Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2020 Mar 26;15(3):e0230506. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0230506

Modelling the health impact of food taxes and subsidies with price elasticities: The case for additional scaling of food consumption using the total food expenditure elasticity

Tony Blakely 1,2,*, Nhung Nghiem 2, Murat Genc 3, Anja Mizdrak 2, Linda Cobiac 4, Cliona Ni Mhurchu 5, Boyd Swinburn 6, Peter Scarborough 4, Christine Cleghorn 2
Editor: Chuanwang Sun7
PMCID: PMC7098589  PMID: 32214329

Abstract

Background

Food taxes and subsidies are one intervention to address poor diets. Price elasticity (PE) matrices are commonly used to model the change in food purchasing. Usually a PE matrix is generated in one setting then applied to another setting with differing starting consumptions and prices of foods. This violates econometric assumptions resulting in likely mis-estimation of total food consumption. In this paper we demonstrate this problem, canvass possible options for rescaling all consumption after applying a PE matrix, and illustrate the use of a total food expenditure elasticity (TFEe; the expenditure elasticity for all food combined given the policy-induced change in the total price of food). We use case studies of: NZ$2 per 100g saturated fat (SAFA) tax, NZ$0.4 per 100g sugar tax, and a 20% fruit and vegetable (F&V) subsidy.

Methods

We estimated changes in food purchasing using a NZ PE matrix applied conventionally, and then with TFEe adjustment. Impacts were quantified for pre- to post-policy changes in total food expenditure and health adjusted life years (HALYs) for the total NZ population alive in 2011 over the rest of their lifetime using a multistate lifetable model.

Results

Two NZ studies gave TFEe’s of 0.68 and 0.83, with international estimates ranging from 0.46 to 0.90 (except a UK outlier of 0.04). Without TFEe adjustment, total food expenditure decreased with the tax policies and increased with the F&V subsidy–implausible directions of shift given economic theory and the external TFEe estimates. After TFEe adjustment, HALY gains reduced by a third to a half for the two taxes and reversed from an apparent health loss to a health gain for the F&V subsidy. With TFEe adjustment, HALY gains (in 1000’s) were: 1,805 (95% uncertainty interval 1,337 to 2,340) for the SAFA tax; 1,671 (1,220 to 2,269) for the sugar tax; and 953 (453 to 1,308) for the F&V subsidy.

Conclusions

If PE matrices are applied in settings beyond where they were derived, additional scaling is likely required. We suggest that the TFEe is a useful scalar, but we also encourage other researchers to examine this issue and propose alternative options.

Introduction

Nutrition policy to prevent or mitigate the obesity epidemic, and improve diets, is a major policy issue.[1] One policy option is food taxes and subsidies.[2, 3] To guide policy making, an important role of research is to estimate the likely impact of such taxes and subsidies on changes in diet (e.g. consumption of fruit and vegetables, total energy intake) [4, 5], intermediate outcomes (e.g. body mass index (BMI) [6], blood pressure), disease outcomes (e.g. stroke, diabetes) [7] and ‘total’ health measures change (e.g. deaths averted, disability adjusted life years averted or quality adjusted life years gained).[8, 9] Ideally, one would have randomized trials of food taxes and subsidies for this estimation (e.g. [1013]), but they are difficult to implement and if implemented follow up for long-periods of time to ascertain both long-run accommodation to new food prices and health outcomes is often not feasible. Alternatively, one can analyze natural experiments, e.g. the tax on sugar-sweetened beverage (SSB) in Mexico [14, 15], the Danish saturated fat tax [16] and the SSB tax in Philadelphia.[17]

To estimate the health impacts, including the relative health impacts across multiple policy options, modelling is therefore useful.[18] A key–and challenging–aspect of this modelling is parameterizing how total diets actually change with food taxes and subsidies. For example, how much does a tax on one food item affect consumption of other foods? Price elasticities (PEs) are commonly used to convert a food tax/subsidy intervention to a change in total diet [19] which is then linked to changes in BMI and other risk factors, then disease rates, and then to morbidity and mortality.

There are two types of PEs. First, there is the own-PE. This measures how much the price (change) of a given food affects its own consumption. For example, a PE of -0.7 on red meat means that if the price of meat increases by 1%, its consumption reduces by 0.7%. The second is cross-PEs. This measures how much the price (change) of another food affects consumption. For example, a cross-PE of +0.1 for red meat given an increase in price of poultry means that if the price of poultry increases by 1%, the consumption of red meat increases by 0.1%. (A positive cross-PE means foods are substitutes and a negative cross-PE that they are complements)

Econometric analyses to generate PEs are demanding, requiring simultaneous data on both price and demand and (ideally) substantial variation in price (e.g. by time or by region). Given the impracticality of calculating new PEs for each new setting in which researchers and analysts estimate the impact of price changes on food purchasing, by necessity PEs from one setting (e.g. a given country for a given year) are often applied in another setting.[5, 6, 8] But there are inevitably variations between settings in food purchasing patterns, prices and demand relationships. Indeed, the most common food price elasticity matrix is a ‘conditional’ one meaning that it is generated under the assumption that there is no change in total food expenditure for food price changes; this nil impact on total food expenditure is violated when a PE matrix is applied to a different distribution of food prices and consumption–likely resulting in implausible shifts in total food expenditure. The Text Box gives a simple food system example, showing how the transfer of price elasticities calculated in one setting of food consumption to another can generate (likely) implausible estimates of post price change consumption.

Box 1. Problems transporting price elasticity from one context to another

Imagine a world with just three foods: fruit, vegetables and cereal. Average daily per person consumption, price per 100g and kJ of energy per 100g are as follows:

kJ per 100g Price per 100g own-PE [fruit - fruit] cross-PE [Fruit-vegetables/cereals]
Fruit 150 $0.40 -1
Vegetables 150 $0.50 0.30
Cereals 500 $1.00 -0.05

The own- and cross-PE estimated for this world are also shown. A 1% increase in the price of fruit will result in a: 1% decrease in consumption of fruit; a 0.3% increase in the consumption of vegetables (a substitute food); and a 0.05% decrease in cereals (a complement food in this world). Now imagine that a 20% subsidy on fruit is implemented. The table below shows the pre-subsidy and post-subsidy consumption, energy and expenditure:

g/day kJ Expenditure
Pre-subsidy Fruit 50 (11.1%) 75 (5.5%) $0.20 (6.3%)
Vegetables 200 (44.4%) 300 (21.8%) $1.00 (31.3%)
Cereals 200 (44.4%) 1,000 (72.7%) $2.00 (62.5%)
Total 450 1375 $3.20
Post-20% subsidy on fruit Fruit 60 (13.3%) 90 (6.5%) $0.24 (7.5%)
Vegetables 188 (41.8%) 282 (20.4%) $0.94 (29.4%)
Cereals 202 (44.9%) 1,010 (73.1%) $2.02 (63.1%)
Total 450 1382 $3.20
Difference pre- to post-subsidy 0% 0.51% 0.00%

The subsidy resulted in no change in total expenditure (consistent with the assumptions inherent within the calculation of ‘conditional’ price elasticities) and increased total energy consumption by 0.51%.

Now imagine we use the above price elasticities in a different setting or population – with differing starting consumption of foods (but the same prices per 100g). The pre- and post-subsidy grams per day consumption, energy intake and expenditure are:

g/day kJ Expenditure
Pre-subsidy in new setting Fruit 100 (25%) 150 (11.5%) $0.40 (13.8%)
Vegetables 100 (25%) 150 (11.5%) $0.50 (17.2%)
Cereals 200 (50%) 1,000 (76.9%) $2.00 (69%)
Total 400 1300 $2.90
Post-20% subsidy on fruit in new setting Fruit 120 (28.8%) 180 (13.5%) $0.48 (16.2%)
Vegetables 94 (22.6%) 141 (10.6%) $0.47 (15.8%)
Cereals 202 (48.6%) 1,010 (75.9%) $2.02 (68%)
Total 416 1331 $2.97
Difference pre- to post-subsidy 4% 2.38% 2.41%

Note that the total expenditure now changes from pre- to post-subsidy, and the percentage change in total energy consumption (which will largely drive health impacts) is over four times greater than in the original setting (2.38% compared to 0.51%).

This simple example demonstrates distortions that may arise applying price elasticities from one setting to another – in this case just due to differing starting consumptions of foods. There may also be differing starting prices, and more fundamentally differing food preferences with ‘genuinely’ differing consumer responses to price changes. Ideally, there would be price elasticities worked out for each different setting that they are applied in, however that is impractical.

This price elasticity transferability issue is problematic for health impact modelling studies, which derive health consequences from absolute differences in dietary consumption patterns between the observed and counterfactual scenarios.[18, 20] For example, our intended modelling will be using National Nutrition Survey (NNS) data from 2009 [21] (whilst older, it is nationally representative and has data by ethnicity and for a wide range of food groups), where the price elasticities were generated with experimental data (conducted in 2016, using foods with overlap but not exact concordance with NNS food groups)[22, 23] using Bayesian priors from price elasticities calculated using Household Economic Survey data (2007/08 and 2009/10) and Food Price Index data (2007 and 2010).[5] Is applying PEs derived from one setting into another setting acceptable? We argue yes–but with care (and rescaling). Look again at the Text Box, and in particular the column percentages shown in parentheses in the tables. Whilst we may be concerned about the validity of the new estimated totals of g/day, kJ and financial expenditure post-subsidy, we may accept that the shifts in relative distribution across foods in g/day, kJ and expenditure is valid. Therefore, all estimates need common rescaling given some constraint (preserving the new column percentages). Possible constraints include no change in (or some tolerable change in) one of the total weight of food, the total energy, or the total financial expenditure. The question then is “what constraint should we use?”–a question we consider in more detail below.

The aim of this paper is to peel back often-unacknowledged uncertainties in the use of PEs to model food taxes and subsidies. Our goal is not to ‘damn the research endeavour to irrelevance’.[24] Quite the converse. We take the view that improving nutrition is a major public health priority, and it is essential for researchers to estimate the health impacts of food taxes and subsidy options. Modelling is an important part of that research agenda. Accordingly, the objectives of this paper are:

  1. Canvass the advantages and disadvantages of options for rescaling total expenditure after conventional application of price changes through a PE matrix, options being: nil change in energy intake; nil change in grams of food; nil change in total expenditure on food; some change in total food expenditure using a total food expenditure elasticity (TFEe; i.e. change in food expenditure is a function of a TFEe and the difference in total food price index (FPI) pre- and post-tax or subsidy policy).

  2. Demonstrate the use of the TFEe and its impact (compared to a conventional unscaled application of a PE matrix generated for New Zealand (NZ) [25]) on household expenditure, energy intake, BMI and health adjusted life years gained, for three NZ case studies: a NZ$2 per 100g of saturated fat tax; a NZ$0.4 per 100g of sugar tax; and a 20% fresh fruit and vegetable subsidy.

Options for rescaling total consumption or expenditure after conventional application of a price elasticity matrix

There are a number of options to rescale all food purchasing after the conventional application of a PE matrix.

  1. Rescale all consumption so that energy intake is unchanged. Some health impacts of dietary change are mediated through mechanisms other than energy balance and these can plausibly be modelled in the way that Smed et al (2016) did when they estimated the health impacts of the Danish saturated fat tax assuming no change in total energy intake. [16] However, in reality for many pricing interventions, the dietary changes will plausibly change energy balance. While in general humans maintain fairly close energy balance on a week by week basis, small increases or decreases in energy intake maintained over the long term will result in a higher or lower body weight on a year by year basis.

  2. Rescale all consumption so that grams of (solid) food purchased is unchanged.

    Studies by Rolls and others [26, 27] suggest that if one changes the energy density of food, and allow (experimental) subjects to freely eat, then they eat to an amount that keeps the weight of food consumed relatively consistent–and energy intake will thus fall if foods of lower energy density are provided or ‘made easier’ to access. However, there are limits to an assumption of constant grams of food. First, and an extreme example, a consumer swapping from pre-mixed drinks to powdered sachets will purchase less weight. Second, and less extreme, a consumer swapping from freshly-prepared to dried pasta, or fresh to dried fruit, will purchase less weight. Third, differing moisture contents of substitute foods (e.g. dry cereals compared to moister mueslis) will also presumably not be direct weight substitutes. We are unaware of algorithms to manage these issues if rescaling by food weight was used.

  3. Rescale all expenditure to be unchanged to that pre-tax/subsidy. This is actually a specific case of the expenditure elasticity approach below. However, it is a simplifying assumption–economic theory suggests that total expenditure on food will change with change in average food price or FPI, as we now explain.

  4. Rescale using total food expenditure elasticity: Rescale all expenditure using econometric methods that generalize conditional PE matrices (assumed zero change in total expenditure on food due to reducing purchasing for foods with increased prices and/or shifting to other foods; and option 3 above) to unconditional PE matrices (permits change in total food expenditure with food price changes by allowing shifts between food and other components of household budgets), by including an additional elasticity of expenditure (TFEe). Such TFEe are occasionally found in the published literature [2830], but have not (to our knowledge) been used to rescale food purchasing post-PE matrix application. For example, if the food price index (FPI; or average food price) increases by 5% following a saturated fat (SAFA) tax, and the TFEe is 0.5 (i.e. expected household expenditure on food will increase by 0.5% for each 1.0% increase in the FPI), then the new total expenditure on food will be 2.5% greater than the starting expenditure due to reduced household consumption of other goods such as housing, savings, holidays, etc. We propose first applying the PE matrix conventionally, then scaling all food consumption by a uniform ratio that ensures total food expenditure increases by 2.5%. There is a strong economic rationale for this approach–all food combined in one grouping of household expenditure that will have its own elasticity of demand based on price.

Methods for TFEe scalar adjustment case studies

Food and drink taxes and subsidies

Three food tax/subsidy policies were used by way of demonstration:

  1. NZ$2 (in 2011 dollars; equivalent to US$1.45 in 2018 dollars) per 100 gram tax on saturated fat, throughout the food system. Such a tax increased the price of butter by 71%, full fat milk by 19% and sausages by 16%.

  2. NZ$0.4 (US$0.29) per 100 gram tax on sugar, throughout the food system. Such a tax increased the price of cordials and fruit drinks by 10.8%, tomato sauce by 12.9% and sugar by 82.9%.

  3. 20% subsidy on fruit and vegetables.

Price elasticities

We used a recent, NZ-specific PE matrix published elsewhere [25], and as shown in S1 Table (standard deviations in S2 Table). Briefly, this PE matrix was generated using a Bayesian approach to a linear almost ideal demand system, whereby priors for demand equation coefficients were generated from a previously published New Zealand food PE matrix [4, 5] informing the analysis of food purchasing data generated in a virtual supermarket experiment that randomized participants to differing price sets for foods. The randomized price sets used in this experiment aimed to maximize price variations on foods often suggested as targets for food subsidies or taxes (e.g. sugar tax, F&V subsidy), approximating the degree of price change we use as case studies in this paper.[23, 31] For computational tractability, and theoretical reasons (i.e. food complements and substitutes for cross-PE elasticity estimation are larger between ‘like’ foods (e.g. poultry and pork) than ‘unlike’ foods (e.g. poultry and dairy)), the demand equations were first estimated for 11 hierarchical subsets of food groups, then aggregated to one large 23 by 23 food group PE matrix–as is common practice (for example [6]).

Disaggregation of the 23-by-23 matrix to a 345-by-345 matrix in the simulation modelling

At the level of 23 food groups, there is still important heterogeneity within food groups in product-level concentrations of sugar and SAFA per 100 grams (for example low and full fat cheeses fall in the same dairy food group). Therefore, we disaggregated foods and their PE to a much larger 345-by-345 food matrix, based on the consumption data in the NZ National Nutrition Survey (2008/09) (acquired directly from the University of Otago’s Life in New Zealand Research Group who conducted the survey; personal communication, Blakey, Smith and Parnell, 2014). For example, full-fat and low-fat versions of dairy products should be taxed differently, and it was necessary to allow for shifts in purchasing within dairy products. Whilst external data for finely disaggregated PE matrices was not available, econometric theory posits that as one keeps disaggregating foods into smaller and smaller subgroupings, the own-PE of each food is expected to increase in absolute value terms.[32, 33] For example, the own-PE of all cheese might be -0.6, but high fat cheese separated out might be -0.65. Why? Because, assuming subgroups in each aggregated category are substitutes, changing the price of just high fat cheese means consumers can swap to low fat cheese. A theoretical constraint in food demand system specifies that the sum of budget share weighted own- and cross-PEs for a food item must be a constant, therefore, positive cross-PEs (e.g. between high fat and low fat cheese when we disaggregate cheeses) will lead to an expectation of larger own-PEs (e.g. the own-PE of high fat and the own-PE of low fat cheese).[34] How much does the own-PE strengthen? Unfortunately, that is difficult to estimate and is genuinely uncertain. Therefore, we first assumed that the own-PE for each of the 23 food groups increases in absolute terms by 2.5% for each additional food sub-group it is disaggregated into, with a relatively wide 1.25% standard deviation (SD) on the normal scale meaning the 95% uncertainty interval traverses 0.05% to 4.95%. (We selected 2.5% as the central value as this would mean a 25% to 50% greater own-PE for each of 10 to 20 disaggregated foods (e.g. the own-PE for types of dairy product considered separately) within one food category (e.g. the own-PE for dairy considered as one group), which seemed plausible given studies that do report both overall and disaggregated own-PEs.) Next, we then ensured the cross-PEs between the newly disaggregated foods satisfied the ‘adding up’ property with contributions proportional to expenditure (ie, Cournot aggregation).[34] Finally, we report analyses in this paper showing how sensitive results are to this PE disaggregation scalar, by estimating the impact on health adjusted life years (HALYs) gained from using the 2.5th and 97.5th percentile values (i.e. 0.05% to 4.95%; other than the sugar tax, results were reasonably insensitive to its value; Fig 1 and S6 Table).

Fig 1. Central estimate of HALY gained and uncertainty ranges, by policy, for: Non-TFEe adjusted; full probabilistic Monte Carlo simulation for total 95% intervals; univariate sensitivity analysis for 2.5th and 97.5th percentile of TFEe distribution; and univariate sensitivity analysis for 2.5th and 97.5th percentile of PE disaggregation scalar.

Fig 1

The central estimates slightly vary between the ‘full’ and two sensitivity analyses, as the former is the mean of all Monte Carlo simulations whereas the latter is the central estimate for one simulation using expected (i.e. average) values for all input parameters. Values used to plot this graph are shown in Table 1 and S5 and S6 Tables.

As an example of how this 2.5% disaggregation scalar works, consider a food group with an aggregated own-PE of -1.0 that is disaggregated to five foods, with proportionate expenditure of 20%, 40%, 20%, 10% and 10% for foods 1 to 5 respectively. The expected own-PE for each of the five foods was -1.125 (i.e. -1–5×0.025), and the cross-PEs for foods 2, 3, 4 and 5 onto 1 were 0.0625 (i.e. 40%/80% × 0.125), 0.03125, 0.015625 and 0.015625 respectively. A similar method was used to disaggregate cross-PE (e.g. the cross-PE of milk onto bread when both food groups were further disaggregated, again ensuring econometric assumptions were met; see elsewhere for details [35]).

Total food expenditure elasticity (TFEe)

Estimating the elasticity of expenditure on all foods considered together at the level of changes in the average price of all foods (i.e. TFEe) requires studies of total household expenditure, with consumption items at the level of all foods combined and other groupings of household expenditure (e.g. housing, recreation, education). We are aware of two NZ estimates: Michelini and Chatterjee (1997) and Michelini (1999) [36, 37]. Michelini (1999) is the best with a longer series of data, the use of an almost ideal demands system model, and more disaggregation of food groups. Table 2 of Michelini (1999) reports an own-PE for food combined of -0.168 (standard error 0.1952), which equates to a TFEe of 0.832 (with the same standard error, which translates to a 95% confidence interval of 0.45 to 1.21). This central value equates to 0.832% increase in total household spending on food for a 1% increase in the FPI. However, the upper confidence limit seems unlikely, as a TFEe greater than 1 suggests people over-compensate for price increases by spending even more than necessary to maintain the same quantity of food purchased. We also found eight international studies that used multi-stage budgeting models to estimate unconditional and uncompensated food own-PEs, for high-income countries up to June 2017 (keywords: “price elasticities” or “price elasticity” or “demand” and “food” and “multi-stage” or “multi stage”; see Table 2 and adjacent text of [35] for further details). Consistent with theoretical expectation, all estimates were between zero and one. The estimates ranged from 0.46 to 0.90 (except a UK outlier of 0.04), with the average, median and standard deviation across these eight studies being 0.59, 0.66 and 0.29, respectively. For Monte Carlo analyses incorporating input parameter uncertainty, we therefore specified a Beta distribution for the TFEe, parameterized alpha = 6 and beta = 2, which returns mean = 0.75, median = 0.77, mode = 0.83, 2.5th percentile = 0.42 and 97.5th percentile = 0.96.

Table 2. Characteristics of selected previous food tax and subsidy modelling papers.
Price elasticity matrix
Author Interventions and setting Number of food groups Derivation of PE matrix Cross-PE used? Constraint or rescaling after PE application? Health gain findings
Blakely et al (current study) NZ. SAFA and sugar tax, F&V subsidy. 340 (disaggregated from 23) Bayesian LAIDs model, 12 hierarchical demand systems. Marshallian conditional PEs. Yes Yes; using TFEe Substantial HALY gains: SAFA tax ≈ sugar tax > F&V subsidy.
Briggs et al (2013) [6] UK. 20% sugar sweetened drink tax. 12 drinks categories and 5 food categories. Bayesian AIDs model, 5 hierarchical demand systems. Unconditional within each demand system; conditional across demand systems. Yes No 20% SSB tax would result in 1.3% reduction in obesity rates.
Cobiac et al (2017) [9] Australia. Separate and combined policies such that all policies had <1% impact on total food expenditure. Salt, sugar, saturated fat and SSB taxes: F&V subsidy. 24 NZ PE matrix as used in Ni Mhurchu et al (2015) [4]. UK PE matrix for sensitivity analysis. Yes, with suppression of statistically non-significant cross-PE. No Combined taxes and F&V subsidy > sugar tax > salt tax ≈ SAFA tax. F&V subsidy alone led to health loss. Sensitive to PE matrix used.
Ni Mhurchu et al (2015) [4] NZ. Sodium and sugar tax. F&V subsidy. Tax on foods contributing to greenhouse gases. 24 Household economic survey data, with prices from food price index Yes, with theoretical suppression of non-important cross-PE. No Sodium tax > sugar tax > F&V subsidy in terms of deaths prevented or postponed.

AIDS = almost ideal demand system. LAIDS = linear AIDS. HALY = health adjusted life year.

Unconditional means that the a change in expenditure was allowed in the assumptions for calculating PE.

Separate food group expenditure elasticities

When using TFEe, from an econometric perspective we are shifting from conditional to unconditional price elasticities (as we allow total food expenditure to change). This change in total food expenditure it similar to a change in total income, which has a separate impact on food purchasing over and above the own- and cross-PEs. We calculated such expenditure elasticities (EE) at the level of the 23 food groups (S3 Table).

Estimating post-tax or post-subsidy food quantities

The estimation of post-tax or post-subsidy food quantities is a two-step process. First, we propagate the food price changes through the Marshallian conditional PEs–which should result in no change in total food expenditure (due to the ‘conditional’ nature of these PEs), but is unlikely to do so for the reasons outlined above and in the Text Box. So we have to rescale all step 1 estimates to ensure this assumption is met. In the second step, we allocate the actual change in total food expenditure out across all foods using the above EEs propagated through the change in total food expenditure (given by the change in food price index and TFEe). However, this is unlikely to generate the ‘correct’ total post-tax or -subsidy food expenditure, so a further scaling step is required. These two steps are now outlined in detail.

Step 1: Application of price elasticities and scaling to ensure no change in total food expenditure. The before-tax or -subsidy total expenditure on food is:

XB=inqiBpiB Eq 1

Where qiB is the before tax- or -subsidy quantity and piB is the before-tax or -subsidy price per unit quantity, and i indexes foods 1, 2, 3,…,n.

The initial estimate of the percentage change in quantity of each food i due to price changes propagated through price elasticities is:

%Δqi,PE=jn(%Δpj×εij) Eq 2

where %Δpj is the percentage change in price of food j, and εij are the food price elasticities for pairwise combinations of foods (i and j). However, it is not guaranteed that these food quantity changes when multiplied through the after-tax or -subsidy food prices will sum to the same total food expenditure before-tax or -subsidy, which is the assumption of a conditional Marshallian PE. (We need to satisfy this assumption before applying the expenditure elasticities that will ‘convert’ the calculations from conditional to unconditional.) So, we calculate the implied total food expenditure arising from Eq 2 as:

XPE=in(1+%Δqi,PE)qiBpiA Eq 3

where piA is the after-tax or -subsidy price of each food item i. We then scale all first estimates of the percentage change in quantity to ensure no change in total food expenditure:

%Δqi,PES=(XBXPE×(1+%Δqi,PE))1 Eq 4

And therefore:

Δqi,PES=%Δqi,PES×qiB Eq 5

Step 2: Application of expenditure elasticities and total food expenditure elasticity (TFEe) to allocate change in total food expenditure across foods. First, we set the change in total food expenditure as:

ΔX=%ΔFPI×TFEe×XB Eq 6

Where the percentage change in food price index is:

%ΔFPI=100%×(inqiBpiAXB1) Eq 7

The preliminary estimate of the percentage change in food quantity due to change in total food expenditure is:

%Δqi,EE=%ΔFPI×TFEe×ηi Eq 8

where ηi the food EE of food i. (Note that Eq 8 is utilizing our assumption that total food expenditure after-tax or -subsidy is set by the TFEe and %ΔFPI.) Thus, the preliminary estimate of EE generated change in food quantity is:

Δqi,EE=%Δqi,EE×(1+%Δqi,PES)×qiB

The preliminary estimate of change in total food expenditure is:

ΔXEE=inΔqi,EE×piA Eq 9

which is unlikely to equal our target change of ΔX (Eq 6). We therefore create a scalar:

Scalar=ΔXΔXEE Eq 10

and multiply all preliminary EE-generated changes in q by this scalar to generate ‘true’ after-tax or -subsidy q:

qiA=(Scalar×Δqi,EE)+Δqi,PES+qiB Eq 11

that ensures total food expenditure post-tax or -subsidy is:

XA=XB+ΔX=inqiApiA Eq 12

Dietary and epidemiological modelling

We estimate the impact of changes in dietary intake and HALYs gained over the remainder of the lives of the New Zealand 2011 population, using a multistate lifetable simulation model. This is a major modelling task. For this paper with objectives of quantifying the impact of TFEe adjustment, and quantifying uncertainty about the same, we only briefly describe this modelling. The conceptual model is shown in S1 Fig, and details are published elsewhere.[35] The starting food consumption was the average (by sex, age, and ethnic group) from the 2008/09 National Nutrition Survey [21], and starting food prices from Nutritrack (a brand-specific packaged food database). Each food was linked to nutrient information using the food composition data from the National Nutrition Survey. By summing across all changes in food intake, several of the outputs presented in this paper were generated: change in total food expenditure, energy intake, and BMI. (The latter BMI change was derived from the change in energy intake, using the method of Hall et al 2011.[38])

The HALYs were estimated using a multi-state lifetable with 14 parallel diet-related diseases, for the entire New Zealand population alive in 2011 modelled over the remainder of their lifetimes. Changes in food, nutrients and physiological measures were combined with relative risks for each of these factors with the diseases (sourced from the Global Burden of Disease study [39]) to generate potential impact fractions (PIFs). These PIFs then altered disease incidence rates (with time lags into the future, e.g. 10 to 30 years (each limit with probabilistic uncertainty) for cancers), which then altered disease prevalence rates and mortality rates, all captured in the main lifetable as incremental changes in HALYs.

Monte Carlo simulation was used to estimate uncertainty in the HALY outputs, by drawing randomly from probability distributions about all input parameters (some given above; others elsewhere [35]; 2000 iterations). In addition to generating 95% uncertainty intervals about the HALYs, we also explore the specific impact of uncertainty in the TFEe and PE disaggregation scalar by reporting the HALY values for the 2.5th and 97.5th percentiles of these two input parameters (i.e. univariate sensitivity analyses).

Results

Table 1 shows the impacts of the three tax and subsidy scenarios onto changes in expenditure, grams of food per day, energy intake, BMI and HALYs gained–before (i.e. conventional analyses) and after TFEe adjustment. Consider first the changes in expenditure in the first column. The SAFA tax resulted in an increase of the total price index (i.e. price of all food together) of 3.91%, yet a conventional application of PEs suggests that the consumer will not compensate at all for this and instead decrease total food expenditure by 1.92% (Table 1). Put another way, this is a ‘revealed’ TFEe of -0.49 (i.e. -1.92/3.91) meaning that for every 1% increase in the overall price of food the consumer will actually reduce expenditure by 0.49%. Our central estimate of the TFEe is 0.75 (i.e. consumers will increase food expenditure by 0.75% for every 1% increase in the food price index), which when used to rescale all expenditure results in a post-TFEe adjusted increase of 2.93% in food expenditure. (We consider uncertainty in this 0.75 estimate below.) Looking down the rest of first column of Table 1 we see that in all instances the conventional PE application shifts the total food expenditure in the opposite direction to theoretical expectation, namely ‘revealed’ TFEs of -0.56 and -0.22 for the sugar tax and F&V subsidy.

Table 1. Model outputs (grams of food/day, expenditure, energy, BMI and HALYs gained) for saturated fat and sugar taxes, and fruit and vegetable subsidy, for the preferred TFEe adjustment and conventional (no TFEe adjustment) analyses.

Expendi- ture # All food (g/day) Energy (kJ) BMI Fruit (g/day) Vege (g/day) Salt (g/day) PUFA (g/day) SSBs (mls/day) Sugar (g/day) HALYs 95% UI HALYs
Business as usual (BAU) 16.09 3016 8,536 27.51 149.44 149.68 3.43 0.050 102.58 108.92 173,012,000
Changes compared to BAU
Saturated fat tax of $2 per 100g (causing a 3.91% increase in the FPI)        
Conventional model–no TFEe adjustment -1.92% -68 -740 -1.30 -0.58 -0.83 -0.19 -0.001 0.40 -5.21 3,343,000
TFEe adjustment 2.93% -14 -348 -0.61 5.75 6.20 -0.07 -0.001 4.65 0.18 1,805,000 (1,337,000 to 2,340,000)
Sugar tax of $0.4/100 grams per 100g (causing a 1.88% increase in the FPI)                    
Conventional model–no TFEe adjustment -1.04% -45 -522 -0.91 -0.05 0.00 -0.04 0.002 -22.50 -17.53 2,504,000
TFEe adjustment 1.41% -16 -321 -0.56 3.20 3.58 0.02 0.002 -20.56 -20.81 1,671,000 (1,220,000 to 2,269,000)
Fruit and vegetable subsidy of 20% (causing a 3.27% decrease in the FPI)                  
Conventional model–no TFEe adjustment 0.72% 78 218 0.39 28.72 53.97 0.04 0.000 -0.46 5.49 415,000
TFEe adjustment -2.45% 45 -56 -0.10 24.22 48.62 -0.05 0.000 -2.88 1.84 953,000 (453,000 to 1,308,000)

† 0% discount rate; HALYs at 3% annual discount rate are shown in S4 Table. Values are ‘expected values’ using central estimates for all input parameters (i.e. not from Monte Carlo simulation).

‡ Uncertainty intervals for 2000 simulations (for TFEe adjusted results only) drawing the 2.5th and 97.5th percentiles.

# $ for BAU. % change for changes compared to BAU.

Rescaling all food purchasing by a common amount so that the overall change in total food expenditure is 75% of the change in food price index, the TFEe adjustments result in: more muted changes in grams of food but no change of direction; lesser reductions in energy intake and BMI for SAFA and sugar tax, and a reversal to a modest reduction in energy intake and BMI for the F&V subsidy.

Regarding the flow on impact to HALYs gained (Table 1 and Fig 1), TFEe adjustment reduced the HALY gains by 46% for the SAFA tax and by 33% for the sugar tax, and reversed an apparent health loss to a health gain for the F&V subsidy. TFEe adjusted HALY gains (in 1000’s) were: 1,805 (95% uncertainty interval 1,337 to 2,340) for the SAFA tax; 1,671 (1,220 to 2,269) for the sugar tax; and 953 (435 to 1,308) for the F&V subsidy. It is important, however, to put these HALY gains in context of the 173 million HALYs under business as usual over the remainder of the population’s lifespan. Accordingly, reconsider the SAFA tax: the conventional analysis was suggesting a 1.93% increase in HALYs, and the TFEe adjustment a 1.05% increase in HALYs–or a 0.88% point difference. And for the F&V subsidy: the conventional analysis was suggesting a 0.24% decrease in HALYs, and the TFEe adjustment a 0.55% increase in HALYs–or a 0.79% point difference. That is, we are trying to pick up relatively small magnitude effect sizes, and a small absolute error or difference appears as a large relative error or difference.

Fig 1 also shows the 95% uncertainty intervals for the TFEe adjusted analysis (i.e. for Monte Carlo simulation where all input parameters are sampled from their uncertainty distributions), plus the range of HALY gain values for the 2.5th to 97.5th percentile values of the probability distributions for the TFEe (2.5th percentile = 0.42 and 97.5th percentile = 0.96), and the PE disaggregation scalar (0.05% and 4.95%). The uncertainty in the TFEe accounts for much of the total 95% uncertainty for the SAFA tax and the F&V subsidy. The uncertainty in the PE disaggregation parameter is less influential, except for the sugar tax where it drives much of the total uncertainty (including more uncertainty than that for the 95% range of TFEe values).

Discussion

Our modelling suggests that conventional application of PE matrices can produce implausible absolute changes in food nutrient intake. Based on the rationale that PE matrix induced changes in relative food intake are valid for food tax and subsidy policies simulated with an appropriate PE matrix (e.g. that a saturated fat tax reduces fatty food purchasing and intake relative to F&V), we present the TFEe scalar as a theoretically plausible solution to scale or constrain total absolute expenditure and therefore total food and nutrient intake. Economic theory suggests that change in total food expenditure will follow change in the total FPI according to an expenditure elasticity, the TFEe. Our empirical simulations using a TFEe adjustment have face validity. For example, the magnitude of HALY gains is maximal for sugar and SAFA taxes that impact many foods.

There are limitations to our proposed method and modelling. First, there may not be a ready source TFEe for a given context. However, there are strong theoretical bounds for the TFEe: it is unlikely to be greater than 1.0 –as this would imply that consumers increase food expenditure by a greater percentage than the percentage change in total food price index; and it is unlikely to be less than 0 –as this would imply that consumers do not increase food expenditure at all in response to a price increase. Thus, it is likely bounded between 0 and 1, and with plausible uncertainty intervals about its value (as we argue we included in this study) the true value will be covered. Put another way, to not use TFEe scaling will often equate to assuming that it is less than 0 or greater than 1.0 (e.g. as implied by some of our unscaled analyses). Second, our study is just for NZ PEs applied to NZ; attempts at replication in other contexts are justified. Third, we assume perfect competition in that the pre-tax market price does not vary once taxes (or subsidies) are imposed, that tax pass-through is 100%, and that the price elasticities we use (with TFEe adjustment) are reasonable proxies for long-run responses to price changes. Fourth, more dietary risk factors could be included than shown in our conceptual model to estimate HALYs (S1 Fig). For example, a recent global burden of disease study includes 15 dietary risk factors with updated relative risks.[40] Including more risk factors will probably just increase the absolute magnitude of HALY changes, but not the alter the pattern of findings–unless a specific tax was placed on a food item not currently in our model (e.g. red meat). Fifth, our study is a modelling study. There is a strong need for more real-world evaluations of food taxes and subsidies. One way forward is to use natural experiment analyses that carefully evaluate the impact of actual policies, for example Smed et al (2016) used econometric fixed effects modelling of consumer purchasing data to evaluate the Danish saturated fat tax.[16] They found that the tax did reduce saturated fat purchasing, and that it also had mixed spillover effects to increase vegetable consumption but also increase salt intake. Interestingly in light of our current study, they found it necessary to constrain or rescale their outputs to an assumption of no change in energy intake when modelling deaths averted or delayed, as sensitivity analyses found the net health impact to be very sensitive to any change in energy intake. Put another way, even though Smed et al undertook as rigorous as possible natural experiment analyses, they still confronted a need for theoretical constraint or scaling of the modelling of health impacts–demonstrating both the challenges in estimating net heath impacts, and also the need for studies such as ours probing deeper the issue and possible solutions.

It is useful to compare our method with some previously published simulation studies using PE matrices (Table 2). Approaches used that may prevent undue violation of assumptions inherent in the calculation of PE matrices include ensuring the total changes in food price for any tax or subsidy policy is less than 1% [9] and policies that use F&V subsidies to offset food tax revenue.[8] (Expressed conversely, any food and tax subsidy policy that sees a sizeable change in the total food price index likely requires some form of constraint–which we propose may be the TFEe.) Briggs et al (2015)[6]–whilst only assessing the impact of taxes on sugary drinks (a small fraction of all food)–used hierarchical demand systems (e.g. solving separate drinks as one system separately from drinks combined with other food groups). This hierarchical approach means that cross-PEs between what we think are disparate food groupings (e.g. meat versus breakfast cereals) are actually constrained to smaller absolute values, as substitutes and complements are assumed to mainly occur within the separate food demand systems.

Our study here offers three advances. First, the price elasticities we draw on use a Bayesian method blending priors with experimental data, and a hierarchical of demand systems that should (consistent with theory) mean cross-PEs between disparate foods are appropriately kept small in absolute terms (similar to Briggs et al above [6]). Second, we present a method for disaggregating a PE matrix to a large (in this case 340 food groups) matrix to allow separate consideration of foods with differing nutrient levels (e.g. sugar content) that consequently attract differing price changes. Third, and the main purpose of this paper, we propose using an additional constraint–the TFEe. We propose that there is good a priori reason to use this constraint, and particularly so: a) if the policies we are assessing generate sizeable changes (e.g. greater than 1%) in the FPI; and/or 2) the modelled total food expenditure following conventional application of the PE matrix is ‘counter-intuitive’ economically, for example with total expenditure decreasing post tax or total expenditure increasing post-subsidy.

In conclusion, we are proposing new methods that we think can improve simulation of food tax and subsidy impacts. We encourage other researchers to scrutinize and critique our proposals, and we strongly recommend future research to compare estimates from such modelling with real-world natural experiments.

Supporting information

S1 Fig. Conceptual diagram of the model.

(DOCX)

S1 Table. Marshallian cross- and own-PEs matrix using a Bayesian Linear Almost Ideal Demand System (LAIDS) approach.

(DOCX)

S2 Table. Standard deviations about the Marshallian cross- and own-PEs shown in S1 Table.

(DOCX)

S3 Table. Food group level (n = 23) expenditure elasticities applied after conventional application of the PE matrix, and before the final TFEe scaling.

(DOCX)

S4 Table. HALYs gained at 3% discount rate for saturated fat and sugar taxes, and fruit and vegetable subsidy, for the preferred TFEe adjustment and conventional (no TFEe adjustment) analyses.

(DOCX)

S5 Table. Univariate sensitivity analyses about low and high (2.5th and 97.5th percentile) values of TFEe, using the “TFEe adjustment” models.

(DOCX)

S6 Table. Univariate sensitivity analyses about low and high (2.5th and 97.5th percentile) values of PE disaggregation scalar.

(DOCX)

Acknowledgments

Nick Wilson, Wilma Waterlander, Liana Jacobi, Andres Ramirez Hassan, Dietary intake data used in this modeling was supplied by Otago University ‘Life in New Zealand’ staff (personal communication, Blakey, Smith and Parnell, 2014).

Data Availability

There are multiple sources of data used in this study, to parameterize the diet and multistate lifetable models. The sex, age and ethnic composition of the NZ population in 2011 was set using Statistics NZ resident population estimates. All-cause mortality and morbidity data, and disease specific incidence, case fatality and prevalence rates, are all provided in an Excel file “Disease Inputs used for Multi-State Life Table Modelling (Version 1.0)” available at the BODE3 publications webpage: https://www.otago.ac.nz/wellington/departments/publichealth/research/bode3/publications/index.html. Note that many of these data are generated specifically for the DIET model, requiring ‘epidemiological coherence’ using the DISMOD epidemiological calculator.1 They may not be fit for other purposes. Excess health system costs for each disease included in the model are provided in the DIET model Technical Report 2 - also available at the above BODE3 publications webpage. The price elasticity matrix is reported in S1 and S2 Tables of the current paper. Relative risks for the risk factor disease associations are in the DIET model Technical Report.2 Starting food consumption at the level of 340 foods, by sex and ethnicity, was taken from the NZ Adult Nutrition Survey; as stated in the paper, was provided by the Otago University ‘Life in New Zealand’ (LINZ) staff (personal communication, Blakey, Smith and Parnell, 2014). Our data access agreement does not allow full disclosure of the estimates we extracted from this data, but others can approach LINZ directly for the data. Starting food prices were sources from Nutritrack data, which is available upon request from the National Institute of Health Innovation, University of Auckland. Other key variables, such as the total food expenditure elasticity (TFEe), are detailed in the manuscript. 1. Barendregt J, Oortmarssen GJ, Vos T, Murray CJL. A generic model for the assessment of disease epidemiology: the computational basis of DisMod II. Popul Health Metr 2003;1(1):4. 2. Cleghorn CL, Blakely T, Nghiem N, Mizdrak A, Wilson N. Technical Report for BODE3 Diet Intervention and Multistate Lifetable Models, Version 1.1. Burden of Disease Epidemiology, Equity and Cost-Effectiveness Programme - Technical Report No16. Wellington: Department of Public Health, University of Otago, Wellington 2018.

Funding Statement

Health Research Council of New Zealand Programme Grants: Burden of Disease Epidemiology, Equity and Cost Effectiveness Programme (10/248); Effective interventions and policies to improve population nutrition and health (13/724). The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1.Roberto CA, Swinburn B, Hawkes C, Huang TTK, Costa SA, Ashe M, et al. Patchy progress on obesity prevention: emerging examples, entrenched barriers, and new thinking. The Lancet. 2015;385(9985):2400–9. 10.1016/s0140-6736(14)61744-x [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.World Cancer Research Fund International. NOURISHING FRAMEWORK: Use economic tools to address food affordability and purchase incentives 2015 [3 July 2015]. Available from: http://www.wcrf.org/int/policy/nourishing-framework/use-economic-tools.
  • 3.Hawkes C, Smith TG, Jewell J, Wardle J, Hammond RA, Friel S, et al. Smart food policies for obesity prevention. The Lancet. 2015;385(9985):2410–21. 10.1016/s0140-6736(14)61745-1 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Ni Mhurchu C, Eyles H, Genç M, Scarborough P, Rayner M, Mizdrak A, et al. Effects of Health-Related Food Taxes and Subsidies on Mortality from Diet-Related Disease in New Zealand: An Econometric-Epidemiologic Modelling Study. PLoS ONE. 2015;10(7):e012847 10.1371/journal.pone.0128477 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Ni Mhurchu C, Eyles H, Schilling C, Yang Q, Kaye-Blake W, Genc M, et al. Food Prices and Consumer Demand: Differences across Income Levels and Ethnic Groups. PLoS One. 2013;8(10):e75934 10.1371/journal.pone.0075934 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Briggs AD, Mytton OT, Kehlbacher A, Tiffin R, Rayner M, Scarborough P. Overall and income specific effect on prevalence of overweight and obesity of 20% sugar sweetened drink tax in UK: econometric and comparative risk assessment modelling study. BMJ. 2013;347:f6189 10.1136/bmj.f6189 . [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Basu S, Vellakkal S, Agrawal S, Stuckler D, Popkin B, Ebrahim S. Averting Obesity and Type 2 Diabetes in India through Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Taxation: An Economic-Epidemiologic Modeling Study. PLoS Medicine. 2014;11(1):e1001582 10.1371/journal.pmed.1001582 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Nnoaham KE, Sacks G, Rayner M, Mytton O, Gray A. Modelling income group differences in the health and economic impacts of targeted food taxes and subsidies. Int J Epidemiol. 2009;38(5):1324–33. 10.1093/ije/dyp214 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Cobiac L, Tam K, Veerman L, Blakely T. Taxes and subsidies for improving diet and population health in Australia: A cost-effectiveness modelling study. PLoS Med. 2017;14(2):e1002232 10.1371/journal.pmed.1002232 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Ni Mhurchu C, Blakely T, Jiang Y, Eyles HC, Rodgers A. Effects of price discounts and tailored nutrition education on supermarket purchases: a randomized controlled trial. Am J Clin Nutr. 2010;91(3):736–47. 10.3945/ajcn.2009.28742 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Ball K, McNaughton SA, Le HN, Gold L, Ni Mhurchu C, Abbott G, et al. Influence of price discounts and skill-building strategies on purchase and consumption of healthy food and beverages: outcomes of the Supermarket Healthy Eating for Life randomized controlled trial. Am J Clin Nutr. 2015;101(5):1055–64. Epub 2015/04/17. 10.3945/ajcn.114.096735 . [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Brimblecombe J, Ferguson M, Chatfield MD, Liberato SC, Gunther A, Ball K, et al. Effect of a price discount and consumer education strategy on food and beverage purchases in remote Indigenous Australia: a stepped-wedge randomised controlled trial. The Lancet Public Health. 2017;2(2):e82–e95. 10.1016/S2468-2667(16)30043-3 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Waterlander WE, de Boer MR, Schuit AJ, Seidell JC, Steenhuis IH. Price discounts significantly enhance fruit and vegetable purchases when combined with nutrition education: a randomized controlled supermarket trial. Am J Clin Nutr. 2013;97(4):886–95. Epub 2013/03/01. 10.3945/ajcn.112.041632 . [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Mexican National Institute of Public Health and the Carolina Population Center at the University of North Carolina. Mexico’s National Institute of Public Health study indicates the federal sugar-sweetened beverage tax is successfully reducing purchases in Mexican households 2015 [3 July 2015]. Available from: http://alianzasalud.org.mx/2015/06/mexicos-national-institute-of-public-health-study-indicates-the-federal-sugar-sweetened-beverage-tax-is-successfully-reducing-purchases-in-mexican-households/.
  • 15.Colchero MA, Popkin BM, Rivera JA, Ng SW. Beverage purchases from stores in Mexico under the excise tax on sugar sweetened beverages: observational study. BMJ. 2016;352:h6704 10.1136/bmj.h6704 . [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Smed S, Scarborough P, Rayner M, Jensen J. The effects of the Danish saturated fat tax on food and nutrient intake and modelled health outcomes: an econometric and comparative risk assessment evaluation. Eur J Clin Nutr. 2016. 10.1038/ejcn.2016.6 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Silver LD, Ng SW, Ryan-Ibarra S, Taillie LS, Induni M, Miles DR, et al. Changes in prices, sales, consumer spending, and beverage consumption one year after a tax on sugar-sweetened beverages in Berkeley, California, US: A before-and-after study. PLoS Med. 2017;14(4):e1002283 Epub 2017/04/19. 10.1371/journal.pmed.1002283 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Eyles H, Ni Mhurchu C, Nghiem N, Blakely T. Food pricing strategies, population diets, and non-communicable disease: a systematic review of simulation studies. PLoS Med. 2012;9(12):e1001353 Epub 2012/12/15. 10.1371/journal.pmed.1001353 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Nghiem N, Wilson N, Genc M, Blakely T. Understanding Price Elasticities to Inform Public Health Research and Intervention Studies: Key Issues. Am J Public Health. 2013;epub date: September 12 2013. Epub 2013/09/14. 10.2105/AJPH.2013.301337 . [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Briggs ADM, Wolstenholme J, Blakely T, Scarborough P. Choosing an epidemiological model structure for the economic evaluation of non-communicable disease public health interventions. Popul Health Metr. 2016;14(17). 10.1186/s12963-016-0085-1 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.University of Otago and Ministry of Health. A Focus on Nutrition: Key findings of the 2008/09 New Zealand Adult Nutrition Survey Wellington Ministry of Health, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Waterlander WE, Jiang Y, Nghiem N, Eyles H, Wilson N, Cleghorn C, et al. The effect of food price changes on consumer purchases: a randomised experiment. Lancet Public Health. 2019;4(8):e394–e405. 10.1016/S2468-2667(19)30105-7 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Waterlander WE, Blakely T, Nghiem N, Cleghorn CL, Eyles H, Genc M, et al. Study protocol: combining experimental methods, econometrics and simulation modelling to determine price elasticities for studying food taxes and subsidies (The Price ExaM Study). BMC Public Health. 2016;16(1). 10.1186/s12889-016-3277-5 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Shemilt I, Marteau TM, Smith RD, Ogilvie D. Use and cumulation of evidence from modelling studies to inform policy on food taxes and subsidies: biting off more than we can chew? BMC Public Health. 2015;15(1). 10.1186/s12889-015-2459-x [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Nghiem N, Jacobi L, Ramírez-Hassan A, Waterlander W, Blakely T. Thomas Bayes goes to the Virtual Supermarket: Assessing price elasticities and food price policies in a large food demand system combining prior elasticity estimates and experimental data. under review. [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Rolls BJ. The relationship between dietary energy density and energy intake. Physiol Behav. 2009;97(5):609–15. 10.1016/j.physbeh.2009.03.011 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Williams RA, Roe LS, Rolls BJ. Comparison of three methods to reduce energy density. Effects on daily energy intake. Appetite. 2013;66:75–83. 10.1016/j.appet.2013.03.004 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Klonaris S, Hallam D. Conditional and unconditional food demand elasticities in a dynamic multistage demand system. Applied Economics. 2003;35(5):503–14. 10.1080/00036840210148058 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Brännlund R, Ghalwash T, Nordström J. Increased energy efficiency and the rebound effect: Effects on consumption and emissions. Energy Economics. 2007;29(1):1–17. 10.1016/j.eneco.2005.09.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Dey MM, Alam MF, Paraguas FJ. A multistage budgeting approach to the analysis of demand for fish: an application to inland areas of Bangladesh. Marine Resource Economics. 2011;26(1):35–58. [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Waterlander W, Nghiem N, Yannan J, Eyles H, Wilson N, Cleghorn C, et al. The effect of randomized changes in food prices on food purchasing in a virtual supermarket experimental study. Under review. [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Andreyeva T, Long MW, Brownell KD. The impact of food prices on consumption: a systematic review of research on the price elasticity of demand for food. Am J Public Health. 2010;100(2):216–22. Epub 2009/12/19. 10.2105/AJPH.2008.151415 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Dharmasena S, Capps O. Intended and unintended consequences of a proposed national tax on sugar-sweetened beverages to combat the U.S. obesity problem. Health Econ. 2011:n/a-n/a. 10.1002/hec.1738 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Raunikar R, Huang CL. Food Demand Analysis Ames: Iowa State University Press; 1987. [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Cleghorn CL, Blakely T, Nghiem N, Mizdrak A, Wilson N. Technical Report for BODE3 Diet Intervention and Multistate Lifetable Models, Version 1.1 Wellington: Department of Public Health, University of Otago, Wellington; 2018 February, 2018. Report No. [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Michelini C. New Zealand household consumption patterns 1983–1992: An application of the almost‐ideal‐demand‐system. New Zealand Economic Papers. 1999;33(2):15–26. 10.1080/00779959909544305 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Michelini C, Chatterjee S. Demographic variables in demand systems: An analysis of New Zealand household expenditure 1984–1992. New Zealand Economic Papers. 1997;31(2):153–73. 10.1080/00779959709544272 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 38.Hall KD, Sacks G, Chandramohan D, Chow CC, Wang YC, Gortmaker SL, et al. Quantification of the effect of energy imbalance on bodyweight. Lancet. 2011;378(9793):826–37. 10.1016/S0140-6736(11)60812-X [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Forouzanfar MH, Alexander L, Anderson HR, Bachman VF, Biryukov S, Brauer M, et al. Global, regional, and national comparative risk assessment of 79 behavioural, environmental and occupational, and metabolic risks or clusters of risks in 188 countries, 1990–2013: a systematic analysis for the Global Burden of Disease Study 2013. The Lancet. 2015. 10.1016/S0140-6736(15)00128-2 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Afshin A, Sur PJ, Fay KA, Cornaby L, Ferrara G, Salama JS, et al. Health effects of dietary risks in 195 countries, 1990–2017: a systematic analysis for the Global Burden of Disease Study 2017. The Lancet. 2019. 10.1016/s0140-6736(19)30041-8 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Decision Letter 0

Chuanwang Sun

11 Dec 2019

PONE-D-19-27149

Modelling the health impact of food taxes and subsidies with price elasticities: the case for additional scaling of food consumption using the total food expenditure elasticity

PLOS ONE

Dear Prof. Blakely,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

We would appreciate receiving your revised manuscript by Jan 25 2020 11:59PM. When you are ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter.

To enhance the reproducibility of your results, we recommend that if applicable you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io, where a protocol can be assigned its own identifier (DOI) such that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). This letter should be uploaded as separate file and labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. This file should be uploaded as separate file and labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. This file should be uploaded as separate file and labeled 'Manuscript'.

Please note while forming your response, if your article is accepted, you may have the opportunity to make the peer review history publicly available. The record will include editor decision letters (with reviews) and your responses to reviewer comments. If eligible, we will contact you to opt in or out.

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Chuanwang Sun

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal Requirements:

When submitting your revision, we need you to address these additional requirements:

  1. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at http://www.plosone.org/attachments/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and http://www.plosone.org/attachments/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf

     

  2. Please include captions for your Supporting Information files at the end of your manuscript, and update any in-text citations to match accordingly. Please see our Supporting Information guidelines for more information: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/supporting-information

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

5. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: The authors adopted price elasticity (PE) matrices to study food taxes. It ‘s an interesting topic and it’s useful for developing countries and areas. The authors may contribute to build the models, but the analysis in the paper is built on literatures and lack of innovation. Furthermore, the conclusions need to be more clear and concrete to show the final findings and economic meanings of the research.

Reviewer #2: This paper uses previously estimated price elasticities for food products to estimate the effect on diets from a taxes on saturated fat and on sugar and a subsidy on fruits and vegetables. The paper goes on to estimate the effect of the estimated change in diets on health, in particular adjusted health years. The innovation in the paper is to adjust the price elasticities to account for the change in total expenditures on food from the change in aggregate food prices, which the authors refer to as the total food elasticity adjustment, TFEe adjustment. The authors find that the adjustment has a significant effect on the price elasticities they use to calculate changes in health.

While the author discuss the TFEe adjustment, I would have liked to have seen more detail regarding how the calculation is made. (On page 15, the authors claim that their approach is a “theoretically plausible solution.” But they don’t demonstrate that point.) If the adjustment or calculation were made using estimated share rather than price elasticities, the calculation would go something like this: Let sit be the share of total food expenditures Et in year t spent on product i. The available estimates of s assume that E is fixed. Thus is it necessary to account for the effect of price change on both s and E in order to measure the effect of the price change on total quantity q consumed of product i. The change in q can be expressed as

Δq=s_(t+1)*E_(t+1)-s_t*E_t=Δs*E_t+s_t*ΔE+Δs*ΔE

An equivalent expression using elasticities would have been helpful.

There is an implicit assumption that the pre-tax market price does not change in response to the taxes and subsidies. It is reasonable to assume perfect competition and constant marginal cost in food production NZ?

Another implicit assumption is that the estimated price elasticities apply in the long run. If I understand how the price elasticities were estimated, I believe that they reflect short run responses to price changes. But, it is expected that over time, consumers will modify their response to the initial price change. This is important since the price elasticities are used to estimate changes in diet over an individual’s lifetime.

If expenditures on food increase as a result of the tax/subsidy policy, might the change in non-food spending result in health effects? For example, might there be less spending on exercise classes or health care, or less driving but more walking?

It would be desirable to compare the change in prices used in the research that generated the price elasticities to the implicit change in prices from the tax/subsidy policy. In particular, are the authors trying to estimate effects that are well outside the range of prices used for the price elasticity estimation?

Regarding the writing, in general, I found it difficult to understand what the authors were attempting to do and then how they did it. The paper could have been made much clearer.

The paper uses estimates that were generated in other papers, for example the price elasticities. I found it difficult to follow the explanation of the price elasticity estimates. It was technical and short compared to the original papers, making it hard to obtain an intuitive understanding of the procedure. I think it might have been desirable if the discussion of how those results were derived was separated from the rest of the discussion.

There are many typos and places where the writing could be made clearer and the presentation improved. Here are some examples, but this is not a comprehensive list:

P3. HALY is defined in the abstract. It should be defined the first time it is used in the body of the paper.

P6, 1st paragraph. The explanation of price elasticity is very basic and could be dropped or relegated to a footnote. On the other hand the explanation for the need to scale the estimated elasticities is not well articulated.

P6, 2nd paragraph. The following is unclear, “…on both price and demand or purchasing with sufficient variation in price…” as is “…starting proportionate consumption…”

P6, 2nd paragraph. The sentence beginning with “Indeed, the most common…” could be improved by more clearly noting that it is in reference to studies that focus just on food consumption. I first thought it meant general studies of price elasticities that assume no change in food expenditures, which didn’t make any sense.

P6, 3rd paragraph. Consider the sentence, “Is applying PEs derived from one setting into another acceptable?” I found this misleading. At first I thought the task was that the paper was taking price elasticity estimated from one data source, and using them to estimate changes using a different data set. But that is not exactly what is being done. The paper does not apply them in another “setting”. I struggled with trying to understand what the authors were doing, and found the writing confusing rather than enlightening.

P7-8. Given that the objective is to estimate the effect on consumption of food items from a price change, the suggestion that one would do assuming that energy intake or grams of food purchased is constant, makes no intuitive sense. I don’t see the point of discussing those two options.

P10, 2nd line. “more important” is not what you mean, but rather “larger”.

P13, Results. Information on the consumption of saturated fats and sugar would have been helpful in understanding how the tax results in a price increase of 3.91% for all food.

P22, Text Box. The text says a 20% subsidy, while the spreadsheets refer to a 10% subsidy.

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files to be viewed.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email us at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

Attachment

Submitted filename: PLoS One - Review - Scaling food consumption.pdf

Decision Letter 1

Chuanwang Sun

3 Mar 2020

Modelling the health impact of food taxes and subsidies with price elasticities: the case for additional scaling of food consumption using the total food expenditure elasticity

PONE-D-19-27149R1

Dear Dr. Blakely,

We are pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been judged scientifically suitable for publication and will be formally accepted for publication once it complies with all outstanding technical requirements.

Within one week, you will receive an e-mail containing information on the amendments required prior to publication. When all required modifications have been addressed, you will receive a formal acceptance letter and your manuscript will proceed to our production department and be scheduled for publication.

Shortly after the formal acceptance letter is sent, an invoice for payment will follow. To ensure an efficient production and billing process, please log into Editorial Manager at https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/, click the "Update My Information" link at the top of the page, and update your user information. If you have any billing related questions, please contact our Author Billing department directly at authorbilling@plos.org.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper to enable them to help maximize its impact. If they will be preparing press materials for this manuscript, you must inform our press team as soon as possible and no later than 48 hours after receiving the formal acceptance. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

With kind regards,

Chuanwang Sun

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Additional Editor Comments (optional):

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer #2: The authors have address all of my comments on the first version of the paper. I have no further comments.

Acceptance letter

Chuanwang Sun

10 Mar 2020

PONE-D-19-27149R1

Modelling the health impact of food taxes and subsidies with price elasticities: the case for additional scaling of food consumption using the total food expenditure elasticity

Dear Dr. Blakely:

I am pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been deemed suitable for publication in PLOS ONE. Congratulations! Your manuscript is now with our production department.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper at this point, to enable them to help maximize its impact. If they will be preparing press materials for this manuscript, please inform our press team within the next 48 hours. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information please contact onepress@plos.org.

For any other questions or concerns, please email plosone@plos.org.

Thank you for submitting your work to PLOS ONE.

With kind regards,

PLOS ONE Editorial Office Staff

on behalf of

Dr. Chuanwang Sun

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Associated Data

    This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

    Supplementary Materials

    S1 Fig. Conceptual diagram of the model.

    (DOCX)

    S1 Table. Marshallian cross- and own-PEs matrix using a Bayesian Linear Almost Ideal Demand System (LAIDS) approach.

    (DOCX)

    S2 Table. Standard deviations about the Marshallian cross- and own-PEs shown in S1 Table.

    (DOCX)

    S3 Table. Food group level (n = 23) expenditure elasticities applied after conventional application of the PE matrix, and before the final TFEe scaling.

    (DOCX)

    S4 Table. HALYs gained at 3% discount rate for saturated fat and sugar taxes, and fruit and vegetable subsidy, for the preferred TFEe adjustment and conventional (no TFEe adjustment) analyses.

    (DOCX)

    S5 Table. Univariate sensitivity analyses about low and high (2.5th and 97.5th percentile) values of TFEe, using the “TFEe adjustment” models.

    (DOCX)

    S6 Table. Univariate sensitivity analyses about low and high (2.5th and 97.5th percentile) values of PE disaggregation scalar.

    (DOCX)

    Attachment

    Submitted filename: PLoS One - Review - Scaling food consumption.pdf

    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Response to referees, Plos One 2.docx

    Data Availability Statement

    There are multiple sources of data used in this study, to parameterize the diet and multistate lifetable models. The sex, age and ethnic composition of the NZ population in 2011 was set using Statistics NZ resident population estimates. All-cause mortality and morbidity data, and disease specific incidence, case fatality and prevalence rates, are all provided in an Excel file “Disease Inputs used for Multi-State Life Table Modelling (Version 1.0)” available at the BODE3 publications webpage: https://www.otago.ac.nz/wellington/departments/publichealth/research/bode3/publications/index.html. Note that many of these data are generated specifically for the DIET model, requiring ‘epidemiological coherence’ using the DISMOD epidemiological calculator.1 They may not be fit for other purposes. Excess health system costs for each disease included in the model are provided in the DIET model Technical Report 2 - also available at the above BODE3 publications webpage. The price elasticity matrix is reported in S1 and S2 Tables of the current paper. Relative risks for the risk factor disease associations are in the DIET model Technical Report.2 Starting food consumption at the level of 340 foods, by sex and ethnicity, was taken from the NZ Adult Nutrition Survey; as stated in the paper, was provided by the Otago University ‘Life in New Zealand’ (LINZ) staff (personal communication, Blakey, Smith and Parnell, 2014). Our data access agreement does not allow full disclosure of the estimates we extracted from this data, but others can approach LINZ directly for the data. Starting food prices were sources from Nutritrack data, which is available upon request from the National Institute of Health Innovation, University of Auckland. Other key variables, such as the total food expenditure elasticity (TFEe), are detailed in the manuscript. 1. Barendregt J, Oortmarssen GJ, Vos T, Murray CJL. A generic model for the assessment of disease epidemiology: the computational basis of DisMod II. Popul Health Metr 2003;1(1):4. 2. Cleghorn CL, Blakely T, Nghiem N, Mizdrak A, Wilson N. Technical Report for BODE3 Diet Intervention and Multistate Lifetable Models, Version 1.1. Burden of Disease Epidemiology, Equity and Cost-Effectiveness Programme - Technical Report No16. Wellington: Department of Public Health, University of Otago, Wellington 2018.


    Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

    RESOURCES