Skip to main content
Other Publishers logoLink to Other Publishers
. 2018 Mar 19;97(3):032308. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.97.032308

Interplay between cost and benefits triggers nontrivial vaccination uptake

Benjamin Steinegger 1, Alessio Cardillo 2,3,2,3, Paolo De Los Rios 1, Jesús Gómez-Gardeñes 3,4,3,4, Alex Arenas 5
PMCID: PMC7217527  PMID: 29776104

Abstract

The containment of epidemic spreading is a major challenge in science. Vaccination, whenever available, is the best way to prevent the spreading, because it eventually immunizes individuals. However, vaccines are not perfect, and total immunization is not guaranteed. Imperfect immunization has driven the emergence of antivaccine movements that totally alter the predictions about the epidemic incidence. Here, we propose a mathematically solvable mean-field vaccination model to mimic the spontaneous adoption of vaccines against influenzalike diseases and the expected epidemic incidence. The results are in agreement with extensive Monte Carlo simulations of the epidemics and vaccination coevolutionary processes. Interestingly, the results reveal a nonmonotonic behavior on the vaccination coverage that increases with the imperfection of the vaccine and after decreases. This apparent counterintuitive behavior is analyzed and understood from stability principles of the proposed mathematical model.

I. INTRODUCTION

The quantitative study of disease propagation has captured the attention of statistical physicists for a long time [1–3]. Specifically, this approach has shed light on many conundrums by considering the networked structure of contacts, their time-varying and multilayer character, as well as the recurrent nature of mobility patterns [4–8]. Vaccination, whenever possible, is the most effective way to harness and prevent the spreading of a disease [9]. Under normal circumstances, the decision of getting vaccinated can be considered as an act of cooperation, since it bestows benefits on the whole population at the expenses of single individuals. Notwithstanding, we are recently witnessing the emergence of widespread antivaccine movements, which are mainly fueled by misconceptions and mischievous news about vaccines [10–16]. Scientists (including physicists) are devoting tremendous efforts in designing efficient immunization strategies [17] as well as shedding light on the mechanisms behind the deliberate decision of not getting vaccinated and their harmful consequences [18,19].

Vaccination can be modeled as a strategy of a game. Under such premises, the evolution of vaccines' voluntary adoption can be investigated using the machinery of game theory [20,21] and statistical physics [22,23]. The first studies carried out on vaccination games use classical game theory, with single round games in which agents have perfect knowledge of their odds to get infected [24,25]. In reality, however, individuals are not perfectly aware of the risk to get infected, and vaccination coverage may evolve in time as a byproduct of personal experiences or imitation. Therefore, evolutionary game theory is the natural workbench to tackle the problem. The seminal works in this direction assumed the simultaneous evolution of vaccination and spreading dynamics [26–28]. A different approach was used in the case of seasonal influenza, by considering that the spreading process reaches its stationary state before vaccination games take place [29–32].

Here, we introduce a mean-field framework to mimic the spontaneous adoption of vaccines against influenza-like diseases. Our model captures the essence of previous approaches to gauge, analytically, the risk of epidemic outbreaks. In particular, we use a minimal evolutionary vaccination game to infer the strategies adopted before an epidemic season. This, in turns, allows us to estimate the risk of future outbreaks by encapsulating agents' strategies into an epidemic model. We get analytical results and insightful conclusions from the analysis of this framework in well-mixed populations. More specifically, we unveil how the interplay between the probability of infection, vaccine effectiveness, and cost, gives rise to nonlinear responses in vaccine uptake. Our analysis reveals a nonmonotonic behavior on the vaccination coverage which, surprisingly, increases as the vaccine quality deteriorates. Such counterintuitive behavior is analyzed and understood from stability principles of the proposed mathematical model.

II. THE MODEL

Let us consider a well-mixed population of N agents or individuals. We assume that this population has initially undergone a susceptible-infected-recovered (SIR) disease spreading [2,3]. To stay simple and keep the problem still analytically solvable, we set the disease incidence in such previous season equal to α. Such quantity is an input parameter of the model and acts as a proxy for the perception of infection risk, e.g., advised through the mass-media. After the first outbreak, the vaccination dynamics takes place. As a result, agents converge to the decision of vaccinating (V) or not (NV). The resulting strategy is the outcome of the evolutionary dynamics (see below) given the previous incidence, α, infection probability, β, recovery cost, T, the cost of the vaccine, c, and its failure rate, γ, or equivalently, its effectiveness (1γ). The corresponding vaccine coverage—given by the fraction of vaccinated agents yeq—is used as the input of a new SIR spreading process, having the same β and T. The results of the SIR dynamics allow us to estimate the total infection incidence, R, as a function of the relevant parameters, especially α. The mathematical definition of α is the probability of infection, in the previous outbreak, of an agent without protection against the disease.

Vaccination dynamics consists of a repeatedly played two strategy game, in which agents either take the vaccine (s=V) or not (s=NV). Agents will decide according to: (i) the cost associated to uptaking the vaccine (c) and (ii) the recovery cost (T) weighted by the perceived risk of getting infected by a contact in a future outbreak. The latter risk depends on the previous incidence α, the infection rate β, and the vaccine effectivenesss (1γ). It is worth stressing that the vaccination cost should not be seen purely as a financial one. It also includes, for example, vaccine hesitancy [11,12]. The payoffs associated to each of the four possible encounters between pairs of agents are:

PVV=cγ2βαTPVNV=cγβαTPNVV=γβαTPNVNV=βαT, (1)

where Ps1s2 is the payoff accumulated by an agent with strategy s1 when it meets another having strategy s2 (s1,s2{V,NV}). As explained above, the prefactors of the recovery cost (T) in Eq. (1) are modulated by the perceived risk of infection given the previous outbreak, encapsulated in α, and the probability that an individual playing with strategy s1 is infected by another with strategy s2.

The fitness of an agent i, πi, is defined as the sum of payoffs accumulated across its pairwise interactions. Every agent i with strategy si chooses randomly another one j, with strategy sj, compares their fitness (πi,πj) and if πj>πi adopts j's strategy with probability:

Γsjsi=πjπimaxsa,sb,sc,sd{V,NV}(PsasbPscsd). (2)

The strategies of the agents are updated synchronously after each round of the game. Using the above update function, and assuming that agents are well-mixed, the mean outcome of the individual decisions follows the so-called replicator equation [20]:

y˙=y(πVπ), (3)

where y is the fraction of vaccinated agents, πV the average payoff of a vaccinated agent, and π the average payoff of the population. According to the payoffs in Eq. (1), the replicator equation reads

y˙=y(1y){cβαT(1γ)[1(1γ)y]}. (4)

The above equation admits two trivial equilibrium points (yeq=0 and yeq=1), and a third, nontrivial, one:

y*=11γ1cβTα(1γ). (5)

The criteria for the existence of the nontrivial equilibrium point have an intuitive interpretation. In fact, the condition y*>0 is equivalent to PNVNV<PVNV, which translates into a vaccination threshold β~=c/αT(1γ). In other words, it is impossible to observe vaccination in a system where c>T, i.e., where vaccinating costs more than recovery. The criterion y*<1 translates into PVV<PNVV, corresponding to β<β~/γ. If this condition is not fulfilled, a vaccinated agent has a higher payoff than a nonvaccinated one regardless of the opponents strategies, hence leading to full vaccination. In the next section, we analyze the stability of the equilibrium points.

A. Stability analysis of the model

The evolution of y is ruled by Eq. (4). To analyze the stability of its fixed points, we need to evaluate the derivatives of the selection gradient, F(y), corresponding to the right-hand side of Eq. (4):

dF(y)dy=(12y){cβαT(1γ)[1(1γ)y]}y(1y)βαT(1γ)2. (6)

Evaluating the derivative at the internal fixed point, y*, we get

dF(y)dy|y=y*=y*(1y*)βαT(1γ)2. (7)

If the internal fixed point lies in (0<y*<1), then it is stable, since dF(y)dy|y=y*<0. Otherwise, if (y*<0) or (y*>1), then the fixed point y* is unstable. Evaluating the derivative at the monomorphic states (yeq=0 and yeq=1), we get

dF(y)dy|y=0=βαT(1γ)c=PVNVPNVNVdF(y)dy|y=1=cβαT(1γ)γ=PNVVPVV. (8)

Consequently, the derivative evaluated at the monomorphic states corresponds to the existence criteria y*>0 and y*<1, respectively. Therefore, the monomorphic states are unstable in the presence of the internal fixed point, y*, and reach stability depending on whether y*<0 or y*>1. These findings are summarized in Fig. 1, which presents the selection gradient as a function of the vaccination coverage, y, in the presence of the internal fixed point, y*. One can see that y* is stable and as the internal fixed point is shifted to y*=0 or y*=1, the corresponding monomorphic state reaches stability.

FIG. 1.

FIG. 1.

Selection gradient, y˙ = F(y), as a function of the vaccination coverage, y. The parameters are set to c=0.1, α=0.3, β=0.55, γ=0.1, and T=1.0.

Therefore, the vaccination coverage, yeq, being defined by the stable equilibrium point, is given by the internal fixed point yeq=y* for β~ββ~/γ, whereas for β<β~ and β~/γ<β it is given by yeq=0 and yeq=1, respectively.

B. Interpretation of results

According to Eq. (5), high values of c are detrimental for vaccination, while high values of T and β boosts it. Additionally, the vaccination coverage depends exclusively on the ratio between vaccination and recovery costs, which we denote as f=c/T. Therefore, considering Eq. (5), one can see that full vaccination cannot be stable for a perfect vaccine unless f=0.

More subtle is the dependence on the vaccination quality γ. In fact, lowering vaccine quality increases vaccine coverage (dy*/dγ>0) if the fraction of effectively vaccinated agents yeff>0.5, where yeff=(1γ)y. Noteworthy, albeit the quality of the vaccine worsens, agents will choose more often to vaccinate.

At first glance, the increase in vaccine uptake as its effectiveness decrease may seem counterintuitive. The rationale behind this is as follows: as γ increases there is a competition between the increasing risk of getting infected and the reduced protection bestowed by the vaccine itself, as shown in Fig. 2.

FIG. 2.

FIG. 2.

Vaccination coverage at equilibrium, y*, as a function of effectiveness, 1γ for two different values of the infection probability β. The dashed line indicates the fraction of effectively vaccinated agents. The other parameters are α=0.4, c=0.1, and T=1.0. The maximum coverage ymax* is denoted by a point, and the dotted line delimits the tolerance range. The inset displays the value of the maximum coverage ymax* given in Eq. (10) as a function of infectivity β. The color highlights the region where vaccination takes place or not.

To shed light on such competition, one may look at the decrease of the vaccine's effectiveness 1γ as a dynamical process. As effectiveness decreases, the risk for a not vaccinated agent of getting infected by a previously vaccinated one becomes yeff×βαγ. Conversely, the risk of a vaccinated agent to get infected by a nonvaccinated becomes (1yeff)×βαγ. Comparing these two risks, the vaccinated agent has an advantage over the nonvaccinated if yeff>(1yeff), which translates into yeff>0.5. Hence, the counterintuitive act of vaccinating when the efficiency of the vaccine is low turns out to be a rational decision to mitigate the infection pressure. Moreover, the existence—for each infectivity β—of a maximum fraction of vaccinated agents, ymax*, delimitates a region of “tolerable effectiveness” beyond which agents decide to non vaccinate. Also, the position of ymax* versus β splits the phase space into two distinct regions (Fig. 2 inset). Interestingly, this effect has been observed previously in other coevolutionary models [31–33], but never explained hitherto. At variance with y, the fraction of effectively vaccinated agents, yeff, is always lowered by a decrease of the vaccine quality, i.e., d[(1γ)y*]dγ<0. Therefore, the higher vaccination coverage is not counterbalancing the lower vaccine quality. Let us analyze this dependency more in detail.

C. Dependence of the vaccination uptake on vaccine quality

There are three different regimes regarding the dependency of the vaccination coverage, yeq, on γ. The first one is the absence of vaccination independently of γ, corresponding to β<cαT=fα. In the second regime y*(γ=0)<0.5 the vaccination coverage is monotonously decreasing with γ. Therefore, maximal vaccination coverage is reached for a perfect vaccine γ=0. The condition y*(γ=0)<0.5 is equivalent to β2fα. In the third regime β>2fα, the dependence of y* on γ is non monotonous, wherefore the vaccination coverage is maximal for a non perfect vaccine. The vaccine quality maximizing the vaccination coverage is then found from dy*/dγ=0, giving

γc=12fβα. (9)

The vaccine quality maximizing the vaccination coverage can also be seen as a tolerance threshold. If 1γ becomes worse than 1γc, agents start refusing taking the vaccine and the vaccination coverage drops rapidly, as illustrated in Fig. 2. From there, the maximal vaccination coverage in the three regimes is then given by

ymax*=0ifβfαymax*=1fβαiffα<β2fαymax*=βα4fif2fαβ. (10)

The maximal vaccination coverage, ymax*, as a function of β is presented, instead, in the inset of Fig. 3.

FIG. 3.

FIG. 3.

Vaccination coverage, yeq (a), and fraction of recovered individuals, R (b), as a function of disease incidence in the previous season, α, and infection probability, β. The red solid line corresponds to the vaccination threshold, β~, separating the region where no vaccine uptake occurs from the one where nonzero vaccination could be observed. In panel (b), the white solid lines correspond to the epidemic thresholds in the absence of (β=0.2), and in presence (α=0.5) of vaccination according to Eq. (13). The other variables are fixed to c=0.1, T=1.0, γ=0.1 and μ=0.2. (c) R as a function of β for different costs of the vaccine, c. The inset presents the vaccination coverage, yeq. Additionally, the critical values of β are presented following Eq. (15) such as the purely epidemic threshold, βc, the vaccination threshold, β~, and the threshold for full vaccination, β~/γ. The remaining variables are fixed to T=1.0, γ=0.4, α=0.4, and μ=0.1.

III. IMPACT OF VACCINATION ON THE EPIDEMIC SPREADING

After discussing the outcome of the vaccination dynamics, we now turn our focus towards its impact on the subsequent epidemic outbreak. Assuming that the vaccination dynamics always ends up in the unique stable equilibrium point, yeq; we can use such information to compute the extent of a future epidemic outbreak by using a SIR compartmental model [3]. The dynamics of the SIR model is then given by

S˙=βISI˙=βISμIR˙=μI, (11)

where S, I, and R denote the fraction of susceptible, infected, and recovered agents, respectively. The aforementioned quantities fulfill the conservation law S+I+R+(1γ)yeq=1. Note that μ=1/T indicates the recovery probability in agreement with the vaccination game. The fraction of recovered agents after the epidemics dies out, R, is given by the following trascendental equation:

R=1(1γ)yeq[1(1γ)yeqI0]eβμR, (12)

where I0 is the initial fraction of infected agents. Equation (12) has no analytical solution, hence it must be solved numerically. Nevertheless, in an infinite size system (N), the term I0 can be neglected since I01. Thus, a nonnegligible fraction of recovered agents, R, exists if

β>μ1(1γ)yeq=βc, (13)

where βc denotes the epidemic threshold. As expected, if the system displays no vaccination, yeq=0, and the above criteria reduces to the purely epidemic SIR threshold βc=μ. Instead, for the full vaccination case, yeq=1, the criteria becomes βc=μ/γ. Finally, for the internal fixed point, yeq=y*, the existence of R>0 in Eq. (12) implies

fμα(1γ)>1. (14)

Surprisingly, this condition is independent of β. Therefore, the increased vaccination coverage balances the increased transmission probability in the subsequent epidemic outbreak.

In Fig. 3, we display the vaccination coverage, yeq (panel a), and the fraction of recovered agents, R (panel b), as a function of the previous season incidence α, and the probability of infection β in the case of a perfect vaccine (γ=0). As expected, a remarkably high fraction of recovered agents is observed for a highly infective epidemic (large β) paired with a small fraction of infected agents in the previous outbreak (small α). In Fig. 3(b), one can observe that, given a value of α, the fraction of recovered individuals is maximal at the vaccination threshold β~. A way of finding the maxima and minima of the fraction of recovered agents, R, is considering its derivative with respect to the tranmission probability, β, dRdβ. Note that in an infinite system, the transcendental equation Eq. (12) takes three different forms depending on the vaccination coverage:

R=1eβμRifμ<ββ~R=β~β1eβμRifβ~<ββ~γR=γ1eβμRifβ~γ<β1. (15)

To find an explicit expression for dRdβ, we derive both sides of Eq. (15) and subsequently rearrange terms, which leads to

dRdβ=RμeβμRβμ,ifμ<ββ~dRdβ=R+μβ1eβμRμββ~eβμRβ~μ,ifβ~<ββ~γdRdβ=RγμeβμRγβμ,ifβ~γ<β1. (16)

To infer information about the sign of dRdβ we need to bound R. By using again Eq. (15) and the inequality 1ex>x1+x, we find a lower bound for R as

R>1μβ,ifμ<ββ~R>β~βμβ,ifβ~<ββ~γR>γμβ,ifβ~γ<β1. (17)

These lower bounds can then be combined with the inequality eλμR1+λμR. The strict inequality holds for all R>0. This enables us to develop the expressions for the derivative in Eq. (16), leading to

dRdβ>0,ifμ<ββ~dRdβ<0,ifβ~<ββ~γdRdβ>0,ifβ~γ<β1. (18)

The cases β<β~ and β~γ<β are as expected. In these regimes the vaccination coverage does not vary with β (yeq=0 and yeq=1, respectively), wherefore R increases monotonously with β. In the intermediate regime β~<β<β~/γ, though, where yeq=y*, R monotonously decreases with β (dRdβ<0). Consequently, vaccination emerges in a way such that it outweighs the increased transmission probability and hinders the epidemic spreading, as illustrated in Fig. 3(c). From these considerations, we can conclude that the fraction of recovered agents is locally maximal at β=β~, and locally minimal at β=β~/γ. The numerical exploration of the parameter space has confirmed hitherto that the former is also a global maximum. Moreover, the highest fraction of recovered, Rmax, for a fully vaccinated population (yeq=1) would correspond to meaningless values of the parameters. Depending on the parameters, the system will not be in all of the three regimes presented in Eq. (18) as the transmission probability, β, is varied. If the parameters are such that β~/γ>1, the system will never fall in the third regime. Consequently, R monotonously decreases once vaccination emerges. Similarly, one might have β~>1 for which the system shows no vaccination and R monotonously increases with β. The different cases are illustrated in Fig. 3(c).

Numerical simulations

To validate that the previous equations are actually describing the behavior of the considered system, we have compared the analytical results discussed above with those obtained via Monte Carlo simulations. The simulations have been made for a system of N=1000 agents updating their strategy accordingly to Eq. (2), and averaged over Nreal=50 realizations. The difference between theory and the simulation for the vaccine coverage, y, and fraction of infected agents, R, is plotted in Figs. 4(a) and 4(b). The maximal differences for y and R are around 0.2% and 2.5%, respectively. The average relative errors, instead, are 0.2% for y and 2.0% for R.

FIG. 4.

FIG. 4.

Differences between the quantities computed using Monte Carlo simulations and their analytical counterparts as a function of parameters α and β. Panel (a) presents the case of yeq, while panel (b) the case of R, instead. The other parameters are set to N=1000, γ=0.1, μ=0.2, and T=1.0, respectively.

The agreement between analytical and numerical simulations, σ, is thus 2%.

We want to remark also that preliminary analysis made in the case of discrete interactions encoded as networks showed similar results, although we lack an analytical solution. Notwithstanding, the well-mixed population proves to be a good approximation for the vaccination dynamics on networks. This is very likely due to the vaccination cost term in the total payoff, which does not scale with the degree of nodes. Additionally, the nontrivial increase in vaccine uptake—as effectiveness decreases—is also observed in simulations on networked populations [31].

IV. CONCLUSIONS

Summing up, we have presented a mean-field model to predict vaccine uptake for influenzalike diseases using the disease incidence during previous outbreak season as a proxy for the “perception of infection risk.” The model predicts the existence of a tolerance range of vaccine effectiveness, where a nontrivial increase in vaccination coverage takes place as the vaccine inefficiency increases. Albeit appearing irrational and counterintuitive at first sight, such behavior is—instead—due to the interplay between the vaccination game and the disease spreading processes. The model predicts also that highly infective—but under control—epidemics might prove dangerous for future infections, since they alter the “risk perception” of the agents and induce them to nonvaccination. Finally, as mentioned in the introduction, the timescale between the two dynamics (decision and spreading) has always been considered fixed. The sole exception, up to our knowledge, are childhood diseases with long term immunity [27,34]. The framework presented here could be used to fill the gap among different model formulations and unify them.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

P.D.L.R. acknowledges the financial support of Swiss National Science Foundation under Grant No. CRSII2_147609. A.C. acknowledges the financial support of MINECO through Grant No. RYC-2012-01043. J.G.G. acknowledges financial support from MINECO (Projects No. FIS2015-71582-C2 and No. 377 FIS2014-55867-P) and from the Departamento de Industria e Innovación del Gobierno de Aragón y Fondo Social Europeo (FENOL group E-19). A.A. acknowledges financial support from Spanish MINECO (Grant No. FIS2015-71582-C2-1), Generalitat de Catalunya ICREA Academia, and the James S. McDonnell Foundation under Grant No. 220020325.

REFERENCES

  • [1].R. Pastor-Satorras, C. Castellano, P. Van Mieghem, and A. Vespignani, Epidemic processes in complex networks, Rev. Mod. Phys. 87, 925 (2015). 10.1103/RevModPhys.87.925 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [2].R. M. Anderson and R. M. May, Population biology of infectious diseases: Part I, Nature 280, 361 (1979). 10.1038/280361a0 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [3].R. M. Anderson and R. M. May, Infectious Diseases of Humans (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1992). [Google Scholar]
  • [4].R. Pastor-Satorras and A. Vespignani, Epidemic Spreading in Scale-Free Networks, Phys. Rev. Lett. 86, 3200 (2001). 10.1103/PhysRevLett.86.3200 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [5].A. Vazquez, B. Rácz, A. Lukács, and A.-L. Barabási, Impact of Non-Poissonian Activity Patterns on Spreading Processes, Phys. Rev. Lett. 98, 158702 (2007). 10.1103/PhysRevLett.98.158702 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [6].M. De Domenico, C. Granell, M. A. Porter, and A. Arenas, The physics of spreading processes in multilayer networks, Nat. Phys. 12, 901 (2016). 10.1038/nphys3865 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [7].P. Holme, Three faces of node importance in network epidemiology: Exact results for small graphs, Phys. Rev. E 96, 062305 (2017). 10.1103/PhysRevE.96.062305 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [8].J. Gómez-Gardeñes, D. Soriano-Paños, and A. Arenas, Critical regimes driven by recurrent mobility patterns of reaction-diffusion processes in networks, Nat. Phys. (2018), doi: 10.1038/s41567-017-0022-7. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [9].M. Wadman and J. You, The vaccine wars, Science 356, 364 (2017). 10.1126/science.356.6336.364 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [10].On the wrong side of history, Nature Microbiol. 2, 17046 (2017). 10.1038/nmicrobiol.2017.46 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [11].P. Schmid, D. Rauber, C. Betsch, G. Lidolt, and M.-L. Denker, Barriers of influenza vaccination intention and behavior—A systematic review of influenza vaccine hesitancy, 2005–2016, PLoS ONE 12, e0170550 (2017). 10.1371/journal.pone.0170550 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [12].H. J. Larson, C. Jarrett, E. Eckersberger, D. M. D. Smith, and P. Paterson, Understanding vaccine hesitancy around vaccines and vaccination from a global perspective: A systematic review of published literature, 2007–2012, Vaccine 32, 2150 (2014). 10.1016/j.vaccine.2014.01.081 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [13].A. Wakefield, et al. , RETRACTED: Ileal-lymphoid-nodular hyperplasia, non-specific colitis, and pervasive developmental disorder in children, Lancet 351, 637 (1998). 10.1016/S0140-6736(97)11096-0 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [14].D. A. Salmon, L. H. Moulton, S. B. Omer, M. P. deHart, S. Stokley, and N. A. Halsey, Factors associated with refusal of childhood vaccines among parents of school-aged children: A case-control study, Arch. Pediatr. Adolesc. Med. 159, 470 (2005). 10.1001/archpedi.159.5.470 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [15].E. K. Brunson, The impact of social networks on parents' vaccination decisions, Pediatrics 131, e1397 (2013). 10.1542/peds.2012-2452 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [16].G. L. Freed, S. J. Clark, A. T. Butchart, D. C. Singer, and M. M. Davis, Sources and perceived credibility of vaccine-safety information for parents, Pediatrics 127, S107 (2011). 10.1542/peds.2010-1722P [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [17].Z. Wang, et al. , Statistical physics of vaccination, Phys. Rep. 664, 1 (2016). 10.1016/j.physrep.2016.10.006 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [18].C. Betsch, Advocating for vaccination in a climate of science denial, Nature Microbiol. 2, 17106 (2017). 10.1038/nmicrobiol.2017.106 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [19].C. Betsch, R. Böhm, L. Korn, and C. Holtmann, On the benefits of explaining herd immunity in vaccine advocacy, Nature Hum. Behav. 1, 56 (2017). 10.1038/s41562-017-0056 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [20].M. A. Nowak, Evolutionary Dynamics—Exploring the Equations of Life (Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, 2006). [Google Scholar]
  • [21].H. Gintis, Game Theory Evolving, 2nd ed. (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2009). [Google Scholar]
  • [22].C. Hauert and G. Szabó, Game theory and physics, Am. J. Phys. 73, 405 (2005) 10.1119/1.1848514 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [23].M. Perc and A. Szolnoki, Coevolutionary games—A mini review, Biosystems 99, 109 (2010) 10.1016/j.biosystems.2009.10.003 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [24].C. T. Bauch, A. P. Galvani, and D. J. D. Earn, Group interest versus self-interest in smallpox vaccination policy, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 100, 10564 (2003). 10.1073/pnas.1731324100 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [25].C. T. Bauch and D. J. D. Earn, Vaccination and the theory of games, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 101, 13391 (2004). 10.1073/pnas.0403823101 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [26].S. Bhattacharyya and C. T. Bauch, A game dynamic model for delayer strategies in vaccinating behavior for pediatric infectious diseases, J. Theor. Biol. 267, 276 (2010). 10.1016/j.jtbi.2010.09.005 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [27].C. T. Bauch and S. Bhattacharyya, Evolutionary game theory and social learning can determine how vaccine scares unfold, PLoS Comput. Biol. 8, e1002452 (2012). 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1002452 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [28].A. d'Onofrio, P. Manfredi, and P. Poletti, The interplay of public intervention and private choices in determining the outcome of vaccination programmes, PLoS ONE 7, e45653 (2012). 10.1371/journal.pone.0045653 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [29].F. Fu, R. I. Rosenbloom, L. Wang, and M. A. Nowak, Imitation dynamics of vaccination behavior on social networks, Proc. R. Soc. B: Biol. Sci. 278, 42 (2011). 10.1098/rspb.2010.1107 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [30].H. Zhang, F. Fu, W. Zhang, and B. Wang, Rational behavior is a “double-edged sword” when considering voluntary vaccination, Physica A: Stat. Mech. Appl. 391, 4807 (2012). 10.1016/j.physa.2012.05.009 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • [31].A. Cardillo, C. Reyes-Suárez, F. Naranjo, and J. Gómez-Gardeñes, Evolutionary vaccination dilemma in complex networks, Phys. Rev. E 88, 032803 (2013). 10.1103/PhysRevE.88.032803 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [32].B. Wu, F. Fu, and L. Wang, Imperfect vaccine aggravates the long-standing dilemma of voluntary vaccination, PLoS ONE 6, e20577 (2011). 10.1371/journal.pone.0020577 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [33].L. G. Alvarez-Zuzek, C. E. La Rocca, J. R. Iglesias, and L. A. Braunstein, Epidemic spreading in multiplex networks influenced by opinion exchanges on vaccination, PLoS ONE 12, e0186492 (2017). 10.1371/journal.pone.0186492 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • [34].C. T. Bauch, Imitation dynamics predict vaccinating behavior, Proc. R. Soc. B 272, 1669 (2005). 10.1098/rspb.2005.3153 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES