labels indicate the percentage of countries falling in each quadrant of catch and profit outcomes. Note that changes in catch and profits do not always match. This occurs when climate change and management strategies differentially favor more productive but less profitable species relative to less productive but more profitable species.

Fig 5. Percent difference in mean catch and profits in 2091–2100 relative to 2012–2021 (“today”) for 156 countries under realistic adaptation implementing management at 5-year intervals.

Fig 5

Grey shading indicates countries without marine territories.

Fig 4. Influence of changes in maximum sustainable yield (MSY) on the ability for management to generate higher catch and profits in the future (2091–2100) relative to today (2012–2021).

Fig 4

Bars indicate the proportion of countries experiencing each combination of catch and profits trajectories under each emissions scenario, management scenario (rows), and change in underlying productivity (columns). The number of countries experiencing reductions in MSY increases under increasingly severe emissions scenarios (see column title for numbers). Although the number of countries experiencing gains in MSY decreases under increasingly severe emissions scenarios (see column title for numbers), the gains in MSY in these countries are actually magnified with increasing emissions (i.e., more fish stocks move into their exclusive economic zones with more rapid warming).

Fig 6. Percent difference in cumulative catch and cumulative profits from 2012–2100 relative to business-as-usual for 156 countries under three emissions scenarios (columns) and two adaptation scenarios (rows).

Fig 6

The percentage labels indicate the percentage of countries falling in each quadrant of catch and profit outcomes.

Discussion

Overall, our results indicate that climate change will dramatically alter the distribution and productivity of marine fisheries, but plausible climate-adaptive management reforms could minimize or eliminate negative impacts in most countries. This reinforces and expands upon the work of Gaines et al. [19] in two important ways. First, whereas Gaines et al. [19] document the benefits of management reform at a global-level, we focus on the distributional consequences of these global effects by evaluating the benefits that individual countries stand to gain from climate-adaptive fisheries reforms. Second, we recognize that perfectly adapting to changing productivity will be a challenge in even the most sophisticated fisheries systems [15,37] and evaluate a more realistic scenario that implements well-intentioned, yet imperfect, adaptation to productivity shifts. These expansions are important because they place more realistic bounds on the ability for management to mitigate the impacts of climate change and present practitioners with a tool for investigating the impacts of climate change and opportunities for reform in their respective country’s fisheries.

Our model predicts shifts in productivity that are consistent in both pattern and magnitude with a recent ensemble model [5] that averaged the predictions of six other peer-reviewed marine ecosystem models. We estimated 2.0% and 18.5% decreases in maximum sustainable yield from 2012–2100 under RCPs 4.5 and 8.5, respectively. By comparison, Lotze et al. [5] estimated 8.6% (±6.0% SD) and 17.2% (±10.7% SD) decreases in marine animal biomass in the absence of fishing from 1990–2100 under the same two emissions scenarios. The Lotze et al. [5] ensemble model, its constituent models, and our model all predict increases in productivity in poleward regions and decreases in productivity in tropical to temperate regions. The slight differences in the productivity shifts predicted by our model and the ensemble model are unsurprising given the differences in the structure, mechanistic drivers, and taxonomic scope of our model and the ensemble’s constituent models.

Importantly, however, our approach differs from these studies, because, in addition to forecasting the impact of climate change on the biological potential of fisheries, we consider the impact of alternative human responses to these changes, which could either exacerbate or alleviate the impacts of changing biological potential [13]. Indeed, our results indicate that all countries would benefit from reforming current management to account for shifting distributions and productivity and that many countries could even see higher catch and profits than today with such reforms. However, the ability for management reform to mitigate the impacts of climate change is dependent on swift efforts to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Even perfect climate-adaptive management (“full adaptation”) is unable to maintain current catch and profits under high-end greenhouse gas emissions (RCP 8.5). Furthermore, although perfect adaptation could maintain global catch and profits under partial emission reductions (RCP 6.0), tropical and temperate regions would still incur dramatic losses in fisheries benefits. This underscores the fact that emission reductions consistent with the Paris Agreement could have significant impacts on the ability for fisheries to feed and employ people into the future [38,39].

The development and implementation of stock assessment methods and management strategies necessary to achieve benefits in the face of climate change is nascent but rapidly developing. For example, Skern-Mauritzen et al. [40] reviewed 1,250 stock assessments from around the world and found that only 2% incorporated ecosystem information into either the final stock assessment model or the recommended harvest control rule. In the United States, Marshall et al. [21] found greater, though still limited, incorporation of ecosystem information into stock assessments: 24% of 206 evaluated assessment reports included ecosystem information in either the exploratory or final stock assessment models. The effective incorporation of environmental information into management strategies is similarly challenging but is also increasing in frequency and effectiveness. Punt et al. [37] reviewed management strategy evaluation (MSE) studies that test procedures for setting environmentally-linked harvest control rules and found that, in general, these procedures were only effective when the environmental drivers were well understood. This emphasizes the need for increasing monitoring and process-oriented lab and field studies in conjunction with the development and testing of more sophisticated analytical techniques [41].

Furthermore, achieving the benefits of climate-adaptive fisheries reform will require accounting for shifting productivity and distributions along a gradient of scientific, management, and enforcement capacities. Many countries lack the monitoring programs required to detect and describe shifts in distribution and productivity, the scientific capacity for conducting either climate-agnostic or climate-adaptive stock assessments, and the management capacity for setting and enforcing fisheries regulations [25,42,43]. This is frequently the case for the tropical developing countries that are forecast to experience the greatest losses in fisheries catch and profits under climate change and exhibit the greatest vulnerability to these reductions in food and income [44]. The tools for enacting climate-adaptive fisheries reforms and achieving biological and socioeconomic resilience to climate change will have to span this gradient of capacity.

Fortunately, a growing body of literature provides guidance on accounting for shifting distributions and productivity in fisheries assessment and management [14,17,45,46] and for fostering socioeconomic resilience to climate change [4749] in diverse fisheries systems. In the remainder of this paper, we provide a brief overview of this literature and recommend general principles as well as specific strategies for achieving the benefits of climate-adaptive management reforms. We offer recommendations for higher and lower capacity fisheries systems as well as recommendations for countries where even the best management reforms will be unable to offset the negative impacts of climate change.

Guiding principles for climate-adaptive fisheries management

Principle #1: Implement best practices in fisheries management

Historically, well-managed fisheries have been among the most resilient to climate change [4], and our results predict that well-intended, albeit imperfect, management will continue to confer climate resilience. Together, these results indicate that the wider implementation of best practices in fisheries management will mitigate many of the negative impacts of climate change. In higher capacity systems, best practices include scientifically-informed catch limits, accountability measures, regional flexibility in policy practices, and protection of essential fish habitat [50]. In the United States, such measures have contributed to dramatic declines in overfishing, increases in biomass, and maintenance of catch and profits [51]. In lower capacity systems, best practices include implementing “primary fisheries management” [52] that uses best available science and precautionary principles to manage data-poor and capacity-limited fisheries and establishing local, rights-based management [48] to incentivize sustainable stewardship. Rights-based management systems include catch share programs such as Individual Transferable Quotas (ITQs) and Territorial Use Rights in Fisheries (TURFs) that define property rights over catch and space, respectively [53]. By giving users ownership of the resource, well-designed rights-based management systems incentivize long-term stewardship and have been shown to promote compliance, prevent overfishing, and increase profits [16,54,55]. Enforcement and the strength of fishing pressure limits are also key for successful fisheries management [56] and contribute to a precautionary approach in the face of climate change. Overall, fisheries best practices confer ecological resilience by maintaining healthy stock sizes, age structures, and genetic diversity and socioeconomic resilience by providing a portfolio of options to fishers and a buffer against climate-driven losses in any one target stock.

Principle #2: Be dynamic, flexible, and forward-looking

Adapting to climate change will require dynamic, flexible, and forward-looking management. This can be achieved by aligning management policies with the spatio-temporal scales of climate change, ecosystem change, and socioeconomic responses [14]. In higher capacity systems, this could involve four broad strategies. First, managers can envision and prepare for alternative futures using tools such as forecasts [57,58], structured scenario planning [59,60], holistic ecosystem models [61,62], risk assessments [63], and climate vulnerability analyses [64]. Second, the proliferation of near real-time biological, oceanographic, social, and/or economic data can be harnessed for proactive and dynamic adjustments in spatial and temporal management actions [65]. Third, developing harvest control rules that account for or are robust to changing environmental conditions affecting productivity can increase catch while also reducing the probability of overfishing [66]. Finally, all of these management procedures should be simulation tested through management strategy evaluation (MSE; [67]) to measure the efficacy of alternative strategies and their robustness under different climate scenarios [37]. In lower capacity systems, forward looking fisheries management could include precautionary management to buffer against uncertainty [68] as well as management strategies that preserve population resilience, age structure, and genetic diversity. For example, size limits, seasonal closures, and protected areas can be used to protect the big, old, fecund, females (BOFFs) that disproportionately contribute to reproductive output [69] and to maintain the genetic diversity required to promote evolutionary adaptations to climate change.

Principle #3: Foster international cooperation

Shifting distributions are already generating management challenges and the rates of these shifts and associated conflicts are expected to increase with climate change [17,18,70]. New or strengthened international institutions and agreements will be necessary to ensure that management remains sustainable as stocks shift between jurisdictions. First, this will require sharing data between Regional Fisheries Management Organizations (RFMOs) or countries to identify, describe, and forecast shifting stocks. Second, it will require a commitment to use these shared data to inform collaborative management. For example, these data could be used to regularly and objectively update national allocations of catch or effort based on changes in distribution rather than historical allocations (e.g., [71,72]). An alternative approach could be to develop fisheries permits that are tradeable across political boundaries, which would allow future resource users access to fisheries not yet in their waters and incentivize good management [73]. Finally, incentivizing the cooperation necessary to establish data sharing and collaborative management will require overcoming prevailing management mentalities that one party “wins” while the other “loses” when stocks shift across boundaries. This could involve broadening negotiations to allow for alternative avenues of compensation or “side payments” [74]. In cases where establishing international cooperation proves difficult, marine protected areas (MPAs) placed along country borders could buy time for negotiations by protecting stocks as they shift across borders. A more precautionary approach would be to put new fishing areas on hold until adaptive management can be put in place, as illustrated by the Central Arctic Ocean Fisheries Agreement (e.g., the CAOF Agreement, [75]).

Principle #4: Build socioeconomic resilience

The impact of climate change on fishing communities can be reduced through measures that increase socioeconomic resilience and adaptive capacity to environmental variability and changing fisheries [49,76,77]. Across low to high capacity systems, these measures include (1) policies that facilitate flexibility, such as diversification of access to fisheries and alternative livelihoods, (2) policies that provide better assets, such as the enhancement of fisheries technology and capacity, (3) policies that provide better organization in the system, including multi-level governance, community-based management, and other governance structures [14,48], and (4) policies that promote agency and learning [49]. For example, policies that promote access to multiple fisheries provide fishers with a portfolio of fishing opportunities that can buffer against variability [78,79] while policies that promote diverse livelihoods reduce reliance on fisheries [80,81]. Increased mobility through technological enhancements can increase social resilience by allowing fishers to follow shifting stocks [49], but can also result in the migration of fishers. Multi-level governance promotes flexibility in resource governance by matching biological and management across scales [82]. Community-based management can increase adaptive capacity by incorporating local knowledge and can improve sustainability by fostering a sense of stewardship [83]. Spatial-rights based approaches such as TURFs may confer social resilience insofar as they are often community-managed and allow fishers to generate revenues through other compatible activities such as tourism, recreation, and aquaculture [84]. On the other hand, ITQs may confer a different kind of resilience because rights are defined over fish catch rather than spatial areas. Therefore, they may be more resilient to range shifts arising from climate change assuming that the quota right remains usable in the new range of the species. Furthermore, all of these measures can be designed to reduce fishing pressure, and promote ecological resilience to climate change.

Aquaculture could help compensate for losses in capture fisheries

Even the best climate-adaptive management will be unable to maintain current catch and profits in most tropical developing countries. Although these countries should still pursue climate-adaptive reforms to maximize catch and profits from capture fisheries, they will also need to develop, expand, and reform other sectors to compensate for capture fishery losses and meet growing production demands [85]. Marine aquaculture (hereafter called mariculture), the cultivation of marine animals and plants, presents a particularly promising substitute for capture fisheries. The biological potential for mariculture is enormous [86] and exceeds both current production and projected demand even after accounting for economic feasibility and the availability of feed for fed-finfish mariculture [87]. This potential is expected to decrease under climate change [88] but breeding a larger proportion of stocks for fast growth could more than offset these negative impacts [89]. Expanding mariculture under climate change will require (1) streamlining permitting for sustainable mariculture in highly regulated countries where mariculture growth has often been slow [9093]; (2) promoting better practices in weakly regulated countries where mariculture growth has often been rapid and less sustainable [92,93]; and (3) promoting access to financial resources such as credit and insurance in countries where mariculture production has yet to develop [94]. Although mariculture has the potential to feed millions of people, it also poses a number of environmental problems including pollution, habitat conversion, disease and parasite transmission, and escapement and hybridization [95]. The expansion of large-scale mariculture for increased food and employment opportunities will thus require a better understanding of these environmental tradeoffs and the best practices for managing them [96].

Conclusions

Although climate change is expected to reduce the productivity of marine fisheries globally [5], climate-adaptive fisheries management reforms could mitigate many of the negative impacts on the food and income provisioning potential of the ocean [19]. Our results suggest that climate-adaptive fisheries could result in higher catch and profits than business-as-usual management in all countries. For most countries, climate-adaptive management reforms could result in higher catch and profits in the future than today. However, the ability for management reforms to offset negative impacts is diminished under increasingly severe greenhouse gas emission scenarios. Thus, swift actions to reduce emissions will be necessary to limit the impacts of climate change on fisheries, especially in developing tropical countries. For many of these countries, even the best climate-adaptive fisheries reforms will be insufficient to maintain current levels of catch and profits into the future. Adaptation in these countries will require innovations in sustainable mariculture and other food sectors to ensure that countries are able to meet the food and nutrition requirements of their growing populations [85]. As land-based sources of food also falter [97], the ocean will become an increasingly important source of nutrition. Achieving these benefits will depend on swift and innovative management actions.

Supporting information

S1 Table. Representative Concentration Pathways (RCPs) evaluated in the analysis*.

* See Table S1 in Gaines et al. [19] for earth system models contributing to ensemble mean. Note: RCP 2.6 is not evaluated because it is no longer likely (Raftery et al. 2017).

(DOCX)

S1 Fig. Initial condition of the 779 species stocks.

The transparent grey box indicates near optimal fisheries management (i.e., i.e., 0.8 ≤ B/BMSY ≤ 1.2 and 0.8 ≤ F/FMSY ≤ 1.2).

(TIFF)

S2 Fig. Projected change in maximum sustainable yield (MSY) as a function of latitude (absolute degrees) under three emissions scenarios.

(TIFF)

S3 Fig. Percent difference in mean catch and profits in 2091–2100 relative to 2012–2021 (“today”) for 156 countries under three emissions scenarios (columns) and seven management scenarios (rows).

The percentage labels indicate the percentage of countries falling in each quadrant of catch and profit outcomes.

(TIFF)

S4 Fig. Percent difference in cumulative catch and cumulative profits from 2012–2100 relative to business-as-usual for 156 countries under three emissions scenarios (columns) and six management scenarios (rows).

The percentage labels indicate the percentage of countries falling in each quadrant of catch and profit outcomes.

(TIFF)

Acknowledgments

We thank Kate Bonzon and Willow Battista for valuable discussions while preparing the manuscript.

Data Availability

All data are available here: https://github.com/SFG-UCSB/cc_trade.

Funding Statement

This work was funded by the Environmental Defense Fund. J.G.M. was supported by the “Tenure-Track System Promotion Program” of the Japanese Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology (MEXT). E.O. was supported by the European Research Council project CLOCK (GA. 679812) and GAIN-Xunta de Galicia Oportunius program. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1.FAO. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2018—Meeting the sustainable development goals. 2018; 1–227.
  • 2.IPCC. IPCC Special Report on the Ocean and Cryosphere in a Changing Climate. 2019. https://report.ipcc.ch/srocc/pdf/SROCC_FinalDraft_FullReport.pdf [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 3.Singh GG, Hilmi N, Bernhardt JR, Montemayor AMC, Cashion M, Ota Y, et al. Climate impacts on the ocean are making the Sustainable Development Goals a moving target travelling away from us. People Nat. 2019;1: 317–330. 10.1002/pan3.26 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Free CM, Thorson JT, Pinsky ML, Oken KL, Wiedenmann J, Jensen OP. Impacts of historical warming on marine fisheries production. Science. 2019;363: 979–983. 10.1126/science.aau1758 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Lotze HK, Tittensor DP, Bryndum-Buchholz A, Eddy TD, Cheung WWL, Galbraith ED, et al. Global ensemble projections reveal trophic amplification of ocean biomass declines with climate change. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2019;116: 12907–12912. 10.1073/pnas.1900194116 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Pinsky ML, Worm B, Fogarty MJ, Sarmiento JL, Levin SA. Marine taxa track local climate velocities. Science. 2013;341: 1239–1242. 10.1126/science.1239352 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Poloczanska ES, Brown CJ, Sydeman WJ, Kiessling W, Schoeman DS, Moore PJ, et al. Global imprint of climate change on marine life. Nat Clim Change. 2013;3: 919–925. 10.1038/nclimate1958 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Poloczanska ES, Burrows MT, Brown CJ, García Molinos J, Halpern BS, Hoegh-Guldberg O, et al. Responses of Marine Organisms to Climate Change across Oceans. Front Mar Sci. 2016;3 10.3389/fmars.2016.00062 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Lam VWY, Cheung WWL, Reygondeau G, Sumaila UR. Projected change in global fisheries revenues under climate change. Sci Rep. 2016;6: 32607 10.1038/srep32607 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Blasiak R, Spijkers J, Tokunaga K, Pittman J, Yagi N, Österblom H. Climate change and marine fisheries: Least developed countries top global index of vulnerability. PLOS ONE. 2017;12: e0179632 10.1371/journal.pone.0179632 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Guillotreau P, Campling L, Robinson J. Vulnerability of small island fishery economies to climate and institutional changes. Curr Opin Environ Sustain. 2012;4: 287–291. 10.1016/j.cosust.2012.06.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Allison EH, Perry AL, Badjeck MC, Neil Adger W, Brown K, Conway D, et al. Vulnerability of national economies to the impacts of climate change on fisheries. Fish Fish. 2009;10: 173–196. 10.1111/j.1467-2979.2008.00310.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Barange M. Avoiding misinterpretation of climate change projections of fish catches. Browman H, editor. ICES J Mar Sci J Cons. 2019;4: 211–3. 10.1093/icesjms/fsz061 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Holsman KK, Hazen EL, Haynie A, Gourguet S, Hollowed A, Bograd SJ, et al. Towards climate resiliency in fisheries management. Anderson E, editor. ICES J Mar Sci. 2019; fsz031. 10.1093/icesjms/fsz031 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Szuwalski CS, Hollowed AB. Climate change and non-stationary population processes in fisheries management. ICES J Mar Sci. 2016;73: 1297–1305. 10.1093/icesjms/fsv229 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Costello C, Ovando D, Clavelle T, Strauss CK, Hilborn R, Melnychuk MC, et al. Global fishery prospects under contrasting management regimes. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A. 2016;113: 5125–5129. 10.1073/pnas.1520420113 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Pinsky ML, Reygondeau G, Caddell R, Palacios-Abrantes J, Spijkers J, Cheung WWL. Preparing ocean governance for species on the move. Science. 2018;360: 1189–1191. 10.1126/science.aat2360 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Spijkers J, Boonstra WJ. Environmental change and social conflict: the northeast Atlantic mackerel dispute. 2017; 1–17. 10.1007/s10113-017-1150-4 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Gaines SD, Costello C, Owashi B, Mangin T, Bone J, Molinos JG, et al. Improved fisheries management could offset many negative effects of climate change. Sci Adv. 2018;4: eaao1378. 10.1126/sciadv.aao1378 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Neubauer P, Thorson JT, Melnychuk MC, Methot R, Blackhart K. Drivers and rates of stock assessments in the United States. MacKenzie BR, editor. PLOS ONE. 2018;13: e0196483–19. 10.1371/journal.pone.0196483 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Marshall KN, Koehn LE, Levin PS, Essington TE, Jensen OP, Handling editor: Marta Coll. Inclusion of ecosystem information in US fish stock assessments suggests progress toward ecosystem-based fisheries management. ICES J Mar Sci J Cons. 2018;76: 1–9. 10.1093/icesjms/fsy152 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Kaschner K, Kesner-Reyes K, Garilao C, Rius-Barile J, Rees T, Froese R. AquaMaps: Predicted range maps for aquatic species. 2019. https://www.aquamaps.org/ [Google Scholar]
  • 23.García Molinos J, Halpern BS, Schoeman DS, Brown CJ, Kiessling W, Moore PJ, et al. Climate velocity and the future global redistribution of marine biodiversity. Nat Clim Change. 2016;6: 83–88. 10.1038/nclimate2769 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Pella JJ, Tomlinson PK. A generalized stock production model. Inter-Am Trop Tuna Comm Bull. 1969;13: 421–454. [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Ricard D, Minto C, Jensen OP, Baum JK. Examining the knowledge base and status of commercially exploited marine species with the RAM Legacy Stock Assessment Database. Fish Fish. 2012;13: 380–398. 10.1111/j.1467-2979.2011.00435.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Martell S, Froese R. A simple method for estimating MSY from catch and resilience. Fish Fish. 2013;14: 504–514. 10.1111/j.1467-2979.2012.00485.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Thorson JT, Cope JM, Branch TA, Jensen OP, Walters CJ. Spawning biomass reference points for exploited marine fishes, incorporating taxonomic and body size information. Can J Fish Aquat Sci. 2012;69: 1556–1568. 10.1139/f2012-077 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.MacCall AD. Dynamic Geography of Marine Fish Populations. Washington Sea Grant Program; 1990. [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Atkinson DB, Rose GA, Murphy EF, Bishop CA. Distribution changes and abundance of northern cod (Gadus morhua), 1981–1993. 1997;54: 7. [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Fisher JAD, Frank KT. Abundance-distribution relationships and conservation of exploited marine fishes. Mar Ecol Prog Ser. 2004;279: 201–213. 10.3354/meps279201 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Southward AJ, Hawkins SJ, Burrows MT. Seventy years’ observations of changes in distribution and abundance of zooplankton and intertidal organisms in the western English Channel in relation to rising sea temperature. J Therm Biol. 1995;20: 127–155. 10.1016/0306-4565(94)00043-I [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Zador S, Aydin K, Cope J. Fine-scale analysis of arrowtooth flounder Atherestes stomias catch rates reveals spatial trends in abundance. Mar Ecol Prog Ser. 2011;438: 229–239. 10.3354/meps09316 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Simpson MR, Walsh SJ. Changes in the spatial structure of Grand Bank yellowtail flounder: testing MacCall’s basin hypothesis. J Sea Res. 2004;51: 199–210. 10.1016/j.seares.2003.08.007 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Sullivan MC, Cowen RK, Able KW, Fahay MP. Applying the basin model: Assessing habitat suitability of young-of-the-year demersal fishes on the New York Bight continental shelf. Cont Shelf Res. 2006;26: 1551–1570. 10.1016/j.csr.2006.03.012 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Melnychuk MC, Clavelle T, Owashi B, Strauss K. Reconstruction of global ex-vessel prices of fished species. ICES J Mar Sci. 2017;74: 121–133. 10.1093/icesjms/fsw169 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.García Molinos J, Burrows MT, Poloczanska ES. Ocean currents modify the coupling between climate change and biogeographical shifts. Sci Rep. 2017;7: 1332 10.1038/s41598-017-01309-y [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Punt AE, A’mar T, Bond NA, Butterworth DS, de Moor CL, De Oliveira JAA, et al. Fisheries management under climate and environmental uncertainty: control rules and performance simulation. ICES J Mar Sci J Cons. 2014;71: 2208–2220. 10.1093/icesjms/fst057 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 38.Cheung WWL, Reygondeau G, Frölicher TL. Large benefits to marine fisheries of meeting the 1.5°C global warming target. Science. 2016;354: 1591–1594. 10.1126/science.aag2331 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Sumaila UR, Tai TC, Lam VWY, Cheung WWL, Bailey M, Cisneros-Montemayor AM, et al. Benefits of the Paris Agreement to ocean life, economies, and people. Sci Adv. 2019;5: eaau3855. 10.1126/sciadv.aau3855 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Skern-Mauritzen M, Ottersen G, Handegard NO, Huse G, Dingsør GE, Stenseth NC, et al. Ecosystem processes are rarely included in tactical fisheries management. Fish Fish. 2015;17: 165–175. 10.1111/faf.12111 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 41.Rijnsdorp AD, Peck MA, Engelhard GH, Möllman C, Pinnegar JK. Resolving the effect of climate change on fish populations. ICES J Mar Sci. 2009;66: 1570–1583. [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Mora C, Myers RA, Coll M, Libralato S, Pitcher TJ, Sumaila RU, et al. Management Effectiveness of the World’s Marine Fisheries. PLoS Biol. 2009;7: e1000131 10.1371/journal.pbio.1000131 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 43.Bundy A, Chuenpagdee R, Boldt JL, de Fatima Borges M, Camara ML, Coll M, et al. Strong fisheries management and governance positively impact ecosystem status. Fish Fish. 2016;18: 412–439. 10.1111/faf.12184 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 44.Golden CD, Allison EH, Cheung WWL, Dey MM, Halpern BS, McCauley DJ, et al. Nutrition: Fall in fish catch threatens human health. Nature. 2016;534: 317–320. 10.1038/534317a [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 45.Pinsky ML, Mantua NJ. Emerging adaptation approaches for climate-ready fisheries management. Oceanography. 2014;27: 146–159. 10.5670/oceanog.2014.93 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Karp MA, Peterson JO, Lynch PD, Griffis RB, Adams CF, Arnold WS, et al. Accounting for shifting distributions and changing productivity in the development of scientific advice for fishery management. Maravelias C, editor. ICES J Mar Sci. 2019; fsz048. 10.1093/icesjms/fsz048 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 47.Miller K, Charles A, Barange M, Brander K, Gallucci VF, Gasalla MA, et al. Climate change, uncertainty, and resilient fisheries: Institutional responses through integrative science. Prog Oceanogr. 2010;87: 338–346. 10.1016/j.pocean.2010.09.014 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 48.Ojea E, Pearlman I, Gaines SD, Lester SE. Fisheries regulatory regimes and resilience to climate change. Ambio. 2017;46: 399–412. 10.1007/s13280-016-0850-1 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Cinner JE, Adger WN, Allison EH, Barnes ML, Brown K, Cohen PJ, et al. Building adaptive capacity to climate change in tropical coastal communities. Nat Clim Change. 2018;8: 117–123. 10.1038/s41558-017-0065-x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.Miller TJ, Jones CM, Hanson C, Heppell S, Jensen OP, Livingston P, et al. Scientific Considerations Informing Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act Reauthorization. Fisheries. 2018;43: 533–541. 10.1002/fsh.10179 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 51.NOAA. Status of Stocks 2017: Annual Report to Congress on the Status of U.S. Fisheries. 2018; 1–7.
  • 52.Cochrane KL, Andrew NL, Parma AM. Primary fisheries management: a minimum requirement for provision of sustainable human benefits in small-scale fisheries. Fish Fish. 2011;12: 275–288. 10.1111/j.1467-2979.2010.00392.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 53.Costello C, Lynham J, Lester SE, Gaines SD. Economic Incentives and Global Fisheries Sustainability. Annu Rev Resour Econ. 2010;2: 299–318. 10.1146/annurev.resource.012809.103923 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 54.Costello C, Gaines SD, Lynham J. Can Catch Shares Prevent Fisheries Collapse? Science. 2008;321: 1678–1681. 10.1126/science.1159478 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 55.Melnychuk MC, Essington TE, Branch TA, Heppell SS, Jensen OP, Link JS, et al. Can catch share fisheries better track management targets? Fish Fish. 2011;13: 267–290. 10.1111/j.1467-2979.2011.00429.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 56.Melnychuk MC, Peterson E, Elliott M, Hilborn R. Fisheries management impacts on target species status. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A. 2017;114: 178–183. 10.1073/pnas.1609915114 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 57.Hobday AJ, Spillman CM, Eveson JP, Hartog JR. Seasonal forecasting for decision support in marine fisheries and aquaculture. Fish Oceanogr. 2016;25: 45–56. 10.1111/fog.12083 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 58.Hobday AJ, Spillman CM, Eveson JP, Hartog JR, Zhang X, Brodie S. A Framework for Combining Seasonal Forecasts and Climate Projections to Aid Risk Management for Fisheries and Aquaculture. Front Mar Sci. 2018;5 10.3389/fmars.2018.00137 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 59.Moore SS, Seavy NE, Gerhart M. Scenario planning for climate change adaptation: A guidance for resource managers. Point Blue Conservation Science and the California Coastal Conservancy; 2013. http://www.prbo.org/refs/files/12263_Moore2013.pdf [Google Scholar]
  • 60.Robinson LM, Marzloff MP, van Putten I, Pecl G, Jennings S, Nicol S, et al. Structured Decision-Making Identifies Effective Strategies and Potential Barriers for Ecosystem-Based Management of a Range-Extending Species in a Global Marine Hotspot. Ecosystems. 2019;22: 1573–1591. 10.1007/s10021-019-00358-w [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 61.Gaichas SK, Seagraves RJ, Coakley JM, DePiper GS, Guida VG, Hare JA, et al. A Framework for Incorporating Species, Fleet, Habitat, and Climate Interactions into Fishery Management. Front Mar Sci. 2016;3 10.3389/fmars.2016.00105 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 62.Metcalf SJ, van Putten EI, Frusher S, Marshall NA, Tull M, Caputi N, et al. Measuring the vulnerability of marine social-ecological systems: a prerequisite for the identification of climate change adaptations. Ecol Soc. 2015;20 Available: https://www.jstor.org/stable/26270198 [Google Scholar]
  • 63.Holsman K, Samhouri J, Cook G, Hazen E, Olsen E, Dillard M, et al. An ecosystem-based approach to marine risk assessment. Ecosyst Health Sustain. 2017;3: e01256 10.1002/ehs2.1256 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 64.Hare JA, Morrison WE, Nelson MW, Stachura MM, Teeters EJ, Griffis RB, et al. A Vulnerability Assessment of Fish and Invertebrates to Climate Change on the Northeast U.S. Continental Shelf. Hiddink JG, editor. PLOS ONE. 2016;11: e0146756 10.1371/journal.pone.0146756 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 65.Hazen EL, Scales KL, Maxwell SM, Briscoe DK, Welch H, Bograd SJ, et al. A dynamic ocean management tool to reduce bycatch and support sustainable fisheries. Sci Adv. 2018;4: eaar3001. 10.1126/sciadv.aar3001 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 66.Tommasi D, Stock CA, Pegion K, Vecchi GA, Methot RD, Alexander MA, et al. Improved management of small pelagic fisheries through seasonal climate prediction. Ecol Appl. 2017;27: 378–388. 10.1002/eap.1458 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 67.Punt AE, Butterworth DS, Oliveira JAAD, Haddon M. Management strategy evaluation: best practices. Fish Fish. 2016;17: 303–334. 10.1111/faf.12104 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 68.Richards LJ, Maguire J-J. Recent international agreements and the precautionary approach: new directions for fisheries management science. Can J Fish Aquat Sci. 1998;55: 1545–1552. 10.1139/f98-043 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 69.Hixon MA, Johnson DW, Sogard SM. BOFFFFs: on the importance of conserving old-growth age structure in fishery populations. ICES J Mar Sci J Cons. 2014;71: 2171–2185. 10.1093/icesjms/fst200 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 70.Spijkers J, Singh G, Blasiak R, Morrison TH, Le Billon P, Österblom H. Global patterns of fisheries conflict: Forty years of data. Glob Environ Change. 2019;57: 101921 10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2019.05.005 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 71.Havice E. Rights-based management in the Western and Central Pacific Ocean tuna fishery: Economic and environmental change under the Vessel Day Scheme. Mar Policy. 2013;42: 259–267. 10.1016/j.marpol.2013.03.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 72.Aqorau T, Bell J, Kittinger JN. Good governance for migratory species. Science. 2018;361: 1208–1209. 10.1126/science.aav2051 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 73.Serdy A. The New Entrants Problem in International Fisheries Law. In: Cambridge Core [Internet]. Feb 2016 [cited 3 Oct 2019].
  • 74.Miller KA, Munro GR. Climate and Cooperation: A New Perspective on the Management of Shared Fish Stocks. Mar Resour Econ. 2004;19: 367–393. [Google Scholar]
  • 75.Schatz VJ, Proelss A, Liu N. The 2018 Agreement to Prevent Unregulated High Seas Fisheries in the Central Arctic Ocean: A Critical Analysis. Int J Mar Coast Law. 2019;34: 195–244. 10.1163/15718085-23342015 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 76.Charles A. People, oceans and scale: governance, livelihoods and climate change adaptation in marine social–ecological systems. Curr Opin Environ Sustain. 2012;4: 351–357. 10.1016/j.cosust.2012.05.011 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 77.Fedele G, Donatti CI, Harvey CA, Hannah L, Hole DG. Transformative adaptation to climate change for sustainable social-ecological systems. Environ Sci Policy. 2019;101: 116–125. 10.1016/j.envsci.2019.07.001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 78.Kasperski S, Holland DS. Income diversification and risk for fishermen. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2013;110: 2076–2081. 10.1073/pnas.1212278110 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 79.Cline TJ, Schindler DE, Hilborn R. Fisheries portfolio diversification and turnover buffer Alaskan fishing communities from abrupt resource and market changes. Nat Commun. 2017;8: 14042 10.1038/ncomms14042 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 80.Cinner JE, Daw T, McClanahan TR. Socioeconomic factors that affect artisanal fishers’ readiness to exit a declining fishery. Conserv Biol. 2009;23: 124–130. 10.1111/j.1523-1739.2008.01041.x [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 81.Daw TM, Cinner JE, McClanahan TR, Brown K, Stead SM, Graham NAJ, et al. To fish or not to fish: factors at multiple scales affecting artisanal fishers’ readiness to exit a declining fishery. PLOS ONE. 2012;7: e31460 10.1371/journal.pone.0031460 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 82.Hughes TP, Bellwood DR, Folke C, Steneck RS, Wilson J. New paradigms for supporting the resilience of marine ecosystems. Trends Ecol Evol. 2005;20: 380–386. 10.1016/j.tree.2005.03.022 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 83.Gutiérrez NL, Hilborn R, Defeo O. Leadership, social capital and incentives promote successful fisheries. Nature. 2011;470: 386–389. 10.1038/nature09689 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 84.Moreno Andrea, Carmen Revenga. The system of territorial use rights in fisheries in Chile. Arlington, VA, USA: The Nature Conservancy; 2014. p. 88. [Google Scholar]
  • 85.Willett W, Rockström J, Loken B, Springmann M, Lang T, Vermeulen S, et al. Food in the Anthropocene: the EAT–Lancet Commission on healthy diets from sustainable food systems. The Lancet. 2019;393: 447–492. 10.1016/S0140-6736(18)31788-4 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 86.Gentry RR, Froehlich HE, Grimm D, Kareiva P, Parke M, Rust M, et al. Mapping the global potential for marine aquaculture. Nat Ecol Evol. 2017;1: 1317–1324. 10.1038/s41559-017-0257-9 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 87.emLab. Estimating the Ocean’s True Potential for Feeding the Planet. The Food and Land Use Coalition (FOLU); 2019. https://www.foodandlandusecoalition.org/knowledge-hub/
  • 88.Froehlich HE, Gentry RR, Halpern BS. Global change in marine aquaculture production potential under climate change. Nat Ecol Evol. 2018;2: 1745–1750. 10.1038/s41559-018-0669-1 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 89.Klinger DH, Levin SA, Watson JR. The growth of finfish in global open-ocean aquaculture under climate change. Proc R Soc B Biol Sci. 2017;284: 20170834 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 90.Davies IP, Carranza V, Froehlich HE, Gentry RR, Kareiva P, Halpern BS. Governance of marine aquaculture: Pitfalls, potential, and pathways forward. Mar Policy. 2019;104: 29–36. 10.1016/j.marpol.2019.02.054 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 91.Lester SE, Gentry RR, Kappel CV, White C, Gaines SD. Opinion: Offshore aquaculture in the United States: Untapped potential in need of smart policy. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2018;115: 7162–7165. 10.1073/pnas.1808737115 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 92.Abate TG, Nielsen R, Tveterås R. Stringency of environmental regulation and aquaculture growth: A cross-country analysis. Aquac Econ Manag. 2016;20: 201–221. 10.1080/13657305.2016.1156191 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 93.Gentry RR, Ruff EO, Lester SE. Temporal patterns of adoption of mariculture innovation globally. Nat Sustain. 2019;2: 949–956. 10.1038/s41893-019-0395-y [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 94.Soto D, Ross LG, Handisyde N, Bueno PB, Beveridge CM, Dabbadie L, et al. Chapter 21: Climate change and aquaculture: vulnerability and adaptation options Impacts of climate change on fisheries and aquaculture: synthesis of current knowledge, adaptation and mitigation options. 2018. p. 26. [Google Scholar]
  • 95.Diana JS. Aquaculture Production and Biodiversity Conservation. BioScience. 2009;59: 27–38. 10.1525/bio.2009.59.1.7 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 96.Klinger D, Naylor R. Searching for solutions in aquaculture: charting a sustainable course. Annu Rev Env Resour. 2012;37: 247–276. 10.1146/annurev-environ-021111-161531 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 97.Schlenker W, Lobell DB. Robust negative impacts of climate change on African agriculture. Environ Res Lett. 2010;5: 014010 10.1088/1748-9326/5/1/014010 [DOI] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

S1 Table. Representative Concentration Pathways (RCPs) evaluated in the analysis*.

* See Table S1 in Gaines et al. [19] for earth system models contributing to ensemble mean. Note: RCP 2.6 is not evaluated because it is no longer likely (Raftery et al. 2017).

(DOCX)

S1 Fig. Initial condition of the 779 species stocks.

The transparent grey box indicates near optimal fisheries management (i.e., i.e., 0.8 ≤ B/BMSY ≤ 1.2 and 0.8 ≤ F/FMSY ≤ 1.2).

(TIFF)

S2 Fig. Projected change in maximum sustainable yield (MSY) as a function of latitude (absolute degrees) under three emissions scenarios.

(TIFF)

S3 Fig. Percent difference in mean catch and profits in 2091–2100 relative to 2012–2021 (“today”) for 156 countries under three emissions scenarios (columns) and seven management scenarios (rows).

The percentage labels indicate the percentage of countries falling in each quadrant of catch and profit outcomes.

(TIFF)

S4 Fig. Percent difference in cumulative catch and cumulative profits from 2012–2100 relative to business-as-usual for 156 countries under three emissions scenarios (columns) and six management scenarios (rows).

The percentage labels indicate the percentage of countries falling in each quadrant of catch and profit outcomes.

(TIFF)

Data Availability Statement

All data are available here: https://github.com/SFG-UCSB/cc_trade.


Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

RESOURCES