Abstract
From mid‐January to March 2020, 3M masks sold on Amazon by third party sellers were priced 2.4 times higher than Amazon's 2019 price. However, this price increase was not uniform across sellers. We estimate that when Amazon is stocked out (one of our measures of scarcity) new (entrant) sellers increase price by 178%, whereas the continuing sellers' increase is limited to 56.7%. This is consistent with the idea that seller reputation limits the extent of profitable price gouging. Similar results are obtained for Purell hand sanitizer and for other measures of scarcity. We also explore policy implications of our results.
Keywords: Amazon, COVID‐19, price gouging
Abbreviations
- AG
attorneys general
- CSR
corporate social responsibility
- ROW
rest of the world
1. INTRODUCTION
In the wake of unexpected negative supply shocks—or positive demand shocks—prices tend to surge. Many economists find such price hikes normal and in fact efficient: it is the law of supply and demand at work (e.g., Culpepper & Block, 2008). By contrast, most of the world accuses sellers of price gouging and clamors for laws protecting buyers from unfair pricing. For example, in the aftermath of Hurricane Sandy, which struck the United States in October 2012, New Jersey authorities filed civil suits accusing seven gas stations and one hotel of price gouging. Meanwhile, Libertarian TV personality John Stossel was inviting his readers to “hug a price gouger” today.
The tension between efficiency and fairness has existed for as long as economic relations have existed. It is not our goal to resolve this tension—nor would we have the ability to do so. Instead, we are interested in a third possibility, a third way between the efficiency‐only and the fairness‐only extremes, namely the possibility that the seller reputation may act as a moderator of the “price gouging” forces. The use of quotation marks reflects the difficulty of defining price gouging, both in economics and in legal terms. 1 For our purposes, we are interested in sudden and large jumps in price resulting from a disaster‐related supply or demand shock.
The idea that a seller reputation affects the seller's actions is not new. For example, Cabral and Hortaçsu (2010) show that higher reputation eBay sellers exert greater effort to satisfy consumers, as they have more to lose from tarnishing their reputation. 2 The idea that fairness standards matter for price setting is also not new. For example, Kahneman et al. (1986) argue that
Even in the absence of government intervention, the actions of firms that wish to avoid a reputation for unfairness will depart in significant ways from the standard model of economic behavior.
The goal of this article is to develop these ideas in the context of the COVID‐19 pandemic and the multiple cases of online price gouging that followed. Specifically, we test the idea that firms with higher reputation levels have more to lose from being perceived as unfair, and thus are less likely to price gouge. We are not the first to formulate this hypothesis. In the wake of the Hurricane Sandy crisis, Cowen (2017) argued that
The reluctance to raise prices is especially strong for nationally branded stores. A local merchant may not care much if people in Iowa are upset at his prices, but major companies will fear damage to their national reputations. The short‐term return from selling the water at a higher price is dwarfed by the risk to their business prospects.
In the example considered by Cowen (2017), high reputation is associated with being a national brand (as opposed to a local brand). We consider two online equivalents of the distinction between sellers who have a lot to lose and sellers who do not. First, we would expect that, all else equal, incumbent sellers—that is, continuing sellers—have more to lose than entrants, where the latter are defined as sellers who only start selling after the demand shock takes place. Second, we would expect that large sellers, which we define as sellers with a greater number of consumer reviews, have more to lose than small sellers.
We construct a dataset of prices, measures of seller reputation, and indicators of excess demand. To account for endogeneity issues, we use time series of number of COVID‐19 cases and number of COVID‐19‐related deaths as instruments of demand and number of competitors. We then test that the price coefficient on the excess demand variable is decreasing on seller reputation, as implicitly predicted by Cabral and Hortaçsu (2010) and Kahneman et al. (1986). The results conform with theory: Higher‐reputation firms are less likely to take advantage of shortages of supply. The effect is statistically and economically significant. Depending on the measure of scarcity we use, we estimate that a one‐standard deviation increase in scarcity leads incumbents to increase price by 27–69%, whereas entrants increase price by 84–141%. We always find economically and statistically significant moderating effects of seller reputation. That said, our analysis also suggests that these reputation effects are insufficient to completely limit the extent of price hikes.
As often is the case with empirical research of this type, our results come with a number of caveats. First, as mentioned earlier, it is difficult to come up with a precise definition of price gouging. 3 Sudden price increases could simply result from sudden cost increases, with margins remaining the same or even decreasing. Second, the differential effect of scarcity on prices could be driven by fear of prosecution rather than reputation. We would not find evidence that larger online sellers are more likely to be censured by Amazon or sued by state authorities, but this would be an alternative interpretation of our results. Third, we make no claim that the role played by seller reputation is welfare‐enhancing, for the same reason that we do not provide a solution to the difficult balance between the costs and benefits of price gouging.
In addition to Cabral and Hortaçsu (2010) and Kahneman et al. (1986), Akerlof (1980), is also germane to our article. He considers the puzzle of involuntary unemployment and proposes a solution based on the idea that employers are reluctant to lower wages to the market equilibrium level. The employer's fear of being punished for being unfair is akin to our seller's fear of tarnishing their reputation.
There is a literature on the ethics of price gouging (e.g., Snyder, 2009), but not much on the empirical issues of price gouging. One exception is given by Neilson (2009), who examines gasoline prices in Bryan/College Station, Texas, during Hurricane Rita. He shows that, while prices increased, margins actually decreased, which is consistent with Rotemberg's (2011) theory of fair pricing. Beatty et al. (2021) find similar evidence for gasoline pricing but in a considerably more systematic way.
Our article is also related to some literature on corporate social responsibility (CSR). In particular, Bénabou and Tirole (2010) present a vision of CSR which essentially corresponds to long‐term corporate decision making. For example, they argue that
a firm could economize on safety or pollution control; this also increases short‐run profits, but creates contingent liabilities down the road: risk of future lawsuits, consumer boycotts and environmental clean‐up costs.
Along these lines, we may think of price gouging as a type of (lack of) CSR, where the corresponding dynamic link is subsequent consumer boycott.
The remainder of the article is structured as follows. The next section provides some basic facts regarding the COVID‐19 crisis. Section 3 lays out the two basic econometric models we propose as a test of the Akerlof (1980) hypothesis. Next, Section 4 describes our data. Our results are included in Section 5. Section 6 concludes the article.
2. THE 2019–2020 COVID‐19 PANDEMIC
The first known COVID‐19 case can be traced back to December 1, 2019, in Wuhan, Hubei, China. The local health authorities released a public notice announcing the new virus on December 31st. Throughout the next month, the virus spread to other Chinese provinces as well as to other countries. The first known US case was confirmed on January 20, 2020, a 35‐year‐old who had returned from Wuhan 5 days earlier. On January 29, the White House Coronavirus Task Force was established, and 2 days later the Trump administration declared a public health emergency. By March 26, the United States had overtaken China and Italy with the highest number of confirmed cases in the world.
As the number of cases increased and media coverage widened, American consumers rushed to stores and online sites in search of personal protective products such as face masks and hand sanitizer. Reports of price gouging soon appeared in the media. For example, a 2 L bottle of Purell sold for as much as $250.
As a result, on March 25th a coalition of 34 attorneys general (AG) sent letters to Amazon, Facebook, Ebay, Walmart, and Craiglist advising them that, “as the American community faces an unprecedented health crisis,” they need to do more to prevent price gouging on their platforms. Two days earlier Amazon had already itself published a statement to the effect that “price gouging has no place in our stores” and further reporting that
Amazon has already removed well over half a million of offers from our stores due to coronavirus‐based price gouging. We have suspended more than 3,900 selling accounts in our U.S. store alone for violating our fair pricing policies. We began taking these enforcement actions promptly upon discovering this kind of misconduct, and we've been partnering directly with law enforcement agencies to combat price gougers and hold them accountable. 4
Notwithstanding Amazon's assurance that they operate “dynamic automated systems” that “locate and remove unfairly priced items,” we observe significant price hikes on Amazon from mid‐January till March. 5 One explanation is that the actual implementation of these mechanisms took place not long before the statement was published.
In other words, as often is the case following a major disaster, there is a period before the law or the market (or both) bring prices to normal levels. Our analysis focuses precisely on this period, the period from the US onset of the COVID‐19 pandemic to March, when we believe Amazon changed its de facto policy. Our goal is to analyze the extent to which different sellers behaved differently. We are particularly interested in testing the prediction that more reputable sellers are less likely to increase prices during the “price gouging” period.
3. MODEL
We wish to test the basic hypothesis that seller reputation moderates the immediate incentive to price gouge. Specifically, we posit that sellers with less to lose in terms of reputation are more likely to price gouge than sellers who have more to lose in terms of reputation. Consistent with this hypothesis, we propose two models, each corresponding to a different way of measuring seller reputation.
3.1. Incumbents and entrants
In the first model, we compare Amazon.com with third‐party sellers, and further distinguish between incumbent and entrant sellers. Amazon is a platform where an item can be sold either by Amazon.com or by a third‐party seller. Amazon.com is the largest seller on Amazon, accounting for roughly 40% of the total sales as of 2019. Though having no clear reputation measures, Amazon.com is widely known to be more reliable than third‐party sellers. Also, for many buyers Amazon.com is effectively a “focal” or “default” seller, a reference point, namely in terms of price.
We separate third‐party sellers into two categories: incumbents and entrants. Incumbent sellers of an item are those who were selling that item from January 1 to January 15, 2020 (that is, before the COVID‐19 US outbreak). 6 By contrast, entrant sellers are those who started selling the item in question after January 16, 2020. Our hypothesis suggests that continuing sellers—who have more at stake than incoming sellers—are less likely to increase prices, or do so by less. 7 Accordingly, our first baseline model takes the form:
(1) |
where i denotes the seller, j the item on sale, and t the day the item is on sale. α j controls for item fixed effects. The value of PriceRijt is defined as
where Amazon19j is item j's average price in 2019 when sold by Amazon.com. In other words, PriceR measures the price ratio between the price at time t and the 2019 price. In a steady state situation, we would expect PriceR to be approximately equal to 1 (except possibly for inflation, which during the period of analysis is minimal, or other exogenous factors). Ii and Ei are indicator variables equal to 1 if seller i is an incumbent seller or an entrant seller, respectively.
The main independent variable is Scarjt, a measure of scarcity of item j in day t. We consider three different scarcity measures, that is, Scar ∈ {S1, S2, S3}. The first measure, S1, is a dummy variable that turns one if Amazon is out of stock of that item on that day:
The idea is that Amazon is generally believed and observed not to price gouge. Moreover, many American buyers use Amazon.com as their primary source. For these reasons, when there is a run‐on a given product Amazon.com is typically the first target and one of the first sellers to run out of stock.
The second measure of scarcity, S2, is defined as
In other words, S2 measures the percentage of item j's sellers during the January 1–15 period who are out of stock at day t. If all sellers active at the beginning of 2020—before the COVID‐19 crisis developed—are stocked at time t, then we say there is no scarcity, that is, S2 equals 0. If none of them is stocked, then we say S2 equals 1, the maximum value. The idea underlying this measure is that, when a large supply or demand shock takes place that results in significant excess demand, speculators get in the scene and price gouge. This results in a high seller turnover rate—entry of speculators, exit of stocked‐out sellers—which in turn results in a high value of S2.
A third possible measure of scarcity, S3, is the cumulative intensity of Google searches, as measured by Google Trends.
where word j relates to the product in question. To maintain consistency across three measures, our Google Trends measure is normalized to the [0, 1] interval.
In order to account for possible endogeneity of prices and scarcity measures, we consider a variety of instruments. Specifically, we consider the logarithm of the number of confirmed COVID‐19 cases and deaths due to COVID‐19 in three different regions: United States, China, and the rest of the world (ROW). One concern of using this set of instruments is the potential impact on prices through competition. To address this issue and to control for competition effects, we include the number of sellers in the regression, which is also instrumented using the same set of instruments.
3.2. Seller history
The distinction between entrant and incumbent provides a first approach at measuring what a seller has to lose from squandering its reputation. However, this is clearly not the only approach. Another possibility is the length of a seller's history. Specifically, we propose the following alternative model:
(2) |
where the main independent variable is log(RCi), the logarithm of seller i's review count. Cabral and Hortaçsu (2010) show that, on eBay, the length of a seller's customer feedback record is a good proxy for the seller's previous sales. In this sense, RCi can be thought of as a proxy of the seller's past experience. The idea is that, the longer a seller's history and/or a seller's size is, the more the seller has to lose from a reputation breakdown, and thus the less the seller is likely to price gouge. Specifically, Akerlof's (1980) hypothesis implies a negative β 3 coefficient: the greater a seller's reputation, the less likely the seller is to increase price as the result of an increase in scarcity. 8
4. DATA
In this section we describe our data. First, we justify our choice of a sample period. Next, we describe the product categories under consideration. Finally, we briefly review some basic descriptive statistics.
4.1. Sample period
As mentioned in the introduction, the first known COVID‐19 case in the United States can be traced back to January 15, 2020. By mid‐March, under pressure from both media and the law, Amazon implemented a series of measures to fight price gougers on its platform. Since we want to study the role of market reputations, we restrict to the period from January 15 to March 25. Our analysis is robust to changing the precise beginning and end dates.
4.2. Product categories
We focus on two categories of consumer goods that are heavily affected by the outbreak of COVID‐19: face masks and hand sanitizers. There are countless items and brands being sold on the market in each of these categories. We focus on the two best known brands: 3M and Purell. We search for 3M face masks and Purell hand sanitizers on Amazon. To exclude illegitimate items and to calculate price margins, we further select items based on the following criteria: First, we restrict to items sold by Amazon.com for at least 7 months during 2019. Second, we also restrict to items with more than three product reviews. 9 Applying these filters, we obtain 31 items, including 14 3M different face masks and 17 different Purell hand sanitizers.
Tables 1 and 2 list the various 3M and Purell products included in our sample. As can be seen, the differences across products (within the same category) correspond primarily to differences in package size.
TABLE 1.
3M 50051138543438 Particulate Respirator 8511, N95 (Pack of 10) |
3M 8210V Particulate Respirator with Cool Flow Valve, Grinding, Sanding, Sawing, Sweeping, Woodworking, Dust, 10/Box |
3M 8233PA1‐A Lead Paint Removal Valved Respirator |
3M 8293 P100 Disposable Particulate Cup Respirator with Cool Flow Exhalation Valve, Standard |
3M 8511 Respirator, N95, Cool Flow Valve (10‐Pack) |
3M 8577CA1‐C‐PS Chemical Odor Valved Respirator, 2‐Pack |
3M 8661PC1‐A Home Dust Mask, 5‐Pack |
3M Air Pollution & Pollen Particulate Respirator, N95, Designed for Smoke and Smog Particles, 2 Pack, Adult |
3M Particulate Respirator 8210PlusPro, N95, Smoke, Dust, Grinding, Sanding, Sawing, Sweeping, 10/Pack |
3M Particulate Respirator 8211, N95 |
3M Particulate Respirator 8247, R95, with Nuisance Level Organic Vapor Relief, 20/Box |
3M Particulate Respirator 8514, N95, with Nuisance Level Organic Vapor Relief |
3M Particulate Respirator 8577, P95, with Nuisance Level Organic Vapor Relief |
3M Particulate Respirator, 8110S, N95, Smoke, Dust, Grinding, Sanding, Sawing, Sweeping, Smaller Size, 20/Pack |
TABLE 2.
PURELL Advanced Green Certified Hand Sanitizer, Gentle & Free Foam, 535 ml EcoLogo Certified Sanitizer Table Top Pump Bottles (Case of 4) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Green Certified Refreshing Gel, Fragrance Free, 12 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 12) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Naturals with Plant Based Alcohol, Citrus Scent, 12 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 2) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Naturals with Plant Based Alcohol, Citrus Scent, 2 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 24) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Naturals with Plant Based Alcohol, Citrus Scent, 2 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 6) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Naturals with Plant Based Alcohol, Citrus Scent, 28 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 4) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Naturals with Plant Based Alcohol, Citrus Scent, 8 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 12) |
Purell Advanced Hand Sanitizer Refreshing Gel 8 oz |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Refreshing Gel, Clean Scent, 2 fl oz Portable Flip Cap Bottle (Pack of 24) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Soothing Gel for the workplace, Fresh scent, with Aloe and Vitamin E—8 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 4) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer Variety Pack, Naturals and Refreshing Gel, 1 fl oz Portable Flip Cap Bottle with JELLY WRAP Carrier (Pack of 36) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer, Refreshing Gel, 2 fl oz Portable, Travel Sized Flip Cap Bottles (Pack of 24) |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer, Refreshing Gel, 36–1 fl oz Portable, Travel Sized Flip Cap Bottles with Display Bowl |
PURELL Advanced Hand Sanitizer, Refreshing Gel, 8 fl oz Sanitizer Table Top Pump Bottles (Pack of 2) |
PURELL Healthcare Advanced Hand Sanitizer Foam, Clean Scent, 18 fl oz Pump Bottle (Pack of 4) |
PURELL Naturals Advanced Hand Sanitizer Gel, with Skin Conditioners and Essential Oils, 12 fl oz Counter Top Pump Bottle (Case of 12) |
PURELL SF607 Advanced Hand Sanitizer Foam, Fragrance Free, 535 ml Sanitizer Counter Top Pump Bottles (Pack of 4) |
We collect price history data and seller characteristics from Keepa, a website that tracks prices of products sold on Amazon. In addition to price, we obtain information on each seller's cumulative number of consumer reviews.
4.3. Descriptive statistics
Table 3 provides basic descriptive statistics of our data. An immediately striking feature is the enormous range in price ratios. For example, 3M masks price ratios vary from 0.74 (lower price in 2020 than in 2019) to a whopping 43.88, a range that would be unusual during normal times. Second, we observe considerable variation in seller size, with an average of about 10,000 reviews but a standard deviation of about 50,000. Our measures of scarcity also vary significantly, in fact S1 and S2 vary from 0 to 1 (S3 varies from 0 to 1 by construction).
TABLE 3.
Variable | # obs. | Mean | SD | Min | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Price (3M) | 13,773 | $45.51 | 29.07 | $6.21 | $349.99 |
Price (Purell) | 9,239 | $51.45 | 35.27 | $2.99 | $199.99 |
PriceR (3M) | 13,773 | 2.72 | 1.77 | 0.74 | 43.88 |
PriceR (Purell) | 9,239 | 1.82 | 1.02 | 0.49 | 17.50 |
RC | 961 | 10,600 | 51,558 | 0 | 954,539 |
log(RC) | 961 | 5.42 | 3.22 | 0 | 13.76 |
S1 | 2,697 | 0.64 | 0.47 | 0 | 1 |
S2 | 1,956 | 0.51 | 0.39 | 0 | 1 |
S3 | 180 | 0.23 | 0.24 | 0 | 1 |
Instruments | |||||
Cases (China) | 88 | 44,785 | 36,282 | 0 | 81,999 |
Deaths (China) | 88 | 1,544 | 1,382 | 0 | 3,299 |
Cases (US) | 88 | 6,774 | 21,357 | 0 | 121,478 |
Deaths (US) | 88 | 101 | 327 | 0 | 2,026 |
Cases (ROW) | 88 | 42,138 | 95,986 | 0 | 457,229 |
Deaths (ROW) | 88 | 1,996 | 5,068 | 0 | 25,327 |
In order to get a better idea of the evolution of scarcity, Figure 1 plots our three measures of scarcity over the first 3 months of 2020. 10 As can be seen, S1 and S2 are highly correlated, with a sharp increase during the last weeks of January. The third measure, by contrast, is less correlated and also more volatile. For example, there is a significant spike in Google searches for masks in end of February, whereas searches for hand sanitizers peaked in mid‐March.
5. RESULTS
We finally come to our results. We structure this section as follows. First, we present some preliminary aggregate analysis of the change in prices by type of seller. This preliminary analysis suggests that there are significant differences between low‐reputation and high‐reputation sellers. We then turn to formal regression analysis, including IV regression (to account for endogeneity of scarcity as well as the number of sellers) and quantify the extent to which reputation acts as a moderator of the effect of scarcity on price. Finally, we consider various robustness tests and extensions of our basic results.
5.1. Preliminary summary statistical analysis
As a preliminary stage in our analysis, Table 4 shows some basic descriptive statistics of our price data. Price ratios are defined with respect to Amazon's 2019 prices. For this reason, the values in the third are equal to 1 by construction. The remaining columns show that, in 2019, third‐party sellers were selling for about 60% higher prices than Amazon. In 2020, Amazon set prices slightly higher than in the previous year (about 3–4%). By contrast, third‐party sellers' markup with respect to Amazon increased from about 60% to about 141% (masks) and 72% (hand sanitizer).
TABLE 4.
# | 2019 | 2020 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Brand | Items | Amazon | Third‐party | Amazon | Third‐party |
3M | 14 | 1.00 | 1.60 | 1.04 | 2.41 |
Purell | 17 | 1.00 | 1.57 | 1.03 | 1.72 |
To further decompose the price changes, we divide 2020 into two time periods: before and after the US outbreak of COVID‐19, which we place at January 16, 2020. Table 5 largely confirms our prior from Akerlof's (1980) theory: incumbent sellers set a price close to twice the Amazon 2019 price, whereas entrants set a price that was on average between three to four times higher than Amazon's 2019 price.
TABLE 5.
Before outbreak | After outbreak | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | Min | Max | Mean | Min | Max | |
Amazon.com | 0.99 | 0.54 | 1.6 | 1.08 | 0.54 | 1.92 |
Third‐party (incumbent sellers) | 1.68 | 0.67 | 6.03 | 1.95 | 0.49 | 14.71 |
Third‐party (entrant sellers) | – | – | – | 3.69 | 0.66 | 43.88 |
Figures 2 and 3 further extend the analysis by plotting price ratios over time by type of seller. We only plot price data when an item is in stock. Since Amazon's items moved frequently between in and out of stock, we plot Amazon's data as a scatter plot. As for third‐party sellers, we observe that there is a clearly defined date when they become out of stock. Accordingly, we plot a continuous price ratio line until that date. For example, 3M mask incumbent sellers (left panel in Figure 2) run out of stock on March 12, about the same time as Amazon, whereas entrant sellers run out of stock on March 25.
In Figure 2 we distinguish between incumbents and entrants. (Recall that entrants are sellers who begin to sell after the first US COVID‐19 case.) Both for masks and for hand sanitizer the data clearly shows that (a) on average third‐party sellers charge a higher price than Amazon; and, more important, (b) within third‐party sellers, entrants are particularly prone to charge higher prices. For masks, our rough estimate is that entrants charge approximately twice as much as incumbents. For hand sanitizer, the difference varies a lot over time, but generally speaking—and with the exception of early February—entrants charge higher prices than incumbents.
While it makes sense to think of incumbents as having more to lose than entrants, presumably some of the entrants could be very large sellers who, not having a specific history in selling masks or purifiers, have a long history of selling on Amazon. To account for this possibility, we consider a second measure of seller reputation, customer review count. In Figure 3, we distinguish between high‐RC sellers (RC greater than 1,000) and low‐RC sellers (RC less than 1,000). Similar to the incumbent/entrant split, we see that, for masks, on average low‐RC sellers set considerably higher prices than high‐RC sellers. Regarding hand sanitizer, while the difference is not as clear‐cut as in the case of masks, the pattern of higher prices by low‐RC sellers persists.
5.2. Regression analysis results
Our systematic regression analysis is guided by a series of choices. First, we consider two possible measures of seller “reputation,” that is, measures of what sellers have to lose from consumer boycott. These measures are (a) whether the seller is an incumbent or an entrant (all else equal, incumbents have more to lose); and (b) a seller's cumulative number of reviews (all else equal, a seller with a larger number of reviews—a proxy for seller size—has more to lose).
Second, we consider three measures of scarcity: (a) a dummy variable indicating whether Amazon is stocked out, (b) the fraction of incumbent sellers who are out of stock, and (c) the intensity of Google searches for the relevant term.
Finally, in order to account for possible endogeneity, we consider both OLS and IV regressions, where the instruments correspond to COVID‐19‐related cases and deaths in the United States, China, and the ROW.
All in all, this corresponds to a large number of regressions. In all of them, the dependent variable is a seller's price for a given product at a given date (measured as a price ratio with respect to Amazon's 2019 price). We organize the regressions as follows. Table 6 explores the contrast between incumbent and entrant sellers relative to prices charged by Amazon.com, whereas Table 7 focuses on a seller's size as measured by its prior review count. In each case, we consider 12 different regression models, corresponding to three scarcity variables times two regression methods (OLS and IV) with different sets of controls.
TABLE 6.
Scarcity measure 1 | Scarcity measure 2 | Scarcity measure 3 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
Scarcity × Amazon | 0.328*** | 0.267*** | 1.444*** | 1.534*** | ||
(0.08) | (0.08) | (0.30) | (0.30) | |||
Scarcity × Incumbent | 0.427*** | 0.506*** | 0.910*** | 0.931*** | 2.872*** | 2.915*** |
(0.02) | (0.02) | (0.02) | (0.03) | (0.08) | (0.08) | |
Scarcity × Entrant | 0.624*** | 0.690*** | 1.343*** | 1.312*** | 3.146*** | 3.226*** |
(0.03) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.04) | (0.10) | (0.10) | |
Constant | 2.548*** | 2.520*** | 2.780*** | 2.862*** | 3.393*** | 3.351*** |
(0.50) | (0.50) | (0.49) | (0.48) | (0.49) | (0.48) | |
Item FE | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Seller FE | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Control – number of sellers | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Model | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV |
N | 22,986 | 22,986 | 22,986 | 22,986 | 22,986 | 22,986 |
R 2 | 0.807 | 0.804 | 0.815 | 0.813 | 0.813 | 0.812 |
Notes: p levels: .01 (***), .05 (**), and .1 (*).
TABLE 7.
Scarcity measure 1 | Scarcity measure 2 | Scarcity measure 3 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
Review count | −0.011*** | 0.018*** | 0.006 | 0.023*** | 0.008** | 0.047*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Scarcity | 2.023*** | 2.905*** | 2.875*** | 3.262*** | 8.235*** | 10.462*** |
(0.04) | (0.06) | (0.05) | (0.07) | (0.12) | (0.17) | |
Review count × Scarcity | −0.118*** | −0.158*** | −0.140*** | −0.182*** | −0.358*** | −0.553*** |
(0.00) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.02) | |
Constant | 2.622*** | 2.133*** | 2.975*** | 2.960*** | 3.248*** | 2.908*** |
(0.05) | (0.06) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.04) | (0.05) | |
Item FE | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Control – number of sellers | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Model | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV |
N | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 |
R 2 | 0.524 | 0.475 | 0.564 | 0.555 | 0.576 | 0.569 |
Notes: p levels: .01 (***), .05 (**), and .1 (*).
Consider first the coefficient estimates displayed in Table 6, where we focus on the distinction between incumbent sellers and entrant sellers. As predicted by theory, the impact of scarcity on prices is greater for third‐party sellers than for Amazon. And, more important, within third‐party sellers, the effect is greater for entrants than for incumbents. Consider for example the IV regression using the S1 scarcity measure (Amazon is stocked out) in column 4. When Amazon stocks out, entrants increase price by the equivalent of 178% of 2019's price, whereas the incumbents' increase corresponds to 56.7%. This is consistent with the idea that entrants have less to lose from ruining their reputation than incumbents have.
An alternative way of measuring the desired effect is to consider a one‐standard deviation change in the independent variable. From Table 3, we see that the standard deviation of S1 is given by 0.47. This implies that a one‐standard deviation in S1 is associated with a change in an entrant's price equal to 84% of Amazon's 2019 price, whereas for an incumbent the number is 27%. The standard deviation of S2 is given by 0.39. We thus estimate that a one‐standard deviation increase in S2 leads entrants to increase in price by 1.312 × 0.39 = 0.88, or about 88% of the 2019 price. By contrast, incumbents increase price by 0.931 × 0.39 = 0.36, or 36% of the 2019 price. The corresponding values for S3 are and 141% and 69% for entrants and incumbents, respectively.
In sum, we estimate that a one‐standard deviation increase in scarcity leads incumbents to increase price by 27–69%, whereas entrants increase price by 84–141%. Although the numbers do vary a bit according to the scarcity measure we use, we note that they are broadly speaking of the same order of magnitude and, more important, the estimate is economically and statistically greater for entrants than it is for incumbents.
Consider now the coefficient estimates displayed in Table 7, where we focus on a seller's reputation count. Our hypothesis predicts that sellers with higher reputation counts have more to lose and are thus less likely to increase prices. In terms of regression coefficients, we predict a negative coefficient on the interaction of scarcity and review counts.
The regression results confirm this expectation: all estimation coefficients of the interaction review count times scarcity are negative. Moreover, the coefficients are significant from both a statistical and an economic perspective. From Table 3, the mean value of the scarcity measures is given by 0.64, 0.51, and 0.23. Moreover, the standard deviation of log (RC) is 3.32. Restricting to IV regressions with full sets of controls, we see that a one‐standard deviation increase in log (RC) leads to a decrease of 33.6% in the effect of scarcity (measured by S1) on the price ratio. In other words, reputation—as measured by log (RC)—acts as a moderator of the effect of scarcity on prices. The corresponding values for S2 and S3 are 30.8% and 42.2%. Again, the fact these estimates fall within a reasonably tight range gives us confidence regarding our measurement of scarcity.
5.3. Extensions and robustness tests
We performed a series of robustness tests in terms of variable definitions and sample period. One possible limitation of our test of the reputation theory is that different sellers have different costs. In particular, it could be the case that higher‐reputation seller costs vary by less than lower‐reputation seller costs. If that were the case, then our results might indicate differences in costs, not differences in reputation strategy. One way to address this possibility is to control for supply shocks by using prices of items that are not related to COVID. Our main results—both the sign and the statistical significance of the key parameter estimates—are robust to including such controls.
One interesting extension of our analysis consists in combining our two approaches to measuring seller reputation: the distinction between incumbent and entrant; and the cumulative number of buyer reviews. Specifically, we consider the following model, which basically combines (1) and (2)
(3) |
The question of interest now is whether β 5 positive or negative, that is, whether the moderating factor of seller history, log (RC), differs from incumbent and entrant sellers.
Table 8 displays the estimates corresponding to (3). As before, we consider three different measures of scarcity (S1, S2, and S3) and two regression types (OLS and IV). Restricting to the set of IV regressions with full sets of controls, we see that the coefficient estimate of the interaction variable log(RCi) ⋅ Scarjt ⋅ Ei is statistically significant. In all three cases, the coefficient is positive, indicating that the moderating factor of log (RC) is greater for incumbents than for entrants. This suggests that reputational concerns play a more important role for incumbents or large/old sellers than for entrants in terms of moderating the incentives for price gouging.
TABLE 8.
Scarcity measure 1 | Scarcity measure 2 | Scarcity measure 3 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
Review count | −0.002 | 0.016*** | 0.010*** | 0.021*** | 0.016*** | 0.050*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Scarcity | 1.221*** | 2.305*** | 2.600*** | 2.618*** | 6.419*** | 9.499*** |
(0.05) | (0.09) | (0.07) | (0.10) | (0.14) | (0.24) | |
Entrant | 0.961*** | 0.330*** | 0.106** | 0.361*** | 0.572*** | −0.038 |
(0.04) | (0.07) | (0.04) | (0.07) | (0.03) | (0.06) | |
Review Count × Scarcity | −0.078*** | −0.157*** | −0.181*** | −0.180*** | −0.353*** | −0.702*** |
(0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.03) | |
Review Count × Scarcity × Entrant | 0.001 | 0.062*** | 0.104*** | 0.062*** | 0.091*** | 0.362*** |
(0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.03) | |
Constant | 2.748*** | 2.441*** | 2.985*** | 2.964*** | 3.091*** | 2.936*** |
(0.05) | (0.06) | (0.05) | (0.05) | (0.04) | (0.05) | |
Item FE | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Control – number of sellers | x | x | x | x | x | x |
Model | OLS | IV | OLS | IV | OLS | IV |
N | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 | 22,044 |
R 2 | 0.562 | 0.535 | 0.581 | 0.575 | 0.595 | 0.579 |
Notes: p levels: .01 (***), .05 (**), and .1 (*).
6. CONCLUSION
The COVID‐19 pandemic has resulted in emergency declarations in most US states. These declarations have the effect of triggering anti‐price gouging statutes. These statutes suffer from several limitations. First, as many economists point out, they may defeat the incentive effect of prices, in particular the incentive to increase supply. Second, they can be rather vague (to the extent that they refer, for example, to terms such as “reasonable” price increases or “necessary” goods and services).
Free‐market proponents suggest that seller reputation may substitute for regulation when it comes to preventing price gouging, possibly to the point of rendering anti‐price gouging unnecessary. Our evidence suggests that seller reputation does act as a limit on how much sellers price‐gouge: Higher‐reputation sellers are less likely to take advantage of shortages of supply. The effect is statistically significant. However, our analysis also suggests that these reputation effects are far from sufficient to limit the extent of price gouging.
In their letter to Amazon and other sellers, a group of 34 AG recommended that the platform
Set policies and enforce restrictions on unconscionable price gouging during emergencies: Online retail platforms should prevent unconscionable price increases from occurring by creating and enforcing strong policies that prevent sellers from deviating in any significant way from the product's price before an emergency. Such policies should examine historical seller prices, and the price offered by other sellers of the same or similar products, to identify and eliminate price gouging.
Our results suggest one specific way cross‐seller price comparison can be made, namely with respect to incumbent sellers. In other words, a possible implementation of the AG recommendation is that, once an emergency period is triggered, new sellers be prevented from selling at a higher price than incumbent sellers. While this would not eliminate price increases, we suggest that it might significantly reduce their extent.
Admittedly, one weakness of this argument is that the price set by incumbent sellers is an equilibrium price, and running a counterfactual without a model is a dangerous exercise. It is possible that, absent the high prices set by entering firms, incumbents would themselves price higher than otherwise. This would defeat the purpose of the proposed rule.
Moreover, there is nothing in the AG argument or in our proposal that shows consumers would be better off by preventing price gouging. As mentioned in the introduction, it is not our purpose to provide a welfare analysis of price gouging or the efforts to prevent it. Such analysis would require considerably more and better data, at the very least data on sales and seller characteristics.
Supporting information
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Views presented in this article are those of the authors, and do not represent the Bank of Canada's views. We are grateful to the editor and three referees for helpful comments and suggestions.
Cabral, L. & Xu, L. (2021) Seller reputation and price gouging: Evidence from the COVID‐19 pandemic. Economic Inquiry, 59:867–879. 10.1111/ecin.12993
Endnotes
Most states in the United States have some form of anti‐gouging law or regulation (Rapp, 2006). Some of these statutes impose explicit percentage limits on post‐disaster price hikes. Others bar “unconscionable” price hikes, with varying definitions of what price hikes are “unconscionable”—often rather vague definitions.
The reputation dynamics literature (e.g., Board & Meyer‐ter‐Vehn, 2013) shows that, at a theoretical level, the relation between reputation and effort to maintain reputation may go both ways (i.e., may be increasing or decreasing). However, at an empirical level, papers like Cabral and Hortaçsu (2010) show that the relation is positive, that is, sellers with higher reputation levels exert greater effort. This is also consistent with the evidence from the present article.
Similarly, while fairness and unfairness relate primarily to the margin set be the seller, anti‐price gouging laws make reference to price levels for the simple reason that prices are more easily measured than margins.
https://blog.aboutamazon.com/company-news/price-gouging-has-no-place-in-our-stores, visited on March 26, 2020.
Throughout the article, we refer to prices of items actually on sale, that is, we exclude prices of stocked‐out items.
We considered alternative definition of incumbent sellers. The estimation results are robust to these changes.
A tantalizing possibility is that incumbent sellers create a separate identity so as to increase prices without damaging their current reputation. For a theoretical treatment of this possibility, see section 3.3.1. in Cabral (2005). Unfortunately, given the nature of our data we are unable to estimate the extent to which this entry strategy takes place. That said, our basic hypothesis would remain that entrants—be they genuine new entrants or masquerading incumbents—would be more likely to increase prices.
Note that Amazon.com is excluded in this analysis because the review count is only available for third‐party sellers.
Other selection criteria are used as a robustness test. Our main results do not change significantly.
Our first measure, the dummy variable which turns 1 when Amazon is out of stock, only takes two values. The time series in Figure 1 corresponds to the fraction of products—within a given category—for which Amazon is out of stock.
REFERENCES
- Akerlof, G.A. (1980) A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(4), 749–775. [Google Scholar]
- Beatty, T.K.M. , Lade, G.E. & Shimshack, J. (2021) Hurricanes and gasoline price gouging. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economics, 8, 347–374. [Google Scholar]
- Bénabou, R. & Tirole, J. (2010) Individual and corporate social responsibility. Economica, 77(305), 1–19. [Google Scholar]
- Board, S. & Meyer‐ter‐Vehn, M. (2013) Reputation for quality. Econometrica, 81(6), 2381–2462. [Google Scholar]
- Cabral, L . (2005) The economics of reputation and trust . Available at: http://luiscabral.net/economics/books/reputation/ [Accessed June 8, 2020].
- Cabral, L. & Hortaçsu, A. (2010) The dynamics of seller reputation: evidence from eBay. Journal of Industrial Economics, 58, 54–78. [Google Scholar]
- Cowen, T . (2017) Price gouging can be a type of hurricane aid. Bloomberg Opinion (September 5).
- Culpepper, D. & Block, W. (2008) Price gouging in the Katrina aftermath: free markets at work. International Journal of Social Economics, 35(7), 512–520. [Google Scholar]
- Kahneman, D. , Knetsch, J.L. & Thaler, R. (1986) Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76(4), 728–741. [Google Scholar]
- Neilson, H. (2009) Price gouging versus price reduction in retail gasoline markets during hurricane Rita. Economics Letters, 105(1), 11–13. [Google Scholar]
- Rapp, G.C. (2006) Gouging: terrorist attacks, hurricanes, and the legal and economic aspects of post‐disaster price regulation. Kentucky Law Journal, 94, 535–560. [Google Scholar]
- Rotemberg, J.J. (2011) Fair pricing. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(5), 952–981. [Google Scholar]
- Snyder, J. (2009) What's the matter with price gouging? Business Ethics Quarterly, 19, 275–293. [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.