Abstract
Public health decision makers value interventions for their effects on overall health and health inequality. Distributional cost-effectiveness analysis (DCEA) incorporates health inequality concerns into economic evaluation by accounting for how parameters, such as effectiveness, differ across population groups. A good understanding of how and when accounting for socioeconomic differences between groups affects the assessment of intervention impacts on overall health and health inequality could inform decision makers where DCEA would add most value. We interrogated 2 DCEA models of smoking and alcohol policies using first national level and then local authority level information on various socioeconomic differences in health and intervention use. Through a series of scenario analyses, we explored the impact of altering these differences on the DCEA results. When all available evidence on socioeconomic differences was incorporated, provision of a smoking cessation service was estimated to increase overall health and increase health inequality, while the screening and brief intervention for alcohol misuse was estimated to increase overall health and reduce inequality. Ignoring all or some socioeconomic differences resulted in minimal change to the estimated impact on overall health in both models; however, there were larger effects on the estimated impact on health inequality. Across the models, there were no clear patterns in how the extent and direction of socioeconomic differences in the inputs translated into the estimated impact on health inequality. Modifying use or coverage of either intervention so that each population group matched the highest level improved the impacts to a greater degree than modifying intervention effectiveness. When local level socioeconomic differences were considered, the magnitude of the impacts was altered; in some cases, the direction of impact on inequality was also altered.
Keywords: distributional cost-effectiveness analysis, economic evaluation, health inequality, public health
Cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) is routinely employed to inform health care resource allocation decisions.1 When allocating resources in public health, decision makers often consider how potential policies would improve population health and reduce unfair health inequalities (i.e., reduce the perceived unfairness of the distribution of health across the population).2,3 The decision about whether to fund a public health intervention is therefore informed by its impact on the distribution of health across the population, both in terms of its sum total and the extent of inequality between relevant population groups. The distributional cost-effectiveness analysis (DCEA) framework considers how interventions affect the distribution of health.4,5 It is used to estimate the net impact of an intervention on overall health and in each population group of interest and to examine the trade-offs between improving overall health and reducing health inequality.
To perform DCEA, the evaluation of costs and consequences of alternative interventions must account for differences between equity relevant groups.6 This requires evidence on how the parameters of the evaluation (e.g., the value of inputs to a decision analytic model) vary between groups. Lack of evidence on between-group differences can make it challenging to conduct a formal evaluation. Even when the evidence is available, a DCEA is more complex than a standard CEA, and policy makers may lack the resources to undertake DCEA in all circumstances. Developing greater understanding of how and when accounting for socioeconomic differences in model inputs affects the final estimate of the intervention impact on the distribution of health could enable us to identify a subset of parameters that are sufficient to inform the intervention impact, which may make it possible to simplify the DCEA process and help decision makers and analysts to know where DCEA would add most and when to gather further evidence on socioeconomic differences.
When appraising how an intervention affects health inequality, a common question is whether anything can be done to modify either the intervention itself or the way in which it is delivered to make it benefit population groups more fairly.7 For example, if uptake of the intervention is socially patterned, policy makers may ask whether it is worthwhile to invest in actions that increase uptake in lower socioeconomic groups. A breakdown showing how eliminating socioeconomic differences in each model input could alter the final distribution of health could help direct efforts to answer such questions.
In the United Kingdom, local authorities have the responsibility of making decisions about which public health interventions to fund for their local population. However, many appraisals of the potential interventions are performed and reported at a national level.8 The extent of socioeconomic differences in model inputs can vary between settings (e.g., the smoking prevalence by socioeconomic status within local authorities differs from the overall national figure).9 The population distribution between socioeconomic groups may also differ between settings. Consequently, evaluating the intervention impact based on national level estimates may not be informative for the impact that would be expected at a local level. Therefore, it may be relevant to local decision makers to understand how local level variation will alter estimated policy impacts compared with the national level estimates.
In this study, we adapted 2 existing DCEA models of public health interventions to address 4 broad questions:
How influential is failing to consider specific socioeconomic differences on the estimated intervention impacts on overall health and health inequality?
Which modifiable intervention characteristics represent the most valuable targets to mitigate socioeconomic differences in intervention impact?
How generalizable are conclusions about the intervention impacts on overall health and health inequality between areas with different characteristics?
What conclusions can we draw about the generalizability of the results of the 2 studies to other interventions or disease areas?
Methods
Overview
DCEA of smoking and alcohol policies were conducted using 2 existing models.10,11 Health benefits were expressed as quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) and costs in pounds sterling (£, 2018 price year) under a National Health Service (NHS) and personal social services perspective. An annual discount rate of 3.5% was applied to both benefits and costs in accordance with National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) guidance.12 The NICE cost-effectiveness threshold of £20,000 per QALY was used.13
In both models, we considered inequality between population groups defined according to the level of socioeconomic deprivation in individuals’ area of residence (i.e., Index of Multiple Deprivation [IMD]).14 IMD is an area-level weighted composite index combining information on income, employment, health, education, housing, crime, and living environment for a geographical area of approximately 1500 residents.14 As IMD is not an individual-level measure, there will be variation in the socioeconomic status of residents within each area, and even highly deprived areas will have some high socioeconomic status inhabitants. The population was divided into 5 groups defined by quintile of IMD, and differences in model inputs across IMD quintiles were characterized. Both models estimate the amount by which policies change health within each population group. Summing over the change in health across all 5 groups gives the total change in population health, expressed as population incremental net health benefit (NHB).1
Considering the general population’s preference for reducing health inequality between rich and poor groups, we can present the total population health as the equally distributed equivalent (EDE) health. To calculate this EDE health, the strength of preference for reducing inequality is used as a weight to provide a weighted total population health. EDE health can be interpreted as the amount of health distributed equally to all population groups that would be considered equally valuable to the distribution being evaluated.4 Given the preference for reducing existing health inequalities, the EDE is lower than the population health, and the difference describes the amount of overall health that people would be willing to sacrifice to achieve an equal distribution. Alternatively, the difference between the EDE and the total population health can be interpreted as the welfare cost of health inequality, as it represents the social value that could be gained if health were redistributed equally. A policy that leaves the total population health unchanged but reduces the difference in health between population groups will increase the EDE health. We expressed the policy impact on health inequality using the difference between how policies alter the EDE health (which increases with total health improvement and with reduction of inequality in health) and how policies alter total health (incremental NHB).
Scenario analyses were performed to explore how altering socioeconomic differences in model inputs affects the estimated impacts.
Models
The smoking model is a cohort Markov model that assesses the cost-effectiveness of nicotine replacement therapies in adult smokers (18–75 years) over a lifetime horizon.10 These therapies are accessed through primary care.10 The Markov model includes 3 mutually exclusive health states: smokers, former smokers, and death. Smokers and former smokers differ in mortality risk, health-related quality of life (HRQoL), and risk of developing 6 smoking-related diseases, modeled as events with an impact on costs and HRQoL. The Sheffield Alcohol Policy Model is a hybrid simulation consisting of 2 linked models that evaluates the cost-effectiveness of screening and brief interventions (SBIs) to reduce alcohol misuse.11 The first part of the model takes a baseline population of individual drinkers and simulates receipt of SBIs and the resulting age-adjusted trends in alcohol consumption over a 20-year time horizon. The second part of the model aggregates these individuals into cohorts based on age, gender, IMD quintile, and baseline drinking level. The model simulates 45 alcohol-related health conditions, which are linked to associated mortality rates and hospital admissions.
In this study, we focus on the provision of e-cigarette in the smoking model and the strategy of delivering SBIs to all patients when registering with a new primary care practice (“Next Registration”) in the alcohol model, both compared with “no intervention.”
Impact on Overall Health
The models estimate the incremental direct health benefits and incremental health care costs of the interventions, compared with no intervention, specific to smokers and alcohol users in each IMD quintile. Zero health benefit accrues to people who are not eligible for the interventions (i.e., non-smokers and those who do not misuse alcohol). The incremental costs are converted into health opportunity costs (i.e., the health that would have been achieved if those resources had been used for other purposes) using the NICE cost-effectiveness threshold. The health benefits of making resources available for other purposes will not fall equally to all socioeconomic groups. Research has shown that a greater proportion of the benefit from changes in NHS spending goes to more deprived groups. Deprived groups therefore lose out most when resources are appropriated for specific policies or conversely stand to gain the most when policies are cost saving and release resources.15 For each IMD quintile, the health opportunity costs are subtracted from the direct health benefits to provide the distribution of the incremental net health benefit (iNHB; i.e., the change in health by population group). The impact on overall health is the population iNHB (i.e., the sum of iNHB across all quintiles).
Impact on Health Inequality
The baseline distribution of health is the distribution of quality-adjusted life expectancy (QALE),16 which combines differences in life expectancy between groups with differences in quality of life between groups. The iNHB in each IMD quintile estimated for each intervention is added to the baseline QALE in each IMD quintile to estimate the predicted distribution of QALE following the implementation of the intervention. The QALE distribution is summarized as EDE health by using the Atkinson index, with an inequality aversion parameter derived from a UK population survey.17 The Atkinson inequality aversion parameter describes the strength of preference for reducing relative inequality in health. When applied to calculate the EDE, it assigns a higher weight to health improvements in more deprived groups that have lower baseline QALE and a lower weight to health improvements in less deprived groups with greater baseline QALE.18 The change from the EDE in the baseline health to the EDE of the health with the intervention (i.e., incremental EDE; iEDE) encompasses the impact of the intervention on both overall health and health inequality. To isolate the impact on health inequality, we look at the difference between iEDE and iNHB, with a positive value showing that the intervention reduces health inequality. We illustrate these calculations for the smoking model in Box 1.
Box 1.
Smoking Cessation Model
1. Extract the incremental direct health benefits (a) and the incremental health care costs (b) of e-cigarette versus “no intervention” from the smoking DCEA model for each IMD quintile in England. | ||||||
2. Sum the incremental costs (c) and then convert to health opportunity costs at a rate of £20,000 per QALY (d), | ||||||
i.e., £ (−156,391,946)/£20,000 = −7820 QALYs. | ||||||
3. Use the proportion of the health opportunity costs borne by each IMD quintile (e) to calculate the size of the health opportunity costs in each IMD quintile (f), e.g., health opportunity costs for IMD1 is −7820 × 0.26 = −2033 QALYs. | ||||||
4. Calculate the incremental NHB for each IMD quintile (g) by subtracting health opportunity costs from the incremental direct health benefits, e.g., the incremental NHB for IMD1 is 6560 − (−2033) = 8593 QALYs. | ||||||
5. Calculate the incremental NHB per capita by IMD quintile (i) using the distribution of the adult population of England (h), e.g., IMD1, the individual incremental NHB, is 8593/8,307,456 = 0.0010 QALYs. | ||||||
6. Add the individual incremental NHB to the baseline QALE (j) to calculate the QALE with the intervention by IMD quintile (k). | ||||||
7. Calculate EDE for the baseline QALE distribution (l) and the QALE distribution with the intervention (m) using the Atkinson social welfare function with an inequality aversion parameter, ε, of 10.95. | ||||||
hi = individual QALE for a person in IMD quintile i | ||||||
N = total population size | ||||||
ε = Atkinson inequality aversion parameter | ||||||
8. Calculate the population incremental EDE with the intervention (n), i.e., the difference of population EDE with the intervention and the population baseline EDE, where the population EDE is multiplying EDE by total population size. | ||||||
9. Calculate the population incremental NHB with the intervention (o), i.e., sum the incremental NHB across all quintiles. | ||||||
10. Calculate how the intervention changes health inequality (iEDE − iNHB) (p), i.e., 70,002 − 80,782 = −10,780 QALYs. | ||||||
IMD1 (Most Deprived) | IMD2 | IMD3 | IMD4 | IMD5 (Least Deprived) | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1. | (a) Incremental direct health benefits,a QALYs | 6560 | 15,619 | 13,201 | 19,350 | 18,233 |
(b) Incremental costs,a£ | −12,544,948 | −32,507,825 | −29,016,052 | −42,924,171 | −39,398,949 | |
2. | (c) Total incremental costs (sum of b), £ | −156,391,946 | ||||
(d) Total health opportunity costs (c/20,000), QALYs | −7820 | |||||
3. | (e) Proportion of health opportunity costsb | 0.26 | 0.22 | 0.22 | 0.16 | 0.14 |
(f) Health opportunity costs (d × e), QALYs | −2033 | −1720 | −1720 | −1251 | −1095 | |
4. | (g) Incremental NHB (a–f), QALYs | 8593 | 17,339 | 14,921 | 20,601 | 19,328 |
5. | (h) Population sizec | 8,307,456 | 8,863,275 | 8,790,681 | 8,657,257 | 8,376,275 |
(i) Individual iNHB (g/h), QALYs | 0.0010 | 0.0020 | 0.0017 | 0.0024 | 0.0023 | |
6. | (j) Baseline QALE (no intervention)d | 64.7 | 68.5 | 70.6 | 73.6 | 75.6 |
(k) QALE with e-cigarette (i + j) | 64.7010 | 68.5020 | 70.6017 | 73.6024 | 75.6023 | |
7. | (l) Baseline EDE, QALYs | 69.465 | ||||
8. | (m) EDE with the intervention, QALYs | 69.467 | ||||
(n) Population iEDE (m × sum of h – l × sum of h), QALYs | 70,002 | |||||
9. | (o) Impact on overall health (sum of g) | 80,782 | ||||
10. | (p) Impact on health inequality (n − o) | −10,780 |
DCEA, distributional cost-effectiveness analysis; EDE, equally distributed equivalent; iEDE, incremental equally distributed equivalent; IMD, Index of Multiple Deprivation; iNHB, incremental net health benefit; NHB, net health benefit; QALY, quality-adjusted life-years; QALE, quality-adjusted life expectancy.
Calculated using results from the model.
Love-Koh et al. Estimating social variation in the health effects of changes in healthcare expenditure. Medical Decision Making. 2020.
Office for National Statistics (ONS) mid-year population estimates 2017.
Love-Koh et al. The social distribution of health: estimating quality-adjusted life expectancy in England. Value Health. 2015.
Inequality in Model Inputs
Model inputs in which we reflect socioeconomic differences were categorized into 4 groups: background parameters, behaviors, health consequences of behavior, and intervention characteristics. The level and direction of inequality in these model inputs between population groups are summarized using the concentration index19 (Table 1). It ranges from −1 to 1, with negative values demonstrating higher values of the input in more deprived groups, whereas positive values demonstrate higher values in less deprived groups. The following sections give an overview of each category of input, and more detailed information is available in the Supplementary Appendix.
Table 1.
Category and Concentration Index of Model Inputs Incorporating Socioeconomic Difference
Category | Socioeconomic difference in: | Concentration Index |
---|---|---|
Background parameters (both models) | Baseline quality-adjusted life expectancy | 0.03 |
Health opportunity costs | −0.12 | |
Behaviors | Smoking: prevalence | −0.08 |
Alcohol: abstention from drinking | 0.06 | |
Alcohol: average weekly consumption | 0.03 | |
Alcohol: peak day consumption | 0.06 | |
Health consequences of behavior | Smoking: mortality | −0.08 |
Alcohol: mortality | −0.07 | |
Smoking-related diseases | −0.02 | |
Alcohol-related diseases | −0.05 | |
Smoking: health-related quality of life | 0.01 | |
Intervention characteristics | Smoking: intervention effectiveness (quit smoking) | 0.04 |
Smoking: intervention uptake | 0.17 | |
Alcohol: individuals screened for alcohol misuse | −0.01 | |
Alcohol: probability of screening positive | −0.01 |
Background Parameters
Background parameters reflect the level of health that would be observed without interventions, including the baseline QALE16 and health opportunity costs.15 Baseline QALE is higher in less deprived areas, and more health opportunity costs fall on residents in more deprived areas (Table 1).
Behaviors
Behaviors including smoking prevalence and abstention from drinking by IMD quintile were based on survey data. The smoking model incorporated the proportion of smokers in each IMD quintile.9 The alcohol model incorporated socioeconomic differences in abstention from drinking, average weekly consumption, and peak day drinking. People in more deprived groups were more likely to smoke but less likely to drink, drink less on average, and binge drink at lower levels (Table 1).
Health Consequences of Behavior
Health consequences of behavior include mortality, related diseases, and HRQoL. In the smoking model, the annual mortality rates for smokers (Supplementary Figure S1) were based on general population all-cause mortality20; proportion of smokers, former smokers, and nonsmokers21; and the increased relative risk of death for smokers.22 Mortality in the alcohol model was modeled separately by health condition, including alcohol-related mortality and all other causes combined (Supplementary Figure S2). In both models, there was a higher death rate in more deprived areas (Table 1).
The socioeconomic difference in the smoking-related diseases was estimated using the average population incidence21 and the relative risk between IMD quintiles of developing smoking-related disease.23 We assumed that the middle IMD quintile (i.e., IMD3) was represented by the average incidence of smoking-related disease and then applied relative risks to estimate the incidence in other IMD quintiles. Data on alcohol-related diseases were obtained from individual hospital records. People living in more deprived areas were more likely to develop smoking- and alcohol-related diseases (Table 1).
The smoking model included HRQoL for smokers and former smokers by IMD quintile, estimated from survey data by linear regression (details available in Supplementary Table S6). People living in less deprived areas tended to have higher HRQoL (Table 1). The same decrement in HRQoL for each smoking-related disease was applied across all IMD quintiles, as no evidence was identified to inform differential effects. In the alcohol model, separate HRQoL values were applied for each alcohol-related health condition for each age-sex subgroup,24 with no evidence available for differences by IMD quintile.
In both models, the health care costs associated with disease-related events were not differentiated by IMD, as we did not identify evidence that would let us impose a different health care costs per health event by deprivation.
Intervention Characteristics
Socioeconomic differences in intervention impact were incorporated in both models. In the smoking model, the socioeconomic difference in effectiveness (Supplementary Table S7) was incorporated assuming that the middle quintile was represented by the average quit rate for the intervention25 and then applying the relative risk of quitting between IMD quintiles.26 The socioeconomic difference in intervention uptake was based on the proportion of smokers supplied with an NHS Stop Smoking Service.21 In the alcohol model, we did not consider socioeconomic difference in the intervention effect because of the lack of clear evidence but incorporated the difference in the access to the intervention. This consists of an initial step in which individuals attending primary care were selected to be screened, informed by the rates at which individuals register with new general practitioner practices,27 (Supplementary Table S8) and a second step in which those identified as drinking at potentially risky levels (screen positive) receive an intervention, estimated using the Alcohol Toolkit Study28 (Supplementary Table S9). The concentration indices show higher effectiveness and uptake of smoking cessation in less deprived areas, whereas those for alcohol interventions show higher screening coverage and screening positive in more deprived areas (Table 1).
Local Authority Level Inputs
To contrast national level results to local area results, we selected two local authorities with distinct socioeconomic profiles (smoking: York and Sheffield; alcohol: Liverpool and Trafford). More residents in York and Trafford lived in the least deprived quintile as compared with England as a whole, while in Sheffield and Liverpool, more residents were living in the most deprived quintile (Supplementary Figures S3 and S4).29 The smoking model used local information on smoking prevalence only (Supplementary Figure S5), while the alcohol model included local information on mortality and morbidity rates from alcohol-related diseases, the abstention of drinking, and mean weekly alcohol consumption (Supplementary Figure S6). The remaining differences for other parameters were based on national level figures in the absence of relevant data.
Analysis
A series of scenario analyses was performed to explore the impact of altering the socioeconomic differences in model inputs on DCEA results, corresponding to the 4 questions raised in introduction. The intervention impacts estimated in each scenario analysis were compared with the base case estimates, which constitute the results when all of the socioeconomic differences in the model inputs mentioned previously are incorporated. We assume that the base case represents the best estimate of the intervention impacts. The base case results and the results of each scenario analysis are presented as scatter plots on the health equity impact plane.3 The differences from the base case reflect in which direction and to what extent each scenario affects how well each model estimates the intervention impact on the distribution of health.
Question (a): all model inputs were set to the population average value in all IMD quintiles. This is equivalent to a standard CEA in which only the average population impact on overall health is calculated. It was expected that ignoring all socioeconomic differences would have minimal effect on the estimated impact on overall health but a larger effect on the impact on health inequality. We then excluded socioeconomic difference in one model input at a time and compared the model outputs with the base case estimates. This illustrates to what degree ignoring socioeconomic difference in each model input would affect the estimates of impacts on overall health and health inequality.
Question (b): the model inputs we identified as potentially modifiable intervention characteristics were set to the highest level achieved in any of the groups to explore the value of “leveling up” to eliminate the differences. In the smoking model, all groups were assumed to have the highest probability of quitting smoking and highest intervention uptake rate. In the alcohol model, the alcohol misuse screening coverage was assumed to go up to the highest level across all quintiles within the same age-sex group (“age-sex max”) and also the highest across all age-sex-deprivation groups (“global max”).
Question (c): the model inputs reflecting socioeconomic differences at the local level were incorporated to estimate the base case results for 2 local authorities in each model. To enable comparisons across areas that differ in population size, the intervention impacts for 100,000 adults were presented. The base case results at the local level were compared between local authorities and to the results for the nation as a whole.
Question (d): as the 2 models evaluated different interventions in different disease areas, we compared the results of the above-mentioned analyses in the 2 models to assess how the conclusions might vary between models. In addition, for analyses in addressing question (a), we rearranged the results by plotting the changes in the estimated impacts against the concentration index of the model input that was ignored and then compared these across both models to explore the possible patterns between the extent of inequality of model inputs and the variations in estimated impacts on overall health and health inequality.
Results
The results of the base case and scenario analyses are summarized in Table 2 and plotted in Figures 1 and 2. These base case estimates indicate that compared with no intervention, e-cigarette was estimated to increase overall health (iNHB = 80,782 QALYs) but increase health inequality (iEDE – iNHB = −10,780 QALYs), whereas the alcohol Next Registration strategy was estimated to increase overall health (iNHB = 4336 QALYs) and reduce inequality (iEDE – iNHB = 444 QALYs; Table 2).
Table 2.
Estimates of Impacts on Overall Health and Health Inequality in Base Case and Scenario Analysis
iNHB | Change in iNHB from Base Case | iEDE | Change in iEDE from Base Case | Inequality (iEDE − iNHB) |
Change in inequality impact from base case | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Smoking model (e-cigarette v. no intervention) | |||||||
Base case | 80,782 | − | 70,002 | −10,780 | Increase inequality | ||
(a) Ignoring all differences | 80,510 | −272 (−0.34%) | 80,510 | 10,508 (15.01%) | 0 | Smaller increase | |
(b) Ignoring difference in: | Baseline QALE | 80,782 | 0 (0%) | 80,781 | 10,779 (15.40%) | −1 | Smaller increase |
Health opportunity costs | 80,782 | 0 (0%) | 69,019 | −983 (−1.40%) | −11,763 | Larger increase | |
Smoking prevalence | 85,683 | 4902 (6.07%) | 69,454 | −548 (−0.78%) | −16,229 | Larger increase | |
Mortality | 79,543 | −1239 (−1.53%) | 70,261 | 259 (0.37%) | −9282 | Smaller increase | |
Smoking-related diseases | 82,418 | 1636 (2.03%) | 70,853 | 851 (1.22%) | −11,564 | Larger increase | |
HRQoL | 80,628 | −153 (−0.19%) | 70,053 | 51 (0.07%) | −10,575 | Smaller increase | |
Effectiveness | 77,236 | −3546 (−4.39%) | 69,942 | −60 (−0.09%) | −7294 | Smaller increase | |
Uptake | 80,436 | −345 (−0.43%) | 81,463 | 11,461 (16.37%) | 1027 | Inequality-reducing | |
(c) Leveling up to the best in: | Effectiveness | 88,229 | 7448 (9.22%) | 79,929 | 9927 (14.18%) | −8300 | Smaller increase |
Uptake | 109,656 | 28,875 (35.74%) | 111,057 | 41,055 (58.65%) | 1400 | Inequality-reducing | |
Alcohol model (“Next Registration” v. no intervention) | |||||||
Base case | 4336 | — | 4780 | — | 444 | Reduce inequality | |
(a) Ignoring all differences | 4083 | −253 (−5.83%) | 3580 | −1199 (−25.08%) | −503 | Increases inequality | |
(b) Ignoring difference in: | Baseline QALE | 4336 | 0 (0%) | 4336 | −444 (−9.29%) | 0 | Smaller reduction |
Health opportunity costs | 4336 | 0 (0%) | 4989 | 209 (+4.37%) | 652 | Larger reduction | |
Abstention | 3947 | −389 (−8.97%) | 4125 | −655 (−13.7%) | 178 | Smaller reduction | |
Mortality | 4530 | 194 (+4.47%) | 4565 | −215 (−4.5%) | 35 | Smaller reduction | |
Alcohol-related diseases | 4856 | 519 (+11.97%) | 4645 | −135 (−2.82%) | −211 | Inequality-increasing | |
Average weekly consumption | 5092 | 756 (+17.44%) | 6253 | 1474 (+30.84%) | 1162 | Larger reduction | |
Peak day consumption | 4724 | 388 (+8.95%) | 5421 | 642 (+13.43%) | 698 | Larger reduction | |
Screening coverage | 4493 | 157 (+3.62%) | 5492 | 713 (+14.92%) | 999 | Larger reduction | |
Screening positive (risky level) | 4803 | 466 (+10.75%) | 5512 | 732 (+15.31%) | 709 | Larger reduction | |
(c) Leveling up to the best in: | Screening rates (age-sex max) | 4817 | 480 (+11.07%) | 6213 | 1433 (+29.98%) | 1397 | Larger reduction |
Screening rates (global max) | 17,893 | 13,556 (+312.64%) | 22,141 | 17,361 (+363.2%) | 4248 | Larger reduction |
HRQoL, health-related quality of life; iEDE, incremental equally distributed equivalent health; iNHB, incremental net health benefit; QALE, quality-adjusted life expectancy.
Figure 1.
Health equity impact plane showing scenario analysis results in which socioeconomic differences are ignored. (a) Smoking model. (b) Alcohol model. In the health equity plane, the y-axis is the increase in population health, and the x-axis is the reduction in health inequality. Interventions that improve overall health fall in the north of the plane. Interventions that reduce inequality fall in the east of the plane. E-cigarette was estimated to increase overall health and increase inequality, so it is located in the northwest quadrant. “Next Registration” was estimated to increase overall health and reduce inequality, so it is located in the northeast quadrant. Compared with the base case, if the location of the result in the scenario analysis moves upward on the y-axis, the model estimates more health improvement; if the location moves toward the right side on the x-axis, the model estimates less inequality. For example, in the smoking model, the result of ignoring the socioeconomic difference in effectiveness moves downward and to the right, which indicates less health improvement and less inequality compared with the base case.
Figure 2.
Health equity impact plane showing scenario analysis results when leveling up to the best. (a) Smoking model. (b) Alcohol model. Compared with the base case, if the location of the result in the scenario analysis moves upward on the y-axis, the model estimates more health improvement; if the location moves toward the right side on the x-axis, the model estimates less inequality. For example, in the smoking model, the result of leveling up uptake moves upward and to the right, which indicates more health improvement and less inequality compared with the base case. The location of “uptake” is in the northeast quadrant, indicating the intervention is estimated to reduce inequality.
(a) How Influential Is Failing to Consider Socioeconomic Differences?
Ignoring socioeconomic differences in all model inputs
Compared with the base case, ignoring socioeconomic differences in all model inputs reduced the amount by which the interventions were predicted to increase overall health (smoking model: −272 QALYs, −0.34%; alcohol model: −253 QALYs, −5.83%; Table 2); e-cigarette was predicted to have no effect on inequality, and the alcohol Next Registration strategy was predicted to increase inequality (Table 2; Figure 1).
Ignoring socioeconomic difference in one model input
Compared with the base case, in the smoking model, ignoring the socioeconomic difference in smoking prevalence resulted in the greatest increase in the estimated overall health impact (4902 QALYs, 6.07% greater than the total in base case), while ignoring the difference in intervention effectiveness resulted in the greatest reduction (−3,546 QALYs, −4.39%; Table 2). In the alcohol model, ignoring the socioeconomic difference in mean alcohol consumption resulted in the greatest increase in the estimated overall health impact (756 QALYs, 17.44%), while ignoring the difference in drinking prevalence resulted in the greatest reduction (−389 QALYs, −8.97%; Table 2).
In the smoking model, ignoring the socioeconomic differences in health opportunity costs, smoking prevalence, and risk of smoking-related diseases increased the extent by which the intervention was estimated to increase inequality, whereas ignoring socioeconomic differences in baseline QALE, mortality risks, HRQoL, effectiveness, and uptake reduced this extent (with removal of the socioeconomic difference in uptake making e-cigarette inequality reducing) compared with the base case (Figure 1a). In the alcohol model, ignoring the socioeconomic differences in average weekly consumption, peak day consumption, screening coverage, likelihood of screening positive, and the health opportunity costs increased the extent by which the intervention was estimated to reduce inequality, while ignoring the socioeconomic differences in abstention from drinking, alcohol-related diseases, and mortality rates reduced it (with removal of the socioeconomic difference in morbidity making the strategy inequality increasing; Figure 1b).
(b) Which Modifiable Intervention Characteristics Represent the Most Value?
Leveling up the effectiveness and uptake of the smoking cessation intervention increased the estimated overall health impact by 7448 QALYs (9.22%) and 28,875 QALYs (35.74%), respectively, and reduced the extent by which it was predicted to increase inequality, with leveling up uptake making e-cigarette inequality reducing as compared with the base case (Table 2; Figure 2a).
In the alcohol model, increasing coverage of the Next Registration strategy to the age-sex specific maximum level increased the estimated improvement in overall health by 480 QALYs (11.07%) and increased the extent by which it was estimated to reduce inequality, and increasing the coverage to population maximum level increased the estimated improvement in overall health by 13,556 QALYs (312.64%) and reduced health inequality to a much greater extent (Table 2; Figure 2b).
(c) How Generalizable Are Conclusions between Settings?
Results per 100,000 adults for each setting are presented in Figure 3. In the smoking model, using local level evidence, e-cigarette was estimated to improve overall health in England, York, and Sheffield with different magnitudes of impacts (Figure 3a); it was estimated to increase inequality in Sheffield and England but reduce inequality in York (Figure 3a). The alcohol Next Registration strategy was estimated to increase overall health and reduce inequality in England and both local authorities, but the greatest increase in overall health was in Liverpool, and the greatest reduction in health inequality was in Trafford (Figure 3b).
Figure 3.
Equity impact plane showing the overall health and health inequality for local authority analysis. (a) Smoking model. (b) Alcohol model. Compared with the base case, if the location of the result in the scenario analysis moves upward on the y-axis, the model estimates more health improvement; if the location moves toward the right side on the x-axis, the model estimates less inequality. For example, in the smoking model, the result for Sheffield moves upward and to the left, which indicates more health improvement and more inequality, compared with the result for England.
(d) How Generalizable Are the Results between Models and Disease Areas?
The concentration index of each model input and the amount by which ignoring it alters the estimated intervention impacts on overall health and health inequality is plotted in Supplementary Figure S7 and Figure 4, respectively. In both models, there was no clear pattern relating inequality of the model input to how it alters the estimated impact on overall health (Supplementary Figure S7). In the smoking model, there was a positive correlation between the concentration index and the impact of ignoring socioeconomic differences in that input on the estimated health inequality impact as compared with the base case (Figure 4a). Ignoring the socioeconomic differences in model inputs that are more concentrated on the less deprived (positive concentration index values) increases the amount by which the intervention is estimated to reduce inequality, while ignoring the socioeconomic differences in model inputs concentrated on the more deprived results (negative concentration index values) decreases it. However, this pattern was not clearly observed in the alcohol model (Figure 4b).
Figure 4.
Impact on health inequality versus concentration index where socioeconomic differences are ignored. (a) Smoking model. (b) Alcohol model.
Discussion
Evidence on how the impacts of policies vary across population groups is vital to inform decisions that rest on consideration of impacts on overall health and health inequality. By interrogating 2 different DCEA models that feature opposite effects on inequality, we demonstrated how the evidence for socioeconomic differences in policy impact could be evaluated within a DCEA framework, which represents a form of stratified CEA. Good understanding of how and when accounting for socioeconomic differences between groups affects the assessment of intervention impacts on overall health and health inequality could advise researchers as to whether it is possible to simplify the DCEA process and inform decision makers where DCEA would add most value.
First, we found that failing to consider socioeconomic differences would affect the estimated policy impacts to a different degree between the 2 models. It has a more minor influence on the estimated overall health impact in the smoking model and a greater influence in the nonlinear alcohol model (smoking model: −0.34% alcohol model: −5.83%). As anticipated, it greatly affected the estimated impact on health inequality, influencing not only the magnitude but also the direction of effect (smoking: increase inequality to no effect; alcohol: reduce inequality to increase inequality). Ignoring socioeconomic differences in just one input can have a substantial effect on the results, but we found no clear relationship that might predict which model inputs are most influential.
Second, leveling up modifiable intervention characteristics to the highest level achieved in any subgroup would improve the estimated health inequality impact to the direction that favors the interventions. It also increases the estimated overall health impact, so it would not impose a trade-off between improvement in overall health and reduction in inequality. Socioeconomic variation in smoking cessation uptake appears a more valuable target for modification than socioeconomic variation in effectiveness. This could inform decision makers where to focus efforts to make policies benefit population groups more fairly. It should be noted that such efforts usually attract additional costs, and further analysis would be needed to explore whether the benefits are worthwhile.
Third, the magnitude of impacts on overall health and health inequality at one local authority was different compared with that at another local authority or the nation as a whole. In the smoking model, the direction of the impact was also different (e-cigarette was estimated to reduce inequality in York but to increase inequality measured across England and Sheffield). The inconsistency in the policy impacts between settings is likely to be driven by the different deprivation structures of the populations and the local level socioeconomic differences. This suggests that caution should be taken when generalizing recommendations of interventions from the national level to local authorities and between local authorities differing in deprivation structure of the population and other model inputs. Prioritization and local level decision making could be better supported by conducting and reporting analyses that reflect differences relevant to the local context.
The conclusions that can be drawn from this study are limited as they are based on only 2 models. Although both decision models have been used to support real resource allocation decisions in the UK, the base case results may omit potential socioeconomic differences in inputs where evidence was not available. For example, if disease-related events require more resource use for treatment or impose a greater quality-of-life decrement in more deprived groups, the socioeconomic differences in health care costs and health-related quality of life would be underestimated. In view of this, sensitivity analyses of more DCEA models can be combined with the results from our analysis to further our understanding of how influential it is to consider socioeconomic differences in different types of model input on the estimated policy impacts. We have not considered alternative interventions or designs of the interventions (e.g., extra efforts on targeting disadvantaged groups), which would be expected to have alternative impacts on inequalities, but there is scope for the use of DCEA and other methods to help inform how best to design interventions to impact on inequality. In addition, the evidence on socioeconomic differences in model inputs is associated with uncertainty. The smoking model incorporated this uncertainty, which could be analyzed with a probabilistic sensitivity analysis, to provide credible intervals around estimated policy impacts. However, the computing time for the individual simulation alcohol model was already high and did not allow for probabilistic sensitivity analysis. Consequently, we did not compare the influence of uncertainty across the 2 models.
The results presented in this study indicate that between-group differences in patterns of disease, intervention efficacy, and intervention use can combine and interact in a complex manner and produce results that are difficult to predict. Thus, a formal analysis of inequality impact, such as that provided by a full DCEA, can be beneficial in guiding resource allocation decisions. In practice, the decision on whether to conduct a DCEA or some other form of stratified analysis may be informed by qualitative approaches, similar to those used in the integrated health technology assessment (HTA) process.30 A number of other methods have been proposed in the literature for including health inequality concerns in economic evaluation, for example, the extended CEA,31 but these methods would rely on the same evidence on socioeconomic differences used here5 and do not use inequality indices to explicitly analyze trade-offs between improving health and reducing health inequality. Although we have seen in this study that additional work is needed to conduct the DCEA and the approach would increase complexity and introduce uncertainty, the applications of DCEA have shown that it is feasible to implement within a typical HTA process, and the skills required lie within the capabilities of analysts currently conducting CEA.4 The trade-offs between health improvement and inequality reduction, informed by a full DCEA, would assist decision makers to clarify and quantify the nature of their inequality concerns and provide better ways of communicating findings to wider audiences.4
Conclusions
By conducting 2 case studies, one assessing smoking cessation intervention and the other assessing alcohol screening and brief intervention, we found that conclusions about their impact on health inequality are strongly influenced by socioeconomic differences in model inputs, but not in an easy way to predict. This affirms the potential value for increasing the extent of formal and quantitative analysis of health inequality impacts to inform resource allocation decisions. Our study also suggests the need for better consideration of the diversity in deprivation structure, epidemiology, and access to services across settings.
Supplemental Material
Supplemental material, 5.appendices-200302.rjf_online_supp for Impact of Socioeconomic Differences on Distributional Cost-Effectiveness Analysis by Fan Yang, Colin Angus, Ana Duarte, Duncan Gillespie, Simon Walker and Susan Griffin in Medical Decision Making
The work was undertaken at the Centre for Health Economics, University of York, and the Sheffield Alcohol Research Group, Health Economics and Decision Science, ScHARR, University of Sheffield; the work was presented at Society for Social Medicine & Population Health Annual Scientific Meeting 2019.
The authors disclosed receipt of the following financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article: Financial support for this study was provided entirely by a grant from Public Health Research Consortium (PHRC). The funding agreement ensured the authors’ independence in designing the study, interpreting the data, writing, and publishing the report.
ORCID iDs: Fan Yang https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4689-265X
Ana Duarte https://orcid.org/0000-0002-0528-4773
Supplemental Material: Supplementary material for this article is available on the Medical Decision Making Web site at http://journals.sagepub.com/home/mdm.
Contributor Information
Fan Yang, Centre for Health Economics, University of York, UK.
Colin Angus, Sheffield Alcohol Research Group, Health Economics and Decision Science, ScHARR, University of Sheffield, UK.
Ana Duarte, Centre for Health Economics, University of York, UK.
Duncan Gillespie, Sheffield Alcohol Research Group, Health Economics and Decision Science, ScHARR, University of Sheffield, UK.
Simon Walker, Centre for Health Economics, University of York, UK.
Susan Griffin, Centre for Health Economics, University of York, UK.
References
- 1. Drummond MF, Sculpher MJ, Torrance GW, O’Brien BJ, Stoddart GL. Methods for the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programmes. 3rd ed. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
- 2. Marmot M, Allen J, Bell R, Bloomer E, Goldblatt P, Consortium for the European Review of Social Determinants of Health and the Health Divide, et al. WHO European review of social determinants of health and the health divide. Lancet. 2012;380(9846):1011–29. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 3. Cookson R, Drummond M, Weatherly H. Explicit incorporation of equity considerations into economic evaluation of public health interventions. Health Econ Policy Law. 2009;4(pt 2):231–45. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 4. Asaria M, Griffin S, Cookson R. Distributional cost-effectiveness analysis: a tutorial. Med Decis Making. 2016;36(1):8–19. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 5. Asaria M, Griffin S, Cookson R, Whyte S, Tappenden P. Distributional cost-effectiveness analysis of health care programmes—a methodological case study of the UK Bowel Cancer Screening Programme. Health Econ. 2015; 24(6):742–54. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6. Love-Koh J, Cookson R, Gutacker N, Patton T, Griffin S. Aggregate distributional cost-effectiveness analysis of health technologies. Value Health. 2019;22(5):518–26. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 7. White M, Adams J, Heywood P. How and why do interventions that increase health overall widen inequalities within populations. In: Babones S, ed. Health, Inequality and Society. Bristol, UK: Policy Press; 2009. p 65–82. [Google Scholar]
- 8. National Institute for Health and Care Excellence. Public Health Guidance. 2019. Available from: https://www.nice.org.uk/guidance/published?type=ph
- 9.Public Health England. Local tobacco control profiles. 2019. Available from: https://fingertips.phe.org.uk/profile/tobacco-control
- 10. York Health Economics Consortium. Smoking Cessation Interventions and Services. 2018. Available from: https://www.nice.org.uk/guidance/ng92/evidence/economic-modelling-report-pdf-4790596573 [Google Scholar]
- 11. Purshouse RC, Brennan A, Rafia R, et al. Modelling the cost-effectiveness of alcohol screening and brief interventions in primary care in England. Alcohol Alcohol. 2013;48(2):180–8. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 12. National Institute for Health and Care Excellence. Guide to the Methods of Technology Appraisal 2013. April 4, 2013. Available from: ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/NBK395867/pdf/Bookshelf_NBK395867.pdf [PubMed]
- 13. Earnshaw J, Lewis G. NICE Guide to the Methods of Technology Appraisal. New York: Springer; 2008. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 14. Department for Communities and Local Government. The English Indices of Deprivation 2015. Statistical Release. Available from: https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/465791/English_Indices_of_Deprivation_2015_-_Statistical_Release.pdf
- 15. Love-Koh J, Cookson R, Claxton K, Griffin S. Estimating social variation in the health effects of changes in health care expenditure. Med Decis Making. 2020. doi:272989X20904360. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 16. Love-Koh J, Asaria M, Cookson R, Griffin S. The social distribution of health: estimating quality-adjusted life expectancy in England. Value Health. 2015;18(5):655–62. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 17. Atkinson AB. On the measurement of inequality. J Econ Theory. 1970;2(3):244–63. [Google Scholar]
- 18. Robson M, Asaria M, Cookson R, Tsuchiya A, Ali S. Eliciting the level of health inequality aversion in England. Health Econ. 2017;26(10):1328–34. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 19. O’Donnell O, Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Lindelow M. Analyzing Health Equity Using Household Survey Data: A Guide to Techniques and Their Implementation. Washington, DC: The World Bank; 2007. [Google Scholar]
- 20. Office for National Statistics. Number of deaths and populations in deprivation decile areas by sex and single year of age, England and Wales, registered years 2001 to 2017. Available from: https://www.ons.gov.uk/peoplepopulationandcommunity/birthsdeathsandmarriages/deaths/adhocs/009299numberofdeathsandpopulationsindeprivationdecileareasbysexandsingleyearofageenglandandwalesregisteredyears2001to2017
- 21. Love-Koh J, Pennington R, Owen L, Griffin S. Frameworks for considering health inequalities and their suitability for use within NICE public health guidelines. Unpublished report. 2018. [Google Scholar]
- 22. Doll R, Peto R. Mortality in relation to smoking: 20 years’ observations on male British doctors. Br Med J. 1976;2(6051):1525–36. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23. Eberth B, Olajide D, Craig P, Ludbrook A. Smoking-related disease risk, area deprivation and health behaviours. J Public Health (Oxf). 2014;36(1):72–80. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 24. Purshouse R, Brennan A, Latimer N, et al. Modelling to assess the effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of public health related strategies and intervention to reduce alcohol attributable harm in England using the Sheffield Alcohol Policy Model version 2. 2009. Available from: https://www.nice.org.uk/guidance/ph24/evidence/economic-modelling-report-371533357
- 25. Caponnetto P, Campagna D, Cibella F, et al. EffiCiency and Safety of an eLectronic cigAreTte (ECLAT) as tobacco cigarettes substitute: a prospective 12-month randomized control design study. PLoS One. 2013;8(6):e66317. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 26. Dobbie F, Hiscock R, Leonardi-Bee J, et al. Evaluating Long-term Outcomes of NHS Stop Smoking Services (ELONS): a prospective cohort study. Health Technol Assess. 2015;19(95):1–156. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 27. Weir S, Juhasz A, Puelles J, Tierney TS. Relationship between initial therapy and blood pressure control for high-risk hypertension patients in the UK: a retrospective cohort study from the THIN general practice database. BMJ Open. 2017;7(7):e015527. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 28. Beard E, Brown J, West R, et al. Protocol for a national monthly survey of alcohol use in England with 6-month follow-up: ‘the Alcohol Toolkit Study’. BMC Public Health. 2015;15:230. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 29. Public Health England. Local authority health profiles. Available from: https://fingertips.phe.org.uk/profile/health-profiles
- 30. Wahlster P, Brereton L, Burns J, et al. An integrated perspective on the assessment of technologies: Integrate-Hta. Int J Technol Assess Health Care. 2017;33(5):544–51. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 31. Verguet S, Laxminarayan R, Jamison DT. Universal public finance of tuberculosis treatment in India: an extended cost-effectiveness analysis. Health Econ. 2015;24(3):318–32. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Supplementary Materials
Supplemental material, 5.appendices-200302.rjf_online_supp for Impact of Socioeconomic Differences on Distributional Cost-Effectiveness Analysis by Fan Yang, Colin Angus, Ana Duarte, Duncan Gillespie, Simon Walker and Susan Griffin in Medical Decision Making