Skip to main content
Elsevier Sponsored Documents logoLink to Elsevier Sponsored Documents
. 2020 Aug;44:101142. doi: 10.1016/j.ecoser.2020.101142

Accounting for changes in flood control delivered by ecosystems at the EU level

Sara Vallecillo 1,, Georgia Kakoulaki 1, Alessandra La Notte 1, Luc Feyen 1, Francesco Dottori 1, Joachim Maes 1
PMCID: PMC7386899  PMID: 32747873

Highlights

  • We present a novel method to account for flood control as ecosystem service.

  • Flood control includes different components: potential, demand and actual flow.

  • We provide an experimental account in line with up-to-date integrated accounting systems.

  • The estimated value of flood control at the EU level is about 16 billion euro.

  • Artificial areas not protected by ecosystems increased between 2006 and 2012.

Keywords: Actual flow, Service providing areas, Service demanding areas, Accounting tables, Monetary valuation, Avoided damage cost

Abstract

Ecosystem service accounts require quantifying the contribution of ecosystems to the society. However, estimation of the ecosystem service used (actual flow) remains still very challenging for regulating services. We developed an experimental ecosystem service account for flood control delivered by ecosystems including: 1) Biophysical modelling of ecosystem service potential, demand and actual flow. 2) Translation of the actual flow in monetary terms. 3) Compilation of accounting tables. Ultimately, we analysed changes in flood control between 2006 and 2012.

The value of flood control delivered by ecosystems in 2012 is estimated at about 16 billion euro. This value increased by 1.14% between 2006 and 2012. This increase is mainly due to the sprawl of artificial areas into floodplains that benefit from flood control delivered by ecosystems. However, the role of natural capital to control floods is slightly decreasing. This is confirmed by the increase of artificial areas not protected by ecosystems (+1.9%, unmet demand). The role of natural capital to control floods could be enhanced by restoring ecosystems upstream from this unmet demand and increase the ecosystems contribution to human well-being. The methodology makes a significant contribution to the assessment of ecosystem services flow and the accounting framework.

1. Introduction

Ecosystems provide benefits to people in a direct or indirect way contributing to human well-being; which is known as ecosystem services (ES). The amount of services that ecosystems can provide to people depends on complex interactions between ecosystem and socioeconomic systems. When assessing ES, it is possible to quantify three different components that are essential to understand and properly assess the amount of service used, and therefore, the benefit generated (Villamagna et al., 2013). These key components are: 1) ES potential, which is the amount of ES that can be delivered in a sustainable way; 2) ES demand which is the need for a specific ES by society; and 3) ES use or actual flow which is the amount of service that is mobilized (used) in a specific place and time (Burkhard and Maes, 2017, Villamagna et al., 2013). ES potential is usually mapped based on the ecosystem’s properties and conditions relevant to the service considered (Syrbe et al., 2017). Mapping ES demand depends on whether it is understood as risk reduction, preferences and values, direct use or consumption of goods and services (see Wolff et al. (2015) for further details). Comparisons between ES potential and demand are common in the literature (Nedkov and Burkhard, 2012, Schulp et al., 2014b, Stürck et al., 2014) providing useful results for policy support and land planning. However, these comparisons do not provide information on actual ES flow. Methods for a consistent quantification of actual ES flow are still under debate, especially for regulating ES (de Groot et al., 2010, Serna-Chavez et al., 2014, Sutherland et al., 2018, Villamagna et al., 2013). Ultimately, the amount of ES used depends on the spatial relationship between the ES potential and ES demand, which are usually more complex than a simple overlap (Costanza, 2008, Fisher et al., 2009, Syrbe and Walz, 2012).

Several examples exist on the assessment of actual ES flow as a function of the ES potential, ES demand and their spatial relationship. Baró et al. (2016) quantifies the ES use of nature-based recreation and air purification by integrating ES potential (or capacity) and ES demand. Similarly, water purification by ecosystems is estimated as a function of the demand, where, similarly to air purification, the concentration of certain pollutants in the environment is used as a proxy to estimate the amount of ES that is actually needed (La Notte et al., 2015). The use of crop pollination can also increase when more pollination-dependent crops are present (Lautenbach et al., 2012). However, the same spatial framework is not applied on other services such as soil erosion and flood control, in which the actual ES flow is quantified without integrating the demand and/or beneficiaries (Barbedo et al., 2014, Grizzetti et al., 2017, Guerra et al., 2016). This ultimately contradicts the notion of ecosystem services (Maes et al., 2013). More concretely, flood control by ecosystems can be assessed using hydrological models quantifying the reduction of the flood peak discharges (Grizzetti et al., 2017, Smithers et al., 2016). Nonetheless, the ecosystem’s function and processes regulating water flows become ES only when there is demand for it (Fisher et al., 2009). Actually, placing more beneficiaries across the landscape may have the effect of increasing service flows (Bagstad et al., 2014). Other studies on flood control (Nedkov and Burkhard, 2012, Stürck et al., 2014) integrate the assessment of the demand for the service; however, estimates on the actual flow are not provided. More sophisticated studies, based on the Artificial Intelligence for Ecosystem Services (ARIES) platform (Villa et al., 2014), integrate the service demand and its spatial relationship with ES potential to quantify the service flow (Bagstad et al., 2014, Zank et al., 2016). However, they are generally applied at municipal and provincial level and the development of customised models in ARIES (and further new algorithms through its k.Lab technology) requires a high level of technical skill (Sharps et al., 2017).

The assessment of actual ES flows is required for natural capital accounts (UN et al., 2014a, UN et al., 2014b). Setting up ecosystem accounts is among the targets of the EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020 and it is accompanied with a growing interest on the integration of natural capital accounting into policy decisions (Schaefer et al., 2015). Therefore, further research is needed to define common and coherent terminology and methods quantifying the actual flow of the ecosystem service, considered in accounting as a ‘transaction’ from ecosystems to socioeconomic systems.

In recent years, losses from floods have increased considerably, due to an increase of the economic activity in flood zones in combination with heavier rainfall in parts of Europe (European Environment Agency, 2016). Flood-related impacts are expected to worsen due to the ongoing socioeconomic and climate changes (Arnell and Gosling, 2016, Feyen et al., 2012). Therefore, understanding and properly assessing the actual use of ecosystems in controlling floods is becoming of particular importance. Flood control, as an ecosystem service, is defined as the regulation of water flows by ecosystems that mitigates or prevents potential damage to economic assets (i.e., infrastructure, agriculture) and human lives (modified from CICES V.5.1, Haines-Young and Potschin (2018)). All ecosystems but in particular forests, heath and shrublands, grasslands and wetlands reduce runoff by retaining water in the soil and aquifers and by slowing down the water flow. This prevents the rapid runoff of surface water, hereby lowering peak runoff, and thus reducing the detrimental effects from flooding on citizens, farmland, and infrastructure.

The main objective of this study is to develop a practical methodology for assessing ecosystem service flows at pan-European level and integrate them into an accounting system, using flood control by ecosystems as a case study. The methodology follows the approach described in the United Nations System of Environmental-Economic Accounting- Experimental Ecosystem Accounts (SEEA EEA) (UN, 2017, UN et al., 2014b). Moreover, practical applications as the one presented here are needed to further develop a standard for ecosystem service accounting. The experimental accounting approach developed here is based on spatially explicit models to assess different components of flood control by ecosystems (i.e., ES potential to reduce runoff, the demand by socioeconomic systems for protection against river floods and the actual flow (or use) of the ecosystem service). Subsequently, we economically valued the actual flow of flood control to fill in the accounting tables in monetary terms.

Since tracking changes over time is one of the main goals of Natural Capital Accounts (NCA), we also assessed changes in flood control by ecosystems for the years for which enough data for the assessment at the EU level were available.

The European Commission has encouraged interventions in flood mitigation that seek “to work with nature rather than against it”, recognizing that mitigating flooding effects through land use adaptation measures are “better environmental options” (Directorate-General for the Environment, 2011). Sustainable ecosystem management for disaster risk reduction such as flood mitigation is now recognised as a priority measure in the Sendai Framework for Disaster Risk Reduction (European Union, 2018). However, the role of ecosystems providing protection against floods to society is often overlooked or undermined and the methodology proposed to account for flood protection as ecosystem service may significantly contribute to give support to these policies.

2. Methods

For the mapping and assessment of the actual flow of flood control by ecosystems, we have adopted the ES framework that integrates the spatial dimension between the ES potential and the ES demand. The spatial relationship between these two components is perfectly accounted for with the spatially explicit mapping of the so-called Service Providing Areas (SPA) (Fisher et al., 2009, Sutherland et al., 2018, Syrbe and Walz, 2012) and Service Demanding Areas (SDA) (Orta Ortiz and Geneletti, 2018, Schirpke et al., 2019). By using the concept of SDA, we refer only to those areas in need for a given ES, but this does not necessarily imply that they benefit from ecosystems providing that service. Only when in SDA there is an effective ES flow, they can be considered as Service Benefiting Areas (SBA) in the sense of Syrbe and Grunewald (2017).

The spatial relationship between SPA and SDA can be of different nature, depending on the ecological and socioeconomic process underlying the service (Costanza, 2008, Fisher et al., 2009, Syrbe and Walz, 2012). Flood control by ecosystems is directional-slope dependent, determined by the hydrogeological system following the slope of the terrain. It implies that the actual ES flow is only generated when the SDA lays downslope from the SPA and takes into account the whole river basin (Fig. 1).

Fig. 1.

Fig. 1

Scheme of the components assessed for flood control delivered by ecosystems.

Different spatial datasets were used to map the different components of flood control by ecosystems at the European Union (EU) level (Appendix A). The accounting layers of the CORINE land cover (CLC) map (EEA, 2017) were used as reference data defining the temporal and spatial resolution for the assessment of the difference components of flood control. The lack of imperviousness data for 2000 restricted the analysis into the years 2006 and 2012. For consistency, all input data were resampled to a common spatial resolution of 100 m. Maps of the different ES components were aggregated at sub-catchment level for visualization purposes. Sub-catchments are taken as spatial reference unit and are based on the Arc Hydro model, with an average sub-catchment size of 180 km2 (Bouraoui et al., 2009). Results are provided for the sub-catchments for which all datasets presented data. This excludes Malta, Cyprus and some areas of Croatia, Bulgaria and Finland. From here onwards, we refer to the study area as EU26. In this study, we focus only on river floods, which are the most frequent and most costly natural hazard (UNISDR, 2011).

The proposed methodology can be applied to any region or country whenever land cover and topographic data are available.

2.1. Ecosystem service potential

The mapping of the ES potential is the first step of the workflow for ecosystem services accounts. ES potential is also known as ‘supply’ or ‘capacity’ in the ecological literature (Maes et al., 2013, Villamagna et al., 2013); however, the use of these alternative terms would generate confusion within the accounting framework (UN et al., 2014b). An indicator of potential runoff retention was used to delineate the SPA for each sub-catchment, as suggested by Sutherland et al. (2018). The assessment of ES potential is based on five main steps described in the following section: 1) Curve number scoring for land cover classes; 2) Curve number adjustment by imperviousness; 3) Adjustment of the CN score by slope; 4) Integration of natural and semi-natural land cover in riparian zones, and 5) Mapping of SPA.

2.1.1. Curve number scoring for land cover classes

The ecosystem contribution to reduce runoff by retaining water largely depends on the type of vegetation or land cover type, the soil hydraulic properties and the slope of the terrain. The Curve Number (CN) method, developed by the United States Department of Agriculture (2004), estimates runoff as a function of the land cover (or land use) and the soil type, for which a lookup table assigns different values. Soils show different hydrological soil properties depending on the textural classes present. The textural classes were reclassified into four categories following Zeng et al. (2017): A) Soils with low runoff potential (sand, loamy sand and sandy loam); B) Soils with moderate infiltration rates (silt, silt-loam and loam); C) Soils with slow infiltration rates (sandy clay-loam); and D) Soils with high runoff potential (clay, silty clay, silty clay-loam, sandy clay, clay-loam). Data of soil textural classes were provided by the European Soil Data Centre (ESDAC) (Ballabio et al., 2016, Joint Research Centre European Soil Data Centre (ESDAC), 2017).

The CN scores range from 0 to 100, with higher scores indicating higher runoff. Given the lack of empirical CN scores covering the EU, the role of each ecosystem type to control floods was initially quantified based on the correlation coefficients between the share of different land cover classes and the mean of ES provision obtained by different modelling techniques at the EU level (Schulp et al., 2014a). Correlation coefficients where rescaled between 0 and 100 (as the CN), and then this value was subtracted from 100 to derive reference CN with higher values in ecosystems generating higher runoff (Table 1). The reference CN scores shown in Table 1 were refined for the different CORINE land cover and soil categories (Appendix B explains the refinement of the CN scores).

Table 1.

Reference values for the assessment of ecosystem potential to control floods.

Land cover type Correlation coefficient [−1, 1]* Correlation rescaled [0–100] Reference Curve Number
Urban −0.533 23 77
Pasture 0.055 53 47
Nature 0.283 64 36
Forest 0.609 80 20
Arable −0.321 34 66

2.1.2. Curve number adjustment by imperviousness

Soil sealing or imperviousness is an ecosystem condition indicator (Maes et al., 2018) that reduces the natural capacity of soils to infiltrate water, driving therefore the ecosystem potential to control floods (United States Department of Agriculture, 1986). Soil sealing is not captured by the CLC map, considering all residential areas the same independently of their level of imperviousness, which may vary depending on the presence of vegetation (i.e., green roofs, parking areas with permeable surfaces). Thus we used imperviousness level (European Union, 2018) to refine the CN scores. Artificial areas are usually assigned a CN score of 98 (United States Department of Agriculture, 1986) that was corrected by imperviousness, according to Eq. (1):

CNTotal=98Imp100+1-Imp100CNCLC (1)

where Imp is the level of imperviousness (as percentage of impervious area within in each pixel at 100 m2) and CNCLC is the CN derived from the Table A.1 in Appendix B. When applying this model to other regions or countries, this step can be skipped if imperviousness data are not available.

2.1.3. Adjustment of the curve number by slope

Since the CN method was initially developed for flat areas (slopes smaller than 5%), the effect of slope is not taken into account in the original CN method. Steeper slopes generate a faster movement of water within the landscape, reducing infiltration and therefore also the ecosystem contribution to control floods. As a consequence, a correction of the CN with respect to the slope was necessary by using Eq. (2) (Huang et al., 2006):

CNFinal=CNTotal322.79+15.63(α)α+323.52 (2)

where α is the slope ratio and CNTotal is derived from Eq. (1). In this way, the CNFinal combines as key variables land cover type, hydrological soil properties, imperviousness of the land surface and slope.

2.1.4. Integration of natural and semi-natural land covers in riparian zones

Given the importance of natural and semi-natural land covers in riparian zones in controlling floods (Bennett and Simon, 2013), we assigned them the maximum CNFinal score. Copernicus data provide a detailed map of riparian zones (European Union, 2018). As natural and semi-natural land covers, we considered agro-forestry areas [CLC 244], forest and semi-natural areas [CLC 311–313], scrub and/or herbaceous vegetation associations [CLC 321–324], wetlands [CLC 411–423].

The CNFinal (higher scores corresponding to higher runoff) was transformed in a dimensionless indicator of potential runoff retention by subtracting to the maximum CNFinal score of the reference year 2012 the CN score in a given location (i.e., complementary values of theCNFinal). This way, high values indicate high potential of ecosystem to retain runoff.

2.1.5. Mapping of service providing areas

The indicator of potential runoff retention provides spatially explicit data to identify key areas for flood control and to delineate SPA (i.e., when indicator is above a certain threshold). Using SPA instead of the indicator of potential runoff retention itself may be considered as an oversimplification, since a map with continuous data is converted into a Boolean map indicating presence or absence of SPA. Still, it is the basis for a spatial approach of ES at the landscape scale (Sutherland et al., 2018, Syrbe and Walz, 2012). Spatial assessments pairing SPA with the corresponding benefiting areas can provide insights into the role of spatial flows in the delivery of a particular ecosystem service (Serna-Chavez et al., 2014) as also demonstrated in previous examples of ecosystem service account (Vallecillo et al., 2019). Importantly, this conversion allows us also moving from a dimensionless indicator (potential runoff retention) to physical units to express ES as hectares of SPA per sub-catchment, which is preferred in an accounting context.

For the delineation of SPA, thresholds were set for three different coarse land cover groups. Setting the same threshold for the whole study areas would discard some relevant zones within cropland and urban areas playing a significant role in controlling floods for these types of ecosystems, which present distinct characteristics from semi-natural ecosystems. The three groups of land covers are: 1) artificial land covers; 2) agricultural land; and 3) the rest of land cover classes defined as natural or semi-natural land covers. The threshold for this last group was based on the average values for the different CLC classes of the mean ES potential for 2012 (used as reference year) minus the standard deviation (Appendix C). This criterion was not restrictive enough for agricultural and artificial land covers, given that the virtue of these land covers to control floods is intrinsically lower. In this case, we took the average values of the mean plus the standard deviation. For comparative purposes, the same thresholds calculated for the year 2012 were applied for 2006 to properly track changes over time.

Distinguishing different thresholds for each land cover group presents advantages from an ecosystem management point of view. For instance, SPA for semi-natural ecosystems excluded only 5% of their extent. The main land covers excluded as SPA are bare rocks and sparsely vegetated areas, which means that their role to control floods is low compared to other semi-natural ecosystems. Ecosystem restoration or nature-based solutions could be implemented to increase runoff retention in these land covers not considered as SPA. For agricultural areas, only 33% are considered SPA, including mainly agro-forestry areas, pastures, and areas with natural vegetation. Measures targeting the increase of natural vegetation in arable land for instance could increase the extent of SPA in agricultural areas. In the case of urban areas, 15% are SPA, which corresponds to artificial surfaces with low imperviousness level. Decrease of impervious areas (e.g., green roofs, parking areas with permeable surfaces) would increase runoff retention, acting therefore as SPA.

2.2. Ecosystem service demand

The service demanding areas (SDA) for flood control in this study are defined as the economic assets located in floodplains. For the mapping of the economic assets, we took artificial surfaces (Label 1 in CLC with grid code [111–142] and TeleAtlas roads) and agricultural areas (Label 1 CLC with grid code [211–244]) (Appendix D). As floodplains, we considered those defined by the flood hazard maps at the EU level for the maximum return period available, which is 500 years (Dottori et al., 2016). This map is available in JRC data catalogue (2018).

2.3. Ecosystem service use: the actual flow

The actual flow of flood control by ecosystems was only quantified for the areas in demand for flood control (SDA). For each 1 ha grid cell of SDA, we computed the share of the area upstream covered by SPA in the total upstream area RatioSPAup was then multiplied by the size of the grid cell to calculate the actual flow per grid cell of SDA (Eq. (3)):

Actualflow(ha)=RatioSPAupSDAGridcellsizeha (3)

where ‘RatioSPAup’ is the ratio of the upstream area covered by SPA and 'Gridcellsize' refers to size of the pixel of demand.

The map of the actual ES flow of flood control is thus expressed as the number of hectares of demand (SDA) protected by upstream ecosystems (SPA) in a given year. The approach used in this report quantifies the role of the ecosystems to control floods in relative terms, compared to the best situation for flood control by ecosystems (i.e., when the entire upstream area of the demand is covered by SPA). This actual ES flow is thus dependent on changes in ecosystems situated upstream as well as on changes in the demand set by the economy (Fig. 1). Lastly, the actual flow per grid cell of SDA was summed up at sub-catchment level.

2.4. Unmet demand

The mapping of the actual ES flow as the number of hectares of demand protected by the ecosystem makes it feasible to map the unmet demand in the same terms. The unmet demand quantifies the part of the demand (economic assets) that is not covered by natural control by ecosystems. The unmet demand is quantified according to Eq. (4):

Unmetdemandha=Demand(ha)-Actualflow(ha) (4)

An additional level of complexity which should be accounted for is that flooding areas usually contain artificial defence measures (e.g., levees, dykes) that are already in place guaranteeing certain level of protection. This should be considered when assessing the unmet demand. At the EU scale, data on the flood protection level are provided in terms of the return period of the flood event that can be borne by the defence measures already in place (European Commission – JRC, 2017). In the case of the Netherlands, the level of protection is high enough to safeguard all economic assets from flooding for the maximum return period considered (500 years). Therefore, we assumed that in this country, the demand for flood control is satisfied by the current level of protection and thus, the unmet demand was not calculated. The unmet demand was finally calculated as the percentage of the total demand for flood control at sub-catchment level (excluding the Netherlands).

It is important to highlight here that defence measures in place indirectly integrate the supporting role of ecosystems in controlling floods (Jongman et al., 2014). The protection level is designed to give protection up to a given flood return period taking into account a specific landscape setting (i.e., land covers). Changes in land cover upstream would alter water levels downstream and consequently the level of protection. It means that the presence of defence measures does not imply the lack of ecosystem’s role controlling floods, but rather ecosystems support the performance of defence measures. Actually, without the protective function of upstream ecosystems, more investment in artificial defence measures would be needed to maintain or guarantee the same level of protection. For this reason, the actual flow of flood control by ecosystems was quantified for the whole extent of the demand, including also the Netherlands, where protection level is the highest in the EU.

2.5. Monetary valuation

The actual ES flow of flood control quantified in biophysical terms is translated into monetary terms using avoided damage cost as valuation technique. This technique is consistent with the SEEA EEA Technical Recommendations (UN, 2017). This technique is based on exchange values and estimates the value of the damage that would occur if the ecosystem service were not present.

Estimation of the damage cost is adapted from the methodology presented in Feyen et al., 2012, Rojas et al., 2013. Damages are derived from depth-damage functions that express the damage cost in EUR/m2 as a function of the flood water depth (in meters) for different classes of land uses (i.e., buildings, commerce, industry, roads and agriculture). Damage functions for each class are adapted to the CLC classes identified as economic assets with demand for flood control following Huizinga (2007).

Damage functions vary among countries based on the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita. No discounting or inflation rate is applied to the estimated values as they are calculated on the damage cost available.

In order to derive expected annual damage costs one should integrate damages for floods with different return periods to integrate the probabilistic terms of the different return periods. At EU level, data on water levels for different return periods are available in flood inundation maps (Appendix A) (Alfieri et al., 2015, Alfieri et al., 2014). The damage cost is calculated for the service demanding areas (SDA) applying the damage functions for the water depths of the available return periods at the EU level (i.e., 10, 20, 50, 100, 200, and 500 years).

The damage cost for each return period is then multiplied by the actual ES flow (Eq. (5)) as a proxy of the avoided cost (AC), required to estimate the monetary value of flood control by ecosystems. This proxy assumes that a higher damage is avoided if there are more upstream ecosystems contributing to control floods (actual ES flow).

AvoidedcostEUR=DamageEUR/m2×ActualESflowm2 (5)

The avoided cost estimated for each return period at grid cell level is then used to calculate the actual ES flow in monetary terms (Eq. (6), Fig. 2). This function is based on the equation used to estimate the Expected Annual Avoided Damage (Feyen et al., 2012).

ActualESflowEUR/year=10500fi-fi-1ACi+ACi-12 (6)

where fi is the frequency of the return period (f = 1/return period i) and ACi is the avoided cost (as calculated with Eq. (5)) estimated for the return period i.

Fig. 2.

Fig. 2

Illustrative example of actual flow in monetary terms and curve truncation.

However, in the monetary valuation, the role of artificial defence measures already in place is of especial relevance, since they reduce the damage generated by floods. Therefore, we also calculated the value of the actual flow considering the role of the defence measures by excluding in the estimates the potential damage of events with a return period lower than the protection level. The resulting value of the actual flow reflects the value of the ecosystem service where the only contribution to controlling floods is derived from natural capital (ActualflowNC). In this sense, Eq. (6) was truncated at the return period of the protection level (Fig. 2). For instance, if an area has a level of protection for a return period of 50 years, damage caused by return periods below this number will not be considered, decreasing accordingly the potential damage from floods (Eq. (7) is derived from the truncation of Eq. (6) for a return period of 50 years as an example):

ActualflowNCEUR/Year=50500fi-fi-1ACi+ACi-12 (7)

With this approach, we can also calculate the difference between the total value of the actual flow (Eq. (6)) and ActualflowNC (Eq. (7)) that would give the value of the actual flow of flood control when floods are controlled by both natural capital and defence measures (ActualflowNC+) (Fig. 2). As mentioned before, the presence of defence measures does not imply the lack of ecosystem’s role controlling floods, but rather ecosystems support the performance of defence measures.

2.6. Accounting tables

The core of ES accounts is focussed on the amount of ES used (the actual flow), which refers to the transaction between ecosystems and socio-economic systems (Fig. 1). The actual flow is reported in the both the supply and use tables, in biophysical and monetary terms (UN, 2017). While the supply table shows the contribution of different ecosystem types to generate the actual flow, the use table reports the contribution of the actual flow to the economic sectors and households using a given ES. Since both tables refer to the same ES flow, total values reported in the supply table are necessarily equal to total values of the use table, which is known as the ‘accounting identity’ (UN, 2017).

In the supply table, the actual flow is allocated to the different ecosystem types. For this allocation, we quantified first the extent of different ecosystem types shaping the SPA upstream from the demand in each country, since SPA are considered to generate the ES flow. Since the role of each ecosystem type controlling floods per unit area is highly variable (i.e., forest retain more runoff than cropland), the extent of each ecosystem type was weighted by a correction factor calculated with Eq. (8):

Correctionfactori=(100-averageCNji)/100 (8)

where i is the ecosystem type, and CNji is the CN of the land cover j belonging to the ecosystem type i (CN scores are shown in Appendix B). The ecosystems classification is based on Maes et al. (2013) (Appendix E shows their correspondence with CLC classes). The correction factors obtained are 0.27 for urban, 0.42 for cropland, 0.78 for woodland and forest, 0.56 for grassland, 0.64 for heathland, 0.33 sparsely vegetated land and 0.8 for wetland. The weighted extent (i.e., ecosystem extent in SPA multiplied by the correction factor) was then used to allocate the total actual flow in relative proportion to the values obtained.

In the case of the use table, the model output already provides the required information since land cover type and actual flow in monetary terms for each grid cell of demand are known. Correspondence between CLC classes with economic sectors and households defined by the Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community (NACE classification) is based on the description of each CLC class provided in Kosztra et al. (2017) (Appendix D).

3. Results

3.1. Biophysical maps of flood control

The maps with the different components of flood control by ecosystems are presented in Fig. 3, showing flood control potential (A); flood control demand (B); actual flow (C); and unmet demand for flood control (D).

Fig. 3.

Fig. 3

Flood control by ecosystems in 2012: A. Ecosystem service potential; B. Ecosystem service demand; C. Actual flow; and D. Unmet demand.

In the EU26, the total service providing area (SPA) in 2012 represented 60% of the study area, showing higher flood control potential in forested areas in Europe and lower values in the main agricultural plains, e.g., in the east of the UK, southern Spain, the Po plain in Italy and in Romania. The total service demanding area (SDA) for flood control correspond to about 4% of the EU26 territory. ES demand is situated in river valleys, agricultural plains and in urban areas. The demand for flood control is composed by agricultural areas (88% of the total demand, with about 123,178 km2), while the remaining 12% is artificial land, with about 18,859 km2 in 2012 (Table 2). This extension of artificial areas in floodplains represents 10% of the total artificial area in the EU.

Table 2.

Summary table at the EU level for the ecosystem service components for flood control.

Flood control at the EU level (EU26)
2006 2012 Changes Changes (%)
ES Potential (km2) 2,400,630 2,400,417 −213 −0.01%
Gains (km2) 5,118
Losses (km2) 5,331
ES Demand (km2) 142,270 142,037 −233 −0.16%
By artificial areas (km2) 18,560 18,859 299 1.61%
By agricultural areas (km2) 123,709 123,178 −532 −0.43%
ES Actual flow (km2) 41,880 41,696 −184 −0.44%
In artificial areas (km2) 4,967 4,982 15 0.30%
In agricultural areas (km2) 36,913 36,714 −199 −0.54%
Unmet demand (km2) 95,169 95,111 −58 −0.06%
Unmet demand artificial areas (km2) 12,544 12,782 238 1.90%
Unmet demand agricultural areas (km2) 82,625 82,329 −296 −0.36%
Monetary value actual flow (million euro) 16,127 16,312 185 1.14%
In artificial areas (million euro) 15,323 15,512 189 1.23%
Value per unit of artificial demand (thousand EUR/km2) 826 823 −3 −0.37%
In agricultural areas (million euro) 804 799 −5 −0.58%
Value per unit of artificial demand (thousand EUR/km2) 6.5 6.5 0 −0.15%

The map of the actual flow shows darker colours when there is higher proportion of SPA upstream from the SDA, but also higher extent of demand benefiting from ecosystems controlling floods (Fig. 3C). The actual ES flow (or use) in 2012 is about 41,696 km2 (Table 2). This flow represents 29% of the service demand areas that are benefiting from ecosystems controlling floods. The unmet demand represent 67% of the total service demand area (the Netherlands is not included. See Section 2.4) and is mainly found in arable plains and large urban areas where the ES potential is generally low (Fig. 3D).

3.2. Compiled accounting tables

Table 3, Table 4 show an extract from the accounting tables in biophysical and monetary terms in the EU26. Accounting tables at country level are presented in Appendix F. In 2012, the value of flood control by ecosystems amounted to 16,312 million euro (Table 3). About 21% of this value is due to flood control derived from natural capital only (ActualflowNC). The remaining 79% represents the value of the service provided by ecosystems in support of artificial defence measures already in place (ActualflowNC+).

Table 3.

Supply of the actual flow of flood control by ecosystem type at EU level (biophysical and monetary terms).

Ecosystem types
Urban Cropland Grassland Heathland and shrub Woodland and forest Sparsely vegetated land Wetlands Total
Year 2006 Biophysical (km2) 262 3,159 7,727 724 29,329 2.5 677 41,880
Monetary
(Million EUR)
89 1,012 3,099 350 11,244 0.9 332 16,127
NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+
70 19 230 781 545 2,554 97 253 2,480 8,764 0.2 0.7 89 243 3,512 12,615
Relative value* (EUR/km2) 416 628 6,089 1,925 7,049 15 3,383 3,779



Year 2012 Biophysical (km2) 262 3,136 7,670 720 29,229 2.4 675 41,696
Monetary
(Million EUR)
89 1,015 3,129 357 11,388 0.9 333 16,312
NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+
71 19 233 782 548 2,581 100 256 2,506 8,883 0.2 0.7 89 244 3,547 12,765
Relative value* (EUR/km2) 420 630 6,147 1,959 7,140 15 3,393 3,822
*

Relative value is calculated as the monetary value per ecosystem type divided by the extent of each specific ecosystem type.

Table 4.

Use of the actual flow of flood control by economic units at EU level (biophysical and monetary terms).

Economic units
Agriculture Mining, manufacturing & energy production Construction Transport Waste management Other tertiary and Households Total
Year 2006 Biophysical (km2) 36,913 397 35 3,012 17 1,506 41,880
Monetary (Million EUR) 804 2,147 156 1,393 0.07 11,627 16,127
NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+
183 621 393 1,754 23 133 366 1,026 0.01 0.06 2,495 9,132 3,461 12,666



Year 2012 Biophysical (km2) 36,714 417 38 2,992 16 1,518 41,696
Monetary (Million EUR) 799 2,237 165 1,384 0.07 11,726 16,312
NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+
182 617 415 1,822 28 137 364 1,020 0.01 0.06 2,506 9,220 3,495 12,816

When looking at the different ecosystem types, around 70% of the total supply value is generated by woodland and forest, also showing a high value per square kilometre of ecosystem (Table 3). Also grasslands and wetlands revealed relatively high values per km2, while urban ecosystems and croplands showed the lowest values. Most of the supply in biophysical terms is used by agriculture (88% of the total) given the large extent of agricultural land in flooding areas (Table 4). However, the service flow in monetary terms is more valuable the tertiary sector and households (72% of the total), where ecosystems protect mainly residential buildings. This difference is due to a higher damage cost for residential areas than agricultural land, which differs by three orders of magnitude (e.g., in Belgium the maximum damage expected for residential area is about 718 EUR/m2 whereas for agricultural land it is about 0.73 EUR/m2).

3.3. Analysis of trends in flood control

Aggregated numbers at EU level show a decrease between 2006 and 2012 in the main components of flood control by ecosystems in biophysical terms: ES potential, ES demand, ES flow and the unmet demand (Table 2). On the contrary, in monetary terms the value of the actual flow of flood control has increased with 1.14% (Table 2). This increase is explained by the growth of artificial land benefiting from ecosystems protection (actual flow for artificial land increased by 0.3%), which is translated in an increase of the monetary value of 1.23%. Importantly, when looking at the value of the actual flow in relation to the amount of demand (EUR/km2) we see a decrease in the value of the ecosystem service for both artificial and agricultural land (by −0.37% and −0.15%, respectively). Although the percentage points of change appear relatively small, they still suggest that the protective role of the ecosystems is decreasing; especially for artificial areas where there is also a notable increase of the unmet demand (Table 2).

The ES potential in the EU26 did not show significant net changes between 2006 and 2012 (−0.01%). However, there is large spatial variability in the distribution of the SPA: with losses of SPA in the EU26 about 5330 km2 and gains of about 5118 km2 (Table 2). Changes in ES potential are mainly due to land-cover changes. Ecosystem extent accounts prove to be useful complementary information to provide a better understanding of the drivers of changes at country level (Ecosystem Extent Accounts for Europe currently undertaken by the EEA, work in progress). The approach adopted to model flood control also highlights the role of imperviousness as an important driver of change in the ES potential. Approximately 30% of the decrease of SPA in the EU26 is due to an increase in imperviousness.

At a larger degree than the ES potential, the demand for flood control has also decreased between 2006 and 2012 of about 0.16% (Table 2). Although this decrease might be considered negligible at EU level, more relevant changes are found when examining the demand for artificial and agricultural areas separately. The extent of artificial land demanding flood control has increased in all countries, showing in the EU26 an increase of 1.6%. On the contrary, the demand by agricultural land has decreased by 0.43% (Table 2).

As consequence of the decrease in ES potential and demand for flood control, the actual flow in biophysical terms has also decreased in the EU26 in a higher rate than the other two components (−0.44% between 2006 and 2012). The decrease in the actual flow highlights the importance of the spatial component defined by the directional flow between SPA and SDA, since it took place at a higher rate than the decrease in the demand (−0.16%), together with an insignificant decrease of the SPA (−0.01%). Ultimately, the impact of SPA changes will depend on the specific location where changes take place in relation to the demand areas.

Complementary to the changes in the actual flow, we also assessed changes in the unmet demand (Table 2). Changes in the total unmet demand show a decrease of −0.06% between 2006 and 2012, however the unmet demand notably increases for artificial areas (by +1.90%).

4. Discussion

This paper presents an experimental ecosystem account that quantifies the actual flow or use of flood control as ecosystem service based on the interaction between ecosystems and socio-economic systems. The model makes use of the best available data at EU level and it is also suitable for integration into an accounting system. The presented methodology makes a significant contribution to the ES assessment and accounting framework, highlighting the importance of assessing the different components of ES: ES potential, ES demand, actual ES flow and also the unmet demand for the ES. This assessment is spatially and temporally explicit to fully incorporate the key role of the spatial relationship between the ES potential and ES demand, and integrate the dynamic of changes over time, which ultimately will affect the benefit generated to the society. Such development is highly needed for regulating ES such as flood control; which are frequently undervalued when multiple ES are assessed given the complexity of measuring the benefits they generate (Sutherland et al., 2018). The proposed methodology can also be used to make forecast of flood control as ecosystem service under future land cover scenarios.

4.1. Flood control by ecosystems in the EU

In this experimental account, the monetary value of the actual flow of flood control by ecosystems in 2012 is estimated at about 16,312 million euro. The ecosystem with the largest contribution to flood control is forest, with a value of about 7 thousand EUR/km2 (Table 3). These values could be potentially used by economic and financial actors whose activities depend on the vulnerability of the territory they act on, e.g. investments on ecosystem restoration or on nature-based solutions could be seen as an opportunity for business by protecting economic assets and reduce therefore the damage generated by flooding.

Monetary values reported in this study are difficult to compare with those reported in the literature because of the different methodologies used. Smithers et al. (2016) estimated the value of forest in approximately 2.5 thousand EUR/km2, which is the same order of magnitude of the value reported in this study. Barth and Döll (2016) estimated the value of flood control for a riparian forest in about 430 thousand EUR/km2. They value only the role a riparian forest (i.e., key ecosystem in flood control) directly benefiting a city downstream, generating therefore a higher value than the reported in this study. Our approach valued the use of forest controlling floods for artificial areas and agricultural areas (with a lower damage cost than artificial surfaces) in relation to the total forest extent (that can be used or not).

The accounting framework we present here highlights the importance of expressing the value of flood control, not only in relation to the ecosystem extent providing the service (as described above), but also in relation to the extent of the demand areas. Actually, the value of the flood control by ecosystems varies significantly depending on the users of the ecosystem service. While the value of the ecosystem contribution to control floods in artificial areas is 823 thousand EUR per square kilometre of demand, for agricultural land is only 6.5 thousand EUR/km2 (Table 2).

The largest percentage of the total value of flood control by ecosystems (80%) takes place in support to artificial defence measures already in place (ActualflowNC+). Without the protective function of upstream ecosystems, more investments in artificial defence measures would be needed to maintain the same level of protection over time. The value of the ecosystem service where the only contribution to controlling floods is derived from natural capital is about 3.5 billion EUR (according to ActualflowNC). This amount is about 55% of the total damage of floods estimated by Feyen et al. (2012) at about 6.4 billion EUR, where return periods protected by defence measures are discarded (i.e., similarly to the estimate of ActualflowNCin our study). This may be understood as if the total flood damage in the absence of ecosystems would be at least 55% higher. However, the value of flood control provided in this study is to some extent underestimated since the damage curve used is based on simulated water levels reached for different return periods that already integrate the role of ecosystems (as represented by CLC 2006). Damages without ecosystem flood control would actually be much larger, since the water level reached for each return period would be also higher if the ecosystem was not there. Given that a situation without ecosystems cannot be realistically simulated, we use the damage function with ecosystems in place as a proxy for the avoided cost evaluation. This limitation could potentially be addressed by using simulations based on different ecosystem scenarios. However, this alternative method would be much more demanding in terms of data needs, technical skills to make the simulations of flooding areas and processing time, which makes it difficult to generate regular updates required for accounting.

The value of flood control increased between 2006 and 2012 (Table 2) mainly due to changes in the users. The sprawl of artificial areas in floodplains benefiting from ecosystems controlling floods increases the value of the ecosystem service. This situation shows that economic assets become more dependent on measures to protect them from floods, by ecosystems or artificial defence measures. Actually, in this case, the increase of the value of the actual ES flow should not be interpreted as a positive sign for natural capital. For this ecosystem service related to the reduction of occurrence probability of a flood event, the demand and especially the unmet demand are crucial. The increase of artificial areas in need for flood control (Table 2) is a consequence of poor spatial planning since urban sprawl is taking place in flooding areas putting at risk both economic assets and population. In addition, the increase of the unmet demand for artificial areas by 1.9% (Table 2) shows that there is a negative trend in the role of natural capital covering the need for flood control in these areas. This is also confirmed by the decrease of the monetary value for artificial areas in 3 thousand EUR/km2.

4.2. Contribution to ecosystem service accounting

The assessment of the actual ES flow for flood control as proposed in this study is consistent with the specifications defined in the SEEA EEA (UN et al., 2014b) and SEEA EEA Technical Recommendations (TR) (UN, 2017). Our approach allows building ecosystem services accounts in biophysical and monetary terms based on relatively low data requirements. The assessment of the actual ES flow modelled as a function of the ES potential and ES demand may benefit ES accounting by facilitating a direct link to the ecosystems reported in the supply table (through the ES potential) and to the economic units reported in the use table (through the ES demand). With this practical example, we have demonstrated the importance of assessing not only the actual flow of an ecosystem service, but also other relevant information such as the unmet demand; which allows a better understanding and appraisal of ecosystems services that act as buffers by mitigating the impact of flooding (see La Notte et al. (2019) for further discussion).

Comparison of the supply and use tables shows that urban and cropland ecosystems appear both as suppliers of flood control (in the supply table) and as users in the use table: agriculture (use table) corresponds to cropland (supply table), and the rest of economic units (use table) can be attributed to urban ecosystems (supply table) (Table 3, Table 4). This means that in urban and cropland ecosystems, vegetation and soils have the role of reducing runoff (although not at the same levels of forests, grassland or wetlands) while at the same time they are using the service for protection of their assets: artificial areas and agricultural areas (Appendix D). Therefore, effective management measures are especially encouraged for these ecosystem types, where an enhancement of the ES supply will return a direct benefit for the users. This is especially important for artificial surfaces, where the monetary value of the actual flow of the ecosystems service is higher, in absolute and relative terms (Table 2), and therefore management measures will be more beneficial. In situations in which suppliers (ecosystems) and users or beneficiaries (economic units) of ecosystem services spatially match or overlap, measures to enhance ecosystem condition are especially encouraged, given the difficulties of converting these land cover types to more natural ecosystems. A decrease in the level of imperviousness in artificial areas would enhance the ES potential rising therefore the use of the service and therefore the benefit to the society. These measures are especially encouraged in areas where there is an unmet demand by artificial surfaces. Although flood control accounts report useful information on the locations where measures are more urgently needed, local scale studies should be considered, together with the stakeholder involvement, for the final implementation of management measures in urban areas (Su et al., 2014).

The developed methodology is still in a testing phase of the SEEA EEA and should be interpreted in this context. Further development of this experimental account of flood control by ecosystems may consider calculating the actual ES flow weighting by the different values of potential runoff retention within each SPA (i.e., forest may retain more runoff than agricultural areas within the same SPA) and perform the corresponding sensitivity analysis. However, in this application, we discarded this option to be consistent with the approach used for the account of other ecosystem services (Vallecillo et al., 2018). Ultimately, the different role of each ecosystem type in providing the service was taken into account when compiling the supply table (see Section 2.6). Another important limitation is the potential bias in the selection of thresholds to delineate SPA, given the lack of scientific knowledge to set a realistic threshold. However, the values chosen as thresholds were suitable to track changes over time and make sound comparisons. Further development of the experimental account proposed here should include sensitivity analysis of the thresholds chosen.

In spite of the limitations, this method provides useful information to build flood control accounts in a consistent way and allows making comparisons over time. The role of precipitation has been implicitly included as a fix factor (climate related) over time in the modelling of floodplains (Dottori et al., 2016). We pose that annual precipitation data (meteorological) are not essential for flood control account, while they remain relevant for a service such as water supply. In fact, to the best of our knowledge, the only published accounts on flood control (Smithers et al., 2016) did not include precipitation data either. Modelling the actual flow of flood control based on annual precipitation data may result in an increase of ES flows when there is higher precipitation, even under circumstances in which the role of ecosystems controlling floods might be decreasing. This might lead to a misleading message since an increase in the actual ES flow might be interpreted as a positive fact from natural capital perspective. In addition, it might be masking important changes in the ecosystem contribution to control floods. We state that for ES accounts, changes in the actual ES flow should be explained by the drivers we consider in this study: ES potential, ES demand and their spatial relationship.

5. Conclusion

Flood control accounts are developed to provide policy support in relation to the mitigation of flood effects through sustainable ecosystem management. They may support the development of flood risk management plans integrating the role of ecosystems providing flood protection. Flood damage mitigation through nature-based solutions and ecosystem restoration is especially important under the expected increase of damage caused by river floods due to climate changes in the EU (Alfieri et al., 2018, Feyen et al., 2012). As pointed out before, this experimental ecosystem service account highlights the importance of managing ecosystem condition such as imperviousness in artificial surfaces when suppliers of the ecosystem service and users are the same. Ecosystem management measures (or nature-based solutions) should be prioritized in areas of unmet demand, especially in artificial surfaces, where the avoided damage cost by ecosystems is higher. The analysis of changes, even when we only considered a period of six years, raises awareness of the important role of flood control as ecosystem service. Although there is an increase of the demand for flood control, the role of ecosystems controlling floods is decreasing. These findings highlight the need of implementation of management actions to enhance ecosystem contribution to human well-being, as targeted in the 2020 EU Biodiversity Strategy.

Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper

Acknowledgments

The content of this publication does not reflect the official opinion of the European Union. Responsibility for the information given and views expressed in this paper lies entirely with the authors. This paper is a contribution to the phase 2 Knowledge and Innovation Project on an Integrated system of Natural Capital and ecosystem services Accounting in the EU (KIP INCA). This paper greatly benefited from the advice and comments of the KIP INCA partners (ESTAT, DG ENV, EEA, RTD) on an earlier version of this manuscript.

Appendix.

Appendix A. Input data for the assessment of the different components of flood control

Input data Source Spatial resolution Temporal coverage
Ecosystem service potential
Accounting layers CORINE land cover https://sdi.eea.europa.eu/catalogue/srv/eng/catalog.search;jsessionid=ECE3C056F58790227AD6D6DCC72446D6#/home 100 m 2000 2006 2012
EU Dem 100 m > derive slope (m/m) https://land.copernicus.eu/pan-european/satellite-derived-products/eu-dem/eu-dem-v1-0-and-derived-products/eu-dem-v1.0?tab=download 100 m Static
USDA soil textural classes: hydraulic properties https://esdac.jrc.ec.europa.eu/resource-type/datasets 500 m Static
Imperviousness https://land.copernicus.eu/pan-european/high-resolution-layers/imperviousness/view 100 m NA1 2006 2012
Riparian zones https://land.copernicus.eu/local/riparian-zones Shapefile Static



Ecosystem service demand
CORINE land cover: accounting layers > economic assets > agriculture and artificial https://sdi.eea.europa.eu/catalogue/srv/eng/catalog.search;jsessionid=ECE3C056F58790227AD6D6DCC72446D6#/home 100 m 2000 2006 2012
Flood hazard map (return period 500 years) https://data.jrc.ec.europa.eu/collection/id-0054 100 m Static
Road network TeleAtlas Shapefile-resampled at 100 m Static



Actual flow (use)
EU Dem 100 m > flow direction and flow accumulation https://land.copernicus.eu/pan-european/satellite-derived-products/eu-dem/eu-dem-v1-0-and-derived-products/eu-dem-v1.0?tab=download 100 m Static



Monetary valuation
Estimated flood protection level (water depth) https://data.jrc.ec.europa.eu/dataset/959355de-514a-4126-a969-27793cd775aa 5 km Static
Flood hazard map (all available return periods) https://data.jrc.ec.europa.eu/collection/id-0054 100 m Static
Damage functions: Huizinga (2007) https://link.springer.com/content/pdf/10.1007%2Fs10584-011–0339-7.pdf Country Static
1NA: Not available

Appendix B. Derivation of the Curve number values at EU level

We refined the Reference Curve Number (CN) scores (see Section 2.1.1) to assign a different CN to the different CLC classes (CNCLC). The refinement was based on the application of the following rules: a) Within each coarse land cover class, assign plus/minus score of 5 depending on the type of vegetation (contrasted with the literature); b) In the case of mixed classes, average values are assigned (i.e. mixed forest); and c) Refined CN scores within each coarse LC class of Table 1 can never reach the values of other coarse LC class. The application of this rules allowed us to estimate the values that appear in the table below black and in bold. The refined values were contrasted with those applied by Hong and Adler (2008) at World level. For this comparison, CN scores of Hong and Adler (2008) were averaged for all soil categories and rescaled between 20 and 77 to match the CN range derived from the correlation coefficients in Table 1. Both approached showed a correlation of 97% (for the black numbers in bold in Table A.1), which confirms the robustness of our approach, but fine-tuned for the EU context. Given the similarity between the CN scores, we used the CN from Hong and Adler (2008) to refine as much as possible those LC classes not included in Schulp et al. 2014a, such as permanent crops and wetlands. The variability of the CN scores across all soil categories was also equivalent to the variability in Hong and Adler (2008).

Table A.1. Processing of the lookup table for the Curve Number scores (CN): from the 'Reference CN' to the 'Refined CN' and the assignment to the different soil categories based on Hong and Adler (2008).

Coarse land cover classes1 Reference CN1 CORINE LC2 Refined CN Comparison with Hong and Adler (2008)
Soil categories4
Average CN for all soil types3 Land cover types A B C D
Forest 20 Broad-leaved forest 15 29 Evergreen/deciduos broadleaf forest (mean) 8 15 18 19
Coniferous forest 25 29 Evergreen/deciduos needleaf forest (mean) 14 24 30 32
Mixed forest 20 30 Mixed forest 12 19 23 25



Nature 36 Transitional woodland-shrub 28 34 Closed shrubland 19 27 31 34
Moors and heathland 36 42 Open shrubland 25 35 40 43
Sclerophyllous vegetation 36 42 Open shrubland 25 35 40 43
Bare rocks 72 64 73 74 77
Sparsely vegetated areas 63 63 Barren or sparsely vegetated 56 64 65 68
Burnt areas 63 63 Barren or sparsely vegetated 44 62 71 75
Natural grassland 41 42 Grasslands 29 40 46 49



Pasture 47 Pasture 47 42 Grasslands 33 46 53 56



Arable 66 Non-irrigated arable land 61 61 Croplands 51 60 65 68
Permanently irrigated land 71 61 Croplands 60 69 76 79
Rice fields 71 61 Croplands 60 69 76 79



Urban 77 Artificial surfaces [except green urban areas] 77 76 Urban and built up 70 75 79 84
Green urban areas5 36 24 35 41 43



Permanent crops Not available Vineyards 61 61 Croplands 49 57 65 72
Fruit trees and berry plantations 61 61 Croplands 49 57 65 72
Olive groves 61 61 Croplands 49 57 65 72



Heterogeneous agricultural areas Not available Annual crops associated with permanent crops 64 51 60 68 75
Complex cultivation patterns 44 44 Cropland/natural vegetation mosaic 32 43 49 52
Land principally occupied by agriculture, with significant areas of natural vegetation 44 44 Cropland/natural vegetation mosaic 32 43 49 52
Agro-forestry areas 44 44 Cropland/natural vegetation mosaic 32 43 49 52



Wetlands Not available Inland marshes 20 20 Permanent wetlands 10 20 24 26
Peat bogs 20 20 Permanent wetlands 10 20 24 26

1Derived from Schulp et al., 2014a (see Table 1).

2Land covers excluded: water courses and water bodies, coastal lagoons; beaches, dunes and sands; glaciers and perpetual snow (similarly to Hong and Adler, 2008, Stürck et al., 2014).

3Rescaled within the range of the 'Reference CN' (20 and 77).

4A. Sand, loamy sand, sandy loam; B. Silt, silt-loam, loam; C. Sandy clay-loam; D. Clay, silty clay, silty clay-loam, sand clay, clay-loam.

5Assigned values equivalent to transitional woodland-shrub.

Numbers in bold were used for the comparison of the estimates in this study and curve number scores in Hong and Adler (2008)

Appendix C. Citeria for the delineation of the Service Providing Areas (SPA) based on different thresholds for three broad ecosystem types

Land covers CORINE Land Cover classes Ecosystem service potential
Criteria Value Threshold
Mean Std. Dev.
Artificial Continuous urban fabric 10.59 5.28 Mean + Std.Dev 15.87 27
Discontinuous urban fabric 20.55 6.25 Mean + Std.Dev 26.80
Industrial or commercial units 16.04 7.94 Mean + Std.Dev 23.98
Road and rail networks and associated land 19.95 6.80 Mean + Std.Dev 26.74
Port areas 12.68 8.25 Mean + Std.Dev 20.93
Airports 22.41 7.45 Mean + Std.Dev 29.86
Mineral extraction sites 25.52 5.03 Mean + Std.Dev 30.55
Dump sites 25.77 5.22 Mean + Std.Dev 30.99
Construction sites 21.81 6.79 Mean + Std.Dev 28.60
Sport and leisure facilities 25.92 5.01 Mean + Std.Dev 30.93



Agricultural Non-irrigated arable land 41.85 5.93 Mean + Std.Dev 47.78 52
Permanently irrigated land 30.35 6.11 Mean + Std.Dev 36.46
Rice fields 30.75 5.23 Mean + Std.Dev 35.98
Vineyards 42.42 6.54 Mean + Std.Dev 48.97
Fruit trees and berry plantations 41.43 7.31 Mean + Std.Dev 48.74
Olive groves 39.10 7.65 Mean + Std.Dev 46.76
Pastures 56.70 6.76 Mean + Std.Dev 63.47
Annual crops associated with permanent crops 40.56 9.42 Mean + Std.Dev 49.98
Complex cultivation patterns 58.20 6.71 Mean + Std.Dev 64.91
Land principally occupied by agriculture 59.24 6.89 Mean + Std.Dev 66.13
Agro-forestry areas 61.33 5.45 Mean + Std.Dev 66.78



Natural and semi-natural Broad-leaved forest 87.05 3.57 Mean - Std.Dev 83.48 61
Coniferous forest 84.04 5.46 Mean - Std.Dev 78.58
Mixed forest 85.51 4.43 Mean - Std.Dev 81.09
Natural grasslands 60.12 5.48 Mean - Std.Dev 54.63
Moors and heathland 68.93 5.65 Mean - Std.Dev 63.28
Sclerophyllous vegetation 65.80 4.08 Mean - Std.Dev 61.72
Transitional woodland-shrub 77.81 5.42 Mean - Std.Dev 72.39
Bare rocks 28.31 3.64 Mean - Std.Dev 24.67
Sparsely vegetated areas 38.43 3.99 Mean - Std.Dev 34.43
Burnt areas 40.23 10.08 Mean - Std.Dev 30.15
Inland marshes 82.64 6.49 Mean - Std.Dev 76.15
Peat bogs 87.79 5.25 Mean - Std.Dev 82.54
Green urban areas* 64.92 11.66 Mean - Std.Dev 53.26
*They were considered in this group because of their different biophysical properties compared to the artificial and impervious land covers

Appendix D. Economic assets considered as demand for flood control and correspondence with the economic sectors

Broad economic assets CORINE Land Cover classes (LABEL 3) Allocation to user of flood control2
Artificial surfaces Continuous urban fabric Other tertiary and households
Discontinuous urban fabric Other tertiary and households
Green urban areas Other tertiary and households
Sport and leisure facilities Other tertiary and households
Road and rail networks and associated land (main roads from TeleAtlas are also added) Transportation
Port areas Transportation
Airports Transportation
Industrial or commercial units Manufacturing and mining
Mineral extraction sites Manufacturing and mining
Dump sites Waste management
Construction sites Construction



Agricultural areas1 Non-irrigated arable land Agriculture
Permanently irrigated land Agriculture
Vineyards Agriculture
Fruit trees and berry plantations Agriculture
Olive groves Agriculture
Pastures Agriculture
Annual crops associated with permanent crops Agriculture
Complex cultivation patterns Agriculture
Land principally occupied by agriculture, with significant areas of natural vegetation Agriculture
Agro-forestry areas Agriculture

1Areas covered by rice fields were excluded from the agriculture class as they are already intentionally planted in flooded areas for cultivation.

2Based on the Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community (NACE) to fill in the use table

Appendix E. Lookup table between CORINE land cover classes and MAES ecosystem types (Maes et al., 2013)

MAES ecosystem CORINE Land Cover
Urban Continuous urban fabric
Discontinuous urban fabric
Industrial or commercial units
Road and rail networks and associated land
Port areas
Airports
Mineral extraction sites
Dump sites
Construction sites
Green urban areas
Sport and leisure facilities
Cropland Non-irrigated arable land
Permanently irrigated land
Rice fields
Vineyards
Fruit trees and berry plantations
Olive groves
Annual crops associated with permanent crops
Complex cultivation patterns
Land principally occupied by agriculture, with significant areas of natural vegetation
Agro-forestry areas
Grassland Natural grasslands
Pastures
Heathland and shrub Moors and heathland
Sclerophyllous vegetation
Woodland and forest Broad-leaved forest
Coniferous forest
Mixed forest
Transitional woodland-shrub
Sparsely vegetated land Beaches, dunes, sands
Bare rocks
Sparsely vegetated areas
Burnt areas
Glaciers and perpetual snow
Wetland Inland marshes
Peat bogs
Rivers and lakes Water courses
Water bodies
Marine inlets and transitional water Salt marshes
Salines
Intertidal flats
Coastal lagoons
Estuaries

Appendix F. Accounting tables in monetary terms at country level

NOTE: Values at national level for the accounting tables are calculated by summing up the value of the actual ES flow (in biophysical and monetary terms) at sub-catchment level. The allocation of the sub-catchments to the different countries was done based on the position of the sub-catchment centroid. Therefore, transboundary catchments (shared by two countries) were only allocated to the country where the centroid of the sub-catchment is located.

Table A.2. Supply table 2006.

Economic units
Ecosystem types

Economic sectors
Households
Total Urban areas
Cropland
Grassland
Heathland and shrub
Woodland and forest
Sparsely vegetated land
Wetlands
Year 2006 NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC
million euro
AT 949 0.21 0.034 29.71 4.70 140.63 22.23 26.34 4.16 620.21 98.04 0.073 0.0115 2.68 0.42
BE 708 4.03 0.569 148.90 21.02 145.96 20.60 2.45 0.35 314.96 44.46 - - 4.45 0.63
BG 67 0.02 0.012 4.48 2.21 4.52 2.23 0.29 0.15 35.22 17.39 0.003 0.0014 0.22 0.11
CZ 426 0.23 0.038 35.54 5.78 54.35 8.83 0.29 0.05 274.73 44.66 - - 1.14 0.19
DE 3732 31.29 6.740 51.90 11.18 749.51 161.48 14.89 3.21 2203.58 474.75 0.020 0.0043 18.92 4.08
DK 22 0.46 0.157 4.09 1.39 0.60 0.20 0.36 0.12 10.03 3.40 - - 0.55 0.19
EE 38 0.09 0.069 1.63 1.21 1.65 1.23 0.00 0.00 17.44 12.99 - - 1.03 0.77
EL 36 0.00 0.002 2.04 1.93 1.79 1.69 2.44 2.31 12.07 11.42 0.012 0.0114 0.03 0.03
ES 478 0.12 0.077 28.18 17.99 37.29 23.81 54.00 34.47 171.85 109.69 0.040 0.0258 0.39 0.25
FI 804 0.83 0.324 19.12 7.48 0.20 0.08 3.94 1.54 523.99 205.03 0.001 0.0005 29.83 11.67
FR 2432 0.99 0.189 160.56 30.64 488.31 93.20 29.23 5.58 1354.50 258.52 0.221 0.0422 8.69 1.66
HR 54 0.00 0.005 0.21 9.53 0.06 2.56 0.00 0.12 0.91 40.56 0.0000 0.0002 0.00 0.13
HU 156 0.11 0.021 10.51 1.97 18.04 3.39 0.07 0.01 100.08 18.80 0.002 0.00028 2.15 0.40
IE 155 0.03 0.011 6.01 2.21 74.87 27.54 0.54 0.20 14.26 5.25 0.001 0.00029 17.54 6.45
IT 501 0.12 0.021 32.84 5.84 27.92 4.96 11.73 2.08 351.57 62.50 0.323 0.0574 0.88 0.16
LT 190 1.15 0.868 24.33 18.34 10.05 7.57 0.05 0.04 70.67 53.25 2.03 1.53
LU 166 0.07 0.009 25.88 3.35 30.48 3.95 0.02 0.00 90.24 11.70 0.09 0.01
LV 331 1.14 0.709 28.21 17.53 28.29 17.57 0.01 0.00 139.86 86.88 6.60 4.10
NL 935 6.07 0.239 17.98 0.71 204.93 8.07 4.28 0.17 659.44 25.96 0.007 0.00027 6.74 0.27
PL 1456 17.92 6.586 102.76 37.77 165.98 61.01 0.41 0.15 767.53 282.13 0.009 0.0034 9.89 3.64
PT 66 0.04 0.111 3.74 9.76 1.63 4.26 2.34 6.12 10.43 27.23 0.002 0.0049 0.01 0.035
RO 199 0.07 0.031 12.07 5.30 20.16 8.85 0.87 0.38 104.56 45.92 0.007 0.0029 0.73 0.32
SE 1303 1.67 1.289 11.81 9.09 6.31 4.86 32.80 25.26 631.93 486.74 0.004 0.0030 51.36 39.56
SI 106 0.00 0.001 4.42 1.16 2.74 0.72 0.98 0.26 76.01 19.99 0.011 0.0029 0.15 0.040
SK 127 0.03 0.004 7.48 1.17 8.40 1.31 0.41 0.06 92.90 14.52 0.18 0.028
UK 692 3.25 0.523 7.02 1.13 329.24 53.00 64.42 10.37 114.82 18.48 0.003 0.00056 76.99 12.39



EU 16,127 70 19 781 230 2554 545 253 97 8764 2480 0.7 0.17 243 89.05

Table A.3. Supply table 2012.

Economic units
Total Ecosystem types

Economic sectors
Households
Urban areas
Cropland
Grassland
Heathland and shrub
Woodland and forest
Sparsely vegetated land
Wetlands
Year 2012 NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC
million euro
AT 955 0.21 0.034 29.84 4.72 141.74 22.40 26.50 4.19 624.02 98.61 0.075 0.0118 2.70 0.43
BE 709 3.75 0.529 143.46 20.25 143.76 20.29 2.33 0.33 323.42 45.66 4.36 0.62
BG 66 0.02 0.012 4.43 2.15 4.46 2.17 0.29 0.14 34.86 16.96 0.003 0.0013 0.22 0.11
CZ 429 0.23 0.038 35.26 5.75 59.23 9.66 0.28 0.05 272.79 44.48 1.12 0.18
DE 3728 31.09 6.716 51.75 11.18 749.25 161.86 14.79 3.20 2200.31 475.33 0.018 0.0039 18.83 4.07
DK 22 0.50 0.170 4.17 1.41 0.61 0.21 0.37 0.12 10.28 3.47 0.56 0.19
EE 40 0.10 0.076 1.70 1.28 1.78 1.34 0.00 0.00 18.28 13.71 1.08 0.81
EL 39 0.00 0.003 2.05 2.23 1.80 1.96 2.48 2.69 12.11 13.15 0.012 0.0133 0.03 0.03
ES 509 0.15 0.097 30.54 19.66 39.37 25.34 57.21 36.83 181.82 117.04 0.040 0.0259 0.44 0.28
FI 809 0.86 0.339 19.24 7.56 0.19 0.07 3.97 1.56 526.49 206.75 0.001 0.0005 30.28 11.89
FR 2442 0.99 0.190 160.84 30.68 489.69 93.42 29.36 5.60 1360.70 259.57 0.219 0.0417 8.72 1.66
HR 55 0.00 0.005 0.21 9.68 0.06 2.61 0.00 0.12 0.91 41.28 0.0000 0.0002 0.00 0.14
HU 161 0.12 0.022 10.83 2.04 18.63 3.51 0.07 0.01 103.93 19.57 0.002 0.0003 2.22 0.42
IE 156 0.03 0.012 5.98 2.21 74.95 27.67 0.54 0.20 14.73 5.44 0.001 0.0003 17.51 6.46
IT 504 0.12 0.021 32.92 5.88 28.08 5.01 11.82 2.11 353.66 63.13 0.324 0.0578 0.89 0.16
LT 190 1.17 0.875 24.38 18.31 9.65 7.24 0.05 0.04 71.42 53.64 2.04 1.53
LU 165 0.07 0.009 25.67 3.34 30.16 3.92 0.02 0.00 89.71 11.67 - 0.09 0.01
LV 343 1.21 0.739 29.60 18.02 28.69 17.46 0.01 0.00 147.02 89.49 6.94 4.22
NL 1046 6.70 0.258 20.11 0.78 228.49 8.81 4.79 0.18 739.58 28.51 0.007 0.0003 7.48 0.29
PL 1455 18.24 6.717 102.17 37.64 164.56 60.61 0.40 0.15 768.44 283.05 0.009 0.0034 9.88 3.64
PT 68 0.04 0.120 3.73 10.35 1.62 4.50 2.33 6.47 10.41 28.85 0.002 0.0054 0.01 0.037
RO 199 0.07 0.031 12.04 5.29 20.12 8.83 0.87 0.38 104.52 45.90 0.007 0.0029 0.72 0.32
SE 1301 1.70 1.314 11.76 9.10 6.30 4.88 32.68 25.30 629.60 487.42 0.004 0.0030 51.17 39.61
SI 106 0.00 0.001 4.40 1.16 2.73 0.72 0.98 0.26 75.87 19.95 0.011 0.0029 0.15 0.040
SK 128 0.03 0.004 7.55 1.18 8.56 1.34 0.42 0.07 94.06 14.70 0.18 0.028
UK 685 3.23 0.517 6.94 1.11 326.09 52.28 63.73 10.22 113.75 18.24 0.004 0.0006 76.33 12.24



EU 16,312 71 19 782 233 2581 548 256 100 8883 2506 0.7 0.18 244 89.42

Table A.3. Use table 2006.

Economic units
Total Agriculture
Manufacturing & energy production
Construction
Transport
Waste management
Other tertiary and Households
Ecosystem types
Year 2006 NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC
million euro
AT 949 18.75 2.79 65.40 10.65 2.42 0.523 73.38 11.71 0.001 0.00013 659.91 103.93
BE 708 11.04 1.58 89.44 11.72 2.11 0.310 25.57 3.70 0.002 0.00026 492.58 70.31
BG 67 2.56 1.55 10.50 4.45 0.64 0.677 4.25 2.71 0.000 0.00005 26.80 12.71
CZ 426 8.18 1.25 80.56 11.63 0.63 0.098 20.81 3.28 0.010 0.00134 256.09 43.29
DE 3732 148.22 30.51 583.32 117.73 9.41 1.757 209.04 47.50 0.008 0.00134 2120.11 463.95
DK 22 1.04 0.36 0.42 0.09 0.14 0.035 0.58 0.21 0.000 0.00000 13.91 4.76
EE 38 2.18 1.54 1.11 1.43 0.48 0.546 3.22 1.89 0.000 0.00000 14.87 10.87
EL 36 2.85 3.53 1.19 4.12 0.05 0.924 3.01 5.04 0.000 0.00000 11.28 3.77
ES 478 11.52 14.03 72.36 28.04 9.14 4.478 38.55 40.85 0.005 0.00336 160.29 98.90
FI 804 10.43 4.86 30.82 15.34 0.00 1.104 45.28 31.33 0.003 0.00119 491.38 173.50
FR 2432 126.41 25.51 259.70 45.26 4.50 0.647 225.57 56.17 0.008 0.00109 1426.30 262.23
HR 54 0.59 15.16 0.00 4.99 0.00 0.602 0.31 11.68 0.000 0.00003 0.28 20.48
HU 156 26.60 5.12 9.98 1.85 1.72 0.283 14.86 2.94 0.002 0.00023 77.80 14.41
IE 155 15.27 5.95 6.40 1.34 0.98 0.262 11.51 4.58 0.000 0.00001 79.08 29.52
IT 501 20.26 4.74 86.77 15.24 1.17 0.377 53.05 10.71 0.000 0.00002 264.12 44.56
LT 190 6.71 4.02 11.65 6.46 0.43 0.349 6.99 3.87 0.001 0.00055 82.50 66.89
LU 166 1.28 0.16 11.51 1.42 0.00 0.000 15.53 2.01 0.000 0.00000 118.45 15.44
LV 331 7.12 6.45 24.32 15.30 4.83 2.031 11.77 8.23 0.000 0.00000 156.07 94.78
NL 935 71.47 2.71 108.38 3.93 84.47 3.235 104.02 3.98 0.002 0.00008 531.11 21.56
PL 1456 66.45 27.14 76.42 21.89 5.51 1.062 45.52 18.84 0.012 0.00365 870.60 322.35
PT 66 1.19 4.43 1.91 4.56 0.01 2.429 3.40 11.83 0.000 0.00000 11.68 24.25
RO 199 12.16 5.22 10.75 5.51 0.29 0.166 7.59 3.71 0.000 0.00008 107.68 46.21
SE 1303 13.47 8.06 90.11 38.44 0.71 1.062 46.12 66.47 0.000 0.00072 585.47 452.78
SI 106 3.00 0.95 16.00 5.19 0.14 0.039 14.08 5.33 0.000 0.00000 51.09 10.66
SK 127 5.19 0.73 16.92 2.50 0.72 0.104 8.32 1.38 0.000 0.00008 78.26 12.38
UK 692 27.13 4.76 88.51 13.71 2.09 0.318 34.02 6.18 0.003 0.00039 443.99 70.93



EU 16,127 621 183.1 1754 393 133 23.42 1026 366 0.059 0.015 9132 2495

Table A.4. Use table 2012.

Economic units

Total Agriculture
Manufacturing & energy production
Construction
Transport
Waste management
Other tertiary and Households
Ecosystem types
Year 2012 NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC NC+ NC
million euro
AT 955 18.65 2.78 67.74 11.07 4.40 0.585 72.96 11.65 0.001 0.0001 661.33 104.30
BE 709 10.95 1.57 91.51 11.99 2.46 0.391 25.55 3.70 0.002 0.0003 490.61 70.03
BG 66 2.55 1.54 10.63 4.61 0.02 0.006 4.24 2.70 0.000 0.0001 26.84 12.69
CZ 429 8.26 1.26 81.68 11.81 0.45 0.098 20.85 3.29 0.009 0.0012 257.66 43.71
DE 3728 147.12 30.28 593.39 120.76 12.25 2.772 207.03 47.08 0.007 0.0012 2106.25 461.46
DK 22 1.04 0.36 0.42 0.09 0.00 0.007 0.58 0.21 0.000 0.0000 14.44 4.91
EE 40 2.18 1.52 1.02 1.32 0.23 0.342 3.26 1.91 0.000 0.0000 16.25 12.12
EL 39 2.83 3.51 1.26 5.69 0.17 2.120 2.96 5.00 0.000 0.0000 11.26 3.77
ES 509 11.46 13.94 82.15 37.94 9.09 4.838 37.98 40.22 0.005 0.0041 168.88 102.33
FI 809 10.39 4.85 30.02 15.28 0.04 1.115 45.34 31.35 0.003 0.0007 495.24 175.58
FR 2442 125.80 25.39 268.46 46.93 3.77 0.675 223.90 55.70 0.008 0.0011 1428.60 262.47
HR 55 0.59 15.14 0.00 6.35 0.00 0.233 0.31 11.57 0.000 0.0000 0.28 20.54
HU 161 26.89 5.14 13.34 2.47 1.55 0.305 15.25 3.06 0.002 0.0002 78.76 14.59
IE 156 15.28 5.93 6.36 1.33 0.15 0.044 11.53 4.60 0.000 0.0000 80.43 30.08
IT 504 20.04 4.69 88.22 15.64 3.06 0.870 52.16 10.48 0.000 0.0001 264.32 44.68
LT 190 6.65 3.99 11.54 6.41 0.70 0.330 6.98 3.87 0.001 0.0005 82.83 67.04
LU 165 1.27 0.16 9.79 1.27 1.38 0.170 15.46 2.00 0.000 0.0000 117.82 15.36
LV 343 7.07 6.38 24.32 15.38 2.80 0.752 11.74 8.19 0.000 0.0000 167.53 99.23
NL 1046 70.23 2.66 138.57 4.74 81.89 3.114 103.03 4.00 0.002 0.0001 613.45 24.31
PL 1455 66.21 27.05 78.51 22.51 7.74 2.049 45.25 18.79 0.013 0.0037 865.97 321.39
PT 68 1.17 4.34 1.87 4.51 0.41 5.506 3.33 11.69 0.000 0.0000 11.38 24.27
RO 199 12.03 5.19 11.20 5.68 0.17 0.117 7.49 3.67 0.000 0.0001 107.44 46.10
SE 1301 13.45 8.05 90.26 39.74 0.75 0.872 46.24 66.91 0.000 0.0007 582.51 452.06
SI 106 3.00 0.95 15.95 5.18 0.14 0.039 14.05 5.32 0.000 0.0000 51.03 10.65
SK 128 5.19 0.73 17.92 2.67 1.18 0.166 8.33 1.39 0.000 0.0001 78.18 12.36
UK 685 27.05 4.75 86.18 13.12 2.09 0.403 33.87 6.15 0.003 0.0004 440.88 70.18



EU 16,312 617 182.1 1822 415 137 27.92 1020 364 0.056 0.015 9220 2506

References

  1. Alfieri L., Salamon P., Bianchi A., Neal J., Bates P., Feyen L. Advances in pan-European flood hazard mapping. Hydrol. Process. 2014;28:4067–4077. doi: 10.1002/hyp.9947. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  2. Alfieri L., Feyen L., Dottori F., Bianchi A. Ensemble flood risk assessment in Europe under high end climate scenarios. Global Environ. Change. 2015;35:199–212. doi: 10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2015.09.004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  3. Alfieri L., Dottori F., Betts R., Salamon P., Feyen L. Multi-model projections of river flood risk in europe under global warming. Climate. 2018;6:6. [Google Scholar]
  4. Arnell N.W., Gosling S.N. The impacts of climate change on river flood risk at the global scale. Clim. Change. 2016;134:387–401. doi: 10.1007/s10584-014-1084-5. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  5. Bagstad K.J., Villa F., Batker D., Harrison-Cox J., Voigt B., Johnson G.W. From theoretical to actual ecosystem services: mapping beneficiaries and spatial flows in ecosystem service assessments. Ecol. Soc. 2014;19 doi: 10.5751/es-06523-190264. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  6. Ballabio C., Panagos P., Monatanarella L. Mapping topsoil physical properties at European scale using the LUCAS database. Geoderma. 2016;261:110–123. doi: 10.1016/j.geoderma.2015.07.006. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  7. Barbedo J., Miguez M., van der Horst D., Marins M. Enhancing ecosystem services for flood mitigation: a conservation strategy for peri-urban landscapes? Ecol. Soc. 2014;19 doi: 10.5751/es-06482-190254. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  8. Baró F., Palomo I., Zulian G., Vizcaino P., Haase D., Gómez-Baggethun E. Mapping ecosystem service capacity, flow and demand for landscape and urban planning: a case study in the Barcelona metropolitan region. Land Use Policy. 2016;57:405–417. doi: 10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.06.006. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  9. Barth N.-C., Döll P. Assessing the ecosystem service flood protection of a riparian forest by applying a cascade approach. Ecosyst. Serv. 2016;21:39–52. doi: 10.1016/j.ecoser.2016.07.012. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  10. Bennett S.J., Simon S. American Geophysical Union; 2013. Water Science and Application. Riparian Vegetation and Fluvial Geomorphology. [Google Scholar]
  11. Bouraoui F., Grizzetti B., Aloe A. Joint Research Centre Scientific and Technical Research Series EUR 24002 EN. Publications Office of the European Union; Luxembourg: 2009. Nutrient discharge from rivers to seas for year 2000. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  12. Burkhard B., Maes J. Pensoft Publishers; 2017. Mapping Ecosystem Services. [Google Scholar]
  13. Costanza R. Ecosystem services: multiple classification systems are needed. Biol. Conserv. 2008;141:350–352. doi: 10.1016/j.biocon.2007.12.020. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  14. de Groot R.S., Alkemade R., Braat L., Hein L., Willemen L. Challenges in integrating the concept of ecosystem services and values in landscape planning, management and decision making. Ecol. Complexity. 2010;7:260–272. doi: 10.1016/j.ecocom.2009.10.006. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  15. Directorate-General for the Environment, 2011. Towards better environmental options for flood risk management. Directorate General Environment of the European Commission, Brussels, Belgium. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/environment/water/water-framework/index_en.html.
  16. Dottori, F., Alfieri, L., Salamon, P., Bianchi, A., Feyen, L., Lorini, V., 2016. Flood hazard map for Europe, 500-year return period. European Commission, Joint Research Centre (JRC) [Dataset] Retrieved from http://data.europa.eu/89h/jrc-floods-floodmapeu_rp500y-tif.
  17. EEA . European Environment Agency; Copenhagen: 2017. Corine Land Cover Accounting (adjusted) Layer (raster 100m) [Google Scholar]
  18. European Commission – JRC, 2017. EFAS estimated flood protection level. European Commission, Joint Research Centre (JRC) PID: http://data.europa.eu/89h/959355de-514a-4126-a969-27793cd775aa Retrieved from https://www.efas.eu/.
  19. European Environment Agency . Publications Office of the European Union; Luxembourg: 2016. Flood Risks and Environmental Vulnerability: Exploring the Synergies between Floodplain Restoration, Water Policies and Thematic Policies. [Google Scholar]
  20. European Union, 2018. European Union, Copernicus Land Monitoring Service 2018, European Environment Agency (EEA). In.
  21. Feyen L., Dankers R., Bódis K., Salamon P., Barredo J.I. Fluvial flood risk in Europe in present and future climates. Clim. Change. 2012;112:47–62. doi: 10.1007/s10584-011-0339-7. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  22. Fisher B., Turner R.K., Morling P. Defining and classifying ecosystem services for decision making. Ecol. Econ. 2009;68:643–653. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.09.014. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  23. Grizzetti B., Liquete C., Pistocchi A., Vigiak O., Reynaud A., Lanzanova D., Brogi C., Cardoso A.C., Zulian G. JRC, Joint Research Centre; 2017. Reports on Stressor Classification and Effects at the European Scale: Impact of Multi-stressors on Ecosystem Services and their Monetary Value. MARS project. [Google Scholar]
  24. Guerra C.A., Maes J., Geijzendorffer I., Metzger M.J. An assessment of soil erosion prevention by vegetation in Mediterranean Europe: current trends of ecosystem service provision. Ecol. Indic. 2016;60:213–222. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2015.06.043. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  25. Haines-Young, R., Potschin, M.B., 2018. Common International Classification of Ecosystem Services (CICES) V5.1 and Guidance on the Application of the Revised Structure. Retrieved from https://cices.eu/content/uploads/sites/8/2018/01/Guidance-V51-01012018.pdf.
  26. Hong Y., Adler R.F. Estimation of global SCS curve numbers using satellite remote sensing and geospatial data. Int. J. Remote Sens. 2008;29:471–477. doi: 10.1080/01431160701264292. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  27. Huang M., Gallichand J., Wang Z., Goulet M. A modification to the soil conservation service curve number method for steep slopes in the Loess Plateau of China. Hydrol. Process. 2006;20:579–589. doi: 10.1002/hyp.5925. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  28. Huizinga, H.J., 2007. Flood damage functions for EU member states. Technical report, HKV Consultants. Implemented in the framework of the contract # 382441-F1SC awarded by the European Commission—Joint Research Centre. Retrieved from.
  29. Joint Research Centre European Soil Data Centre (ESDAC). Retrieved from esdac.jrc.ec.europa.eu (accessed July 2017).
  30. Jongman B., Hochrainer-Stigler S., Feyen L., Aerts J.C.J.H., Mechler R., Botzen W.J.W., Bouwer L.M., Pflug G., Rojas R., Ward P.J. Increasing stress on disaster-risk finance due to large floods. Nat. Clim. Change. 2014;4:264. doi: 10.1038/nclimate2124. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  31. Kosztra B., Büttner G., Hazeu G., Arnold S. European Environment Agency; Copenhagen: 2017. Updated CLC Illustrated Nomenclature Guidelines. [Google Scholar]
  32. La Notte A., Liquete C., Grizzetti B., Maes J., Egoh B.N., Paracchini M.L. An ecological-economic approach to the valuation of ecosystem services to support biodiversity policy. A case study for nitrogen retention by Mediterranean rivers and lakes. Ecol. Ind. 2015;48:292–302. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2014.08.006. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  33. La Notte A., Vallecillo S., Marques A., Maes J. Beyond the economic boundaries to account for ecosystem services. Ecosyst. Serv. 2019;35:116–129. doi: 10.1016/j.ecoser.2018.12.007. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  34. Lautenbach S., Seppelt R., Liebscher J., Dormann C.F. Spatial and Temporal Trends of Global Pollination Benefit. PLoS ONE. 2012;7 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0035954. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  35. JRC, 2018. JRC data catalogue. https://data.jrc.ec.europa.eu/.
  36. Maes, J., Teller, A., Erhard, M., Liquete, C., Braat, L., et al., 2013. Mapping and Assessment of Ecosystems and their Services: An analytical framework for ecosystem assessments under Action 5 of the EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020 Publication office of the European Union, Luxembourg. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/environment/nature/knowledge/ecosystem_assessment/pdf/MAESWorkingPaper2013.pdf.
  37. Maes J., Teller A., Erhard M., Grizzetti B., Barredo J., Paracchini M., Condé S., Somma F., Orgiazzi A., Jones A., Zulian G., Vallecillo S., Petersen J., Marquardt D., Kovacevic V., Abdul Malak D., Marin A., Czúcz B., Mauri A., Loffler P., Bastrup-Birk A., Biala K., Christiansen T., Werner B. Publications office of the European Union; Luxembourg: 2018. Mapping and Assessment of Ecosystems and their Services: an analytical framework for ecosystem condition. [Google Scholar]
  38. Nedkov S., Burkhard B. Flood regulating ecosystem services—mapping supply and demand, in the Etropole municipality, Bulgaria. Ecol. Ind. 2012;21:67–79. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2011.06.022. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  39. Orta Ortiz M.S., Geneletti D. Assessing mismatches in the provision of urban ecosystem services to support spatial planning: a case study on recreation and food supply in Havana, Cuba. Sustainability. 2018;10:2165. [Google Scholar]
  40. Rojas R., Feyen L., Watkiss P. Climate change and river floods in the European Union: socio-economic consequences and the costs and benefits of adaptation. Global Environ. Change. 2013;23:1737–1751. doi: 10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.08.006. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  41. Schaefer M., Goldman E., Bartuska A.M., Sutton-Grier A., Lubchenco J. Nature as capital: advancing and incorporating ecosystem services in United States federal policies and programs. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A. 2015;112:7383–7389. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1420500112. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  42. Schirpke U., Tappeiner U., Tasser E. A transnational perspective of global and regional ecosystem service flows from and to mountain regions. Sci. Rep. 2019;9:6678. doi: 10.1038/s41598-019-43229-z. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  43. Schulp C.J.E., Burkhard B., Maes J., Van Vliet J., Verburg P.H. Uncertainties in ecosystem service maps: a comparison on the european Scale. PLoS ONE. 2014;9 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0109643. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  44. Schulp C.J.E., Lautenbach S., Verburg P.H. Quantifying and mapping ecosystem services: demand and supply of pollination in the European Union. Ecol. Ind. 2014;36:131–141. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2013.07.014. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  45. Serna-Chavez H.M., Schulp C.J.E., van Bodegom P.M., Bouten W., Verburg P.H., Davidson M.D. A quantitative framework for assessing spatial flows of ecosystem services. Ecol. Ind. 2014;39:24–33. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2013.11.024. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  46. Sharps K., Masante D., Thomas A., Jackson B., Redhead J., May L., Prosser H., Cosby B., Emmett B., Jones L. Comparing strengths and weaknesses of three ecosystem services modelling tools in a diverse UK river catchment. Sci. Total Environ. 2017;584–585:118–130. doi: 10.1016/j.scitotenv.2016.12.160. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  47. Smithers R., Korkeala O., Whiteley G., Brace S., Holmes B. Customer UK Office for National Statistics. 2016. Valuing flood-regulation services for inclusion in the UK ecosystem accounts. Ricardo Energy & Environment. [Google Scholar]
  48. Stürck J., Poortinga A., Verburg P.H. Mapping ecosystem services: the supply and demand of flood regulation services in Europe. Ecol. Ind. 2014;38:198–211. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2013.11.010. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  49. Su W., Ye G., Yao S., Yang G. Urban land pattern impacts on floods in a New District of China. Sustainability. 2014;6:6488. [Google Scholar]
  50. Sutherland I.J., Villamagna A.M., Dallaire C.O., Bennett E.M., Chin A.T.M., Yeung A.C.Y., Lamothe K.A., Tomscha S.A., Cormier R. Undervalued and under pressure: a plea for greater attention toward regulating ecosystem services. Ecol. Indic. 2018;94:23–32. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2017.06.047. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  51. Syrbe R.-U., Grunewald K. Ecosystem service supply and demand – the challenge to balance spatial mismatches. Int. J. Biodivers. Sci., Ecosyst. Serv. Manage. 2017;13(2):148–161. doi: 10.1080/21513732.2017.1407362. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  52. Syrbe R.-U., Walz U. Spatial indicators for the assessment of ecosystem services: providing, benefiting and connecting areas and landscape metrics. Ecol. Ind. 2012;21:80–88. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2012.02.013. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  53. Syrbe R.-U., Schröter M., Grunewald K., Walz U., Burkhard B. What to map? In: Burkhard B., Maes J., editors. Mapping Ecosystem Services. Opensoft Publisher; Sofia, Bulgaria: 2017. [Google Scholar]
  54. UN, EC, FAO, IMF, OECD, World Bank, 2014a. System of Environmental-Economic Accounting 2012. Central Framework. Retrieved from http://unstats.un.org/unsd/envaccounting/seeaRev/SEEA_CF_Final_en.pdf.
  55. UN, EC, FAO, OECD, World Bank, 2014b. System of Environmental-Economic Accounting 2012. Experimental Ecosystem Accounting, United Nations, New York, USA.
  56. UN, 2017. Technical Recommendations in support of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting 2012 – Experimental Ecosystem Accounting. Retrieved from https://seea.un.org/sites/seea.un.org/files/technical_recommendations_in_support_of_the_seea_eea_final_white_cover.pdf.
  57. UNISDR, 2011. Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction: Revealing risk, redefining development United Nations, Geneva. Retrieved from.
  58. United States Department of Agriculture . USDA; Washington, D.C: 2004. National Engineering Handbook, Section 4: Hydrology, Soil Conservation Service. [Google Scholar]
  59. United States Department of Agriculture, 1986. Urban Hydrology for Small Watersheds. TR-55. Retrieved from https://www.nrcs.usda.gov/Internet/FSE_DOCUMENTS/stelprdb1044171.pdf.
  60. Vallecillo S., La Notte A., Polce C., Zulian G., Alexandris N., Ferrini S., Maes J. Publications Office of the European Union; Luxembourg: 2018. Ecosystem Services accounting: Part I – Outdoor Recreation and Crop Pollination, EUR 29024 EN. [Google Scholar]
  61. Vallecillo S., La Notte A., Zulian G., Ferrini S., Maes J. Ecosystem services accounts: valuing the actual flow of nature-based recreation from ecosystems to people. Ecol. Model. 2019;392:196–211. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2018.09.023. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  62. Villa F., Bagstad K.J., Voigt B., Johnson G.W., Portela R., Honzák M., Batker D. A methodology for adaptable and robust ecosystem services assessment. PLoS ONE. 2014;9 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0091001. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  63. Villamagna A.M., Angermeier P.L., Bennett E.M. Capacity, pressure, demand, and flow: a conceptual framework for analyzing ecosystem service provision and delivery. Ecol. Complexity. 2013;15:114–121. doi: 10.1016/j.ecocom.2013.07.004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  64. Wolff S., Schulp C.J.E., Verburg P.H. Mapping ecosystem services demand: a review of current research and future perspectives. Ecol. Ind. 2015;55:159–171. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2015.03.016. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  65. Zank B., Bagstad K.J., Voigt B., Villa F. Modeling the effects of urban expansion on natural capital stocks and ecosystem service flows: a case study in the Puget Sound, Washington, USA. Landscape Urban Plann. 2016;149:31–42. doi: 10.1016/j.landurbplan.2016.01.004. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  66. Zeng Z., Tang G., Hong Y., Zeng C., Yang Y. Development of an NRCS curve number global dataset using the latest geospatial remote sensing data for worldwide hydrologic applications. Remote Sens. Lett. 2017;8:528–536. doi: 10.1080/2150704x.2017.1297544. [DOI] [Google Scholar]

RESOURCES