Skip to main content
Elsevier - PMC COVID-19 Collection logoLink to Elsevier - PMC COVID-19 Collection
. 2008 Nov 20;15(2):59–71. doi: 10.1016/j.jairtraman.2008.09.010

The impact of US–EU “Open Skies” agreement on airline market structures and airline networks

Kenneth Button 1
PMCID: PMC7147837  PMID: 32372849

Abstract

The gradual liberalization of international air transport has largely benefited the traveling public. Progress since the development of concepts such as “Open Skies” in the late 1970s as an alternative to the restrictive bilateral air service agreements that had effectively controlled most international air transport since the mid-1940s has been uneven and spasmodic. The recent move to open the North Atlantic more fully to competition has proved a particularly challenging task, and the agreement between the US and the European Union is still both partial and conditional. This paper offers an overview of the economics of the situation and provides insights into the reasons why it has developed in the way it has, the outcomes that we may expect from it, and some consideration of the wider, non-commercial, impacts that it may have.

Keywords: Transatlantic, Airline alliances, European Union, Chicago Convention

1. Introduction

From the late 1970s, when first the US domestic cargo market was liberalized followed by the domestic passenger sector, there has been a gradual withdraw of the state from the specific economic regulation of airlines. Internationally, the initial moves at deregulation can be traced to the initiation of the US's “Open Skies” policy from 1979. The recent opening up, at least to a substantial extent, of the US–EU1 transatlantic market is the one of the most significant measures of international airline liberalization since the removal of international market barriers within the European Union (EU). The US–EU passenger market is substantial. In 2007 it accounted for 55 million passengers, 385 flights per day in each direction and 235 nonstop city-pairs served by 45 airlines comprising eight from the US, 26 from the EU and 11 others. Geographically, 32 airports in 23 states were served on the US side and 53 airports in 19 countries in the EU.

The development comes at a time when similar measures have been initiated in other long-haul markets (e.g. between the US and Australia), and when there are similar, some complementary, changes taking place within air transportation more generally, including initiatives to improve air navigation systems, the coming on-line of new aircraft, developments in the way that airports are used and financed, and structural changes within the industry as a new wave of merger takes hold.

Understanding a little of the history of the recent develops on the North Atlantic helps us appreciate why the current arrangements exist, and offers some insights into likely future institutional changes. It is inevitable that the current regime is only a stepping-stone. Understanding the nature and economics of the airline industry helps in appreciating how carriers, and other suppliers such as airports, are likely to react to the new situation. It is also helpful to look beyond the narrow and specific confines of air transportation issues to explore the implications of more generic policies, such as industrial and security policies, may be for the long-term development of the North Atlantic market.

2. Institutional background

International air transportation has, until recently, been one of the most regulated of industries. The Chicago Convention of 1944 laid down a basis upon which a system of international bilateral air service agreements (ASAs) was founded.2 This was a compromise arrangement that attempted to reconcile the very liberal, free market ideas of the US on the one hand and the more restrictive ones of countries such as Australia (that wanted a single global carrier) on the other. There were particular fears in some countries that the US, that had the largest fleet of commercial aircraft at the time and the potential of adding to this by converting surplus military hardware, would dominate any largely market-based outcome and thus an institutional structure emerged that led to piecemeal, and restrictive, practical arrangements.

The Convention did not stipulate any particular form of international service structure but rather established national sovereignty over airspace and an institutional framework within which nations could essentially trade these rights (“freedoms of the skies”) amongst themselves. The outcome was a mass of bilateral agreements between countries that, in general, stipulated which airlines that could fly between them, the capacity of each airline, the fares to be charged, and, often, how the revenues generated were to be shared between the carriers. Similarly, air navigation services were sovereign responsibilities and a patchwork of systems emerged that impinged upon any notion of seamless air travel.

These restrictive bilateral ASA regimes were, at the time, seem as a step forward from the ad hoc and often opaque institutional structures that existed before, and they came at a time when international air transportation was still relatively new with many markets small and embryonic after the devastation of the Second World War. Because of this, they probably did little to impede the development of the sector for some time. Additionally, domestic markets were normally regulated although the structure differed between countries. In some countries there were single state-owned monopoly carriers whereas in others, such as the US, there were private airlines but competition was highly regulated. In many cases, institutional barriers prevented domestic and international carriers of a country operating in each other's markets.

The macro-economic conditions of the late 1970s (“Stagflation”), combined with background pressures generated in part by a series of academic studies, led to a sea-change in policy thinking. The US initially legally removed most economic regulation from its domestic market in 1978 and other countries, either through de jure reforms or de facto actions, gradually loosened theirs. The move towards greater economic and, to a lesser degree political, integration in Europe in the 1990s brought with it the creation of a Single European Market, including that for air services. This embraces not simply the ability of airlines that meet safety and environmental criteria and do not violate European Union (EU)3 competition policy from operating anywhere within Europe, but it also removed any ownership restrictions for airlines offering purely domestic or intra-Union services.

The experiences of deregulation (or in Europe, “liberalization”) of air transport markets over the past quarter of a century are generally seen as having produced significant economic benefits.4 Not everyone has gained, certainly some communities have lost services or have seen service quality decline, some airlines have gone bankrupt, and some classes of passengers are now paying higher fares, but for those few that have been adversely affected there are many more who can fly more cheaply, have a greater variety of services to choose from, or have found jobs in the extended air transportation value chain. No positive change occurs without disruption, and that has certainly been the experiences of airlines, but these negative features have been far outweighed by the positive effects.

International air transportation deregulation was generally slower to emerge than domestic reform because of the need for a double coincidence of interests.5 US policy makers first muted the general idea of bilateral “Open Skies” policies to replace the highly restrictive air service agreements as early as 1979, but it took another dozen or so years before the first major one, with the Netherlands, was signed. Since that time, a further 60 or so liberal agreements, of varying importance, have been signed between the US and partners, including many European states. The emergence of the large free trade area in air transportation service within Europe from the mid-1990s was another element in freeing-up other international markets by having both knock-on and demonstration effects for regions outside of the European area.6

3. The economic condition of the airline industry

Airlines find it difficult to recover their full costs in competitive markets. As seen in Fig. 1 that reports operating margins,7 both globally and for two of the largest markets, there are clear cycles in the financial performance of the industry that correlate with the larger business cycle. But, in addition, taken overall, the airline industry has performed badly across cycles. In the US, for example, over the past 20 years or so the operating margins of US airlines has been about 0.4% compared with an average of well over 5% for US industry as a whole. The period has also seen a number of traditional airlines cease operations permanently (e.g. Pan Am and TWA in the US and Sabena and Swissair in Europe) as well as a much larger number of new entrants, and particularly low cost carriers.

Fig. 1.

Fig. 1

Operating margins of airlines (1988–2006). Notes: (i) a lack of a bar indicates a missing observation and not a zero operating margin, (ii) memberships of the various reporting bodies vary over time and thus the reported margins reflect the associated carriers at the time of reporting. Sources: Boeing Commercial Airplane, Association of European Airlines, Air Transport Association of America, International Air Transport Association.

There have been a number of “events” in recent years that particularly impacted on commercial aviation, adding the to normal market uncertainties of the industry and the larger, temporal trends that are on-going.

3.1. September 11th, 2001 terrorist attacks

The attacks on the US in 2001 had implications for the global air transportation market. It not only led to an immediate shutting-down of large parts of the system, most notably those associated with the US market, but also to a longer-term reduction in demand as concerns about the safety of air travel emerged. The additional security measures that were put in place following 9/11 added to the cost of air travel, not simply in monetary terms but also because of the additional time and inconvenience associated air travel. This came at a time when there was already a downturn in the business cycle that began in the US in 2000.

3.2. Severe acute respiratory syndrome (SARS)

The SARS epidemic had a severe, albeit it relatively short-term impact on the international civil aviation market in 2003, and in particular adversely affected a number of Asian markets. While difficult to isolate out the particular implications of the disease of the finances of the sector, the Official Airline Guide shows that flights to China fell by 45% between June 2002 and 2003, by 36% between Europe and Hong Kong, by 69% between the US/Canada and Hong Kong, and by 3% globally.

3.3. 2nd Gulf War

The impact of the 2nd Gulf War on the airline industry overlapped with the SARS epidemic but its main impacts were in different markets; e.g. most flights to Israel and Egypt were immediately suspended together with some flights to Athens, Istanbul and Ankara and Karachi. The wider geographical impacts were on tourist traffic due to fears of potential terrorist attacks.

3.4. High fuel prices

There have been unprecedented rises in costs of aviation fuel (kerosene) since 2001. The price of jet fuel has risen from $30.5 a barrel in 2001 to $81.9 a barrel in 2006, to $113.4 in December 2007 and is over $140 at the time of writing (July, 2008). The result is that for international airlines, fuel costs that constituted 13% of operating costs rose to 26% by 2006 and has climbed since. This has put financial pressures on the airlines to the extent that some have imposed fuel surcharges that are impacting adversely on the fares paid by passengers.8

4. Overall analyses of regulatory change

Much of the analysis of the effects of market change has inevitably focused on domestic liberalizations, with a particular emphasis on the post-1978 US market. Not only is this the world's largest air transport market, and one where, because of the 10% sampling of tickets, there is an abundance of information and data, but it is also one that until comparatively recently, because of the relatively small amount of external traffic, is closely geographically bounded. Added to this, the geography of the country makes air transportation the only viable mode for long distance travel, and as such stimulates public interest.

The emphasis, however, has largely been on the direct effects of deregulation on the airlines and their customers with rather less on the implications for overall employment, other than narrowly for airline personnel. The broader economic impacts on industrial structure and regional economic development have largely been assessed indirectly through impact studies of the airports that handle the larger traffic volumes. The evidence from this, however, combined with the few impartial studies that have directly sought to link airline deregulation to economic development, is that more commercial sensitive domestic airline markets do facilitate economic growth in regions.

Analysis of international airline market deregulation is sparser. From the studies that have been completed, it is clear that more open-air transportation markets foster trade and stimulate the growth of major industries such as tourism. Air transportation, and international air transportation in particular, is a key input to the location and production product positioning decisions of many multi-national corporations. This is not surprising given that air transport carriers transport about 40% the world's trade by value and its importance is growing as structural economic changes take place. While excessive transportation will always be wasteful, optimal transportation supply as determined by market forces, constrained within appropriate institutional structures, is a major facilitator of economic development and allows countries and regions to exploit their comparative advantages more fully.

Open Skies air service agreements have not only removed restrictions governing rates and fares, market entry, and the ways revenues are allocated, but have also permitted the emergence of various forms of business alliances. Strategic alliances now dominate international air transportation. Although not all have been successful, in a commercial world there are inevitably failures, they have allowed wider network economies of scope, and density on the costs side, and economies of market presence on the demand side to be exploited. They also provide a degree of protection for airlines that would otherwise, in excessively competitive conditions that can emerge in aviation, find it difficult to recover their full costs even if they are highly efficient.9 This is confirmed in a variety of previous studies that have looked at some of these alliances. Although the links have seldom been explicitly drawn, the enhanced efficiency of international airlines, given the derived nature of the demands for their services, would seem inevitably to have improved the vitality and economic performances of the regions they serve.

The case for continually reviewing the nature of the institutional structure within which air transportation services are delivered becomes stronger when taken in the context of changes in the global market. Air transportation is clearly growing in many relative new markets in Asia, particularly China and India, but it is also forecasted to expand in some more traditional markets such as the North Atlantic; Boeing Commercial Airplane (2005) suggests a growth rate of about 4.6% over the next two decades, if current relationships continue. But even if the long-term projections prove excessive, there is a strong case for ensuring that the full comparative economic advantages of the EU economy are exploited. While there have been short-term disruptions to the growth in US/EU passenger movements, the evidence is that the downturn in international trade in air services across the Atlantic that followed the events of September 11th, 2001 has passed and there is once again an outward shift in the demand for air transportation (Fig. 2 ).

Fig. 2.

Fig. 2

US–EU transatlantic air passengers.

The matter is effectively one of balance. Although it would be economically inefficient to over invest, or otherwise seek to artificially stimulate this market, impeding market driven international transportation with inappropriate institutional barriers equally stymies the economic performances of the macro-economies of both the US and countries within the EU. Air transportation is a matter of everyday public concern, especially regarding such things as safety matters, but the general evidence is that market liberalization has produced net benefits of a more durable kind.

Although there is evidence that regulatory reforms in the international air transportation market have largely been beneficial, there are groups that are, for a variety of reasons and quite understandably, at the micro-level, opposed to further reform. In the US, for example, there are military concerns about losing the lift capabilities under the Civil Reserve Air Force program that are made available at time of national emergency; US carriers provide equipment and crew at such times and there is a fear this will not be available if US carriers become foreign owned. There have been traditional concerns expressed by airline employees about erosion of their higher pay scales should EU workers be able to work in the US. This argument, however, seems rather moot in 2008 given the state of US airlines' finances and of the US dollar. Equally, in the UK and other countries where restrictive ASAs still exist, there are those that would lose out should there be a regime change; for example, it would affect the relative competitive position of their airlines and airports.10

5. Transatlantic air service bilaterals

The ASAs that have governed much of the global international air transport market since the 1940s have changed considerably over the past 25 years. They have largely moved from being highly restrictive on the fares that can be charged and the capacity that is provided to become a relatively liberal regime of agreements under which trade in air transportation services is comparatively free in many parts of the world. There are also increasing numbers of very liberal multilateral agreements, as for example within Europe. There is even some very limited involvement of the World Trade Organization (WTO) to remove some “soft rights” technical limitations to trade in air transportation services.11

Different regions and countries have moved at their own paces, and change has not been continuous. Countries whose airlines have benefited under restrictive bilateral ASAs have often encountered pressures to resist reforms from their carriers and their labor forces. There have been three major developments as far as transatlantic air transportation is concerned.

5.1. Traditional ASA bilaterals

Traditional ASAs that grew up from the immediate post Second World War period varied somewhat between the country pairs involved, but had many common features. The changes that have taken place have also not been entirely consistent across country pairs. Table 1 , however, provides details of the general characteristics of US ASA bilaterals prior to the move to the Open Aviation Area (as favored by the EU side) and Open Skies model (the preferred, and currently accepted, favored by the US). A major difference between bilateral ASA involving the US prior to the 1980s was that charter traffic was regulated in addition to scheduled services.12 Within Europe, while intra-Union international scheduled services were subjected to fare and entry controls, the charter market was somewhat more liberal, although still encumbered by restrictions that sought to limit its use to leisure travelers.

Table 1.

Main features of US bilateral air service agreements.

Pre-1978 bilateral air service agreements 1978–1991 Open market bilaterals
Post-1991 Open Skies bilateral
US airlines Foreign airlines
Market access Only to specified points From any point in the US to specified points in foreign countries Access limited to a number of US points Unlimited
Limited 5th freedom rights granted to US carriers Extensive 5th freedom rights granted Unlimited 5th freedom rights
Charter rights not included Unlimited charter rights
7th Freedom rights not granted
Cabotage not allowed



Designation Single – some multiple Multiple
Airlines must be “substantially and effectively controlled” by nationals of designated state



Capacity Capacity agreed or shared 50:50. No capacity/frequency controls in liberal bilaterals, but subject to review No frequency or capacity controls
Break of gauge permitted in some agreements Break-of-gauge rights granted



Tarrifs Approval by both governments (double approval) or as agreed by IATA Double disapproval (filed tariffs operative unless both governments disapproval) or country of origin rules Free pricing



Code sharing Not part of bilateral Code-sharing permitted

5.2. The bilateral Open Skies agreements

The US initiated liberal international air service agreements as a logical extension of the regulatory reforms of its domestic market; the term “Open Skies” was first used by Alfred Kahn, the chairman of the Civil Aeronautics Board, in 1979 when discussing objectives to be pursued after the enactment of the 1978 Airline Deregulation Act. Initially the response of European governments was tepid, in part because the focus of the EU at the time was more on internal transportation matters, especially surface transportation, and because the efficiency of US carriers induced many European airlines to believe that they would be at a significant competitive disadvantage.13

The practical outcome within the EU was a series of liberalizing agreements between a number of European states (e.g. the UK with Netherlands, Belgium, Germany and Luxemburg) in the 1980s. These did not, however, represent full market liberalization (government intervention remained potentially significant) but rather they were a relaxation of the older regimes. They gave much more flexibility to the routes that could be served, removed capacity and service level constraints on these routes, and moved away from the double approval of fares to one based upon double disapproval. The nature of the European industry at the time, and the domination of state-owned “flag carriers”, together with the size of markets still generally limited them to one airline per route, whereas within the US by this time more than one US carrier served the same route.

The growth in air traffic as incomes grew and trade expanded, coupled with the generally favorable views on domestic reforms and the extension of hub-and-spoke operations to international markets, resulted in pressures emerging in many countries for the removal of further constraints on air transportation provisions. In Europe, the move to commercialize air transportation, as well as removing institutional barriers to trade, resulted in flag carriers seeking to develop their networks as they were weaned off long-standing regimes of state subsidies and turned over to private ownership.

The outcome, from 1992, was a series of bilateral “Open Skies” agreements between EU states and the US. These first involved the Netherlands but then extended to other EU member countries (Table 2 ). These “Open Skies” agreements allow fights to any two points in the signatory countries, with no restriction on fares, service level, or fifth freedom operations. Charter operations are included as well as scheduled services. They also, through parallel measures in the realm of anti-trust and competition policy, allow code sharing and other strategic alliance activities. The US at this time also facilitated the process by offering a relative simple template Open Skies agreement with standard clauses in it. By 2007, of the 19 of the European countries offering direct US–EU, 16 already had Open Skies agreements corresponding to 54% of seat capacity across the North Atlantic.

Table 2.

The European based “Open Skies” initiatives (passenger services).

Netherlands In Force 10/14/92
Belgium Provisional 3/1/95
Finland In Force 3/24/95
Denmark In Force 4/26/95
Norway In Force 4/26/95
Sweden In Force 4/26/95
Luxembourg In Force 6/6/95
Austria In Force 6/14/95
Czech Repub. In Force 12/8/95
Germany Provisional 2/29/96
Italy Comity and Reciprocity 11/11/98
Portugal In Force 12/22/99
Malta In Force 10/12/00
Poland In Force 5/31/01
France In Force 10/19/01

Not all European countries, however, had Open Skies agreements with the US, and in some cases they are not fully operational (Table 2). In particular, the important US/UK air services market still operated under the “Bermuda II” agreement originally signed in 1977, although amended periodically since its inception. This limits, besides other things, the number of carriers that can serve London Heathrow Airport to two from each country (American Airlines and United Airlines, and British Airways and Virgin Atlantic respectively from the US and UK) and the number of US gateways served. Greece, Ireland, and Spain also have restrictions; e.g., Ireland required one US flight through Shannon for everyone to Dublin, and limits fifth freedom rights, and Greece, besides limiting fifth freedom rights also limits the gateways served, the number of airlines on some routes, and freedom of fare setting. Others have similar deviations from a market-based agreement.

Additionally, Open Skies bilateral agreements do not mean entirely open markets in the conventional economic sense. There are “nationality clauses” that affect the carriers that may enter markets; in the US case they must be “substantially and effectively controlled” by nationals of the designated state or by its nationals. While outwardly aimed at preventing third parties entering the bilateral, de facto nationality clauses act to impede the full functioning of international air transportation capital markets. Linked with this, foreign ownership of carriers operating in US and intra-European markets is also limited, both in terms of the share ownership permitted and the voting power of these shares. For example, the Air Commerce Act 1926 requires that US citizens own at least 51% of any individual aircraft in order for it to be registered under the US and the Civil Aeronautics Act 1938, Congress requires that US citizens own or control at least 75% of the voting interests of US airlines.14 This standard has remained the same since. This makes mergers and cross investment impossible outside of the limits set and, because of the lack of control over its use, is not exactly an incentive for foreigners to invest their money. There are, in addition, regulations over the nationality of who may hold senior managerial positions.15

There are also rules regarding cabotage, or eighth freedom rights. In the US, domestic services can only be provided by an airline “established” in the country. This, because of the inability to create feeder services, limits the capability of a non-US carrier to develop a full double hub-market across the Atlantic. The emergence of strategic alliances may be seen as a second-best attempt to circumvent the restriction.

Within Europe, because of the sovereignty of each nation, US carriers can only fly where they can obtain appropriate fifth and sixth freedom rights to carry passengers between states, although not within them. The US also prohibits “wet leasing” – the leasing of a plane and crew – although this practice is legal in European countries, and this constrains the efficient movement of physical capital by airlines between international markets to meet exceptional needs. In addition, the Fly America requirement means that US government and military personnel must normally use a US carrier or one that is part of an approved strategic alliance with relevant anti-trust immunity for international air travel.

6. EU/US negotiations on open skies

The EU as an entity had set the creation of a Common Transport Policy (CTP) as one of its two major goals under the founding Treaty of Rome. Air transportation was, mainly because of its relative small size and the magnitude of the task of tackling distortions in other transport markets, explicitly excluded until it was felt a Union-wide approach was needed. Progress on the CTP was snail-like until the creation of the Single European Market in 1992. By this time air transportation had grown in importance, and, in part stimulated by a series of legal judgment and proactive initiatives from the European Commission, had become an issue of political concern (Button, 2004). A number of “Packages” successively, liberalized and standardized exiting ASAs, deregulated the market for intra-European international traffic, and, finally, liberalized the entire internal market by allowing cabotage.

At the same time the US effectively developed and spread its Open Skies strategies by stimulating beggar-thy-neighbor policies in Europe as the aviation component of the CTP evolved.16 The US sought to breakdown the highly restrictive ASAs by initiating a liberal agreement with one major EU international aviation country and, thereby, to force others to follow suit to retain market share. Added to this, some EU airlines found that their domestic and EU markets were constrained by regulation and sought outside expansion – hence, the adoption of the Netherlands and others of more open agreements at a fairly early stage.17 This in turn put pressure on others to emulate.

The growth in demand for transatlantic travel from the mid-1990s (see again Fig. 2) stimulated significant numbers of larger European airlines to seek even more reforms in extra-EU markets to allow them to exploit their scale economies and extra-EU service networks (Association of European Airlines, 1999). From the late 1990s, and after the liberalization of internal air transportation market, legal issues also emerged regarding extra-Union authorities; specifically matters of the respective responsibilities of the Union and of the individual member states that transcend narrow aviation considerations. The European Commission questioned the legality of the existing Open Skies agreements that effectively gave preferential treatment, through the nationality rules, to the European national carriers involved. The ruling of the European Court of Justice, although not precluding strategic alliances and revised liberal agreements, effectively resulted in the Commission gaining power in June 2003 over extra-EU air services policy involving relations with the US.

Negotiations subsequently took place but while there was some initial progress through compromise in a number of technical areas,18 little substantive agreement emerged for some time regarding the key and fundamental economic issues; there were 11 rounds of negotiations. The interests of the domestic coalitions that influence the US stance strongly favor a US/EU Open Skies arrangement, whilst the Union has favored a much more free market approach that allows for cabotage and flexible movement of capital, as is the case within Europe via an Open Aviation Area. The impasse was broken in March 2007 with a compromise, short-term agreement that effectively opened the skies over the North Atlantic but not the factor markets. An agreement was signed the following month.

7. The new situation

The new transatlantic agreement, that is provisionally being applied beginning March 30, 2008, extends Open Skies principles to 11 EU countries where the US has had previously held restrictive agreements or none at all, including Greece, Ireland, Spain, and the UK. The US and the EU have agreed to begin second-stage negotiations on further liberalization within 60 days of application of the agreement. Putting the structure into a global perspective, since 1992, US policy has resulted in the conclusion of Open Skies ASAs with partners from every region of the world. By 2007, there are more than 60 such partners (including some with no airlines or US air services), including the 27 countries of the EU (Table 3 ). The extension to all EU countries may thus be important, but is only a part of larger changes.

Table 3.

Extent of Open Skies coverage as a result of the 2007 agreement.

Originally covered Now
Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovakia, and Sweden UK, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Estonia, Ireland, Greece, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Spain, and Slovenia

The new agreement contains these major provisions:

  • Open Skies between the US and the EU and its member states;

  • Broader entry into cooperative marketing arrangements for code sharing, franchising, and leasing;

  • Creation of a cooperative joint committee to further airline deregulation;

  • Guarantees for US investors to participate as minority shareholders in any majority-EU-owned airline (effectively including minority shares of state-owned firms);

  • Restatement of US investment policy in US airlines (25% legislated cap on voting equity, 25%-minus-one-share regulatory cap on non-voting equity). The US will consider foreign requests to hold larger shares of non-voting equity, including combinations in which the total of voting and non-voting equity exceeds 50%;

  • For EU carriers, the ability to route flights between any EU member state and the US without touching the home country's “community carriers” (for example, a German Lufthansa flight can go from Paris to the US, without having to pass through Germany);

  • US agreement that purchased by an EU carrier or investor of a controlling share in a carrier (passenger or cargo) from third countries that have Open Skies agreements with the US – such as Switzerland, Liechtenstein, members of the European Common Aviation Area (ECAA), Kenya, or African countries – would not jeopardize the acquired airlines' rights to operate in the US;

  • Authorization for EU carriers (scheduled and charter, passenger and cargo) to carry certain Fly America traffic, except for the US Department of Defense; and

  • For EU cargo carriers, the ability to route flights between third-party states and the US without touching the home country, and between the US and members of the ECAA.

As can be seen, while this institutional structure is often touted as an Open Aviation Area in Europe the lack of a fully open factor market and cabotage makes it, de facto, an Open Skies arrangement. These wider matters are to be discussed in the “second phase”. The negations, in effect, however, avoided addressing the important concerns of organized labor regarding job security and remuneration and of the US military regarding the continuation of a civilian airlift capacity under the Civil Reserve Air Fleet (CRAF) program. This is aside from broader questions of different generic approaches to competition and mergers policies on either side of the Atlantic.

8. The economics of the subject

The restrictive ASA bilaterals that typified the institutional structure of international airline markets before the advent of Open Skies manifestly had a number of adverse effects on the efficiency of supply and, specifically, on the levels of benefits society could reap from air travel. These effects are not easy to isolate in a simple way but Fig. 3 offers a general representation of the issues that are involved. In particular, it highlights the potential fare and output implications of the various types of transatlantic regulatory regimes.19

Fig. 3.

Fig. 3

The simple economics of Open Skies policies.

The initial position of the demand curve for transatlantic services under the pre-1980s regulatory regime is assumed linear and shown as D1 in the figure, and the average cost curve per passenger, which for simplicity is assumed to rise more than linearly with quantity, as C1. Market forces, however, because of the institutional interventions in place, did not determine fares and capacity across the Atlantic. Capacity under this system was limited (seen as the “capacity constraint” in the figure) and fares were regulated. If we assume that the terms reached under the bilateral agreement regarding fares allowed for at least cost recovery by the partners' airlines this implies a fare levels up to F1.20 The removal of both this capacity constraint and of negotiated pricing, as happens under the Open Skies arrangements, results in competition for air services, and a move towards cost-recovery pricing strategies by the carriers. This would reduce fares to F 1.

Open Skies policies, coupled with the permitting of strategic alliances, not only removes the capacity constraint but also affects both the demand and supply curves for transatlantic air travel. The ability of airlines to more effectively feed their transatlantic routes and coordinate their activities, through the restructuring of their business and networks, will reduce the average cost of carriage to C2 in the figure. The effect is often reinforced due to downward pressure on costs because, although not strictly part of the Open Skies framework, the wider competitive environment within Europe, and the privatization of many carriers, by heightening commercial pressures, reduces the amount of both static and dynamic X-inefficiency in the airline industry. In other words, there is the combined pressure of both free airline markets across the Atlantic and within the two feeder markets at either end.

The Open Skies policy also has stimulation effects on the demand side. By allowing more effective feed to the long-haul stage of transatlantic services through the concentration of traffic at international hub airports, it increases the geographical market being serviced and also generates economies of scope and scale. The larger physical market demand, combined usually with the improved quality of the “product” that accompanies more integrated services, such as code sharing, interchangeable frequent-flier programs, common lounges, and through baggage checking, pushes out the demand for international air services to D2 in Fig. 3.

The outcome of the lowering of costs and the outward shift in demand is that the number of passengers traveling increases to Q2 and, because Open Skies allow price flexibility, the fare falls to F2 in the way our example is drawn. It should be noted that fares might not actually fall; indeed they may rise as the result of the freer market conditions. The reason for this is that the outward shift in demand reflects a better “quality” of service – e.g., more convenient flights, transferability of frequent-flier miles, and seamless ticketing – and that, on average, potential travelers are willing to pay more for this than the generic portfolio of features that were found under the old bilateral ASA structure. (In Fig. 1, the shift out in demand may counteract the fall in costs resulting in F 1  < F2).21

What does become pertinent, however, is the extent to which the fare structure is influenced by the market power of the airlines. The analysis presented in Fig. 1 assumes that, in the Open Skies environment, fares are set to recover costs; in other words, competition and mergers policy can effectively fulfill the role of regulation. This raises issues as to the nature of a market served by a relatively small number of network carriers. A degree of competition exists between the various alliances for the trunk hauls market, and there is also competition at either end of routes with many other, including low cost, carriers competing for passengers in overlapping feeder and origin-destination traffic to international hub airports. There are also theoretical reasons derived from game theory suggesting that the outcome in a market with three players approaches that of competition. Nevertheless, each alliance by dint of product differentiation (e.g., they serve different airports) inevitably enjoys some degree of monopoly power. This could lead to fares higher than F2 and a smaller output than Q2 with consequential reductions in consumer surplus.22

The effects of a full Open Aviation Area – a genuine open market – can be seen as an extension of this framework. Free capital markets, together with the ability to have more flexible feeder networks owned by the truck carrier at both ends of transatlantic services, would further lower costs and may generate additional economies of market presence, although this latter effect is unlikely to be large. The ability to invest across national boundaries provides for short-term support in situations of local market fluctuations and more integrated long-term planning of infrastructure; it would in effect produce air networks akin to those enjoyed by US railroads that can move investment funds across states rather than have separate rail companies each limited intra-state operations. In terms of Fig. 3, it would mean lower fares and larger air traffic volumes with concomitant increases in society benefits.

9. The potential quantitative effects of transatlantic air transport liberalisation

The changes that have taken place in the regulation of transatlantic air transportation have not gone entirely unresearched. The studies have looked at a variety of different aspects of the transatlantic market, but especially the implications of the situation for their industrial structure and for wider, economic develop effects. The changes embodied in the transatlantic agreement are also likely to be somewhat less than they would have been if the two internal markets involved (the EU and the US) had not already been liberalized, there were not already in place alliance agreements that allow airlines and their customers some of the benefits of an Open Skies, and if many of the main transatlantic routes were not already subjects of individual liberal national bilateral agreements.

We provide a brief summary of some of the more germane work that has been done and the findings that they report. In general the emphasis is, because air transport is an intermediate activity, on the larger economic impacts of regulatory changes on the North Atlantic. After all the aim of policy is generally seen to be social welfare and not that of any particular industry. The narrower, purely airline, effects are treated in less detail.

9.1. Impacts of airline alliances

International airline alliances involving transatlantic services began to emerge in the late 1980s as carriers sought to create the economies of scope and density on the cost side and market presence on the revenue side. These were being enjoyed in domestic markets but because of capacity and fare-setting constraints of the traditional ASAs could not be enjoyed on non-European international routes. Competition and mergers policy also made takeovers and mergers a more cumbersome business, even if nationality rules could be circumvented. The long-haul nature of the transatlantic market, the density of traffic, and nature of the potential feeder market at either end of the trunk haul offered the potential to reap the diverse benefits of larger scale operations. The restrictive characteristics of the prevailing bilateral ASAs effectively forced the airlines to move to a second-best alliance approach to squeeze out synergies from their various operations.

The alliances took a variety of forms but essentially entailed code shares and coordinated frequent-flier programs that have, as ASA reforms have progress, resulted in rationalization of schedules. Fig. 4 offers a simple representation of the “dog-bone” networks that have emerged. Taking B as a major European hub, the European partner airline would use its domestic and intra-European network to feed traffic from a, b, c,…, i into intercontinental hub. Similarly, in the US the American partner would consolidate traffic from its domestic services, x, y, z,…, j into its hub A. The combined flows create density economies and the consolidation process from a variety of short haul services provides scope.

Fig. 4.

Fig. 4

The “dog-bone” international hub-and-spoke network.

The number of strategic global alliances has stabilized and virtually all the major air carriers belong to one of the three global strategic alliances (the Star Alliance, oneWorld, and SkyTeam) that now dominate much of international aviation (Table 4 ).23 The alliances differ in detail and in their operations, but the largest variation is in term of the US anti-trust immunity that they enjoy. In particular, oneWorld has no such immunity, mainly because the UK has no Open Skies agreement with the US, and that limits the ability of its members to fully exploit synergies in their business.

Table 4.

The main US and European airlines that are part of the major strategic alliances

Star Alliance oneWorld SkyTeam
United Airlines American Airlines Delta Airlines
Lufthansa British Airways Continental
bmi Aer Lingus Northwest
TAP Portugal Air France Alitalia
Finnair Iberia Air France/KLM
Lauda Air CAS Czech Airlines
LOT Polish Airlines
Spanair
SAS Scandinavian Airlines
Austrian Airways
Tyrolean Airlines

The impacts of the long-haul hubbing phenomenon have attached considerable attention since its inception, not least because of anti-trust considerations, the problems encountered by the hubs in handling massive banks of international traffic, and the concerns of airlines that are outside of the alliance structures. The illiberal elements of ASAs that have remained, or are only slowly been reformed, have weakened the effectiveness of strategic alliances on many routes, and thus impeded the full emergence of the gains from network operations.

Table 5 provides a brief survey of the main studies that have been conducted on the impact of strategic alliances on the North Atlantic routes. They focus mainly on the implications for the airlines involved, their competitors, and the traveling public. Because it takes time for the effects of alliances to be fully realized, the nature of the analysis varies; however, most use data from the 1990s when the composition of the alliances was somewhat different and the number of strategic alliances larger (e.g., KLM and Northwest were allied and outside of the SkyTeam).

Table 5.

Studies of the effects of strategic alliancea.

Study Alliances Period Findings
Gellman Research Associates (1994) BA/US Air, KLM/NW 1994 Profits increased for all parties with BA and KLM gaining more than their partners



Youssef and Hansen (1994) Swissair and SAS 1989–1991 Increases in flight frequency; variations in fare levels; the strongest service levels had the lowest fare increases



US General Accounting Office (1995) KLM/NW, US Air/BA, UAL/Lufthansa UAL/Ansett, UAL/BMA 1994 All carriers enjoyed increased revenues and traffic gained at competitors' expense, not industry growth



Dresner et al. (1995) Continental/SAS, Delta Swissair, KLM/NW 1987–1991 Mixed successes with traffic volumes; in general alliances did not benefit partners



Park (1997) KLM/NW, Delta/Swissair/Sabena 1990–1994 Traffic increases at the expense of rivals. Complementary alliances lowered fares while parallel alliances increased fares



Oum et al. (2000) Star Alliance, oneWorld SkyTeam, KLM/NW 1992–1994 Increased traffic on alliance routes



Brueckner and Whelen (2000) US international alliances 1999 Fare are some 18–20% lower on international alliance, interlining routes
a

These effects may be seen as the removal of the capacity constraint and the downward movement of costs illustrated in Fig. 3.

The various analyses do not paint an entirely consistent picture; one reason for this was that they often differ in the underlying question being asked. Many, for example, were more concerned with competitive effects between the alliances and other carriers rather than with the overall effect of strategic alliances. Additionally, the earlier alliances took somewhat more limited forms than those found today and there was far more experimentation going on. The lack of a fully liberalized EU market, prior to the mid-1990s, also added constraints to what could be achieved in the transatlantic market. Finally, there are qualitative differences in the work done; generally speaking, the more detailed studies suggest that the ability to form alliances added to the efficiency of the airline market.

9.2. The General Accounting Office report

The US General Accounting Office Report (GAO) (2004) study relied mainly on published evidence and interviews, rather than mathematical modeling and econometric analysis, to look at the implications for US airlines and passengers of removing the “nationality” clauses from ASAs with EU countries. The broad conclusions are that not only would there be benefits from greater access to Heathrow Airport in the UK but also to other European hubs that had traditionally and continue to be dominated by a local carrier. The removal would also benefit US passengers if it facilitated more consolidation of European airlines that in turn would allow access to more on-line services, albeit at the possible cost of reduced competition.

9.3. The Brattle report

In 2002, the Brattle Group reported to the European Commission on the expected impacts of an Open Aviation Area (that embraces the removal of all foreign ownership restrictions and cabotage restrictions as well as liberal air service agreements) on Europe and the US. The analysis covered a number of dimensions of the subject, although the matter of economic development was not at its core.

The benefits of the Open Aviation Area are divided between those associated with the ability of airlines to set fares as they please (“pricing synergies”) and those associated to adjust output (“No output-restricting ASA bilaterals”).24 The gains are measured in a variety of ways, including consumer and producer surplus gains, and airline cost savings, and under a variety of scenarios regarding cost effects, elasticities, and the efficiency of airports at handling additional traffic. The analysis seeks to embrace the full network effects involving feeder services and other services with the European and the US as well as the implications for direct transatlantic services.

The study focuses mainly on looking at the implications of the open area on the air transport industry and on the consumers' surplus generated through lower airfares. It does, however, also offer some indication of employment generating effects, notably for airports under a number of different scenarios and these are laid out in Table 6 .25 Given that airport jobs are but one of the employment effects of air transportation, the suggested impact is significant.

Table 6.

The Brattle Group's estimates of the direct employment effects for Europe of an Open Aviation Area (in thousands of employed).

Airline employment Airport employmenta Airport employmentb
Low bound scenarioc
 Pricing synergies 600 188 481
 No output-restricting ASA bilaterals 1587 436 1092



 Total 2178 624 1573



Low bound scenariod
 Pricing synergies 3523 1124 2820
 No output-restricting ASA bilaterals 1578 436 1092



 Total 5101 1560 3912

Source: Adapted from Brattle Group (2002).

a

High ideal airport capacity.

b

Low ideal airport capacity.

c

Assumes volume growth from an 18% reduction in prices following the creation of an Open Aviation Area, where price elasticity is unity.

d

Assumes volume growth from a 28% reduction in prices following the creation of an Open Aviation Area, where price elasticity is 2.5.

The study's findings on airline productivity indicate a gain that would reduce costs by about 4.2%, the vast majority of which would be linked to enhanced efficiency of intra-EU airline operations. Translated into consumers surplus for passengers this amounts to some €2.9 billion per annum, with a further €370 million from lower fares that additional competition would generate. In physical terms, the forecast is that a full, open transatlantic aviation market would lead to between 4.1 million and 11.0 million additional transatlantic passengers and, through network effects, between 17.7 million and 46.7 million passengers on intra-EU routes. These gains would not, though, be evenly spread. Amongst the current non-Open Skies countries, the UK, by far the largest market, would take the majority of the benefits with Greece, Ireland and Spain assuming lesser benefits.

The study, as it must, does rely on a variety of assumptions regarding fare elasticities, the reaction of airlines and airports to new market conditions under Open Skies, and on diversion effects through a network system in which many economies have already been exploited. For example, it is assumed that there will be a 10% increase in traffic volume across the Atlantic that flows directly from full liberalization that is independent of any natural growth rate. These are subjective assessments.

9.4. Chamber of commerce of Ireland report

Ireland is one of the EU countries that did not have an Open Skies agreement with the US. This study (Sørenson and Dukes, 2005) explicitly looks at the potential gains that the country could enjoy of a more liberal regime were introduced. The study makes extensive use of the findings of the Brattle Group to derive estimates specific to Ireland by focusing at the micro-level on the country's airports. Many of the findings are qualitative rather than quantitative and rely on a variety of published material. Overall, it is concluded, “Benefits will accrue to business interest in Ireland, including tourism, and to transatlantic passengers to and from Ireland.”

9.5. The Button and Taylor study

To gain a better handle on the implications of a country not having an Open Skies agreement with the US, and ipso facto what would happen by opening the market, Button and Taylor (2000) used simple regression analysis and looks specifically at variations in high-technology employment between European regions. High-technology employment follows the EU definition, which it is quite broad and is adopted to reflect the attraction of a region for the more mobile elements of modern production. The level of analysis is a mixture of European NUTS 226 and NUTS 3 regions because NUTS regions are administrative units rather than economic units, and countries differ in the ways that their administrative units are defined. To allow for this, where a nation has relative small districts or counties these are aggregated to make them more comparable with NUTS level 3 regions elsewhere.

The estimations indicated that the move to an Open Skies agreement would result is some 30,000 jobs for the surrounding region of each major airport.27 This standard error is somewhat high, however, as may be expected given the diverse nature of the national air markets in which these regions are located. From a forecasting perspective, the high-technology employment creation from expanding the existing national Open Skies arrangement to a full EU agreement may be below the 30,000 figure because there will be some diversionary effects from regions benefiting from existing Open Skies; there are also capacity constraints in some of the regions in countries that did not previously have a liberal ASA with the US that will dampen the effects of liberalization. Counter to this, however, there will also be the “low-technology jobs” created that come through subsequent multiplier effects.

9.6. The Booz Allen Hamilton report

With the move towards agreement, the European Commission commissioned the consultants Booz Allen Hamilton (2007) to essentially up-date the work of the Brattle Group and their work is based on the broadly the same rationale and same four countries with the addition of Hungary as the Brattle study.

The study estimates that some 72,000 jobs will be created across the EU and US over five years as a result of the Open Skies agreement, with a 1–2% boost to the cargo market and 26 million more passengers being carried. In economic terms this is translated into a gain of $160 to €340 million per annum with fare reductions of 2–6%. These figures may be seen as quite modest compared to the impacts of existing bilateral transatlantic Open Skies agreements. Earlier US work (US Department of Transportation, 2000) had shown that fares on US–EU Open Skies bilateral routes between 1996 and 1999 and after the two major alliances had been given anti-trust immunity, had fallen by 20.1% overall and by 23.9% in beyond European routes compared to 10.3% overall for non-Open Skies routes.

In terms of broader effects, the study used standard economic multiplier analysis to estimate potential employment creation in both the US and the EU, separating out the affects into the gains from removal of output restrictions and the gains from additional interlining. The results suggest that more than 70,000 additional long-term jobs will be created as a result of the increased traffic that will accompany the new transatlantic passenger arrangements, with over 1800 additional jobs stemming from pricing efficiencies gains from interlining. Up to another 20,000 jobs would result from the more flexible cargo market.

9.7. The impacts so far

It is clearly early days, and especially at a time of record fuel prices, a low US dollar, and a general slowing of many economies, extrapolating long-term from the developments to date on the North Atlantic is virtually impossible. A simple examination indicates that there have been new US services established at Heathrow (Table 7 ) and from June, transatlantic travelers could choose from 95 flights a day each way between Heathrow and the US, 18 more than a year earlier. Airlines have also spent on buying access to the market, e.g. Continental paid about $209 million to secure four daily landing slots at Heathrow. Not all airlines have begun new services or, as in the case of British Airways, transferred services from Gatwick. Virgin Atlantic, for example, has not done so and bmi, which holds the second largest number of slot at Heathrow (Table 8 ) has not entered the UK–US market. These are commercial decisions have a degree of confidentiality surrounding them, but one motivation that may be of concern is that the second phrase of negotiations that have to be completed by 2010 will fail, and the UK authorities will then revert back to the Bermuda II bilateral structure. The airlines do not want to sink costs with this uncertainty.

Table 7.

Number of round-trip flights US–London Heathrow (June).

Airline 2007 2008
Air France 0 1
American 10.9 12.8
British Airways 12.7 16.2
Continental 0 4
Delta 0 3
Northwest 0 3
United 0 1
US Airways 0 1

Source: Sabre Airline Solutions.

Table 8.

Market share of passengers by airline at European's largest airports (2002).

Airport Carriers 1 Carrier 2 Carrier 3
London Heathrow British Airways 41.6% bmi 12.1% Lufthansa 4.8%
Frankfurt Lufthansa 59.4% British Airways 3.6% Austrian 2.9%
Paris Charles de Gaulle Air France 56.6% British Airways 5.15 Lufthansa 4.9%
Amsterdam KLM 52.2% Transavia 5.5% easyJet 4.3%
Madrid Iberia 57.0% Spanair 12.7% Air Europa 7.1%
London Gatwick British Airways 55.1% eastJet 12.8% flybe British European 5.6%
Rome Alitalia 46.2% Air One 10.0% Meridiana 3.9%
Munich Lufthansa 56.8% Deutsche BA 6.6% Air Dolomiti 6.5%

10. Some broader issues

10.1. Airport capacity allocation

While there are some airports in the US with severe capacity problems, there is in general not a significant capacity problem overall. In contrast, most of the major European international airports do have capacity issues (Debbage, 2002).28 The ways in which slots29 reallocated also differs on either side of the Atlantic. In the US there are, with some few period exceptions, no explicit slot allocations – essentially the air traffic control takes planes as they arrive with adjustments being made for technical reasons such as the size of the hardware. In contrast, the systems in Europe involve scheduling committees at airports that allocate the slots periodically, initially to improve interlining arrangements, generally giving preference to the “grandfathering” of incumbent carriers.30 The EU has intervened in the past, and particularly since 2004, to force reallocation of little used slots. Nevertheless, as can be seen from Table 8 the main international airports in Europe are still dominated by the traditional “flag carriers”, and this includes those long under Open Skies agreements.

The transatlantic Open Skies agreement does little to resolve the congestion issues either at airports or regarding air traffic control, and the potential of additional North Atlantic traffic that feeds into US and European banks of flights for connection purposes is likely to add to difficulties.

10.2. The environment

Air transport is environmentally intrusive. While there have been significant decreases in the environmental footprint of individual passengers over time, the sheer growth of traffic continues to pose concerns at the global level because of CO2 emissions and at the local level because of noise nuisance.

Focusing on global concerns, the impacts of the North Atlantic Open Skies on the environment become particularly difficult to isolate at time when other measures are being introduced that will either implicitly or explicitly impact on airline fuel efficiency. The new generation of large aircraft, the Boeing 787 and the Airbus 380 will provide for more fuel efficiency and less noise per passenger or ton carried, and modifications of existing hardware also reduce their adverse environmental impact. Hopefully, the initiatives of the US's Federal Aviation Administration and the EU's EUROCONTROL, through its Single European Sky strategy, to up-grade their air navigation systems, together initiatives to allocate airport slots more effectively, will increase the efficiency with which airspace is used and hence reduce fuel wasted from congestion. More directly, there are initiatives to introduce what amount to carbon taxes to influence airlines to make more effective use of fuel and, through fare adjustments, to make air travelers cognizant of the external costs that they impose.

The opening up of the remaining transatlantic routes will generate additional traffic and, despite and off-setting effects of new technology, this will have some environmental implications. Focusing largely on the generated tourist traffic effects that will accompany new fare levels and service developments, and making assumptions about when peak US base trips and EU based trips take place, Mayor and Tol (2007) estimate that CO2 emissions would rise by a maximum of 0.7%. One reason for this relatively low figure is the adjustment made for trip diversion – many leisure travelers will be switching from other destinations to US–EU routes thus reducing emissions elsewhere.

10.3. Safety

There would seem to be no evidence that the increase in Open Skies style arrangements across the globe has in anyway impacted adversely on air transport safety. Indeed, there may be very good reason to expect safety to improve somewhat as a more flexible international airline market stimulates the expansion of the strategic alliances with the larger carriers putting pressure on their smaller partners to maintain safety standards (Button, 1997). The freer transatlantic market will also have a trade diversion effect taking some, albeit probably small, amount of traffic from other less safe routes.

Perhaps as important is the strength of the international institutional structure that oversees aviation safety. The UN's International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) develops and sets safety standards that are adhered to by all nations under the US–EU transatlantic Open Skies agreement. In addition, member countries have their own safety authorities that generally apply standards in excess of the minimum ICAO requirements and also allow other countries involved in their air transport market to inspect on a reciprocal basis to ensure compliance.

The fear is that market liberalization could weaken this structure because airlines would be driven to neglect safety in pursue of a viable return in a more competitive commercial environment. Evidence from other airline markets, for example domestic markets within the EU and within the US and international markets that have long established Open Skies agreements, provide no evidence of diminished safety (Robyn et al., 2005). The gradual increase in air transportations safety that has been a feature of the industry has continued unabated.

Security is an on-going issue, but again it is difficult to see why the challenges of ensure adequate standards will be compounded by the new agreement. There is no evidence that security is less tight for markets under bilateral Open Skies agreements, and there may be arguments that the new structure, by stimulating more alliance activities may make security easier. As with safety, national and international arrangements, including the role of the ICAO, dominate the effectiveness of security at airports and on airlines. Frictions that have emerged in the past between the EU and US, for example over documentation and release of passenger lists, are really unrelated to the nature of the air ASA in place.

10.4. Regulation and competition policy

The EU and US have somewhat different overall approaches to such things as anti-trust and mergers policy that extend well beyond the air transportation sector. In 1991 the European Commission and the US competition agencies, the Federal Trade Commission and the Department of Justice, entered into a cooperation agreement on competition policy enforcement. Progress on convergence has been slow and the new aviation arrangements are unlikely to affect this pattern.

Open Skies agreements between individual EU states and the US have often involved a concomitant agreement that the US would give anti-trust immunity to alliances between airlines of the participation countries – the lack of anti-trust immunity for American airlines and British Airways within the oneWorld alliance has largely been attributed to the continuation of the Bermuda II bilateral agreement. The new US–EU agreement has already seen the UK and US authorities agree to anti-trust immunity for bmi and its US Star Alliance partner, United Airlines. British Airways and American, that withdrew their request for immunity in 2002, have not announced any fresh initiative despite the new climate.

Foreign ownership restrictions have been only been marginally relaxed under the new agreement, and whether this will be sufficient to stimulate large scale movements of capital across the Atlantic is doubtful.31 Lufthansa, however, has taken a 19% holding in the US domestic low cost carrier JetBlue, and in the context of its history of investing in airlines to bolster feeder traffic. It owns European regional airlines Air Dolomiti and Lufthansa CityLine, as well as the Swiss International Air Lines and has a 49% stake in Eurowings, a 30% stake in bmi, and a 13% stake in Luxair. In a similar vein, Virgin Atlantic Airlines own 23% of recently launched Virgin America that will provide feed for its North Atlantic routes at JFK and other international gateways. In the US and Europe there has been a considerable shift by the legacy carriers to develop their transatlantic services and, as part of a wider strategy, to consolidate, although at the time of writing exactly what combinations of carriers will combine is still far from certain.32

11. Conclusions

The experiences of deregulation (or in Europe, “liberalization”) of air transportation and other markets over the past quarter of a century are generally seen as having produced significant economic benefits. Not everyone has gained, certainly some communities have lost airline services, some airlines have gone bankrupt, and some classes of passengers are now paying higher fares, but for those few that have been adversely affected there are many more who can fly more cheaply, have a greater variety of services to choose from, and have found jobs in the extended air transportation value chain. No positive change occurs without disruption, this has certainly been the experience of airlines, but these negative features have been far outweighed by the positive impacts.33 One would expect very much the same general outcome from the transatlantic Open Skies agreement. Since the move is to a more market-based system, the exact outcomes of the new institutional structure are, almost be definition impossible, to foresee; after all if one could predict them then these could have been enacted through command and control measures.

The emergence of more flexible international air transport regimes for extra-European movements has benefited those involved. Efforts to get a comprehensive Transatlantic agreement have proved challenging, however, in part because of somewhat differing views in Europe and the US on the meaning of free trade. What does seem to be clear, from a European perspective, is that there are benefits for the Union as a whole in adopting a uniform Open Skies agreement with the US, although there may be additional gains in extending this to a full and genuine Open Aviation Area of the type found within the US and the EU. The challenge now is to develop a mutually acceptable framework that allows both parties to move from a simple, product based, Open Skies to one that embodies the mobility of factors of production as well within a full open market.

Footnotes

1

US–EU is used throughout rather than EU–US simply because of where the author is currently based.

2

The Convention also established the United Nations' International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) to oversee international agreements. Importantly, the ICAO also has remits that cover a range of safety and security oversight matters that has largely allowed these to be treated separately to issues of economic regulation.

3

For ease of drafting, the title European Union (EU) is used throughout although legally it has changed over time.

4

For example see Button (2004) for an examination of the European experience, and Morrison and Winston (1995) for an account of the effects of deregulation in the US. Following the initial moves to creation of the Single European Aviation Market in 1993 the average annual growth rate in traffic between 1995 and 2004 was almost double the rate of growth from 1990 to 1994 (InterVISTAS-ga2, 2006).

5

In addition, liberalization of other elements in the air transportation supply chain (airports, air traffic control, etc.) has been slow leading to continuing distortions in both domestic and international markets that inevitably will limit any gains from the further liberalization of airline markets.

6

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (1997) provides an account of wider trends in international air transportation, and offers some alternatives for moving forward with market liberalization.

7

Operating margins are reported rather than net margins that can be influenced by vagaries in tax structures and lumpy investments. Estimates by IATA Fact Sheet, March 2007 are that the net margins for its members were −1.5%, −0.8% and −0.1%, respectively, for 2004, 2005, and 2006. Physical measures – revenue passenger kilometers and revenue ton kilometers are the standard industrial parameters – are not used because they do not directly affect the financial performance of airlines.

8

In the first three months of 2008, for example, American Airlines recorded a loss of $328 million, United, $542 million, and Delta, $274 million.

9

Technically, there is evidence that scheduled air services offered in a competitive market suffer from the problems of an “empty core” (Button, 2005).

10

Some of the challenges facing the authorities in Europe regarding further efforts to liberalize North Atlantic services are summarized in UK House of Lords Select Committee (2003).

11

Findlay (2003) puts the role of the WTO measures into a wider aviation market context.

12

Indeed, one of the reasons the US signed an early Open Skies policy with the Netherlands was to allow its charter carriers access to Amsterdam.

13

In particular the domestic reforms in the US had considerably improved the efficiency of the US airlines; see Good et al. (1993) for an empirical examination of the relative efficiency of US and European airlines between 1976 and 1986.

14

What constitutes US “citizenship” posed problems with the package carrier DHL in 2002.

15

For example the Chief Executive Office is legally required to be a US citizen. The fact that the Canadian, Donald Carty held the post at American Airlines for some years suggests the US Empire is somewhat larger than many think.

16

A similar strategy was used at the early phase of the initiative in Asia with little success, in part because of the nature of the Asian airline industry, but has proved to be more powerful in recent years as market in Asia have in general become more liberalized.

17

These countries were also the first to seek more liberal bilaterals within the EU (Button, 2004).

18

Common ground for example has been reached reading, wet leasing, competition rules, the EU nationality clause, and market access (with the exception of cabotage).

19

The treatments of elements in the figure are static in the sense that technology is held constant. Modern economic theory holds that at least part of technical change is endogenous and thus a function of market and institutional structures.

20

In practice, fares tended to reflect the bargaining power of the parties and the objectives of the countries' overall approaches to the airlines market. Continental European airlines have had a long tradition of supporting their flag carriers for a variety of reasons that are linked to their perceptions of their national interest. In some cases, the fares may have been below the level required for cost recovery whilst in others it may have been higher if, for example, one partner sought to cross-subsidize domestic services.

21

If there are economies of scope or density from offering air services in this market, as is often the case, the cost curve would be downward sloping and in this case the outward shift in demand reinforces the cost curve more and fares will always fall.

22

If there are declining costs, however, this monopoly power may be needed to allow for the recovery of the fixed costs of providing a scheduled service.

23

There are also very many alliances that cover individual routes and services that are not included here. These often provide additional feed into the larger carriers' networks. Airline Business publishes a full list of the main alliances annually.

24

These are essentially a primary multiplier effects.

25

The Nomenclature des Unites Territoriales Statistiques (NUTS) is the five-tier hierarchical structure used in the European Union to standardize territorial units.

26

As with most work of this kind a constant technology is assumed. Both the theory underpinning the New Regional Economics and the empirical evidence that has been produced in its support indicate that there are endogenous growth effects from agglomeration. A free transportation market generally facilitates more efficient dynamic urban structures.

27

There is a major problem, however, in the New York–London market one of the busiest markets in the world. Most of the major airports in each metropolitan area are officially slot-constrained, and they include London's Heathrow and Gatwick, and New York's JF Kennedy and La Guardia. Furthermore, five of the top 10 US-based gateways to the world feature Heathrow as the foreign gateway and they include JFK, Los Angeles, Chicago, San Francisco, and Washington DC.

28

Normally defined as permission to schedule a flight at a particular airport at a particular time.

29

Grandfather rights mean that an airline that held and used a slot last year is entitled to do so again in the same season the following year.

30

There are also lurking memories of the problems that arose in the past when British Airways invested in the then US Air and KLM in Northwest when the European carriers felt they had insufficient control over their assets.

31

Delta and Northwest are teetering on merging, and Continental is in discussions with both United and American Airlines. The consolidation trend within Europe also continues with Air France/KLM moving to merge with Alitalia and continuing speculation about an Iberia–British Airways merger.

32

Basically, deregulation has brought about a Hick-Kaldor improvement.

33

A more comprehensive survey of airline alliances is in Morrish and Hamilton (2002).

References

  1. Association of European Airlines . AEA; Brussels: 1999. Towards a Transatlantic Common Aviation Area: AEA Policy Statement. [Google Scholar]
  2. Boeing Commercial Airplanes . Boeing; Seattle: 2005. Current Market Outlook. [Google Scholar]
  3. Booz Allen Hamilton . European Commission; Brussels: 2007. The Economic Impacts of an Open Aviation Area between the EU and the US. TREN/05/MD/S07.52650. [Google Scholar]
  4. Brattle Group . Brattle Group; Washington, DC: 2002. The Economic Impact of an EU–US Open Aviation Area. [Google Scholar]
  5. Brueckner J.J., Whelen W.T. The price effect of international airline alliances. Journal of Law and Economics. 2000;43:503–545. [Google Scholar]
  6. Button K.J. Interactions of global competition, airline strategic alliances and air traffic safety. In: Soekkha H.M., editor. Aviation Safety: Human Factors – System Engineering – Flight Operations – Economics Strategies – Management. VSP; Utrecht: 1997. [Google Scholar]
  7. Button K.J. Ashgate; Aldershot: 2004. Wings Across Europe: Towards an Efficient European Air transport System. [Google Scholar]
  8. Button K.J. The economics of cost recovery in transport. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy. 2005;39:241–257. [Google Scholar]
  9. Button K.J., Taylor S.Y. International air transportation and economic development. Journal of Air Transport Management. 2000;6:209–222. [Google Scholar]
  10. Debbage K.G. Airport runway slots: limits to growth. Annals of Tourism Research. 2002;29:933–951. [Google Scholar]
  11. Dresner M., Flipcop S., Windle R. Trans-Atlantic airline alliances: a preliminary evaluation. Journal of the Transportation Research Forum. 1995;35:13–25. [Google Scholar]
  12. Findlay C. Plurilateral agreements on trade in air transport services: the US model. Journal of Air Transport Management. 2003;9:211–220. [Google Scholar]
  13. Gellman Research Associates . Office of Aviation and International Economics, Office of the Secretary of the US Department of Transportation; Washington DC: 1994. A Study of International Airline Code Sharing. [Google Scholar]
  14. Good D.H., Röller L.-H., Sickles R.C. US airline deregulation: implications for European transport. Economic Journal. 1993;103:1028–1041. [Google Scholar]
  15. InterVISTAS-ga2 . InterVISTAS-ga2; Washington DC: 2006. The Economic Impact of Air Service Liberalization. [Google Scholar]
  16. Mayor K., Tol R.S.J. Hamburg University; 2007. The Impact of the EU–US Open Skies Agreement on International Travel and Carbon Dioxide Emissions. working paper. [Google Scholar]
  17. Morrish S.C., Hamilton R.T. Airline alliances – who benefits. Journal of Air Transport Management. 2002;8:401–408. [Google Scholar]
  18. Morrison S.A., Winston C. Brookings Institution; Washington, DC: 1995. The Evolution of the Airline Industry. [Google Scholar]
  19. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development . OECD; Paris: 1997. The Future of International Air Transport Policy: Responding to Global Change. [Google Scholar]
  20. Oum T.H., Park J.H., Zhang A. Elsevier; Amsterdam: 2000. Globalization and Strategic alliances: the Case of the Airline Industry. [Google Scholar]
  21. Park J.H. The effects of airline alliances on markets and economic welfare. Transportation Research E. 1997;33:181–194. [Google Scholar]
  22. Robyn D., Moselle B., Reitzes J.D. Beyond Open Skies: the economic impact of a US–EU Open Aviation Area. In: Hamilton D.S., Quinlan J.P., editors. Deep Integration: How Transatlantic Markets are Leading Globalization. The Brookings Institution; Washington DC: 2005. [Google Scholar]
  23. Sørenson F., Dukes . Chambers of Commerce of Ireland; Dublin: 2005. EU/US Air Transport Agreement – Potential Impacts on Ireland. [Google Scholar]
  24. UK House of Lords Select Committee on the European Union . The Stationary Office; London: 2003. Inquiry into the Future of European Aviation Relations with the United States of America (US) and Other States Unified Negotiations of Transatlantic Air Service Agreements, HL 92. [Google Scholar]
  25. US Department of Transportation . USDOT; Washington DC: 2000. Second Report on International Aviation Developments. [Google Scholar]
  26. US General Accounting Office . USGAO; Washington DC: 1995. International Aviation: Airline Alliances Produce Benefits, But Effect on Competition is Uncertain. GAO/RCED-95–99. [Google Scholar]
  27. Youssef W., Hansen M. Consequences of strategic alliances between international airlines: the case of Swissair and SAS. Transportation Research A. 1994;28:415–431. [Google Scholar]

Articles from Journal of Air Transport Management are provided here courtesy of Elsevier

RESOURCES